SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 10
Download to read offline
International relations: historical aspects



INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS:
HISTORICAL ASPECTS


UDK 338(091)

                                             Recent decades have witnessed an in-
THE FEATURES                            crease in the number of works dedicated to
OF CHOOSING                             the analysis of effects of historical events on
AN INSTITUTIONAL                        the choice of institutions and further econo-
                                        mic and social development of regions. This
DEVELOPMENT                             article employs the new institutional econo-
TRAJECTORY                              mic theory approach to consider the choices
IN EASTERN EUROPE                       regarding title to land and serfdom in Mos-
         th  th                         covy and the Polish — Lithuanian Com-
IN THE 16 —17                           monwealth (earlier the Grand Duchy of Li-
CENTURIES:                              thuania) in the 16th—17th centuries. The author
                                        emphasizes the factors, which affected the
MOSCOVY AND
                                        choice of institutional development trajectory,
THE POLISH—LITHUANIAN                   and considers the influence exerted by these
                                        institutes on the political and military devel-
COMMONWEALTH                            opment of these states. This article shows
                                        how the contingent property rights in Mosco-
                                        vy turned out to be competitive in the condi-
M. S. Vdovin*                           tions of a considerable contribution of decen-
                                        tralisation factors to defence capacity and,
                                        opposite to the situation in the Polish — Li-
                                        thuanian Commonwealth, ensured the forma-
                                        tion of large and efficient troops. This work
                                        contributes to the research on the property
                                        rights and Russian economic history.

                                             Key words: institutional economy, histo-
                                        rical analysis, serfdom, property rights, Mos-
                                        covy, Polish — Lithuanian Commonwealth

                                            The recent decades have witnessed an
                                        increase in the number of works dedi-
                                        cated to the analysis of the influence of
                                        historical events on institutional choices
* National research university          and further economic and social devel-
‘Higher school of economics’            opment of regions. This line of research
20, Myasnitskaya Ul., Moscow,
101000, Russia.                         is called New Institutional Economic His-
                                        tory, NIEH1. The principal conclusion
Received on June 08, 2012.              drawn by scholars in the framework of

1
    A detailed review of works on NIEH is given in [1; 2].

90
M. S. Vdovin


NIEH is that history “matters”. Different exogenous factors (natural re-
sources, climate, legal institutions established in the course of colonization,
political inequality) relate to the choice of institutions (first of all, the institu-
tion of proprietary rights), which, in their turn affect the economic develop-
ment.
    This work considers from the perspective of the NIEH approach the fea-
tures of the choice of fundamental institutions in Moscovy and the Polish—
Lithuanian Commonwealth (earlier the Grand Duchy of Lithuania) in the
16th—17th centuries, namely the regime of proprietary rights to land and serf-
dom and identifies the factors that affected this choice. Throughout the pe-
riod under consideration, Moscovy and the Polish—Lithuanian Common-
wealth were the key actors on the military and political map of Eastern Eu-
rope and long-standing religious opponents. Alongside the political, military,
and religious aspects of the competition, one can also speak of the competi-
tion at the institutional level. In this case, the competition is understood not
as a direct collision of institutions, but their diverse effect on the social and
political and military spheres leading to different economic and military con-
sequences, and, as a result, to a wider distribution or, on the contrary, aban-
donment of such institutions.
    In the course of the 16th—17th centuries, the institutional choice in the
states considered was made for two principal markets — those of land and
labour. The institutional decision was a choice between two alternatives for
each market: free labour — non-free labour (serfdom) and unconditional
ownership (patrimonial land tenure) — conditional ownership (manorial
land tenure). History shows that the choice was different for Moscovy and
the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth. Whereas both states chose non-free
labour (this choice was affected by several factors), as to the regime of pro-
prietary rights, the choices were opposite: in Moscovy, contingent proprie-
tary rights were widely spread, whereas in the Polish-Lithuanian Common-
wealth, they were replaced by vested ones. These features of institutional
development require a further explanation, which can be provided through
an analysis of historical development alternatives.

               Serfdom and manorial land tenure as a social contract

    From the perspective of an institutional analysis, the establishment of
serfdom and development of manorial land tenure characteristic, for exam-
ple, of Muscovy can be considered as a conclusion of a tacit social contract
between the supreme ruler and the nobility. To this effect, the supreme ruler
restricts proprietary rights to land, undermines the authority of large patri-
monial landowners (monasteries, nobility) and, relying on the interests of a
different group - manorial land owners - becomes a chief landowner. The in-
troduction of serfdom, which resulted in the restriction of mobility of peas-
ants and establishment of monopsony in the labour market, was a necessary
step to support landowners as a loyal interest group, which received in the

                                                                                   91
International relations: historical aspects


conditions of serfdom the surplus of peasant labour. In return, landowners
agree to waive certain rights to land and yield the political function, con-
tenting themselves with military and administrative services.
    The social contract will persist (i. e. contingent proprietary rights will do-
minate and serfdom will be established), if it proves to be profitable for the
mentioned interest groups — the supreme ruler and the nobility. Otherwise,
the social contract will be denounced, and contingent proprietary right to
land and serfdom will cease to be equal institutions.
    Let us identify what factors supported the tacit contract. Landowners will
be more interested in maintaining the contract, if the area of ploughed fields
and grain prices are increasing. In this case, they get an opportunity to multi-
ply their profit; hence, they are more encouraged to maintain the contract.
High costs of military service (the obligation to take part in campaigns,
equipping themselves and servants), on the contrary, are poor incentives: if
the costs are too big, they can outweigh the monopsony profit of the land-
owner generated from the allocated land. Finally, there is a system of repres-
sive measures and non-economic costs for evaders and traitors (reputation,
moral and religious repercussions): if the punishment for apostasy is sub-
stantial and very probable, incentives to maintaining the contract increase
and persist, even when the monopsony income of the landowner generated
by serfs is not very high2.
    Another interest of the supreme ruler is the formation of a large and ef-
fective army. Thus, he is interested in manorial tenure: in this case, the ruler
gets an opportunity to form a large army rapidly without spending personal
and public funds, since landowners take on the obligation to serve through
accepting their lands. The incentives for maintaining manorial tenure in-
crease when the contribution of decentralised factors (landowner regimenta-
tion, cavalry) into the defence potential is considerable. And, vice versa, as
military profession develops and the significance of centralised factors (artil-
lery, regiments of the “new order”) increases — when the strength of the army
becomes less important than its infrastructure, training, and discipline, — the
incentives for the supreme ruler to maintain the social contract decrease.
    Now let us focus on how the features of the institutional choice of Mus-
covy and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth can be interpreted from the
perspective of this approach.

     Land ownership and the establishment of serfdom in Muscovy

     The 16th century divides Russian history into two completely different
parts — the feudal and Moscovian, which were characterised, inter alia, by
the opposite types of land relations — patrimonial and manorial land tenure.
It is the 15th century, when the institution of contingent manorial land tenure

2
 A more detailed analysis of incentives for landowners and the supreme ruler to
maintain the social contract in Muscovy is given in [3].

92
M. S. Vdovin


gained grounds, which formed the bases of the military and service class or-
ganisation of Muscovy. This watershed is manifested in the wills of Moscow
princes. Dmitry of the Don guaranteed his boyars the rights to their land and
acknowledges them as absolute owners (14th century):

            …with your assistance strengthened I the grand duchy, and brought
        peace and quiet, and kept the land of my fathers… and I did not do evil to any
        of you, nor took anything away by force, nor offended you, nor plundered,
        not disorder… thus, I call you not the boyars, but the princes of my land [4,
        p. 398].

    However, just two centuries later, Ivan the Terrible writes in his letter to
the Polish king Sigismund Augustus in his peculiar manner about the chan-
ges that had taken place in Muscovy:

            …our unfettered stardom of great sovereigns is not like your pitiful king-
        dom; our great sovereigns are never instructed by anyone, but your lords or-
        der you as they please… our sovereigns are autocrats and no one can order
        them, and they are free to pardon or execute [4, p. 408].

    The manorial systems suddenly emerged in Muscovy under Ivan III at
the end of the 15th century and started to develop rapidly [5]. The establish-
ment of manorial system is explained by contemporaries and historians by
taking after the Ottoman Empire [6; 7], and the period of development of
Muscovy in the 15th century was the time of adopting Turkish ways and
transforming Russia according to the Ottoman model [8].
    The final formation of the manorial system under Ivan the Terrible,
when the order and principle of cavalry, recruit, and arms services provided
by lands were settled, gave rise to the formation of one of the largest armies
of the time, which could be compared only to the sultan’s army. As contem-
poraries reported, whereas earlier, the army of the Moscow tsar was rather
small, under Ivan the Terrible, when each nobleman could bring one or two
“fighting serfs”, it reached the strength of 80,000 people and, according to
some accounts (which can be exaggerated), there were two armies of
100,000 people each [9; 10]. So, the task of increasing the military potential
was solved, and Muscovy safeguarded its sovereignty and got an opportunity
to further territorial expansion. In the conditions of significant influence of
decentralised factors on defence potential, the supreme ruler was especially
interested in the formation of a large manorial army and, as a result, had suf-
ficient incentives to maintain the “land for service” social contract.
    There were equal incentives for landowners to maintain the tacit con-
tract. Firstly, it was them who were granted new manors as a result of mili-
tary campaigns and territorial expansion in the 16th century. The establish-
ment of serfdom was necessary to eliminate the competition between landlords
for peasants in the conditions of the territorial expansion and prevent peasant
escapes. This conclusion corresponds to E. Domar’s hypothesis about the im-
pact of land surplus on the development of serfdom in Russia [11].

                                                                                   93
International relations: historical aspects


    Secondly, the principle of the army formation was established from as
early as Ivan the Terrible’s services code: a landowner had to provide one
soldier from each 150 dessiatinas3 of land and be present at the inspection
with horses, people, and arms. It is worth noting that the obligations of a
landowner depended on the area of land he possessed, which settled the costs
of military services and ensured that the social contract was maintained.
    Finally, in the 16th century, the evasion of service started to be consid-
ered not as a simple refusal to conclude a contract between a free and inde-
pendent landowner and the supreme ruler, but as treason. The punishment
for apostasy (confiscation of property, plunder of the manor) could be an
important incentive to maintain the social contract, which was supplemented
by different kinds of non-economic coercion. It could result in significant
reputation costs for the landowner, which kept him from violating the “land
for service” agreement. So, when entering the service of the Moscow king,
the contract was supposed to be reinforced by kissing the cross and guaran-
tees from a metropolitan and people in service. The ones who wanted to
leave this “cartel”, would face both religious punishment and the breach of
relations with the “colleagues”.
    The establishment of such a system in Muscovy was probably inter-
preted as (and actually was) the best decision in the struggle for sovereignty
and safety of residents. However, one should not consider the Ottoman alter-
native the only one available at the time. Muscovy also interacted with other
states and could consider as an alternative to the “authority-property” institu-
tion the institution of private property, which gained grounds in Livonia and
the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth. The reason for the variant being re-
jected might have been confessional tensions, since the Grand Duchy of
Lithuania was a Catholic state and, from the perspective of Moscow princes
was an opponent to orthodoxy [12]. At the same time, the military advan-
tages of the Turkish model were so obvious that one could easily ignore that
it was adopted from “pagans”.

             Serfdom 2.0 in the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth
                   (the former Grand Duchy of Lithuania)

     The case of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth shows that there were
alternative paths of institutional development. Unlike Muscovy, an increase
in feudal land tenure in this region related to the reinforcement of owner’s
rights and the development of vested property rights. The lack of strong cen-
tral authority contributed to the strengthening of knighthood. As a result of
weak central authority, the social contract could not be maintained by effi-
cient enforcement from the state. Contingent property rights did not gain
such vast grounds in the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth as in Muscovy.
Large vassals managed to secure privileged rights to fief, which ensured the
patrimonial right to the land.

3
    Translator’s note: an obsolete Russian measure of land, roughly 1.1 hectares.

94
M. S. Vdovin


     Against the background of the development of vested land right regime,
peasants are turned to surfs. It was a variation of the Roman slavery system,
and economy acquires market and export character not unlike that of the
Southern United States. As early as the 1530s — 1540s, the price revolution
taking place in Western Europe (increase in the prices for bread, flax, hemp,
cattle) resulted in the development of the corvee labour system of feudal
economy. Feudal lords use the external factor, adding to their income gener-
ated through in-kind and monetary inflows from peasants, income from
manors, and export of grain to England and Holland. The structure of manor
incomes started to be dominated not by income from peasants (agricultural
products and money), but that from the manor itself. At the same time, grain
accounted for 70—90 % of the manor income; and 40—50 % of the harvest
yielded by large manors was exported. The trend towards the strengthening
of corvee and serfdom was most pronounced in the regions in the vicinity of
floatable rivers: the location in proximity to export ports (Narva, Tallinn,
Pärnu, Riga) and the convenience of water and land freight was an additional
incentive for landowners [13].
     The high bread prices and serfdom scenario was characteristic of many
countries of Eastern Europe (the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth, Bohe-
mia, Prussia, Pomerania). Unlike the Moscovite serfdom, the market and
private property institutions were rather widespread there, and the revival of
serfdom in these countries is explained traditionally by the growing demand
for bread [14]. The reinforcement of serfdom was manifested in the aspira-
tion of feudal lords to eliminate the peasant’s right to leave manors and find
ways to prevent escapes. However, unlike other states (for instance, Mus-
covy), where the strong central authority took care of the interests of the no-
bility, legislation on peasant escapees turned into territorial intraclass agree-
ments (for example, "einigungen" in Livonia). The struggle for peasants be-
tween landowners escalated in the periods of plunders, for instance, in the
course of the Livonian War. Thus, feudal lords concluded private contracts,
taking on the obligation not to entice someone else’s serfs and return them to
the owner in case they come of their own accord. So, the need for the forced
return of escapees resulted in the establishment of a special police and judi-
cial mechanism of Hackengerichts, which, nevertheless, were of a local ra-
ther than nationwide nature [15].
     So, under the influence of external factors (high prices for exported
grain), the landowners of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth managed to
establish a monopsony in the labour market without the interference of the
state and conclusion of a social contract, which resulted in the emergence of
serfdom 2.0. It substantiated the above mentioned idea that, against the
background of rising prices the product of labour, the profit of a monopson-
ist increases alongside the incentives for landowners to establish serfdom. At
the same time, the absence of strong state authority was an obstacle to a
change in the land right regime towards contingent rights. The nobility and
gentry, as the dominant political force, were interested in securing their lands
and could generate a monopsony profit through reviving serfdom without
involving the state.

                                                                              95
International relations: historical aspects




         Competition between institutions and the consequences
                       of the institutional choice

    The comparative analysis of development of land tenure rights and the
reasons for the emergence of serfdom makes it possible to identify the key
factors of maintaining the “land for service” social contract and explain the
features of the institution development in Muscovy and the Polish-
Lithuanian Commonwealth (table).

              The significance of factors affecting the maintenance
                     of the “land for service” social contract

                                     The “land for service” social
                                                                         Social contract
                                       contract is maintained
                                                                        is not maintained
                                           (contingent land
             Factor                                                      (only serfdom)
                                          rights + serfdom)
                                                                       Polish-Lithuanian
                                              Muscovy
                                                                        Commonwealth
Resource allotment (availability
of unoccupied lands for allo-                     +                               —
cating in exchange for service)
Strong central authority                          +                               —
The development of a strata inte-
                                                  —                                +
rested in vested property rights
Export-oriented production (grain)                —                                +
Considerable contribution of de-
centralised factors into defence                  +                               —
potential

    The historical consequences of the institutional choice in the states under
consideration are neither easily predictable, nor logical. The case of the Po-
lish-Lithuanian Commonwealth shows that the spread of “good” institutions
of vested land rights ensuring the protection of property rights and incentives
to investment is not the only and sufficient factor of long-term economic de-
velopment.
    The weakness of state authority results in the division of the history of
the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth in two stages: the “golden age” of
Polish nobility following the signing of the Union of Lublin in 1569 (the es-
tablishment of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth) and a series of mili-
tary defeats in the 17th century (by Bohdan Khmelnitsky’s Cossacks, the
Swedish Deluge) and resulting in three divisions of Poland in the late 18th
century and the fall of the empire. The predominance of export-oriented ag-
riculture and the establishment of serfdom allowed the nobility to generate
monopsonic income, which was directed to internal consumption (for exam-
ple, luxury goods). Unlike Muscovy, the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth

96
M. S. Vdovin


did not maintain a social contract between the supreme ruler and landow-
ners. In the field of politics, the nobility pursued narrow intraclass interests,
focused on solving local problems, which made it possible to increase per-
sonal income, rather than state affairs, first of all, the defence potential.
     By the mid-17th century, after a series of heavy defeats, the military inef-
ficiency of the Polish-Lithuanian nobility becomes evident. The Polish ca-
valry and the famous Polish “winged” hussars could hardly meet the new
warfare conditions — sieges and attacks of musket-armed infantry. The lack
of strong central authority, when the king “reigned but not ruled” and the
nobility was convinced of stability of their financial and political freedoms,
resulted in the crown not having enough funds for army reforms [16]. In the
conditions, when the neighbouring absolute monarchies conducted active
army modernisation (for example, the Swedish king Karl Gustav, having un-
derstood that the Polish cavalry is not to be defeated by being outnumbered,
focused on improving discipline and developing artillery), Poland had nei-
ther financial, nor political resources to reform its army. As a result, by the
end of 18th century, the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth ceased to be an
independent state and turned from one of the largest states of Europe into an
object of territorial division carried out by stronger neighbours.
     The Moscow State found itself caught in a similar trap in the 17th cen-
tury. Reformation (the abandonment of the social contract) would have
meant a sharp decrease in the defence potential, thus it could not be con-
ducted at once and over a short period. On the other hand, as the contribution
of centralised factors in the defence potentiation increases, the weaknesses of
landowner army become evident. In 1610, in the battle of Klushino, the Po-
lish “winged” hussars inflicted a devastating defeat on the troops of Dmitry
Shuisky, which were four times their strength; it was the first sign of the inef-
ficiency of the extant system and the army formed on its bases. The 1659 de-
feat at Konotop resulted in such a heavy toll that the landowner army lost its
earlier significance forever.
     However, Muscovy (and later the Russian Empire) could carry out mili-
tary modernisation through the resources of strong state authority. However,
the rejection of the “military service for land” model was gradual and lasted
for more than two centuries. Firstly, the regiments of the “new order” were
created in the 1630—1670s; they were formed by non-landed gentry, who
were paid in bread and money [16]. Secondly, after the decree of 1762, the
nobility were exempt from obligatory military service; however, they re-
tained the rights to serf ownership. Although military service was voluntary,
it still involved most of the nobility and gentry, since it was a source of fi-
nancing alongside the income from serfs. And the final reform was intro-
duced after the major crisis of the system — the defeat in the Crimean War
in the 19th century, which was a result of the technical backwardness of the
Russian army. As the contribution of decentralised factors into the defence
potential decreased, the maintenance of the social contract by the tsar
seemed less and less probable, but the defeat in the Crimean War was the fi-
nal incentive to terminate the social contract and abolish serfdom.

                                                                              97
International relations: historical aspects




                                   Conclusion

     The history of Muscovy and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth —
two states that took different paths of institutional development — shows
that, according to the NIEH approach, economic institutions are formed un-
der the influence of different external factors and affect their future eco-
nomic and political development.
     At the same time, the historical analysis demonstrates that the institu-
tions considered “bad” and ineffective from the perspective of economic the-
ory, can turn out to be competitive under certain historical conditions. For
example, the contingent proprietary rights in Muscovy, despite their evident
negative impact on the economic sphere, become competitive in the condi-
tions of significant contribution of decentralised factors in the defence poten-
tial and ensure the formation of a large and efficient army. On the other
hand, against the background of a weak state authority, the vested right regi-
me characteristic of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth allows certain in-
terest groups — the nobility — to maximise their income, but cannot support
the achievement of such important state objectives as army modernisation.

                                    References

     1. Nunn, N. 2009, The Importance of History for Economic Development, An-
nual Review of Economics, no. 1, p. 65—92.
     2. Greif, A. 1996, Micro Theory and Recent Developments in the Study of Eco-
nomic Institutions Through Economic History, Stanford Economics Working Paper,
no. 96—001, available at: http://www.ecsocman.edu.ru/data/070/766/1216/9611132.pdf
(accessed 20 December 2010).
     3. Vdovin, М. S. Modelirovanie zakrepowenija krest'jan v Moskovskom carstve
[Modeling the enslavement of the peasants in Muscovy], available at: http://issuu.
com/mikevdovin/docs/ (accessed 20 December 2010).
     4. Diakonov, М. А. 1908, Ocherki obwestvennogo i gosudarstvennogo stroja
Drevnej Rusi [Essays on social and political system of ancient Russia], Saint Peters-
burg.
     5. Vernadsky, G. 1945, On Some Parallel Trends in Russian and Turkish His-
tory, Transactions of Connecticut Academy of Arts an Sciences, Vol. 36, p. 24—36.
     6. Whipper, R. G. 1944, Ivan Groznyj [Ivan the Terrible], Moscow.
     7. Krizhanich, Yu. 1997, Politika [Policy], Moscow.
     8. Nefedov, S. А. 2002, Reformy Ivana III i Ivana IV: osmanskoe vlijanie [Re-
forms of Ivan III and Ivan IV: Ottoman influence], Voprosy istorii, no. 11, p. 30—53.
     9. Foscarini, М. 1991, Rassuzhdenija o Moskovii [Speculations about Mus-
covy]. In: Inostrancy o drevnej Moskve [Foreigners of ancient Moscow], Moscow.
     10. Fletcher, D. 1906, O gosudarstve Russkom [On the Russian State], Saint Pe-
tersburg.
     11. Domar, E. 1970, The causes of slavery or serfdom: a hypothesis, Journal of
Economic History, p. 18—32.
     12. Latov, Yu. V. 2004, Vlast'-sobstvennost' v srednevekovoj Rossii [Power-
property in medieval Russia], Ekonomicheskij vestnik Rostovskogo gosudarstven-

98
M. S. Vdovin


nogo universiteta=TERRA ECONOMICUS, Vol. 2, no. 4, p. 111—133, available at:
http://sfedu.ru/evjur/data/2004/journal2.4.pdf (accessed 20 December 2010).
      13. Doroshenko, V. 1974, Trade and agrarian development in the Baltic pro-
vinvs 15th—19th centuries, Tallin.
      14. Skazkin, S. D. 1958, Osnovnye problemy tak nazyvaemogo «vtorogo iz-
danija krepostnichestva» v Srednej i Vostochnoj Evrope [The main problem of the
so-called "second edition of serfdom" in Central and Eastern Europe], Voprosy isto-
rii, no. 2, p. 96—119.
      15. Doroshenko, V. V. 1960, Ocherki agrarnoj istorii Latvii v XVI veke [Essays
on the agrarian history of Latvia in the XVI century], Riga.
      16. Penskoi, V. V. 2010, Velikaja ognestrel'naja revoljucija [Great bullet revo-
lution], Moscow.

                                   About author

    Mikhail S. Vdovin, PhD student, Faculty of Economics, National re-
search university ‘Higher school of economics’.
    E-mail: m_vdovin@mail.ru

More Related Content

Viewers also liked

Responsive & Adaprove Design
Responsive & Adaprove DesignResponsive & Adaprove Design
Responsive & Adaprove DesignMike Vdovin
 
Intro To It Services
Intro To It ServicesIntro To It Services
Intro To It Servicespjlisowsky
 
Digital в условиях турбулентности
Digital в условиях турбулентностиDigital в условиях турбулентности
Digital в условиях турбулентностиMike Vdovin
 
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...Mike Vdovin
 
iTunes University and Mobile Learning
iTunes University and Mobile LearningiTunes University and Mobile Learning
iTunes University and Mobile Learningpjlisowsky
 
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectives
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectivesEnserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectives
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectivesMike Vdovin
 
Mobile Learning and iTunes University
Mobile Learning and iTunes UniversityMobile Learning and iTunes University
Mobile Learning and iTunes Universitypjlisowsky
 
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]Bmb peta+malaysia[2]
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]Normah Zainal
 
Генетика прокариот
Генетика прокариотГенетика прокариот
Генетика прокариотTanusha_547
 
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08Ahmad Abdullah
 
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008Ahmad Abdullah
 
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009Ahmad Abdullah
 
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008Ahmad Abdullah
 

Viewers also liked (17)

Responsive & Adaprove Design
Responsive & Adaprove DesignResponsive & Adaprove Design
Responsive & Adaprove Design
 
Intro To It Services
Intro To It ServicesIntro To It Services
Intro To It Services
 
Digital в условиях турбулентности
Digital в условиях турбулентностиDigital в условиях турбулентности
Digital в условиях турбулентности
 
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...
Сельскохозяйственный и экономический кризис XVI в. в России: влияние институт...
 
iTunes University and Mobile Learning
iTunes University and Mobile LearningiTunes University and Mobile Learning
iTunes University and Mobile Learning
 
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectives
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectivesEnserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectives
Enserfment in The Great Princedom of Moscow: institutional perspectives
 
Mobile Learning and iTunes University
Mobile Learning and iTunes UniversityMobile Learning and iTunes University
Mobile Learning and iTunes University
 
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]Bmb peta+malaysia[2]
Bmb peta+malaysia[2]
 
Генетика прокариот
Генетика прокариотГенетика прокариот
Генетика прокариот
 
Bekas Tnaman Berngkai
Bekas Tnaman BerngkaiBekas Tnaman Berngkai
Bekas Tnaman Berngkai
 
Arabelli Suvi
Arabelli SuviArabelli Suvi
Arabelli Suvi
 
Kerusi Taman
Kerusi TamanKerusi Taman
Kerusi Taman
 
Air Terjun Simenfero
Air Terjun SimenferoAir Terjun Simenfero
Air Terjun Simenfero
 
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08
Projek Pargola Kayu Terbuang 08
 
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008
Projek Membina Air Terjun Linangan Reco 2008
 
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009
Projek X Stadunt Laman Ikhlas 2009
 
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008
Projek Laman Terapi Ppki Mei 2008
 

Similar to INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT TRAJECTORY IN EASTERN EUROPE IN THE 16th—17th CENTURIES: MOSCOVY AND THE POLISH—LITHUANIAN COMMONWEALTH

Power Powder & Patriotism
Power Powder & PatriotismPower Powder & Patriotism
Power Powder & PatriotismSam Hueston
 
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...Le1 ccg
 
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...nicacho04
 
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docx
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docxdependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docx
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docxtheodorelove43763
 
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docx
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docxChapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docx
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docxchristinemaritza
 
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...Dr Igor Calzada, MBA, FeRSA
 
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - Analysis
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - AnalysisR Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - Analysis
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - AnalysisRustam Begaliev
 
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...Rocznik Integracji Europejskiej
 
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)tapanma
 
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptx
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptxBA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptx
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptxLuckySisodia1
 
An analysis of essential elements of the State
An analysis of essential elements of the StateAn analysis of essential elements of the State
An analysis of essential elements of the Stateinventionjournals
 
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docx
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docxTHEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docx
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docxsusannr
 
Law P 539 Exam Final Paper Colonization - Developing
Law P 539      Exam Final Paper      Colonization - Developing Law P 539      Exam Final Paper      Colonization - Developing
Law P 539 Exam Final Paper Colonization - Developing Rustam Begaliev
 
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)Samuel Anderson
 
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist Analysis
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist AnalysisDeconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist Analysis
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist AnalysisAbdeslam Badre, PhD
 
Geography and Politics in A World Divided
Geography and Politics in A World DividedGeography and Politics in A World Divided
Geography and Politics in A World DividedAI Publications
 
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...Alexander Decker
 

Similar to INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT TRAJECTORY IN EASTERN EUROPE IN THE 16th—17th CENTURIES: MOSCOVY AND THE POLISH—LITHUANIAN COMMONWEALTH (20)

Philosophy of history
Philosophy of historyPhilosophy of history
Philosophy of history
 
Power Powder & Patriotism
Power Powder & PatriotismPower Powder & Patriotism
Power Powder & Patriotism
 
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...
THE CIVIL-MILITARY RELATIONS AND DEMOCRATIC CONTROL ON ARMED FORCES IN CAUCAS...
 
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...
What the 2014 Scottish Referendum Can Reveal About State Development (Introdu...
 
GREEK CASE ICJ
GREEK CASE ICJGREEK CASE ICJ
GREEK CASE ICJ
 
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docx
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docxdependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docx
dependency andworld-systems theoriesChristopher Chase-.docx
 
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docx
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docxChapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docx
Chapter 4 The political dimension of globalization Political g.docx
 
1552.pdf
1552.pdf1552.pdf
1552.pdf
 
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...
'European City-Regions and the Re-scaling of the Nation-State: The Role of Ci...
 
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - Analysis
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - AnalysisR Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - Analysis
R Begaliev - Law P 539 The History of Development - Analysis
 
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...
The role of ethno-regional parties in European integration. Is it a distracto...
 
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)
Society and the stalinist state in the period of the five year plans (1)
 
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptx
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptxBA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptx
BA. LLB (HONS.) HISTORY AND LAW UNIT -1.pptx
 
An analysis of essential elements of the State
An analysis of essential elements of the StateAn analysis of essential elements of the State
An analysis of essential elements of the State
 
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docx
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docxTHEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docx
THEODORE C. BESTORDepartment of AnthropologyHarvard Univer.docx
 
Law P 539 Exam Final Paper Colonization - Developing
Law P 539      Exam Final Paper      Colonization - Developing Law P 539      Exam Final Paper      Colonization - Developing
Law P 539 Exam Final Paper Colonization - Developing
 
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)
MNC Behavior (Argumentative form) - (DVM1100)
 
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist Analysis
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist AnalysisDeconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist Analysis
Deconstructing the “Arab Spring”: A Constrcutivist Analysis
 
Geography and Politics in A World Divided
Geography and Politics in A World DividedGeography and Politics in A World Divided
Geography and Politics in A World Divided
 
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...
Parliamentary sovereignty in the modern legal policy in the russian federatio...
 

INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT TRAJECTORY IN EASTERN EUROPE IN THE 16th—17th CENTURIES: MOSCOVY AND THE POLISH—LITHUANIAN COMMONWEALTH

  • 1. International relations: historical aspects INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS: HISTORICAL ASPECTS UDK 338(091) Recent decades have witnessed an in- THE FEATURES crease in the number of works dedicated to OF CHOOSING the analysis of effects of historical events on AN INSTITUTIONAL the choice of institutions and further econo- mic and social development of regions. This DEVELOPMENT article employs the new institutional econo- TRAJECTORY mic theory approach to consider the choices IN EASTERN EUROPE regarding title to land and serfdom in Mos- th th covy and the Polish — Lithuanian Com- IN THE 16 —17 monwealth (earlier the Grand Duchy of Li- CENTURIES: thuania) in the 16th—17th centuries. The author emphasizes the factors, which affected the MOSCOVY AND choice of institutional development trajectory, THE POLISH—LITHUANIAN and considers the influence exerted by these institutes on the political and military devel- COMMONWEALTH opment of these states. This article shows how the contingent property rights in Mosco- vy turned out to be competitive in the condi- M. S. Vdovin* tions of a considerable contribution of decen- tralisation factors to defence capacity and, opposite to the situation in the Polish — Li- thuanian Commonwealth, ensured the forma- tion of large and efficient troops. This work contributes to the research on the property rights and Russian economic history. Key words: institutional economy, histo- rical analysis, serfdom, property rights, Mos- covy, Polish — Lithuanian Commonwealth The recent decades have witnessed an increase in the number of works dedi- cated to the analysis of the influence of historical events on institutional choices * National research university and further economic and social devel- ‘Higher school of economics’ opment of regions. This line of research 20, Myasnitskaya Ul., Moscow, 101000, Russia. is called New Institutional Economic His- tory, NIEH1. The principal conclusion Received on June 08, 2012. drawn by scholars in the framework of 1 A detailed review of works on NIEH is given in [1; 2]. 90
  • 2. M. S. Vdovin NIEH is that history “matters”. Different exogenous factors (natural re- sources, climate, legal institutions established in the course of colonization, political inequality) relate to the choice of institutions (first of all, the institu- tion of proprietary rights), which, in their turn affect the economic develop- ment. This work considers from the perspective of the NIEH approach the fea- tures of the choice of fundamental institutions in Moscovy and the Polish— Lithuanian Commonwealth (earlier the Grand Duchy of Lithuania) in the 16th—17th centuries, namely the regime of proprietary rights to land and serf- dom and identifies the factors that affected this choice. Throughout the pe- riod under consideration, Moscovy and the Polish—Lithuanian Common- wealth were the key actors on the military and political map of Eastern Eu- rope and long-standing religious opponents. Alongside the political, military, and religious aspects of the competition, one can also speak of the competi- tion at the institutional level. In this case, the competition is understood not as a direct collision of institutions, but their diverse effect on the social and political and military spheres leading to different economic and military con- sequences, and, as a result, to a wider distribution or, on the contrary, aban- donment of such institutions. In the course of the 16th—17th centuries, the institutional choice in the states considered was made for two principal markets — those of land and labour. The institutional decision was a choice between two alternatives for each market: free labour — non-free labour (serfdom) and unconditional ownership (patrimonial land tenure) — conditional ownership (manorial land tenure). History shows that the choice was different for Moscovy and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth. Whereas both states chose non-free labour (this choice was affected by several factors), as to the regime of pro- prietary rights, the choices were opposite: in Moscovy, contingent proprie- tary rights were widely spread, whereas in the Polish-Lithuanian Common- wealth, they were replaced by vested ones. These features of institutional development require a further explanation, which can be provided through an analysis of historical development alternatives. Serfdom and manorial land tenure as a social contract From the perspective of an institutional analysis, the establishment of serfdom and development of manorial land tenure characteristic, for exam- ple, of Muscovy can be considered as a conclusion of a tacit social contract between the supreme ruler and the nobility. To this effect, the supreme ruler restricts proprietary rights to land, undermines the authority of large patri- monial landowners (monasteries, nobility) and, relying on the interests of a different group - manorial land owners - becomes a chief landowner. The in- troduction of serfdom, which resulted in the restriction of mobility of peas- ants and establishment of monopsony in the labour market, was a necessary step to support landowners as a loyal interest group, which received in the 91
  • 3. International relations: historical aspects conditions of serfdom the surplus of peasant labour. In return, landowners agree to waive certain rights to land and yield the political function, con- tenting themselves with military and administrative services. The social contract will persist (i. e. contingent proprietary rights will do- minate and serfdom will be established), if it proves to be profitable for the mentioned interest groups — the supreme ruler and the nobility. Otherwise, the social contract will be denounced, and contingent proprietary right to land and serfdom will cease to be equal institutions. Let us identify what factors supported the tacit contract. Landowners will be more interested in maintaining the contract, if the area of ploughed fields and grain prices are increasing. In this case, they get an opportunity to multi- ply their profit; hence, they are more encouraged to maintain the contract. High costs of military service (the obligation to take part in campaigns, equipping themselves and servants), on the contrary, are poor incentives: if the costs are too big, they can outweigh the monopsony profit of the land- owner generated from the allocated land. Finally, there is a system of repres- sive measures and non-economic costs for evaders and traitors (reputation, moral and religious repercussions): if the punishment for apostasy is sub- stantial and very probable, incentives to maintaining the contract increase and persist, even when the monopsony income of the landowner generated by serfs is not very high2. Another interest of the supreme ruler is the formation of a large and ef- fective army. Thus, he is interested in manorial tenure: in this case, the ruler gets an opportunity to form a large army rapidly without spending personal and public funds, since landowners take on the obligation to serve through accepting their lands. The incentives for maintaining manorial tenure in- crease when the contribution of decentralised factors (landowner regimenta- tion, cavalry) into the defence potential is considerable. And, vice versa, as military profession develops and the significance of centralised factors (artil- lery, regiments of the “new order”) increases — when the strength of the army becomes less important than its infrastructure, training, and discipline, — the incentives for the supreme ruler to maintain the social contract decrease. Now let us focus on how the features of the institutional choice of Mus- covy and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth can be interpreted from the perspective of this approach. Land ownership and the establishment of serfdom in Muscovy The 16th century divides Russian history into two completely different parts — the feudal and Moscovian, which were characterised, inter alia, by the opposite types of land relations — patrimonial and manorial land tenure. It is the 15th century, when the institution of contingent manorial land tenure 2 A more detailed analysis of incentives for landowners and the supreme ruler to maintain the social contract in Muscovy is given in [3]. 92
  • 4. M. S. Vdovin gained grounds, which formed the bases of the military and service class or- ganisation of Muscovy. This watershed is manifested in the wills of Moscow princes. Dmitry of the Don guaranteed his boyars the rights to their land and acknowledges them as absolute owners (14th century): …with your assistance strengthened I the grand duchy, and brought peace and quiet, and kept the land of my fathers… and I did not do evil to any of you, nor took anything away by force, nor offended you, nor plundered, not disorder… thus, I call you not the boyars, but the princes of my land [4, p. 398]. However, just two centuries later, Ivan the Terrible writes in his letter to the Polish king Sigismund Augustus in his peculiar manner about the chan- ges that had taken place in Muscovy: …our unfettered stardom of great sovereigns is not like your pitiful king- dom; our great sovereigns are never instructed by anyone, but your lords or- der you as they please… our sovereigns are autocrats and no one can order them, and they are free to pardon or execute [4, p. 408]. The manorial systems suddenly emerged in Muscovy under Ivan III at the end of the 15th century and started to develop rapidly [5]. The establish- ment of manorial system is explained by contemporaries and historians by taking after the Ottoman Empire [6; 7], and the period of development of Muscovy in the 15th century was the time of adopting Turkish ways and transforming Russia according to the Ottoman model [8]. The final formation of the manorial system under Ivan the Terrible, when the order and principle of cavalry, recruit, and arms services provided by lands were settled, gave rise to the formation of one of the largest armies of the time, which could be compared only to the sultan’s army. As contem- poraries reported, whereas earlier, the army of the Moscow tsar was rather small, under Ivan the Terrible, when each nobleman could bring one or two “fighting serfs”, it reached the strength of 80,000 people and, according to some accounts (which can be exaggerated), there were two armies of 100,000 people each [9; 10]. So, the task of increasing the military potential was solved, and Muscovy safeguarded its sovereignty and got an opportunity to further territorial expansion. In the conditions of significant influence of decentralised factors on defence potential, the supreme ruler was especially interested in the formation of a large manorial army and, as a result, had suf- ficient incentives to maintain the “land for service” social contract. There were equal incentives for landowners to maintain the tacit con- tract. Firstly, it was them who were granted new manors as a result of mili- tary campaigns and territorial expansion in the 16th century. The establish- ment of serfdom was necessary to eliminate the competition between landlords for peasants in the conditions of the territorial expansion and prevent peasant escapes. This conclusion corresponds to E. Domar’s hypothesis about the im- pact of land surplus on the development of serfdom in Russia [11]. 93
  • 5. International relations: historical aspects Secondly, the principle of the army formation was established from as early as Ivan the Terrible’s services code: a landowner had to provide one soldier from each 150 dessiatinas3 of land and be present at the inspection with horses, people, and arms. It is worth noting that the obligations of a landowner depended on the area of land he possessed, which settled the costs of military services and ensured that the social contract was maintained. Finally, in the 16th century, the evasion of service started to be consid- ered not as a simple refusal to conclude a contract between a free and inde- pendent landowner and the supreme ruler, but as treason. The punishment for apostasy (confiscation of property, plunder of the manor) could be an important incentive to maintain the social contract, which was supplemented by different kinds of non-economic coercion. It could result in significant reputation costs for the landowner, which kept him from violating the “land for service” agreement. So, when entering the service of the Moscow king, the contract was supposed to be reinforced by kissing the cross and guaran- tees from a metropolitan and people in service. The ones who wanted to leave this “cartel”, would face both religious punishment and the breach of relations with the “colleagues”. The establishment of such a system in Muscovy was probably inter- preted as (and actually was) the best decision in the struggle for sovereignty and safety of residents. However, one should not consider the Ottoman alter- native the only one available at the time. Muscovy also interacted with other states and could consider as an alternative to the “authority-property” institu- tion the institution of private property, which gained grounds in Livonia and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth. The reason for the variant being re- jected might have been confessional tensions, since the Grand Duchy of Lithuania was a Catholic state and, from the perspective of Moscow princes was an opponent to orthodoxy [12]. At the same time, the military advan- tages of the Turkish model were so obvious that one could easily ignore that it was adopted from “pagans”. Serfdom 2.0 in the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth (the former Grand Duchy of Lithuania) The case of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth shows that there were alternative paths of institutional development. Unlike Muscovy, an increase in feudal land tenure in this region related to the reinforcement of owner’s rights and the development of vested property rights. The lack of strong cen- tral authority contributed to the strengthening of knighthood. As a result of weak central authority, the social contract could not be maintained by effi- cient enforcement from the state. Contingent property rights did not gain such vast grounds in the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth as in Muscovy. Large vassals managed to secure privileged rights to fief, which ensured the patrimonial right to the land. 3 Translator’s note: an obsolete Russian measure of land, roughly 1.1 hectares. 94
  • 6. M. S. Vdovin Against the background of the development of vested land right regime, peasants are turned to surfs. It was a variation of the Roman slavery system, and economy acquires market and export character not unlike that of the Southern United States. As early as the 1530s — 1540s, the price revolution taking place in Western Europe (increase in the prices for bread, flax, hemp, cattle) resulted in the development of the corvee labour system of feudal economy. Feudal lords use the external factor, adding to their income gener- ated through in-kind and monetary inflows from peasants, income from manors, and export of grain to England and Holland. The structure of manor incomes started to be dominated not by income from peasants (agricultural products and money), but that from the manor itself. At the same time, grain accounted for 70—90 % of the manor income; and 40—50 % of the harvest yielded by large manors was exported. The trend towards the strengthening of corvee and serfdom was most pronounced in the regions in the vicinity of floatable rivers: the location in proximity to export ports (Narva, Tallinn, Pärnu, Riga) and the convenience of water and land freight was an additional incentive for landowners [13]. The high bread prices and serfdom scenario was characteristic of many countries of Eastern Europe (the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth, Bohe- mia, Prussia, Pomerania). Unlike the Moscovite serfdom, the market and private property institutions were rather widespread there, and the revival of serfdom in these countries is explained traditionally by the growing demand for bread [14]. The reinforcement of serfdom was manifested in the aspira- tion of feudal lords to eliminate the peasant’s right to leave manors and find ways to prevent escapes. However, unlike other states (for instance, Mus- covy), where the strong central authority took care of the interests of the no- bility, legislation on peasant escapees turned into territorial intraclass agree- ments (for example, "einigungen" in Livonia). The struggle for peasants be- tween landowners escalated in the periods of plunders, for instance, in the course of the Livonian War. Thus, feudal lords concluded private contracts, taking on the obligation not to entice someone else’s serfs and return them to the owner in case they come of their own accord. So, the need for the forced return of escapees resulted in the establishment of a special police and judi- cial mechanism of Hackengerichts, which, nevertheless, were of a local ra- ther than nationwide nature [15]. So, under the influence of external factors (high prices for exported grain), the landowners of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth managed to establish a monopsony in the labour market without the interference of the state and conclusion of a social contract, which resulted in the emergence of serfdom 2.0. It substantiated the above mentioned idea that, against the background of rising prices the product of labour, the profit of a monopson- ist increases alongside the incentives for landowners to establish serfdom. At the same time, the absence of strong state authority was an obstacle to a change in the land right regime towards contingent rights. The nobility and gentry, as the dominant political force, were interested in securing their lands and could generate a monopsony profit through reviving serfdom without involving the state. 95
  • 7. International relations: historical aspects Competition between institutions and the consequences of the institutional choice The comparative analysis of development of land tenure rights and the reasons for the emergence of serfdom makes it possible to identify the key factors of maintaining the “land for service” social contract and explain the features of the institution development in Muscovy and the Polish- Lithuanian Commonwealth (table). The significance of factors affecting the maintenance of the “land for service” social contract The “land for service” social Social contract contract is maintained is not maintained (contingent land Factor (only serfdom) rights + serfdom) Polish-Lithuanian Muscovy Commonwealth Resource allotment (availability of unoccupied lands for allo- + — cating in exchange for service) Strong central authority + — The development of a strata inte- — + rested in vested property rights Export-oriented production (grain) — + Considerable contribution of de- centralised factors into defence + — potential The historical consequences of the institutional choice in the states under consideration are neither easily predictable, nor logical. The case of the Po- lish-Lithuanian Commonwealth shows that the spread of “good” institutions of vested land rights ensuring the protection of property rights and incentives to investment is not the only and sufficient factor of long-term economic de- velopment. The weakness of state authority results in the division of the history of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth in two stages: the “golden age” of Polish nobility following the signing of the Union of Lublin in 1569 (the es- tablishment of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth) and a series of mili- tary defeats in the 17th century (by Bohdan Khmelnitsky’s Cossacks, the Swedish Deluge) and resulting in three divisions of Poland in the late 18th century and the fall of the empire. The predominance of export-oriented ag- riculture and the establishment of serfdom allowed the nobility to generate monopsonic income, which was directed to internal consumption (for exam- ple, luxury goods). Unlike Muscovy, the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth 96
  • 8. M. S. Vdovin did not maintain a social contract between the supreme ruler and landow- ners. In the field of politics, the nobility pursued narrow intraclass interests, focused on solving local problems, which made it possible to increase per- sonal income, rather than state affairs, first of all, the defence potential. By the mid-17th century, after a series of heavy defeats, the military inef- ficiency of the Polish-Lithuanian nobility becomes evident. The Polish ca- valry and the famous Polish “winged” hussars could hardly meet the new warfare conditions — sieges and attacks of musket-armed infantry. The lack of strong central authority, when the king “reigned but not ruled” and the nobility was convinced of stability of their financial and political freedoms, resulted in the crown not having enough funds for army reforms [16]. In the conditions, when the neighbouring absolute monarchies conducted active army modernisation (for example, the Swedish king Karl Gustav, having un- derstood that the Polish cavalry is not to be defeated by being outnumbered, focused on improving discipline and developing artillery), Poland had nei- ther financial, nor political resources to reform its army. As a result, by the end of 18th century, the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth ceased to be an independent state and turned from one of the largest states of Europe into an object of territorial division carried out by stronger neighbours. The Moscow State found itself caught in a similar trap in the 17th cen- tury. Reformation (the abandonment of the social contract) would have meant a sharp decrease in the defence potential, thus it could not be con- ducted at once and over a short period. On the other hand, as the contribution of centralised factors in the defence potentiation increases, the weaknesses of landowner army become evident. In 1610, in the battle of Klushino, the Po- lish “winged” hussars inflicted a devastating defeat on the troops of Dmitry Shuisky, which were four times their strength; it was the first sign of the inef- ficiency of the extant system and the army formed on its bases. The 1659 de- feat at Konotop resulted in such a heavy toll that the landowner army lost its earlier significance forever. However, Muscovy (and later the Russian Empire) could carry out mili- tary modernisation through the resources of strong state authority. However, the rejection of the “military service for land” model was gradual and lasted for more than two centuries. Firstly, the regiments of the “new order” were created in the 1630—1670s; they were formed by non-landed gentry, who were paid in bread and money [16]. Secondly, after the decree of 1762, the nobility were exempt from obligatory military service; however, they re- tained the rights to serf ownership. Although military service was voluntary, it still involved most of the nobility and gentry, since it was a source of fi- nancing alongside the income from serfs. And the final reform was intro- duced after the major crisis of the system — the defeat in the Crimean War in the 19th century, which was a result of the technical backwardness of the Russian army. As the contribution of decentralised factors into the defence potential decreased, the maintenance of the social contract by the tsar seemed less and less probable, but the defeat in the Crimean War was the fi- nal incentive to terminate the social contract and abolish serfdom. 97
  • 9. International relations: historical aspects Conclusion The history of Muscovy and the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth — two states that took different paths of institutional development — shows that, according to the NIEH approach, economic institutions are formed un- der the influence of different external factors and affect their future eco- nomic and political development. At the same time, the historical analysis demonstrates that the institu- tions considered “bad” and ineffective from the perspective of economic the- ory, can turn out to be competitive under certain historical conditions. For example, the contingent proprietary rights in Muscovy, despite their evident negative impact on the economic sphere, become competitive in the condi- tions of significant contribution of decentralised factors in the defence poten- tial and ensure the formation of a large and efficient army. On the other hand, against the background of a weak state authority, the vested right regi- me characteristic of the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth allows certain in- terest groups — the nobility — to maximise their income, but cannot support the achievement of such important state objectives as army modernisation. References 1. Nunn, N. 2009, The Importance of History for Economic Development, An- nual Review of Economics, no. 1, p. 65—92. 2. Greif, A. 1996, Micro Theory and Recent Developments in the Study of Eco- nomic Institutions Through Economic History, Stanford Economics Working Paper, no. 96—001, available at: http://www.ecsocman.edu.ru/data/070/766/1216/9611132.pdf (accessed 20 December 2010). 3. Vdovin, М. S. Modelirovanie zakrepowenija krest'jan v Moskovskom carstve [Modeling the enslavement of the peasants in Muscovy], available at: http://issuu. com/mikevdovin/docs/ (accessed 20 December 2010). 4. Diakonov, М. А. 1908, Ocherki obwestvennogo i gosudarstvennogo stroja Drevnej Rusi [Essays on social and political system of ancient Russia], Saint Peters- burg. 5. Vernadsky, G. 1945, On Some Parallel Trends in Russian and Turkish His- tory, Transactions of Connecticut Academy of Arts an Sciences, Vol. 36, p. 24—36. 6. Whipper, R. G. 1944, Ivan Groznyj [Ivan the Terrible], Moscow. 7. Krizhanich, Yu. 1997, Politika [Policy], Moscow. 8. Nefedov, S. А. 2002, Reformy Ivana III i Ivana IV: osmanskoe vlijanie [Re- forms of Ivan III and Ivan IV: Ottoman influence], Voprosy istorii, no. 11, p. 30—53. 9. Foscarini, М. 1991, Rassuzhdenija o Moskovii [Speculations about Mus- covy]. In: Inostrancy o drevnej Moskve [Foreigners of ancient Moscow], Moscow. 10. Fletcher, D. 1906, O gosudarstve Russkom [On the Russian State], Saint Pe- tersburg. 11. Domar, E. 1970, The causes of slavery or serfdom: a hypothesis, Journal of Economic History, p. 18—32. 12. Latov, Yu. V. 2004, Vlast'-sobstvennost' v srednevekovoj Rossii [Power- property in medieval Russia], Ekonomicheskij vestnik Rostovskogo gosudarstven- 98
  • 10. M. S. Vdovin nogo universiteta=TERRA ECONOMICUS, Vol. 2, no. 4, p. 111—133, available at: http://sfedu.ru/evjur/data/2004/journal2.4.pdf (accessed 20 December 2010). 13. Doroshenko, V. 1974, Trade and agrarian development in the Baltic pro- vinvs 15th—19th centuries, Tallin. 14. Skazkin, S. D. 1958, Osnovnye problemy tak nazyvaemogo «vtorogo iz- danija krepostnichestva» v Srednej i Vostochnoj Evrope [The main problem of the so-called "second edition of serfdom" in Central and Eastern Europe], Voprosy isto- rii, no. 2, p. 96—119. 15. Doroshenko, V. V. 1960, Ocherki agrarnoj istorii Latvii v XVI veke [Essays on the agrarian history of Latvia in the XVI century], Riga. 16. Penskoi, V. V. 2010, Velikaja ognestrel'naja revoljucija [Great bullet revo- lution], Moscow. About author Mikhail S. Vdovin, PhD student, Faculty of Economics, National re- search university ‘Higher school of economics’. E-mail: m_vdovin@mail.ru