SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 90
Download to read offline
Real-world issue 2: When are markets unable to satisfy important
economic objectives – and does government intervention help?
➢ In theory, if market agents behave rationally, then the market will be allocatively
efficient. Consumers get what they want or need, as long as they are willing and able to
pay a price for it, and producers are rewarded for their efforts. Everyone is happy.
➢ However, do all markets behave in a way that results in allocative efficiency and
socially desirable outcomes for all?
Consider these examples:
● Food shortages
● Climate change
● Obesity
● Microplastic pollution
● Bisphenol A (BPA) toxicity in plastic food containers
In all of these examples, the market system has created outcomes that have
consequences for broader society, rather than just for the consumers and producers of
that good or service.
Governments can intervene in the following ways:
● Price controls
● Indirect taxes
● Subsidies
● Direct provision of services
● Command and control regulation and
legislation
● Consumer nudges
Concept
Intervention
➢ Markets are tremendous forces for innovation and prosperity, but they can also
create problems that are difficult to manage without intervention. Markets can fail
to be allocatively efficient, which means they do not allocate resources in a way
that maximises the interests of participants or third parties.
➢ When markets create problems beyond the transaction between buyers and sellers,
the government can be justified to intervene using a variety of methods.
Why do governments intervene?
There are many reasons why governments want to intervene in markets
.The reasons include:
● To earn government revenue
● To support firms
● To support households on low incomes
● To influence the level of production
● To influence the level of consumption
● To correct market failure
● To promote equity
Earning government revenue
➢ The first significant reason to tax the consumption of goods and
services is to raise government revenue. Governments tax a variety
of goods and services, with many countries employing a
goods and services tax (GST) or a value added tax (VAT) to most goods and
services.
➢ Like any other tax,indirect taxes produce revenue for the government
that can be used to finance government spending. Governments might
use tax revenue to provide public goods and services, to invest in
infrastructure, to improve education or to provide healthcare for the
population of the country.
➢ Governments run budgets and need sources of income to finance
their projects and expenditures.
➢ Indirect tax is a source of income for the government.
➢ Each time the government charges an indirect tax on a good or
service, it collects a revenue equal to the tax charged per unit of the
good sold multiplied by the quantity of goods sold.
Supporting firms
➢ Governments like to use methods of intervention to support
firms in particular industries. This can be for economic
reasons, but also for political and strategic reasons.
➢ The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the European Union
supports farming in member states by providing ‘direct
payments’ to farming sectors in order to help support jobs and
growth, modernise the industry and improve sustainability. In
economics, we call this kind of support a subsidy
Supporting households on low incomes
➢ Governments can also seek to support households in the country. Support can be targeted
to certain households, or be universally applied.
➢ As an example, Indonesia has had fuel subsidies in place since the country gained its
independence in 1949.
➢
➢ They are primarily designed to support people on lower incomes to afford fuel for their
cars, mopeds, and other fuel-reliant equipment.
➢ In addition, because the subsidy is universally applied, the wealthy, who have no problems
paying for fuel for their luxury cars, also benefit from the lower fuel prices.
Influencing the level of production
➢ Governments can use a number of methods to increase or decrease production of goods and
services.
➢ In the case of undesirable goods, governments will often want to discourage their production,
even though this will impact the businesses and employees in those industries.
➢ This is because the production of some goods can have negative effects on society.
➢ A good example of this is that many governments want to decrease the
production of energy that uses fossil fuels. When energy is produced
using natural gas, coal or petroleum, carbon dioxide is released into the
atmosphere.
➢ This carbon dioxide pollutes the atmosphere, contributes to global
climate change, and can create smog that affects the air quality of the
local area.
➢ The Chinese government has acted in recent years to try to reduce the
country’s dependence on energy produced by coal-fired power plants
by investing in clean energy and operating an emissions trading
scheme.
Influencing the level of consumption
➢ Governments can use a variety of methods to increase or decrease
consumption of goods and services.
➢ In the case of undesirable goods, governments will often want to discourage
the consumption of them because it has negative consequences for those
consuming as well as others in society. We call these kinds of goods
demerit goods.
➢ Governments have a range of effective measures to help reduce smoking,
including indirect taxes, support programmes to help people quit and
legislation, such as age restrictions, bans on tobacco advertising, and smoking
bans.
Correcting market failure
➢ Market failure occurs when markets fail to allocate resources efficiently, and
community surplus is not maximised. We will explore this concept in much
greater detail later in this subtopic, but for now we can discuss a few basic ideas.
➢ The most prominent example of market failure today is the issue of
climate change.
➢ Climate change is an example of market failure because the firms and
consumers responsible for the problems have not contributed sufficiently
to the costs associated with climate change
Promoting equity
➢ Governments often choose to intervene in markets to improve the equity of
the income distribution in the economy. We have already read about the fuel
subsidies in Indonesia that aim to make fuel cheaper for low-income families.
➢ The most common forms of government intervention to promote equity are
found in health care and education. These are two services that are deemed to
be human rights, and thus most governments try to offer these goods at no
cost to the public.
➢ Many governments think that a child’s ability to succeed in life should not be
determined by their parents’ income.
Price ceilings
➢ The market price for a good or service is sometimes
unaffordable. This is common for essential goods and services,
such as rented accommodation or food.
➢ The government can set a maximum price, also known as a price
ceiling, below the equilibrium price to prevent producers from
selling their product above it.
➢ This is done to protect consumers and is usually applied to
necessity and/or merit goods.
The aims of this policy are usually to:
● increase consumption of the good or service.
● reduce the price of certain goods or services for low-income
consumers.
● prevent exploitation by monopolies .
Two common situations where maximum price controls are used to
ensure the availability of:
● low-cost food for low-income earners.
● affordable housing for low-income families.
➢ As shown in Figure 1, with no government intervention, the rented accommodation
market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE.
➢ If the government set a maximum price on rented accommodation, it would be set
below the equilibrium price at Pmax, as shown in Figure 1. Cities like Berlin,
Stockholm and New York currently employ price controls for rented
accommodation.
➢ At the lower price, consumers would now be willing and able to consume a greater
amount, Q2, while producers, on the other hand, would be willing and able to
supply less, Q1. This would create an excess of demand from Q1 to Q2 and the
consumption of rented accommodation would actually fall to Q1 even though those
consumers would pay a lower price for them.
Possible consequences of imposing a maximum price
A price ceiling may produce several consequences. Let us
look at some of its possible outcomes and effects:
● It produces shortages.
● It generates a rationing problem.
● It promotes the creation of parallel (black) markets.
● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare
loss.
● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
It produces shortages
➢ At the price ceiling Pmax, the quantity supplied, Q1, is much lower than the
quantity demanded, Q2, therefore not all of the consumers who are willing
and able to buy the good at that price will be able to do so. The reduction
in quantity supplied is because producers cut production in response to
the lower price, and a shortage of Q2 – Q1 is created.
➢ If the price is kept at Pmax, there will be a quantity QE demanded by the
consumers who would have purchased the good at the previous price PE,
plus an additional quantity demanded by all of the new entrants to the
market attracted by the low price, who will not have access to it now.
It generates a rationing problem
As not all of the interested consumers will be able to purchase the good because of the
generated shortage, the problem of who gets to consume the good and how to ration the
available amount arises.
Because the price is no longer the method used to distribute the good,
non-price rationing methods have to be used. These include:
● People line up and wait their turn to buy the good, and only those who arrive first will
be able to do so.
● Coupons are distributed between the interested buyers so that they can purchase a
fixed amount of the good in a given time period.
Sellers use favouritism to choose who they sell the good to; sellers can sell the good to their
preferred clients.
It promotes the creation of parallel (black) markets
➢ A parallel market, is a market where buying and selling transactions are unrecorded, and
are usually illegal.
➢ In this case, many consumers who were willing and able to purchase the good
at a higher price than the one set by the government will not be able to
purchase the good through the legal market because of the shortage produced
by the maximum price
➢ At the same time, many producers who could have sold more units of the good
at a higher price than Pmax before setting the price control will not be able to
sell that higher amount through the legal market either.
It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss
➢ As a smaller amount of the good is being produced and consumed (Q1) than
the socially optimal amount determined by market equilibrium (QE), there
will be an under-allocation of resources to the production of the good from
the society's point of view.
➢ This allocative inefficiency results in society being worse off.
➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price controls, the market equilibrium is at
price PE and quantity QE. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B and
producer surplus is equal to C + D + E.
➢ When the price ceiling is set, consumers only consume the quantity Q1,
therefore the consumer surplus is area A + C (all of the area below the
demand curve and above the price paid by consumers Pmax, for the
units consumed).
➢ Producer surplus is now only E (all of the area above the supply curve
and below the price received by producers, Pmax, for the units sold).
➢ The total community surplus after the maximum price control is set is
the area A + C + E. By comparing this to the total social welfare before
the maximum price, we can see that society suffers a deadweight loss of
B + D, as shown by the shaded area in the diagram.
Consumers: Some consumers of the good are better off and some are worse off. Those who
get to buy the good at a lower price than before are better off. Those who do not get to
consume it at any price at all because of shortages or rationing are worse off.
Producers: Producers now sell a smaller amount of the good than before (Q1 < Qe) and
receive a lower price for it. Their total revenue falls after the price ceiling is imposed,
therefore they are worse off.
Workers: As the size of the market is reduced and fewer units of the good are sold, it is
probable that workers will be fired in this market and unemployment will increase. Thus,
those workers will be worse off.
Government: Government does not have a revenue or a cost from this specific policy.
However, it may gain political popularity from those consumers who get to consume the good
at a lower price than before.
Solutions to maximum price control consequences
The basic problem created by the maximum price is the excess demand or shortage of
the product in the market.
There are three ways in which the government can do this. It can:
● grant subsidies to the producers to encourage them to increase
supply by producing more of the good.
● increase supply by producing the shortfall quantity of the good itself
to meet total demand.
● store some of the product (as long as it is not a perishable good)
before setting the price ceiling, then increase supply when needed by
releasing some of its stocks on to the market.
Price floors
➢ The situation for minimum price controls (price floors) is the opposite to maximum
price controls.
➢ In this case, the government sets a minimum price above the equilibrium price,
preventing producers from selling their product below it.
➢ This is done to protect producers, usually in the case of commodities and in the
labour market.
Usually the aims of this policy for the government are:
● to increase the income of producers of goods and services that the government
considers important, such as agricultural products, which are subject to large price
fluctuations or great foreign competition.
● to protect workers, by setting a minimum wage that ensures they earn enough to have
a reasonable standard of living.
➢ Figure 1 shows the example of corn. With no government intervention,
the market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE.
➢ If the government set a minimum price on corn, it would be set above
the equilibrium price at Pmin, as shown in the diagram.
➢ At the higher price, producers would be willing and able to supply a
greater amount, Q2, while consumers would be willing and able to buy
less, Q1. This would create an excess of supply from Q1 to Q2.
Possible consequences of imposing a minimum
price
A price floor may produce several consequences. Let us analyse some of its possible
outcomes and effects:
● It produces surpluses.
● It promotes the creation of black markets.
● The government needs to dispose of the surplus.
● It might create firm inefficiency.
● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss.
● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
Surpluses
➢ Figure 1 shows that at the price floor, Pmin, the quantity supplied, Q2, is much
higher than the quantity demanded, Q1, therefore not all of the crop
produced will be bought by consumers.
➢ Consumers will purchase less in response to the higher price and a surplus of
Q2 – Q1 is created.
➢ If the price is kept at Pmin, there will be a quantity QE supplied by all the
producers who would have produced the good at the previous price PE, plus
an additional quantity supplied by all of the new entrants to the market
attracted by the high price, who will not be able to sell it anymore.
Informal (black) markets
➢ If producers cannot sell all of their goods at the regulated price
Pmin, they may try to sell it at a lower price on the informal (or
black) market.
➢ This practice is illegal and will go against the original objective of
the policy by selling the good at a lower price nearer to the original
equilibrium price.
Government must dispose of the surplus
As not all of the product will be sold to consumers, the problem of what to do
with the surplus arises.
One option is that the government purchases the excess supply, shifting the
demand curve outwards, as shown in Figure 2, up to the new equilibrium
quantity Q2. This will generate a cost for the government.
Once it has bought the surplus, the government needs to decide what to do with it. The
government can:
● store the good, which will generate additional costs.
● sell the surplus abroad (export). It may have to consider what price to sell it at, if it
aims to make back the money spent buying the surplus initially and also ensure the
price is competitive abroad. It would need to be careful to not be seen to ‘dump’ the
surplus abroad and be accused of unfair trade practices.
● send the surplus as aid to developing countries, but this usually causes problems for
these countries, by reducing the demand for locally produced goods and potentially
damaging local businesses.
● burn the excess good, but burning food (as in this example) is seen as being
extremely wasteful and unethical given that so many people in the world are
starving.
Firm inefficiency
➢ If firms know they will receive a higher price no matter how
inefficient they are in their production process, they will not be
motivated to reduce costs and use more efficient methods of
production.
➢ Higher prices than the equilibrium price may lead to production
inefficiency, because the high prices protect the firms from
lower-cost competitors.
Allocative inefficiency and welfare loss
➢ As a greater amount of the good is produced, Q2, than the socially optimal
amount determined by the market equilibrium, Qe,
➢ There is an over-allocation of resources to the production of the good from the
society's point of view. Allocative inefficiency causes the society to be worse off.
➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price control the market equilibrium is set at the
price Pe and the quantity Qe. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B + C and
producer surplus is equal to D + E.
Price floors
➢ The situation for minimum price controls (price floors) is the opposite
to maximum price controls.
➢ In this case, the government sets a minimum price above the
equilibrium price, preventing producers from selling their product
below it.
➢ This is done to protect producers, usually in the case of commodities
and in the labour market.
Usually the aims of this policy for the government are:
● to increase the income of producers of goods and services that the
government considers important, such as agricultural products, which are
subject to large price fluctuations or great foreign competition.
● to protect workers, by setting a minimum wage that ensures they earn
enough to have a reasonable standard of living.
Figure 1 shows the example of corn. With no government intervention, the
market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE.
➢ If the government set a minimum price on corn, it would be set
above the equilibrium price at Pmin, as shown in the diagram.
➢ At the higher price, producers would be willing and able to supply a
greater amount, Q2, while consumers would be willing and able to
buy less, Q1. This would create an excess of supply from Q1 to Q2.
➢ If the government does not intervene further, then the original policy
objective of protecting producers of corn by increasing their revenue
might not be achieved.
➢ The price has increased, but only for those who are still willing and
able to consume the good at the higher price, so the quantity sold has
fallen.
➢ Whether or not setting a minimum price will increase the producers'
total revenue depends on which of the two effects – an increased price
or decreased quantity demanded – has been stronger (this depends on
the relative elasticity of demand).
Possible consequences of imposing a minimum price
A price floor may produce several consequences. Let us
analyse some of its possible outcomes and effects:
● It produces surpluses.
● It promotes the creation of black markets.
● The government needs to dispose of the surplus.
● It might create firm inefficiency.
● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare
loss.
● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
Surpluses
➢ Figure 1 shows that at the price floor, Pmin, the quantity supplied, Q2, is much higher than
the quantity demanded, Q1, therefore not all of the crop produced will be bought by
consumers.
➢ Consumers will purchase less in response to the higher price and a surplus of Q2 – Q1 is
created.
➢ If the price is kept at Pmin, there will be a quantity QE supplied by all the producers who
would have produced the good at the previous price PE, plus an additional quantity
supplied by all of the new entrants to the market attracted by the high price, who will not
be able to sell it anymore.
Informal (black) markets
➢ If producers cannot sell all of their goods at the regulated price Pmin,
they may try to sell it at a lower price on the informal (or black)
market.
➢ This practice is illegal and will go against the original objective of the
policy by selling the good at a lower price nearer to the original
equilibrium price.
Government must dispose of the surplus
➢ As not all of the product will be sold to consumers, the problem of
what to do with the surplus arises.
➢ One option is that the government purchases the excess supply,
shifting the demand curve outwards, as shown in Figure 2, up to the
new equilibrium quantity Q2. This will generate a cost for the
government.
Once it has bought the surplus, the government needs to decide what to do with it. The
government can:
● store the good, which will generate additional costs.
● sell the surplus abroad (export). It may have to consider what price to sell it at, if it aims
to make back the money spent buying the surplus initially and also ensure the price is
competitive abroad. It would need to be careful to not be seen to ‘dump’ the surplus
abroad and be accused of unfair trade practices.
● send the surplus as aid to developing countries, but this usually causes problems for
these countries, by reducing the demand for locally produced goods and potentially
damaging local businesses.
● burn the excess good, but burning food (as in this example) is seen as being extremely
wasteful and unethical given that so many people in the world are starving.
Firm inefficiency
➢ If firms know they will receive a higher price no matter how
inefficient they are in their production process, they will not be
motivated to reduce costs and use more efficient methods of
production.
➢ Higher prices than the equilibrium price may lead to production
inefficiency, because the high prices protect the firms from
lower-cost competitors.
Allocative inefficiency and welfare loss
➢ As a greater amount of the good is produced, Q2, than the socially optimal
amount determined by the market equilibrium, Qe, there is an
over-allocation of resources to the production of the good from the society's
point of view. Allocative inefficiency causes the society to be worse off.
➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price control the market equilibrium is set at
the price Pe and the quantity Qe. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B +
C and producer surplus is equal to D + E.
Consequences for market stakeholders
Consumers. Consumers of the good are worse off as they will now consume a smaller amount of the good at a
higher price.
Producers. If the government purchases the surplus, producers will sell a greater amount of the good than
before (Q2 > Qe) and receive a higher price for it. Their total revenue increases after the price floor is imposed,
therefore they are better off. If the government does not purchase the surplus then producers sell a lower
volume of the good at a higher price. It depends on the price elasticity of demand whether their revenue
increases or falls.
Workers. As the size of the market increases, it is likely that more workers will be hired in this market and
consequently employment will rise; therefore workers will be better off.
Government. If the government buys the surplus it will incur a cost and have less funds to spend on other
public goods and services, which is an opportunity cost. Additionally, if it has to store the product the cost will
be even higher.
Indirect taxes
➢ Indirect taxes refer to taxes on expenditure. They are not charged directly
on people's incomes or wealth. They are paid indirectly by consumers when
they purchase a good, as indirect taxes are included in the price of the
good.
The aims of this policy for the government are usually to:
● collect government revenue.
● discourage consumption of undesirable and/or dangerous goods.
● redistribute income within the population.
● correct negative externalities and socially inefficient allocation of
resources.
Indirect taxes are also called excise taxes. There are two types to
consider:
● Specific tax. This is a fixed amount of tax imposed on a good or
service per unit sold; for example, a tax of EUR 2 per can of
beer.
● Percentage tax or ad valorem tax. This is a fixed percentage
charged on the selling price of the good; for example, a 20 per
cent tax on the price of cigarettes. In this case the amount of the
tax increases as the price of the good or service increases.
➢ When a tax is imposed on a good or service, it is paid by the
firm to the government. This means that for every level of
output, the firm will try to pass the tax on to consumers,
shifting the supply curve upwards by the amount of the tax.
➢ The firm will be willing and able to supply to the market each
level of output at the original price plus the amount of the tax.
Or, put differently, for each original pre-tax price, the firm
will be willing to supply less output (seen as a shift inwards/to
the left of the supply curve).
Figure 2a shows the effect of imposing a specific tax on the supply curve of
a good. S1 is the original supply curve and S2 is the curve after the tax (S1
+ tax). As the amount of the tax is the same regardless of the price of the
good, the new supply curve shifts upwards parallel to the original one, by
the amount of the tax per unit.
In Figure 2b the tax is a percentage of the price, so the amount of tax
increases as the price of the good increases. The supply curve shifts
upwards by the amount of the tax per unit, but the gap between S1 and S2
will be bigger as the price is higher. So a 20 per cent tax on a price of EUR
5 is EUR 1, while a 20 per cent tax on a price of EUR 10 is EUR 2.
➢ Before the tax, the market was in equilibrium where D crosses S1, at an initial
equilibrium price PE and equilibrium quantity QE.
➢ Once the tax is set, the supply curve shifts upwards from S1 to S2 by the amount of
the tax. At the previous equilibrium price PE, producers will now be willing and able
to supply a smaller amount of the good to the market, as they have to pay the tax to
the government per unit of output. Alternatively, producers can try to pass the tax on
to consumers in order to sell the same amount QE.
➢ At higher prices, because of the law of demand, consumers will demand less of the
good, and therefore the new equilibrium price and quantity will be established at PC
and QT.
The effect on the different stakeholders
To understand the changes produced by an indirect tax on market outcomes,
and how the different stakeholders are affected in each case, we should try to
answer the following questions.
● What will happen to the price paid by consumers before and after tax?
● What will happen to the revenue received by producers?
● What is the situation of the government before and after tax?
● What will happen to the size of the market and what will be the
subsequent effect on the workers in that market?
● Is there an effect on society as a whole?
➢ The market outcomes due to the tax, reflected in Figure 2a, are as follows:
the equilibrium quantity produced and consumed decreases from Q* to
Qt, which means a reduction in the size of the market.
➢ The equilibrium price increases from P* to Pc, which is the price paid by
consumers. Producers receive Pc from consumers, but have to pay the
amount of the tax to the government for every unit sold, so their final
revenue is Pp per unit.
➢ In Table 1 we can see the specific effect of the tax on each of the market's
stakeholders, based on Figure 2a.
The effects of indirect tax on consumer and producer surplus
➢ In subtopic 2.3, we learned that in a competitive free market, at the market
equilibrium point (and with no government intervention), community surplus is
maximised and society is producing the socially optimal amount of a good,
thereby achieving allocative efficiency.
➢ This is shown in Figure 3a at the point (Q*, P*), where the marginal social cost is
equal to the marginal social benefit (MSC = MSB).
➢ What happens to consumer surplus, producer surplus and the total social welfare
after imposing an indirect tax on a good?
➢ After the tax, the supply curve shifts from S1 to S2 and the equilibrium
point moves from (Q*, P*) to (Qt, Pc).
➢ Consumer surplus is reduced from the yellow shaded triangle between P*
and the demand curve up to quantity Q* (Figure 3a, before the tax) to the
yellow triangle between Pc and the demand curve up to Qt (Figure 3b, after
the tax).
➢ Producer surplus is reduced from the peach shaded triangle between P*
and the supply curve up to quantity Q* (before the tax) to the peach
shaded triangle between Pp and the supply curve up to Qt (after the tax).
➢ The rectangle (Pc – Pp) × Qt in Figure 3b is now the government tax revenue, which comes
back to society in the form of government spending. However, there are two parts of the
original consumer and producer surplus that are lost: triangles A and B in Figure 3b.
➢ The area A + B represents the social welfare that is completely lost because of the tax and is
called
welfare loss or deadweight loss.
➢ The welfare loss appears because the tax distorts the market outcome, reducing the quantity
produced so that it is lower than the socially optimal amount (Qt < Q*), assuming there are no
externalities present.
➢ Therefore, there is an under-production of the good and an under-allocation of resources from
the society's point of view, resulting in allocative inefficiency.
Effect on society as a whole
➢ This policy should be evaluated within the context of the objective or reason for setting this tax.
For example, the reasons are often to achieve other social objectives or to solve market
externalities.
➢ However, assuming that free market equilibrium, with no government intervention, is the socially
optimal amount of the good, in the absence of externalities, then society as a whole is worse off.
➢ This is because the imposition of the tax distorts the market, producing an under-allocation of
resources to the production of this good
Subsidies
➢ Subsidies are per-unit payments that are used to lower production costs and
increase the output of the market.
Broadly, the aims of subsidies for the government are usually:
● to increase revenues of producers.
● to make basic necessities and merit goods more affordable to low-income
consumers.
● to encourage the consumption of a good or service that is considered beneficial
to consumers.
● to support growth of a particular industry.
● to encourage exports and protect national industry from foreign competition.
● to correct positive externalities, improving the allocation of resources.
The effect of subsidies on the market
➢ Figure 1 shows the case of granting a subsidy to the dairy industry, per
unit of output of milk. Dairy farming is subsidised by the European
Union.
➢ Before the subsidy, the market was in equilibrium where D crosses S1,
at an initial equilibrium price P* and equilibrium quantity Q*.
❖ Once the subsidy is granted, the supply curve shifts downwards from S1 to S2 by
the amount of the subsidy.
❖ Producers are willing and able to supply a greater amount of milk to the market at
the previous equilibrium price, P*, because their cost of production has fallen due
to the subsidy they have received from the EU per unit of output sold.
❖ As the supply increases, the equilibrium price in the market falls from P* to Pc.
❖ At lower prices, because of the law of demand, consumers will demand more milk
and therefore the new equilibrium price and quantity will be established at Pc and
Qsb.
The effect on different stakeholders
To understand the changes produced by a subsidy on market outcomes, we need
to repeat the same methodology we used for indirect taxes and analyse how the
different stakeholders are affected, answering the following questions.
● What will happen to the price paid by consumers before and after the
subsidy?
● What will happen to the revenue received by producers?
● What is the situation of the government before and after the subsidy?
● What will happen to the size of the market and, therefore, what will the
effect be on workers in that market?
● Is there an effect on society as a whole?
➢ The market outcomes due to the subsidy, reflected in Figure 1, are as
follows: the equilibrium quantity of milk produced and consumed
increases from Q* to Qsb, which means an increase in the size of the
market.
➢ The equilibrium price decreases from P* to Pc, which is the price paid by
consumers. Producers receive Pc from consumers, plus the amount of the
subsidy per unit of output, so their final revenue is Pp per unit.
➢ In Table 1 we can see the specific effect of the tax on each of the market's
stakeholders, based on Figure 1.
Direct provision of services
Other services that are often provided directly by the
state include:
● Public transport
● Rail networks
● Telecommunications
● Airlines
● Education
● Energy
➢ Some governments or political parties would like to nationalise or
renationalise certain services. Some argue that these are essential
services for which profit should not be a motive, and that citizens have
a right to access these services cheaply.
➢ It may also be argued that these industries are inherently
uncompetitive, so that having multiple suppliers of these services does
not really work.
➢ Public services are often examples of natural monopolies. Does it make
sense to have multiple train companies operating the same rail line?
Or to have multiple companies supplying water to your home?
➢ On the other hand, supporters of privatised essential services argue
that the profit motive promotes efficiency.
➢ By employing the principles of competition and free markets, a
privately funded health care system might allocate resources better and
be more cost effective.
➢ Privately funded services would be subject to less political debate, and
often might be provided sooner because the projects would have fewer
political hurdles and less bureaucracy to overcome.
Command and control regulation and legislation
➢ Regulation and legislation involve the government intervening in markets
through the legal system. Legislation refers to laws set out by legislative
bodies.
➢ For example, in many countries it is the law that all children attend
school or participate in education until a certain age. In order for schools
to demonstrate that children are participating in education,
➢ it is a legal requirement that schools register their students on a daily
basis and report frequent absences to the local authority or government.
In some countries, parents can even be fined if their children do not
attend school regularly.
Untitled presentation.pdf rreal world issue

More Related Content

Similar to Untitled presentation.pdf rreal world issue

IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptx
IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptxIGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptx
IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptxssuser569157
 
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptxHSWong4
 
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revision
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revisionComplete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revision
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revisionManishadhokia3105
 
Markets and government in a modern economy
Markets and government in a modern economyMarkets and government in a modern economy
Markets and government in a modern economyblues26
 
Nov12 presentation
Nov12 presentationNov12 presentation
Nov12 presentationitay1202
 
Managerial Economics (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)
Managerial Economics    (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)Managerial Economics    (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)
Managerial Economics (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)Ajeenkya D Y Patil
 
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.Arifa Saeed
 
Public Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxPublic Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxBedri Muktar
 
How basic economic problems are solved in different economies
How basic economic problems are solved in different economiesHow basic economic problems are solved in different economies
How basic economic problems are solved in different economiesMansoor Paleri
 
Introduction to microeconomics
Introduction to microeconomicsIntroduction to microeconomics
Introduction to microeconomicsmattbentley34
 

Similar to Untitled presentation.pdf rreal world issue (20)

Unit 6. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 6. ECONOMIC ACTIVITYUnit 6. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 6. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
 
Unit 5
Unit 5Unit 5
Unit 5
 
Unit 5
Unit 5Unit 5
Unit 5
 
IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptx
IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptxIGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptx
IGCSE Allocative Mechanisms & Problems of Transition.pptx
 
Unit 6
Unit 6Unit 6
Unit 6
 
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx
3.1 - Reasons for Government Intervention in Market.pptx
 
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITIESUnit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES
 
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revision
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revisionComplete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revision
Complete Economic Environment & Business Unit 4 revision
 
Markets and government in a modern economy
Markets and government in a modern economyMarkets and government in a modern economy
Markets and government in a modern economy
 
unit 3.pdf
unit 3.pdfunit 3.pdf
unit 3.pdf
 
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITYUnit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
 
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITYUnit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
 
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITYUnit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
Unit 5. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
 
Nov12 presentation
Nov12 presentationNov12 presentation
Nov12 presentation
 
Managerial Economics (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)
Managerial Economics    (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)Managerial Economics    (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)
Managerial Economics (Ajeenkya D Y Patil)
 
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.
MARKET FAILURE SITUATION IN THE ECONOMY.
 
Public Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxPublic Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptx
 
How basic economic problems are solved in different economies
How basic economic problems are solved in different economiesHow basic economic problems are solved in different economies
How basic economic problems are solved in different economies
 
Introduction to microeconomics
Introduction to microeconomicsIntroduction to microeconomics
Introduction to microeconomics
 
2
22
2
 

Recently uploaded

Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignHenry Tapper
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Serviceranjana rawat
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfGale Pooley
 
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...shivangimorya083
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spiritegoetzinger
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdfAdnet Communications
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfAdnet Communications
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfMichael Silva
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptxOAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptxhiddenlevers
 
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...Suhani Kapoor
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Commonwealth
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingMaristelaRamos12
 
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot ModelsAndheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Modelshematsharma006
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Roomdivyansh0kumar0
 
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewNew dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewAntonis Zairis
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxanshikagoel52
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
 
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
 
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
Russian Call Girls In Gtb Nagar (Delhi) 9711199012 💋✔💕😘 Naughty Call Girls Se...
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptxOAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptx
OAT_RI_Ep19 WeighingTheRisks_Apr24_TheYellowMetal.pptx
 
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
VIP Call Girls LB Nagar ( Hyderabad ) Phone 8250192130 | ₹5k To 25k With Room...
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
 
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot ModelsAndheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
 
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewNew dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
 

Untitled presentation.pdf rreal world issue

  • 1. Real-world issue 2: When are markets unable to satisfy important economic objectives – and does government intervention help? ➢ In theory, if market agents behave rationally, then the market will be allocatively efficient. Consumers get what they want or need, as long as they are willing and able to pay a price for it, and producers are rewarded for their efforts. Everyone is happy. ➢ However, do all markets behave in a way that results in allocative efficiency and socially desirable outcomes for all?
  • 2. Consider these examples: ● Food shortages ● Climate change ● Obesity ● Microplastic pollution ● Bisphenol A (BPA) toxicity in plastic food containers In all of these examples, the market system has created outcomes that have consequences for broader society, rather than just for the consumers and producers of that good or service.
  • 3. Governments can intervene in the following ways: ● Price controls ● Indirect taxes ● Subsidies ● Direct provision of services ● Command and control regulation and legislation ● Consumer nudges
  • 4. Concept Intervention ➢ Markets are tremendous forces for innovation and prosperity, but they can also create problems that are difficult to manage without intervention. Markets can fail to be allocatively efficient, which means they do not allocate resources in a way that maximises the interests of participants or third parties. ➢ When markets create problems beyond the transaction between buyers and sellers, the government can be justified to intervene using a variety of methods.
  • 5. Why do governments intervene? There are many reasons why governments want to intervene in markets .The reasons include: ● To earn government revenue ● To support firms ● To support households on low incomes ● To influence the level of production ● To influence the level of consumption ● To correct market failure ● To promote equity
  • 6. Earning government revenue ➢ The first significant reason to tax the consumption of goods and services is to raise government revenue. Governments tax a variety of goods and services, with many countries employing a goods and services tax (GST) or a value added tax (VAT) to most goods and services. ➢ Like any other tax,indirect taxes produce revenue for the government that can be used to finance government spending. Governments might use tax revenue to provide public goods and services, to invest in infrastructure, to improve education or to provide healthcare for the population of the country.
  • 7. ➢ Governments run budgets and need sources of income to finance their projects and expenditures. ➢ Indirect tax is a source of income for the government. ➢ Each time the government charges an indirect tax on a good or service, it collects a revenue equal to the tax charged per unit of the good sold multiplied by the quantity of goods sold.
  • 8.
  • 9. Supporting firms ➢ Governments like to use methods of intervention to support firms in particular industries. This can be for economic reasons, but also for political and strategic reasons. ➢ The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the European Union supports farming in member states by providing ‘direct payments’ to farming sectors in order to help support jobs and growth, modernise the industry and improve sustainability. In economics, we call this kind of support a subsidy
  • 10. Supporting households on low incomes ➢ Governments can also seek to support households in the country. Support can be targeted to certain households, or be universally applied. ➢ As an example, Indonesia has had fuel subsidies in place since the country gained its independence in 1949. ➢ ➢ They are primarily designed to support people on lower incomes to afford fuel for their cars, mopeds, and other fuel-reliant equipment. ➢ In addition, because the subsidy is universally applied, the wealthy, who have no problems paying for fuel for their luxury cars, also benefit from the lower fuel prices.
  • 11. Influencing the level of production ➢ Governments can use a number of methods to increase or decrease production of goods and services. ➢ In the case of undesirable goods, governments will often want to discourage their production, even though this will impact the businesses and employees in those industries. ➢ This is because the production of some goods can have negative effects on society.
  • 12. ➢ A good example of this is that many governments want to decrease the production of energy that uses fossil fuels. When energy is produced using natural gas, coal or petroleum, carbon dioxide is released into the atmosphere. ➢ This carbon dioxide pollutes the atmosphere, contributes to global climate change, and can create smog that affects the air quality of the local area. ➢ The Chinese government has acted in recent years to try to reduce the country’s dependence on energy produced by coal-fired power plants by investing in clean energy and operating an emissions trading scheme.
  • 13.
  • 14. Influencing the level of consumption ➢ Governments can use a variety of methods to increase or decrease consumption of goods and services. ➢ In the case of undesirable goods, governments will often want to discourage the consumption of them because it has negative consequences for those consuming as well as others in society. We call these kinds of goods demerit goods. ➢ Governments have a range of effective measures to help reduce smoking, including indirect taxes, support programmes to help people quit and legislation, such as age restrictions, bans on tobacco advertising, and smoking bans.
  • 15. Correcting market failure ➢ Market failure occurs when markets fail to allocate resources efficiently, and community surplus is not maximised. We will explore this concept in much greater detail later in this subtopic, but for now we can discuss a few basic ideas. ➢ The most prominent example of market failure today is the issue of climate change. ➢ Climate change is an example of market failure because the firms and consumers responsible for the problems have not contributed sufficiently to the costs associated with climate change
  • 16. Promoting equity ➢ Governments often choose to intervene in markets to improve the equity of the income distribution in the economy. We have already read about the fuel subsidies in Indonesia that aim to make fuel cheaper for low-income families. ➢ The most common forms of government intervention to promote equity are found in health care and education. These are two services that are deemed to be human rights, and thus most governments try to offer these goods at no cost to the public. ➢ Many governments think that a child’s ability to succeed in life should not be determined by their parents’ income.
  • 17.
  • 18. Price ceilings ➢ The market price for a good or service is sometimes unaffordable. This is common for essential goods and services, such as rented accommodation or food. ➢ The government can set a maximum price, also known as a price ceiling, below the equilibrium price to prevent producers from selling their product above it. ➢ This is done to protect consumers and is usually applied to necessity and/or merit goods.
  • 19. The aims of this policy are usually to: ● increase consumption of the good or service. ● reduce the price of certain goods or services for low-income consumers. ● prevent exploitation by monopolies . Two common situations where maximum price controls are used to ensure the availability of: ● low-cost food for low-income earners. ● affordable housing for low-income families.
  • 20.
  • 21. ➢ As shown in Figure 1, with no government intervention, the rented accommodation market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE. ➢ If the government set a maximum price on rented accommodation, it would be set below the equilibrium price at Pmax, as shown in Figure 1. Cities like Berlin, Stockholm and New York currently employ price controls for rented accommodation. ➢ At the lower price, consumers would now be willing and able to consume a greater amount, Q2, while producers, on the other hand, would be willing and able to supply less, Q1. This would create an excess of demand from Q1 to Q2 and the consumption of rented accommodation would actually fall to Q1 even though those consumers would pay a lower price for them.
  • 22. Possible consequences of imposing a maximum price A price ceiling may produce several consequences. Let us look at some of its possible outcomes and effects: ● It produces shortages. ● It generates a rationing problem. ● It promotes the creation of parallel (black) markets. ● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss. ● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
  • 23. It produces shortages ➢ At the price ceiling Pmax, the quantity supplied, Q1, is much lower than the quantity demanded, Q2, therefore not all of the consumers who are willing and able to buy the good at that price will be able to do so. The reduction in quantity supplied is because producers cut production in response to the lower price, and a shortage of Q2 – Q1 is created. ➢ If the price is kept at Pmax, there will be a quantity QE demanded by the consumers who would have purchased the good at the previous price PE, plus an additional quantity demanded by all of the new entrants to the market attracted by the low price, who will not have access to it now.
  • 24. It generates a rationing problem As not all of the interested consumers will be able to purchase the good because of the generated shortage, the problem of who gets to consume the good and how to ration the available amount arises. Because the price is no longer the method used to distribute the good, non-price rationing methods have to be used. These include: ● People line up and wait their turn to buy the good, and only those who arrive first will be able to do so. ● Coupons are distributed between the interested buyers so that they can purchase a fixed amount of the good in a given time period. Sellers use favouritism to choose who they sell the good to; sellers can sell the good to their preferred clients.
  • 25. It promotes the creation of parallel (black) markets ➢ A parallel market, is a market where buying and selling transactions are unrecorded, and are usually illegal. ➢ In this case, many consumers who were willing and able to purchase the good at a higher price than the one set by the government will not be able to purchase the good through the legal market because of the shortage produced by the maximum price ➢ At the same time, many producers who could have sold more units of the good at a higher price than Pmax before setting the price control will not be able to sell that higher amount through the legal market either.
  • 26. It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss ➢ As a smaller amount of the good is being produced and consumed (Q1) than the socially optimal amount determined by market equilibrium (QE), there will be an under-allocation of resources to the production of the good from the society's point of view. ➢ This allocative inefficiency results in society being worse off. ➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price controls, the market equilibrium is at price PE and quantity QE. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B and producer surplus is equal to C + D + E.
  • 27.
  • 28. ➢ When the price ceiling is set, consumers only consume the quantity Q1, therefore the consumer surplus is area A + C (all of the area below the demand curve and above the price paid by consumers Pmax, for the units consumed). ➢ Producer surplus is now only E (all of the area above the supply curve and below the price received by producers, Pmax, for the units sold). ➢ The total community surplus after the maximum price control is set is the area A + C + E. By comparing this to the total social welfare before the maximum price, we can see that society suffers a deadweight loss of B + D, as shown by the shaded area in the diagram.
  • 29. Consumers: Some consumers of the good are better off and some are worse off. Those who get to buy the good at a lower price than before are better off. Those who do not get to consume it at any price at all because of shortages or rationing are worse off. Producers: Producers now sell a smaller amount of the good than before (Q1 < Qe) and receive a lower price for it. Their total revenue falls after the price ceiling is imposed, therefore they are worse off. Workers: As the size of the market is reduced and fewer units of the good are sold, it is probable that workers will be fired in this market and unemployment will increase. Thus, those workers will be worse off. Government: Government does not have a revenue or a cost from this specific policy. However, it may gain political popularity from those consumers who get to consume the good at a lower price than before.
  • 30. Solutions to maximum price control consequences The basic problem created by the maximum price is the excess demand or shortage of the product in the market.
  • 31. There are three ways in which the government can do this. It can: ● grant subsidies to the producers to encourage them to increase supply by producing more of the good. ● increase supply by producing the shortfall quantity of the good itself to meet total demand. ● store some of the product (as long as it is not a perishable good) before setting the price ceiling, then increase supply when needed by releasing some of its stocks on to the market.
  • 32. Price floors ➢ The situation for minimum price controls (price floors) is the opposite to maximum price controls. ➢ In this case, the government sets a minimum price above the equilibrium price, preventing producers from selling their product below it. ➢ This is done to protect producers, usually in the case of commodities and in the labour market. Usually the aims of this policy for the government are: ● to increase the income of producers of goods and services that the government considers important, such as agricultural products, which are subject to large price fluctuations or great foreign competition. ● to protect workers, by setting a minimum wage that ensures they earn enough to have a reasonable standard of living.
  • 33. ➢ Figure 1 shows the example of corn. With no government intervention, the market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE. ➢ If the government set a minimum price on corn, it would be set above the equilibrium price at Pmin, as shown in the diagram. ➢ At the higher price, producers would be willing and able to supply a greater amount, Q2, while consumers would be willing and able to buy less, Q1. This would create an excess of supply from Q1 to Q2.
  • 34.
  • 35. Possible consequences of imposing a minimum price A price floor may produce several consequences. Let us analyse some of its possible outcomes and effects: ● It produces surpluses. ● It promotes the creation of black markets. ● The government needs to dispose of the surplus. ● It might create firm inefficiency. ● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss. ● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
  • 36. Surpluses ➢ Figure 1 shows that at the price floor, Pmin, the quantity supplied, Q2, is much higher than the quantity demanded, Q1, therefore not all of the crop produced will be bought by consumers. ➢ Consumers will purchase less in response to the higher price and a surplus of Q2 – Q1 is created. ➢ If the price is kept at Pmin, there will be a quantity QE supplied by all the producers who would have produced the good at the previous price PE, plus an additional quantity supplied by all of the new entrants to the market attracted by the high price, who will not be able to sell it anymore.
  • 37. Informal (black) markets ➢ If producers cannot sell all of their goods at the regulated price Pmin, they may try to sell it at a lower price on the informal (or black) market. ➢ This practice is illegal and will go against the original objective of the policy by selling the good at a lower price nearer to the original equilibrium price.
  • 38. Government must dispose of the surplus As not all of the product will be sold to consumers, the problem of what to do with the surplus arises. One option is that the government purchases the excess supply, shifting the demand curve outwards, as shown in Figure 2, up to the new equilibrium quantity Q2. This will generate a cost for the government.
  • 39. Once it has bought the surplus, the government needs to decide what to do with it. The government can: ● store the good, which will generate additional costs. ● sell the surplus abroad (export). It may have to consider what price to sell it at, if it aims to make back the money spent buying the surplus initially and also ensure the price is competitive abroad. It would need to be careful to not be seen to ‘dump’ the surplus abroad and be accused of unfair trade practices. ● send the surplus as aid to developing countries, but this usually causes problems for these countries, by reducing the demand for locally produced goods and potentially damaging local businesses. ● burn the excess good, but burning food (as in this example) is seen as being extremely wasteful and unethical given that so many people in the world are starving.
  • 40.
  • 41. Firm inefficiency ➢ If firms know they will receive a higher price no matter how inefficient they are in their production process, they will not be motivated to reduce costs and use more efficient methods of production. ➢ Higher prices than the equilibrium price may lead to production inefficiency, because the high prices protect the firms from lower-cost competitors.
  • 42. Allocative inefficiency and welfare loss ➢ As a greater amount of the good is produced, Q2, than the socially optimal amount determined by the market equilibrium, Qe, ➢ There is an over-allocation of resources to the production of the good from the society's point of view. Allocative inefficiency causes the society to be worse off. ➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price control the market equilibrium is set at the price Pe and the quantity Qe. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B + C and producer surplus is equal to D + E.
  • 43. Price floors ➢ The situation for minimum price controls (price floors) is the opposite to maximum price controls. ➢ In this case, the government sets a minimum price above the equilibrium price, preventing producers from selling their product below it. ➢ This is done to protect producers, usually in the case of commodities and in the labour market.
  • 44. Usually the aims of this policy for the government are: ● to increase the income of producers of goods and services that the government considers important, such as agricultural products, which are subject to large price fluctuations or great foreign competition. ● to protect workers, by setting a minimum wage that ensures they earn enough to have a reasonable standard of living. Figure 1 shows the example of corn. With no government intervention, the market would be trading at a price of PE and a quantity QE.
  • 45.
  • 46. ➢ If the government set a minimum price on corn, it would be set above the equilibrium price at Pmin, as shown in the diagram. ➢ At the higher price, producers would be willing and able to supply a greater amount, Q2, while consumers would be willing and able to buy less, Q1. This would create an excess of supply from Q1 to Q2.
  • 47. ➢ If the government does not intervene further, then the original policy objective of protecting producers of corn by increasing their revenue might not be achieved. ➢ The price has increased, but only for those who are still willing and able to consume the good at the higher price, so the quantity sold has fallen. ➢ Whether or not setting a minimum price will increase the producers' total revenue depends on which of the two effects – an increased price or decreased quantity demanded – has been stronger (this depends on the relative elasticity of demand).
  • 48. Possible consequences of imposing a minimum price A price floor may produce several consequences. Let us analyse some of its possible outcomes and effects: ● It produces surpluses. ● It promotes the creation of black markets. ● The government needs to dispose of the surplus. ● It might create firm inefficiency. ● It eliminates allocative efficiency and generates welfare loss. ● There are consequences for market stakeholders.
  • 49. Surpluses ➢ Figure 1 shows that at the price floor, Pmin, the quantity supplied, Q2, is much higher than the quantity demanded, Q1, therefore not all of the crop produced will be bought by consumers. ➢ Consumers will purchase less in response to the higher price and a surplus of Q2 – Q1 is created. ➢ If the price is kept at Pmin, there will be a quantity QE supplied by all the producers who would have produced the good at the previous price PE, plus an additional quantity supplied by all of the new entrants to the market attracted by the high price, who will not be able to sell it anymore.
  • 50. Informal (black) markets ➢ If producers cannot sell all of their goods at the regulated price Pmin, they may try to sell it at a lower price on the informal (or black) market. ➢ This practice is illegal and will go against the original objective of the policy by selling the good at a lower price nearer to the original equilibrium price.
  • 51. Government must dispose of the surplus ➢ As not all of the product will be sold to consumers, the problem of what to do with the surplus arises. ➢ One option is that the government purchases the excess supply, shifting the demand curve outwards, as shown in Figure 2, up to the new equilibrium quantity Q2. This will generate a cost for the government.
  • 52. Once it has bought the surplus, the government needs to decide what to do with it. The government can: ● store the good, which will generate additional costs. ● sell the surplus abroad (export). It may have to consider what price to sell it at, if it aims to make back the money spent buying the surplus initially and also ensure the price is competitive abroad. It would need to be careful to not be seen to ‘dump’ the surplus abroad and be accused of unfair trade practices. ● send the surplus as aid to developing countries, but this usually causes problems for these countries, by reducing the demand for locally produced goods and potentially damaging local businesses. ● burn the excess good, but burning food (as in this example) is seen as being extremely wasteful and unethical given that so many people in the world are starving.
  • 53.
  • 54. Firm inefficiency ➢ If firms know they will receive a higher price no matter how inefficient they are in their production process, they will not be motivated to reduce costs and use more efficient methods of production. ➢ Higher prices than the equilibrium price may lead to production inefficiency, because the high prices protect the firms from lower-cost competitors.
  • 55. Allocative inefficiency and welfare loss ➢ As a greater amount of the good is produced, Q2, than the socially optimal amount determined by the market equilibrium, Qe, there is an over-allocation of resources to the production of the good from the society's point of view. Allocative inefficiency causes the society to be worse off. ➢ As shown in Figure 3, with no price control the market equilibrium is set at the price Pe and the quantity Qe. Consumer surplus is equal to area A + B + C and producer surplus is equal to D + E.
  • 56.
  • 57. Consequences for market stakeholders Consumers. Consumers of the good are worse off as they will now consume a smaller amount of the good at a higher price. Producers. If the government purchases the surplus, producers will sell a greater amount of the good than before (Q2 > Qe) and receive a higher price for it. Their total revenue increases after the price floor is imposed, therefore they are better off. If the government does not purchase the surplus then producers sell a lower volume of the good at a higher price. It depends on the price elasticity of demand whether their revenue increases or falls. Workers. As the size of the market increases, it is likely that more workers will be hired in this market and consequently employment will rise; therefore workers will be better off. Government. If the government buys the surplus it will incur a cost and have less funds to spend on other public goods and services, which is an opportunity cost. Additionally, if it has to store the product the cost will be even higher.
  • 58. Indirect taxes ➢ Indirect taxes refer to taxes on expenditure. They are not charged directly on people's incomes or wealth. They are paid indirectly by consumers when they purchase a good, as indirect taxes are included in the price of the good. The aims of this policy for the government are usually to: ● collect government revenue. ● discourage consumption of undesirable and/or dangerous goods. ● redistribute income within the population. ● correct negative externalities and socially inefficient allocation of resources.
  • 59.
  • 60. Indirect taxes are also called excise taxes. There are two types to consider: ● Specific tax. This is a fixed amount of tax imposed on a good or service per unit sold; for example, a tax of EUR 2 per can of beer. ● Percentage tax or ad valorem tax. This is a fixed percentage charged on the selling price of the good; for example, a 20 per cent tax on the price of cigarettes. In this case the amount of the tax increases as the price of the good or service increases.
  • 61.
  • 62. ➢ When a tax is imposed on a good or service, it is paid by the firm to the government. This means that for every level of output, the firm will try to pass the tax on to consumers, shifting the supply curve upwards by the amount of the tax. ➢ The firm will be willing and able to supply to the market each level of output at the original price plus the amount of the tax. Or, put differently, for each original pre-tax price, the firm will be willing to supply less output (seen as a shift inwards/to the left of the supply curve).
  • 63. Figure 2a shows the effect of imposing a specific tax on the supply curve of a good. S1 is the original supply curve and S2 is the curve after the tax (S1 + tax). As the amount of the tax is the same regardless of the price of the good, the new supply curve shifts upwards parallel to the original one, by the amount of the tax per unit. In Figure 2b the tax is a percentage of the price, so the amount of tax increases as the price of the good increases. The supply curve shifts upwards by the amount of the tax per unit, but the gap between S1 and S2 will be bigger as the price is higher. So a 20 per cent tax on a price of EUR 5 is EUR 1, while a 20 per cent tax on a price of EUR 10 is EUR 2.
  • 64. ➢ Before the tax, the market was in equilibrium where D crosses S1, at an initial equilibrium price PE and equilibrium quantity QE. ➢ Once the tax is set, the supply curve shifts upwards from S1 to S2 by the amount of the tax. At the previous equilibrium price PE, producers will now be willing and able to supply a smaller amount of the good to the market, as they have to pay the tax to the government per unit of output. Alternatively, producers can try to pass the tax on to consumers in order to sell the same amount QE. ➢ At higher prices, because of the law of demand, consumers will demand less of the good, and therefore the new equilibrium price and quantity will be established at PC and QT.
  • 65. The effect on the different stakeholders To understand the changes produced by an indirect tax on market outcomes, and how the different stakeholders are affected in each case, we should try to answer the following questions. ● What will happen to the price paid by consumers before and after tax? ● What will happen to the revenue received by producers? ● What is the situation of the government before and after tax? ● What will happen to the size of the market and what will be the subsequent effect on the workers in that market? ● Is there an effect on society as a whole?
  • 66. ➢ The market outcomes due to the tax, reflected in Figure 2a, are as follows: the equilibrium quantity produced and consumed decreases from Q* to Qt, which means a reduction in the size of the market. ➢ The equilibrium price increases from P* to Pc, which is the price paid by consumers. Producers receive Pc from consumers, but have to pay the amount of the tax to the government for every unit sold, so their final revenue is Pp per unit. ➢ In Table 1 we can see the specific effect of the tax on each of the market's stakeholders, based on Figure 2a.
  • 67.
  • 68.
  • 69. The effects of indirect tax on consumer and producer surplus ➢ In subtopic 2.3, we learned that in a competitive free market, at the market equilibrium point (and with no government intervention), community surplus is maximised and society is producing the socially optimal amount of a good, thereby achieving allocative efficiency. ➢ This is shown in Figure 3a at the point (Q*, P*), where the marginal social cost is equal to the marginal social benefit (MSC = MSB). ➢ What happens to consumer surplus, producer surplus and the total social welfare after imposing an indirect tax on a good?
  • 70.
  • 71.
  • 72. ➢ After the tax, the supply curve shifts from S1 to S2 and the equilibrium point moves from (Q*, P*) to (Qt, Pc). ➢ Consumer surplus is reduced from the yellow shaded triangle between P* and the demand curve up to quantity Q* (Figure 3a, before the tax) to the yellow triangle between Pc and the demand curve up to Qt (Figure 3b, after the tax). ➢ Producer surplus is reduced from the peach shaded triangle between P* and the supply curve up to quantity Q* (before the tax) to the peach shaded triangle between Pp and the supply curve up to Qt (after the tax).
  • 73. ➢ The rectangle (Pc – Pp) × Qt in Figure 3b is now the government tax revenue, which comes back to society in the form of government spending. However, there are two parts of the original consumer and producer surplus that are lost: triangles A and B in Figure 3b. ➢ The area A + B represents the social welfare that is completely lost because of the tax and is called welfare loss or deadweight loss. ➢ The welfare loss appears because the tax distorts the market outcome, reducing the quantity produced so that it is lower than the socially optimal amount (Qt < Q*), assuming there are no externalities present. ➢ Therefore, there is an under-production of the good and an under-allocation of resources from the society's point of view, resulting in allocative inefficiency.
  • 74. Effect on society as a whole ➢ This policy should be evaluated within the context of the objective or reason for setting this tax. For example, the reasons are often to achieve other social objectives or to solve market externalities. ➢ However, assuming that free market equilibrium, with no government intervention, is the socially optimal amount of the good, in the absence of externalities, then society as a whole is worse off. ➢ This is because the imposition of the tax distorts the market, producing an under-allocation of resources to the production of this good
  • 75.
  • 76. Subsidies ➢ Subsidies are per-unit payments that are used to lower production costs and increase the output of the market. Broadly, the aims of subsidies for the government are usually: ● to increase revenues of producers. ● to make basic necessities and merit goods more affordable to low-income consumers. ● to encourage the consumption of a good or service that is considered beneficial to consumers. ● to support growth of a particular industry. ● to encourage exports and protect national industry from foreign competition. ● to correct positive externalities, improving the allocation of resources.
  • 77. The effect of subsidies on the market ➢ Figure 1 shows the case of granting a subsidy to the dairy industry, per unit of output of milk. Dairy farming is subsidised by the European Union. ➢ Before the subsidy, the market was in equilibrium where D crosses S1, at an initial equilibrium price P* and equilibrium quantity Q*.
  • 78. ❖ Once the subsidy is granted, the supply curve shifts downwards from S1 to S2 by the amount of the subsidy. ❖ Producers are willing and able to supply a greater amount of milk to the market at the previous equilibrium price, P*, because their cost of production has fallen due to the subsidy they have received from the EU per unit of output sold. ❖ As the supply increases, the equilibrium price in the market falls from P* to Pc. ❖ At lower prices, because of the law of demand, consumers will demand more milk and therefore the new equilibrium price and quantity will be established at Pc and Qsb.
  • 79.
  • 80. The effect on different stakeholders To understand the changes produced by a subsidy on market outcomes, we need to repeat the same methodology we used for indirect taxes and analyse how the different stakeholders are affected, answering the following questions. ● What will happen to the price paid by consumers before and after the subsidy? ● What will happen to the revenue received by producers? ● What is the situation of the government before and after the subsidy? ● What will happen to the size of the market and, therefore, what will the effect be on workers in that market? ● Is there an effect on society as a whole?
  • 81. ➢ The market outcomes due to the subsidy, reflected in Figure 1, are as follows: the equilibrium quantity of milk produced and consumed increases from Q* to Qsb, which means an increase in the size of the market. ➢ The equilibrium price decreases from P* to Pc, which is the price paid by consumers. Producers receive Pc from consumers, plus the amount of the subsidy per unit of output, so their final revenue is Pp per unit. ➢ In Table 1 we can see the specific effect of the tax on each of the market's stakeholders, based on Figure 1.
  • 82.
  • 83.
  • 85. Other services that are often provided directly by the state include: ● Public transport ● Rail networks ● Telecommunications ● Airlines ● Education ● Energy
  • 86. ➢ Some governments or political parties would like to nationalise or renationalise certain services. Some argue that these are essential services for which profit should not be a motive, and that citizens have a right to access these services cheaply. ➢ It may also be argued that these industries are inherently uncompetitive, so that having multiple suppliers of these services does not really work. ➢ Public services are often examples of natural monopolies. Does it make sense to have multiple train companies operating the same rail line? Or to have multiple companies supplying water to your home?
  • 87.
  • 88. ➢ On the other hand, supporters of privatised essential services argue that the profit motive promotes efficiency. ➢ By employing the principles of competition and free markets, a privately funded health care system might allocate resources better and be more cost effective. ➢ Privately funded services would be subject to less political debate, and often might be provided sooner because the projects would have fewer political hurdles and less bureaucracy to overcome.
  • 89. Command and control regulation and legislation ➢ Regulation and legislation involve the government intervening in markets through the legal system. Legislation refers to laws set out by legislative bodies. ➢ For example, in many countries it is the law that all children attend school or participate in education until a certain age. In order for schools to demonstrate that children are participating in education, ➢ it is a legal requirement that schools register their students on a daily basis and report frequent absences to the local authority or government. In some countries, parents can even be fined if their children do not attend school regularly.