SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 9
Download to read offline
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   1	
  
Discuss the pros and cons of using the subjective wellbeing
(happiness) approach to environmental valuation. Use examples to
illustrate your answer.
	
  
The subjective wellbeing (SWB) approach (hereafter, life satisfaction approach
(LSA)) to valuation has been gaining popularity in recent years, in contrast to the
traditional preference-based techniques (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). The LSA
provides an estimate of the value of non-market goods by looking at how they impact
on people’s reported wellbeing, using regression analysis. This valuation technique
has its pros over the more traditional techniques, but also faces its own set of
limitations. Valuation using LSA relies on two assumptions; a central assumption that
reported life satisfaction (LS) is a good proxy for an individual’s underlying utility
(Frey et al., 2009), and the less fundamental but more controversial assumption of
interpersonal comparability of LS scores (Menz, 2011). The latter assumption
however is contentiously regarded as a weakness of this valuation technique.
Conversely, the strength of the LSA is that it obviates some of the major limitations
of both stated and revealed preference techniques. Furthermore, Valuation using LSA
has the advantage of being potentially more informative than the standard techniques.
Nevertheless, the most arguably significant weakness of the LSA is that many
valuation studies give implausibly high estimates, which can be counter informative.
The rest of this essay will entail a critical discussion of the pros and cons of the LSA
outlined above, using illustrative examples where relevant.
The LSA has an advantage over both the revealed and stated preference methods that,
at least, in principle, makes it a more accurate valuation method. First, an advantage
of LSA over revealed preference methods is that it does not make the assumption of
market equilibrium. The hedonic method (HM) relies on the assumption of
equilibrium in the housing market, but this assumption is often violated (e.g. Ambrey
& Fleming, 2011) which results in biased willingness to pay (WTP) estimates (Frey et
al., 2009). The LSA, however, explicitly captures individual welfare in the absence of
market equilibrium (Frey et al., 2009), thus, obviating the resulting bias caused by the
assumption of market equilibrium in HM, and, therefore, giving more accurate
estimates. Second, the LSA attempts to avoid the major concerns with the use of
stated preference methods. The hypothetical nature of questions in stated preference
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   2	
  
studies are likely to entail superficial answers and strategic behavior from the
respondents (Di Tella & MacCulloch, 2008). Notably, these problems are difficult to
overcome (Frey et al., 2009). Although its disputable, the LSA is not affected by
either of these limitations of the standard techniques because the only information
people provide is their life satisfaction, which is cognitively less demanding and there
is no reason to expect strategic behavior bias (Frey et al., 2009).
A limitation of the LSA identified in the literature is its assumption of interpersonal
comparability of self-reported LS. Several studies using LSA to value environmental
conditions assume cardinality (thus interpersonal comparability), and whether this is a
weakness of the LSA still remains controversial. Interpersonal comparability is an
issue for studies using cross-sectional or panel datasets on wellbeing (Fujiwara &
Campbell, 2011). Notably, Welsch (2002, 2003, 2006, 2007) compare mean LS and
mean air pollutant values at the whole-country level, thereby making a strong
assumption of cardinality. At the individual level, the problem is that people could use
the LS scales differently (Stiglitz et al., 2009). At the whole-country level, Diener et
al. (1999) found evidence that LS scales might have to an extent different meaning
between cultures (Larsen, 2008). However, Veenhoven (1993) and subsequently
Bolle & Kemp (2009) find no indication that cultural or linguistic bias may prevent a
comparison of happiness across nations. Sandvik et al. (1993) have shown that
individuals are able to recognise and predict the satisfaction of others, suggesting that
SWB is observable and comparable between individuals (Fujiwara & Campbell,
2011; Welsch, 2006). Nevertheless, the assumption of cardinality, if incorrectly made
would yield estimates from LS studies that are both biased and inconsistent (Hill et
al., 2008 in Ambrey & Fleming, 2014).
Contrary to the Welsch studies, some LSA studies do not assume cardinality. In
specifying a happiness function, there are basically two varieties: a function with
individual happiness (micro approach) or a function with aggregate (average)
happiness (macro approach) (Welsch, 2006). The micro approach does not require a
cardinal self-reported happiness function but requires control for heterogeneity in
individuals’ characteristics (Welsch, 2006). Many authors (e.g. Ambrey et al., 2014)
have shown that estimates of coefficients are virtually unchanged, regardless of what
assumption is taken, contingent on individual heterogeneity being addressed
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   3	
  
appropriately (Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). Also, LSA studies that are not interested in
marginal utility of income or the environmental good separately, but only the ratio of
the two (MWTP) are not sensitive to the issue of interpersonal comparability
(Levinson, 2012). Thus two inferences can be made from this. First, evidence shows
that the assumption of interpersonal comparability is not particularly a significant
limitation of the LSA, because the bias caused by the assumption are not large.
Second, assuming it is a significant weakness of the LSA, not all studies make this
assumption, and therefore, it is only at best, a weak con of the LSA.
Conversely, another strength of the LSA to environmental valuation is the possibility
of going beyond average effects, which makes LS studies more informative relative to
the standard methods. Although the focus of valuation exercises usually entail
estimates for a typical member of the population under consideration (i.e. average), it
is possible to assess how estimates differ by age, income group or other
characteristics (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). Several studies report differentiated
effects for different subgroups of the population such as predicted risk groups, the
elderly or environmentalists (Frey et al., 2009). A notable example is the study based
on 35,000 happiness responses from OECD countries between 1975 and 1997 by Di
Tella & MacCulloch (2008) who investigated the effect of a number of variables on
life satisfaction including environmental degradation (measured by sulphur oxides
(SOx) emissions). Not only did they find a statistically significant negative impact of
SOx pollution on happiness, they also show that its effect on young adults is more
than twice the size of the effect on the elderly and that its also more negative on LS of
the highest income group relative to the country average. Frey et al. (2009) identify
that such differentiated effects can serve as robustness and plausibility check and also
provide valuable information for policy makers (Frey et al., 2009).
Furthermore, Fujiwara & Campbell (2011) note that sufficient sample size is a
prerequisite for subgroup valuations and most LSA studies use large national or
multinational datasets (e.g. Di Tella & MacCulloch, 2008). From these large datasets
comes another advantage over preference-based techniques. The larger datasets that
LSA studies have over both revealed preference and stated preference studies mean
that sample results are more representative of the population in general (Fujiwara &
Campbell, 2011). This however, does not apply to all LSA studies because some have
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   4	
  
small sample sizes (e.g. Mackerron & Mourato, 2009) and unrepresentative sample
groups (e.g. Mackerron & Mourato, 2013). Also, it should also be borne in mind that
many of these studies with large datasets such as Welsch (2002, 2003, 2006, 2007)
and Di Tella & MacCulloch (2008) face problems such as unobserved heterogeneity
from aggregated data that are regarded as serious limitations. Therefore, while the
relatively larger datasets of LSA studies and the potential of going beyond average
measures are seen as advantages, its validity will depend on the specific studies, their
methodology and the particular limitations they face.
In contrast, it is recognised that environmental valuation using LSA produces
implausibly high valuations, which presents itself as a significant con of the LSA. The
problem here involves the estimation of marginal utility of income in the LS
regression, where the coefficient of income tends to be statistically significant but
small, which often results in implausible WTP estimates for the environmental good
(Dolan et al., 2011). The causes often cited in the literature for the downward bias on
the estimate of the income coefficients are the issue of reverse causality between
income and LS and the closely related issues of adaptation to income and influence of
relative aspects of income on an individual’s LS. Many LSA studies have generated
implausible valuations (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). For example, in a study on air
pollution in London, Mackerron & Mourato (2009) find that a 1% increase in NO2
levels is equivalent, in LS terms, to a drop of 5.3% in income. They identify that that
this value is unrealistically high, both intuitively and in comparison with results from
revealed and stated preference studies. Such high values tend to be fairly common in
LS research to date (Mackerron & Mourato, 2009). As acknowledged in various
studies, including Mackerron & Mourato (2009), valuation estimates from most LSA
studies are somewhat higher than those calculated using stated and revealed
preference techniques (Menz, 2011). As a result, interpretation from LSA studies is a
controversial issue and a cautionary approach towards this approach is recommended
in the literature.
However, the issue of high valuation may not necessarily be as big a problem as it
often regarded. Firstly, some LSA studies estimate values using subjective wellbeing
score instead of monetary valuation (e.g. Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). Secondly, not all
LSA studies face the same outcome of implausible high valuations. Some valuation
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   5	
  
studies such as Luechinger & Raschky (2007) LS have produced reasonable estimates
that fall in a similar range as the preference-based techniques (table 1). Thirdly,
investigating the relationship between income and life satisfaction is a fast growing
area of research and better estimates of marginal utility of income are evolving
(Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). For example, Ambrey & Fleming (2014) use a subset of
windfall income (restricted windfall income) in place of the more conventional
household income measure in their study and find that the causal effect of income on
life satisfaction is substantially higher (and MWTP estimates substantially lower)
when restricted windfall income is used. Likewise, many other studies have
developed ways such as controlling for new relative income variables to reduce the
downward bias on estimate of income in LSA (e.g. Luttmer, 2005;Powdthavee, 2009;
Luechinger 2009a).
This essay shows that the LSA has its own pros and cons, but more importantly, there
are nuances within these well-identified factors. In relation to revealed preference
method, LSA has an advantage of avoiding the often-violated assumption of market
equilibrium that gives biased estimates. Similarly, the LSA has advantage over
revealed preference techniques because it circumvents the major issues of superficial
answers and strategic behavior inherent in hypothetical questions, but it also faces it
own related problems that have not been discussed here. Whether or not assuming
interpersonal comparability is a weakness of the LSA remains debatable.
Nevertheless, I argue that it is, at best, a weak con of this approach. Studies that adopt
the LSA can have an advantage of going beyond average estimates and tend to have
larger and more representative samples. However, the validity of these advantages
depends on individual studies. Arguably the most significant con of the LSA is the
relatively high and sometimes implausible valuation estimates studies produce.
Nonetheless, I debate that it is not as big a con as it portrayed because some studies
do not produce monetary valuations, others also produce estimates in a similar range
as the preference-based techniques and notably, the LSA is still evolving with
increase in research towards its improvement. It is important to note that there are also
other cons of the LSA including measurement errors and bias from reported LS as a
result of mood states, self-selection and the influence by immediate context, that have
not been discussed here. The nice feature of this approach is that, while it avoids the
problems of the preference-based techniques, its shortcomings also differ markedly
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   6	
  
from theirs, making it useful for comparison. Fujiwara & Campbell (2011)
recommend the LSA to be currently regarded as a complement to the more standard
methods. The UK Government is committed to improving the way that wellbeing and
social impacts are incorporated into policy decisions (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011).
With the increase in research towards improving the LSA and the stagnant status of
preference-based techniques, I believe the LSA has the potential of overcoming its
cons and significantly contributing to the government’s commitment to improvements
in the future.
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   7	
  
Appendix 1. TABLE
Table 1: valuation of PM10 using non-market valuation techniques. From Menz
(2011).
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   8	
  
Appendix	
  2.	
  References	
  Cited	
  
	
  
Ambrey,	
  C.L.	
  &	
  Fleming,	
  C.M.,	
  2011.	
  Valuing	
  scenic	
  amenity	
  using	
  life	
  satisfaction	
  
data.	
  Ecological	
  Economics,	
  72,	
  pp.106-­‐15.	
  
	
  
Ambrey,	
  C.L.	
  &	
  Fleming,	
  C.M.,	
  2014.	
  The	
  causal	
  effect	
  of	
  income	
  on	
  life	
  
satisfaction	
  and	
  the	
  implications	
  for	
  valuing	
  non-­‐market	
  goods.	
  Economics	
  
Letters,	
  123,	
  pp.131-­‐34.	
  
	
  
Ambrey,	
  C.L.,	
  Fleming,	
  C.M.	
  &	
  Chan,	
  A.Y.-­‐C.,	
  2014.	
  Estimating	
  the	
  cost	
  of	
  air	
  	
  
pollution	
  in	
  South	
  East	
  Queensland:	
  An	
  application	
  of	
  the	
  life	
  satisfaction	
  non-­‐
market	
  valuation	
  approach.	
  Ecological	
  Economics,	
  97,	
  pp.172-­‐81.	
  
	
  
Bolle,	
  F.	
  &	
  Kemp,	
  S.,	
  2009.	
  Can	
  we	
  compare	
  life	
  satisfaction	
  between	
  
nationalities?	
  Evaluating	
  actual	
  and	
  imagined	
  situations.	
  Social	
  Indicators	
  
Research,	
  90(3),	
  pp.297-­‐408.	
  
	
  
Di	
  Tella,	
  R.	
  &	
  MacCulloch,	
  R.,	
  2008.	
  Gross	
  national	
  happiness	
  as	
  an	
  answer	
  to	
  the	
  
Easterlin	
  Paradox.	
  Journal	
  of	
  Development	
  Economics,	
  86,	
  pp.22-­‐42.	
  
	
  
Diener,	
  E.,	
  1984.	
  Subjective	
  Well-­‐Being.	
  Psychological	
  Bulletin,	
  95(3),	
  pp.542-­‐75.	
  
Dolan,	
  P.,	
  Layard,	
  R.	
  &	
  Metcalfe,	
  R.,	
  2011.	
  Measuring	
  Subjective	
  Wellbeing	
  for	
  
Public	
  Policy:	
  Recommendations	
  on	
  Measures.	
  Special	
  paper.	
  London:	
  Centre	
  for	
  
Economic	
  Performance,	
  London	
  School	
  of	
  Economics	
  and	
  Political	
  Science	
  	
  
London	
  School	
  of	
  Economics	
  and	
  Political	
  Science.	
  
	
  
Frey,	
  B.S.,	
  Luechinger,	
  S.	
  &	
  Stutzer,	
  A.,	
  2009.	
  The	
  Life	
  Satisfaction	
  Approach	
  to	
  
Environmental	
  Valuation.	
  4478th	
  ed.	
  Bonn:	
  IZA.	
  
	
  
Fujiwara,	
  D.	
  &	
  Campbell,	
  R.,	
  2011.	
  Valuation	
  Techniques	
  for	
  Social	
  Cost-­‐Benefit	
  
Analysis:	
  Stated	
  Preference,	
  Revealed	
  Preference	
  and	
  Subjective	
  Well-­‐Being	
  
Approaches.	
  London:	
  HM	
  Treasury	
  and	
  Department	
  for	
  Works	
  and	
  Pensions	
  
(DWP).	
  
	
  
George,	
  M.	
  &	
  Mourato,	
  S.,	
  2013.	
  Happiness	
  is	
  greater	
  in	
  natural	
  environments.	
  
Global	
  Environmental	
  Change,	
  23,	
  pp.992-­‐1000.	
  
	
  
Larsen,	
  E.,	
  2008.	
  The	
  Science	
  of	
  Subjective	
  Well-­‐Being.	
  1st	
  ed.	
  Ney	
  York:	
  The	
  
Guilford	
  Press.	
  
	
  
Levinson,	
  A.,	
  2012.	
  Valuing	
  public	
  goods	
  using	
  happiness	
  data:	
  The	
  case	
  of	
  air	
  
quality.	
  Journal	
  of	
  Public	
  Economics,	
  96,	
  pp.869-­‐80.	
  
	
  
Luechinger,	
  S.,	
  2009a.	
  Valuing	
  Air	
  Quality	
  using	
  the	
  Life	
  Satisfaction	
  Approach.	
  
The	
  Economic	
  Journal	
  ,	
  119,	
  pp.482-­‐515.	
  
	
  
Luechinger,	
  S.	
  &	
  Raschky,	
  P.A.,	
  2007.	
  Valuing	
  Flood	
  Disasters	
  Using	
  the	
  life	
  
Satisfaction	
  Approach.	
  Zurich.	
  
	
  
Candidate	
  Number:	
  68250	
   9	
  
MacKerron,	
  G.	
  &	
  Mourato,	
  S.,	
  2009.	
  Life	
  satisfaction	
  and	
  air	
  quality	
  in	
  London.	
  
Ecological	
  Economics,	
  68,	
  pp.1441-­‐53.	
  
	
  
Menz,	
  T.,	
  2011.	
  Do	
  people	
  habituate	
  to	
  air	
  pollution?	
  Evidence	
  from	
  international	
  
life	
  satisfaction	
  data.	
  Ecological	
  Economics,	
  71,	
  pp.211-­‐19.	
  
	
  
Powdthavee,	
  N.,	
  2009.	
  How	
  much	
  does	
  money	
  really	
  matter?	
  Estimating	
  the	
  
causal	
  effects	
  of	
  income	
  on	
  happiness.	
  Empirical	
  Economics,	
  39,	
  pp.77-­‐92.	
  
	
  
Sandvik,	
  E.,	
  Diener,	
  E.	
  &	
  Seidlitz,	
  L.,	
  1993.	
  Subjective	
  Well-­‐Being:	
  The	
  
Convergence	
  and	
  stability	
  of	
  Self-­‐Reported	
  and	
  Non-­‐Self-­‐Report	
  Measures.	
  
Journal	
  of	
  Personality	
  ,	
  61(3),	
  pp.317-­‐42.	
  
	
  
Stiglitz,	
  J.E.,	
  Sen,	
  A.	
  &	
  Fitoussi,	
  J.-­‐P.,	
  2009.	
  Report	
  by	
  the	
  Commission	
  on	
  the	
  
Measurement	
  of	
  Economic	
  Performance	
  and	
  Social	
  Progress.	
  Paris:	
  Commission	
  
on	
  the	
  Measurement	
  of	
  Economic	
  Performance	
  and	
  Social	
  Progress	
  French	
  
Government.	
  
	
  
Veenhoven,	
  R.,	
  1993.	
  Happiness	
  in	
  Nations:	
  Subjective	
  Appreciation	
  of	
  Life	
  in	
  56	
  
Nations	
  1946-­‐1992.	
  Rotterdam:	
  Erasmus	
  University	
  Press	
  Erasmus	
  University.	
  
	
  
Welsch,	
  H.,	
  2002.	
  Preferences	
  over	
  prosperity	
  and	
  pollution:	
  environmental	
  
valuation	
  based	
  on	
  happiness	
  surveys.	
  Kyklos,	
  55(4),	
  pp.473-­‐94.	
  
	
  
Welsch,	
  H.,	
  2003.	
  Environment	
  and	
  Happiness:	
  Valuation	
  of	
  Air	
  Pollution	
  in	
  Ten	
  
European	
  Countries.	
  German	
  Institute	
  for	
  Economic	
  Research.	
  
	
  
Welsch,	
  H.,	
  2006.	
  Environment	
  and	
  happiness:	
  Valuation	
  of	
  air	
  pollution	
  using	
  
life	
  satisfaction	
  data.	
  Ecological	
  Economics,	
  58,	
  pp.801-­‐13.	
  
	
  
Welsch,	
  H.,	
  2007.	
  Environmental	
  welfare	
  analysis:	
  A	
  Life	
  satisfaction	
  approach.	
  
Ecological	
  Economics,	
  62,	
  pp.544-­‐51.	
  
	
  

More Related Content

Similar to The_pros_and_cons_of_using_the_subjectiv

Addressing Gender Inequality In Science The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...
Addressing Gender Inequality In Science  The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...Addressing Gender Inequality In Science  The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...
Addressing Gender Inequality In Science The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...Nathan Mathis
 
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09Kathryn Ashton
 
Couples in the UK Labour Market: Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...
Couples in the UK Labour Market:  Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...Couples in the UK Labour Market:  Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...
Couples in the UK Labour Market: Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...Wendy Olsen
 
Beyond measures and monitoring
Beyond measures and monitoringBeyond measures and monitoring
Beyond measures and monitoringScott Miller
 
Ak park zak_2007
Ak park zak_2007Ak park zak_2007
Ak park zak_2007Jang Park
 
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for Jan
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for JanDatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for Jan
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for JanOllieShoresna
 
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183Soma Sinha Roy
 
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jonesSailendra Nangadam
 
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...Sonia Whiteley
 
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor Analysis
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor AnalysisA Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor Analysis
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor AnalysisKamden Strunk
 
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on Employees
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on EmployeesResearch Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on Employees
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on EmployeesAnnie-Pierre Fortier
 
A General Approach To Causal Mediation Analysis
A General Approach To Causal Mediation AnalysisA General Approach To Causal Mediation Analysis
A General Approach To Causal Mediation AnalysisJeff Brooks
 
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
Machine Learning and Causal InferenceMachine Learning and Causal Inference
Machine Learning and Causal InferenceNBER
 
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docx
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docxWhat determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docx
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docxalanfhall8953
 

Similar to The_pros_and_cons_of_using_the_subjectiv (20)

Addressing Gender Inequality In Science The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...
Addressing Gender Inequality In Science  The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...Addressing Gender Inequality In Science  The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...
Addressing Gender Inequality In Science The Multifaceted Challenge Of Assess...
 
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09
LongitudinalAttrtionLitReviewNov09
 
Couples in the UK Labour Market: Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...
Couples in the UK Labour Market:  Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...Couples in the UK Labour Market:  Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...
Couples in the UK Labour Market: Labour Supply And Sociological Interpretati...
 
Beyond measures and monitoring
Beyond measures and monitoringBeyond measures and monitoring
Beyond measures and monitoring
 
Ak park zak_2007
Ak park zak_2007Ak park zak_2007
Ak park zak_2007
 
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...
There’s No Escape from External Validity – Reporting Habits of Randomized Con...
 
DuncanReese2013
DuncanReese2013DuncanReese2013
DuncanReese2013
 
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for Jan
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for JanDatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for Jan
DatosEmployee Wellness CenterStart DateDurationProcurement for Jan
 
Multimode Global Scale Usage
Multimode Global Scale UsageMultimode Global Scale Usage
Multimode Global Scale Usage
 
Dissertation
DissertationDissertation
Dissertation
 
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183
Ejbrm volume6-issue1-article183
 
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones
02. predicting financial distress logit mode jones
 
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...
Mitigating errors of representation: a practical case study of the University...
 
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor Analysis
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor AnalysisA Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor Analysis
A Method for Meta-Analytic Confirmatory Factor Analysis
 
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on Employees
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on EmployeesResearch Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on Employees
Research Paper- The Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility on Employees
 
A General Approach To Causal Mediation Analysis
A General Approach To Causal Mediation AnalysisA General Approach To Causal Mediation Analysis
A General Approach To Causal Mediation Analysis
 
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
Machine Learning and Causal InferenceMachine Learning and Causal Inference
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
 
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...
How Much Can We Generalize? Measuring the External Validity of Impact Evaluat...
 
Dr. Obumneke Amadi-Onuoha Scripts- 7_project_rsch
Dr.  Obumneke Amadi-Onuoha Scripts- 7_project_rschDr.  Obumneke Amadi-Onuoha Scripts- 7_project_rsch
Dr. Obumneke Amadi-Onuoha Scripts- 7_project_rsch
 
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docx
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docxWhat determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docx
What determines the behaviour and performance of healthprofe.docx
 

The_pros_and_cons_of_using_the_subjectiv

  • 1. Candidate  Number:  68250   1   Discuss the pros and cons of using the subjective wellbeing (happiness) approach to environmental valuation. Use examples to illustrate your answer.   The subjective wellbeing (SWB) approach (hereafter, life satisfaction approach (LSA)) to valuation has been gaining popularity in recent years, in contrast to the traditional preference-based techniques (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). The LSA provides an estimate of the value of non-market goods by looking at how they impact on people’s reported wellbeing, using regression analysis. This valuation technique has its pros over the more traditional techniques, but also faces its own set of limitations. Valuation using LSA relies on two assumptions; a central assumption that reported life satisfaction (LS) is a good proxy for an individual’s underlying utility (Frey et al., 2009), and the less fundamental but more controversial assumption of interpersonal comparability of LS scores (Menz, 2011). The latter assumption however is contentiously regarded as a weakness of this valuation technique. Conversely, the strength of the LSA is that it obviates some of the major limitations of both stated and revealed preference techniques. Furthermore, Valuation using LSA has the advantage of being potentially more informative than the standard techniques. Nevertheless, the most arguably significant weakness of the LSA is that many valuation studies give implausibly high estimates, which can be counter informative. The rest of this essay will entail a critical discussion of the pros and cons of the LSA outlined above, using illustrative examples where relevant. The LSA has an advantage over both the revealed and stated preference methods that, at least, in principle, makes it a more accurate valuation method. First, an advantage of LSA over revealed preference methods is that it does not make the assumption of market equilibrium. The hedonic method (HM) relies on the assumption of equilibrium in the housing market, but this assumption is often violated (e.g. Ambrey & Fleming, 2011) which results in biased willingness to pay (WTP) estimates (Frey et al., 2009). The LSA, however, explicitly captures individual welfare in the absence of market equilibrium (Frey et al., 2009), thus, obviating the resulting bias caused by the assumption of market equilibrium in HM, and, therefore, giving more accurate estimates. Second, the LSA attempts to avoid the major concerns with the use of stated preference methods. The hypothetical nature of questions in stated preference
  • 2. Candidate  Number:  68250   2   studies are likely to entail superficial answers and strategic behavior from the respondents (Di Tella & MacCulloch, 2008). Notably, these problems are difficult to overcome (Frey et al., 2009). Although its disputable, the LSA is not affected by either of these limitations of the standard techniques because the only information people provide is their life satisfaction, which is cognitively less demanding and there is no reason to expect strategic behavior bias (Frey et al., 2009). A limitation of the LSA identified in the literature is its assumption of interpersonal comparability of self-reported LS. Several studies using LSA to value environmental conditions assume cardinality (thus interpersonal comparability), and whether this is a weakness of the LSA still remains controversial. Interpersonal comparability is an issue for studies using cross-sectional or panel datasets on wellbeing (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). Notably, Welsch (2002, 2003, 2006, 2007) compare mean LS and mean air pollutant values at the whole-country level, thereby making a strong assumption of cardinality. At the individual level, the problem is that people could use the LS scales differently (Stiglitz et al., 2009). At the whole-country level, Diener et al. (1999) found evidence that LS scales might have to an extent different meaning between cultures (Larsen, 2008). However, Veenhoven (1993) and subsequently Bolle & Kemp (2009) find no indication that cultural or linguistic bias may prevent a comparison of happiness across nations. Sandvik et al. (1993) have shown that individuals are able to recognise and predict the satisfaction of others, suggesting that SWB is observable and comparable between individuals (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011; Welsch, 2006). Nevertheless, the assumption of cardinality, if incorrectly made would yield estimates from LS studies that are both biased and inconsistent (Hill et al., 2008 in Ambrey & Fleming, 2014). Contrary to the Welsch studies, some LSA studies do not assume cardinality. In specifying a happiness function, there are basically two varieties: a function with individual happiness (micro approach) or a function with aggregate (average) happiness (macro approach) (Welsch, 2006). The micro approach does not require a cardinal self-reported happiness function but requires control for heterogeneity in individuals’ characteristics (Welsch, 2006). Many authors (e.g. Ambrey et al., 2014) have shown that estimates of coefficients are virtually unchanged, regardless of what assumption is taken, contingent on individual heterogeneity being addressed
  • 3. Candidate  Number:  68250   3   appropriately (Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). Also, LSA studies that are not interested in marginal utility of income or the environmental good separately, but only the ratio of the two (MWTP) are not sensitive to the issue of interpersonal comparability (Levinson, 2012). Thus two inferences can be made from this. First, evidence shows that the assumption of interpersonal comparability is not particularly a significant limitation of the LSA, because the bias caused by the assumption are not large. Second, assuming it is a significant weakness of the LSA, not all studies make this assumption, and therefore, it is only at best, a weak con of the LSA. Conversely, another strength of the LSA to environmental valuation is the possibility of going beyond average effects, which makes LS studies more informative relative to the standard methods. Although the focus of valuation exercises usually entail estimates for a typical member of the population under consideration (i.e. average), it is possible to assess how estimates differ by age, income group or other characteristics (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). Several studies report differentiated effects for different subgroups of the population such as predicted risk groups, the elderly or environmentalists (Frey et al., 2009). A notable example is the study based on 35,000 happiness responses from OECD countries between 1975 and 1997 by Di Tella & MacCulloch (2008) who investigated the effect of a number of variables on life satisfaction including environmental degradation (measured by sulphur oxides (SOx) emissions). Not only did they find a statistically significant negative impact of SOx pollution on happiness, they also show that its effect on young adults is more than twice the size of the effect on the elderly and that its also more negative on LS of the highest income group relative to the country average. Frey et al. (2009) identify that such differentiated effects can serve as robustness and plausibility check and also provide valuable information for policy makers (Frey et al., 2009). Furthermore, Fujiwara & Campbell (2011) note that sufficient sample size is a prerequisite for subgroup valuations and most LSA studies use large national or multinational datasets (e.g. Di Tella & MacCulloch, 2008). From these large datasets comes another advantage over preference-based techniques. The larger datasets that LSA studies have over both revealed preference and stated preference studies mean that sample results are more representative of the population in general (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). This however, does not apply to all LSA studies because some have
  • 4. Candidate  Number:  68250   4   small sample sizes (e.g. Mackerron & Mourato, 2009) and unrepresentative sample groups (e.g. Mackerron & Mourato, 2013). Also, it should also be borne in mind that many of these studies with large datasets such as Welsch (2002, 2003, 2006, 2007) and Di Tella & MacCulloch (2008) face problems such as unobserved heterogeneity from aggregated data that are regarded as serious limitations. Therefore, while the relatively larger datasets of LSA studies and the potential of going beyond average measures are seen as advantages, its validity will depend on the specific studies, their methodology and the particular limitations they face. In contrast, it is recognised that environmental valuation using LSA produces implausibly high valuations, which presents itself as a significant con of the LSA. The problem here involves the estimation of marginal utility of income in the LS regression, where the coefficient of income tends to be statistically significant but small, which often results in implausible WTP estimates for the environmental good (Dolan et al., 2011). The causes often cited in the literature for the downward bias on the estimate of the income coefficients are the issue of reverse causality between income and LS and the closely related issues of adaptation to income and influence of relative aspects of income on an individual’s LS. Many LSA studies have generated implausible valuations (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). For example, in a study on air pollution in London, Mackerron & Mourato (2009) find that a 1% increase in NO2 levels is equivalent, in LS terms, to a drop of 5.3% in income. They identify that that this value is unrealistically high, both intuitively and in comparison with results from revealed and stated preference studies. Such high values tend to be fairly common in LS research to date (Mackerron & Mourato, 2009). As acknowledged in various studies, including Mackerron & Mourato (2009), valuation estimates from most LSA studies are somewhat higher than those calculated using stated and revealed preference techniques (Menz, 2011). As a result, interpretation from LSA studies is a controversial issue and a cautionary approach towards this approach is recommended in the literature. However, the issue of high valuation may not necessarily be as big a problem as it often regarded. Firstly, some LSA studies estimate values using subjective wellbeing score instead of monetary valuation (e.g. Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). Secondly, not all LSA studies face the same outcome of implausible high valuations. Some valuation
  • 5. Candidate  Number:  68250   5   studies such as Luechinger & Raschky (2007) LS have produced reasonable estimates that fall in a similar range as the preference-based techniques (table 1). Thirdly, investigating the relationship between income and life satisfaction is a fast growing area of research and better estimates of marginal utility of income are evolving (Ambrey & Fleming, 2011). For example, Ambrey & Fleming (2014) use a subset of windfall income (restricted windfall income) in place of the more conventional household income measure in their study and find that the causal effect of income on life satisfaction is substantially higher (and MWTP estimates substantially lower) when restricted windfall income is used. Likewise, many other studies have developed ways such as controlling for new relative income variables to reduce the downward bias on estimate of income in LSA (e.g. Luttmer, 2005;Powdthavee, 2009; Luechinger 2009a). This essay shows that the LSA has its own pros and cons, but more importantly, there are nuances within these well-identified factors. In relation to revealed preference method, LSA has an advantage of avoiding the often-violated assumption of market equilibrium that gives biased estimates. Similarly, the LSA has advantage over revealed preference techniques because it circumvents the major issues of superficial answers and strategic behavior inherent in hypothetical questions, but it also faces it own related problems that have not been discussed here. Whether or not assuming interpersonal comparability is a weakness of the LSA remains debatable. Nevertheless, I argue that it is, at best, a weak con of this approach. Studies that adopt the LSA can have an advantage of going beyond average estimates and tend to have larger and more representative samples. However, the validity of these advantages depends on individual studies. Arguably the most significant con of the LSA is the relatively high and sometimes implausible valuation estimates studies produce. Nonetheless, I debate that it is not as big a con as it portrayed because some studies do not produce monetary valuations, others also produce estimates in a similar range as the preference-based techniques and notably, the LSA is still evolving with increase in research towards its improvement. It is important to note that there are also other cons of the LSA including measurement errors and bias from reported LS as a result of mood states, self-selection and the influence by immediate context, that have not been discussed here. The nice feature of this approach is that, while it avoids the problems of the preference-based techniques, its shortcomings also differ markedly
  • 6. Candidate  Number:  68250   6   from theirs, making it useful for comparison. Fujiwara & Campbell (2011) recommend the LSA to be currently regarded as a complement to the more standard methods. The UK Government is committed to improving the way that wellbeing and social impacts are incorporated into policy decisions (Fujiwara & Campbell, 2011). With the increase in research towards improving the LSA and the stagnant status of preference-based techniques, I believe the LSA has the potential of overcoming its cons and significantly contributing to the government’s commitment to improvements in the future.
  • 7. Candidate  Number:  68250   7   Appendix 1. TABLE Table 1: valuation of PM10 using non-market valuation techniques. From Menz (2011).
  • 8. Candidate  Number:  68250   8   Appendix  2.  References  Cited     Ambrey,  C.L.  &  Fleming,  C.M.,  2011.  Valuing  scenic  amenity  using  life  satisfaction   data.  Ecological  Economics,  72,  pp.106-­‐15.     Ambrey,  C.L.  &  Fleming,  C.M.,  2014.  The  causal  effect  of  income  on  life   satisfaction  and  the  implications  for  valuing  non-­‐market  goods.  Economics   Letters,  123,  pp.131-­‐34.     Ambrey,  C.L.,  Fleming,  C.M.  &  Chan,  A.Y.-­‐C.,  2014.  Estimating  the  cost  of  air     pollution  in  South  East  Queensland:  An  application  of  the  life  satisfaction  non-­‐ market  valuation  approach.  Ecological  Economics,  97,  pp.172-­‐81.     Bolle,  F.  &  Kemp,  S.,  2009.  Can  we  compare  life  satisfaction  between   nationalities?  Evaluating  actual  and  imagined  situations.  Social  Indicators   Research,  90(3),  pp.297-­‐408.     Di  Tella,  R.  &  MacCulloch,  R.,  2008.  Gross  national  happiness  as  an  answer  to  the   Easterlin  Paradox.  Journal  of  Development  Economics,  86,  pp.22-­‐42.     Diener,  E.,  1984.  Subjective  Well-­‐Being.  Psychological  Bulletin,  95(3),  pp.542-­‐75.   Dolan,  P.,  Layard,  R.  &  Metcalfe,  R.,  2011.  Measuring  Subjective  Wellbeing  for   Public  Policy:  Recommendations  on  Measures.  Special  paper.  London:  Centre  for   Economic  Performance,  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science     London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science.     Frey,  B.S.,  Luechinger,  S.  &  Stutzer,  A.,  2009.  The  Life  Satisfaction  Approach  to   Environmental  Valuation.  4478th  ed.  Bonn:  IZA.     Fujiwara,  D.  &  Campbell,  R.,  2011.  Valuation  Techniques  for  Social  Cost-­‐Benefit   Analysis:  Stated  Preference,  Revealed  Preference  and  Subjective  Well-­‐Being   Approaches.  London:  HM  Treasury  and  Department  for  Works  and  Pensions   (DWP).     George,  M.  &  Mourato,  S.,  2013.  Happiness  is  greater  in  natural  environments.   Global  Environmental  Change,  23,  pp.992-­‐1000.     Larsen,  E.,  2008.  The  Science  of  Subjective  Well-­‐Being.  1st  ed.  Ney  York:  The   Guilford  Press.     Levinson,  A.,  2012.  Valuing  public  goods  using  happiness  data:  The  case  of  air   quality.  Journal  of  Public  Economics,  96,  pp.869-­‐80.     Luechinger,  S.,  2009a.  Valuing  Air  Quality  using  the  Life  Satisfaction  Approach.   The  Economic  Journal  ,  119,  pp.482-­‐515.     Luechinger,  S.  &  Raschky,  P.A.,  2007.  Valuing  Flood  Disasters  Using  the  life   Satisfaction  Approach.  Zurich.    
  • 9. Candidate  Number:  68250   9   MacKerron,  G.  &  Mourato,  S.,  2009.  Life  satisfaction  and  air  quality  in  London.   Ecological  Economics,  68,  pp.1441-­‐53.     Menz,  T.,  2011.  Do  people  habituate  to  air  pollution?  Evidence  from  international   life  satisfaction  data.  Ecological  Economics,  71,  pp.211-­‐19.     Powdthavee,  N.,  2009.  How  much  does  money  really  matter?  Estimating  the   causal  effects  of  income  on  happiness.  Empirical  Economics,  39,  pp.77-­‐92.     Sandvik,  E.,  Diener,  E.  &  Seidlitz,  L.,  1993.  Subjective  Well-­‐Being:  The   Convergence  and  stability  of  Self-­‐Reported  and  Non-­‐Self-­‐Report  Measures.   Journal  of  Personality  ,  61(3),  pp.317-­‐42.     Stiglitz,  J.E.,  Sen,  A.  &  Fitoussi,  J.-­‐P.,  2009.  Report  by  the  Commission  on  the   Measurement  of  Economic  Performance  and  Social  Progress.  Paris:  Commission   on  the  Measurement  of  Economic  Performance  and  Social  Progress  French   Government.     Veenhoven,  R.,  1993.  Happiness  in  Nations:  Subjective  Appreciation  of  Life  in  56   Nations  1946-­‐1992.  Rotterdam:  Erasmus  University  Press  Erasmus  University.     Welsch,  H.,  2002.  Preferences  over  prosperity  and  pollution:  environmental   valuation  based  on  happiness  surveys.  Kyklos,  55(4),  pp.473-­‐94.     Welsch,  H.,  2003.  Environment  and  Happiness:  Valuation  of  Air  Pollution  in  Ten   European  Countries.  German  Institute  for  Economic  Research.     Welsch,  H.,  2006.  Environment  and  happiness:  Valuation  of  air  pollution  using   life  satisfaction  data.  Ecological  Economics,  58,  pp.801-­‐13.     Welsch,  H.,  2007.  Environmental  welfare  analysis:  A  Life  satisfaction  approach.   Ecological  Economics,  62,  pp.544-­‐51.