SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 23
Download to read offline
American Economic Association
Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle
Author(s): Steven Klepper
Reviewed work(s):
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 3 (Jun., 1996), pp. 562-583
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118212 .
Accessed: 09/10/2012 08:02
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
.
American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.
http://www.jstor.org
Entry,Exit,Growth,and Innovationover the ProductLifeCycle
By STEVEN KLEPPER*
Regularities concerning how entry, exit, marketstructure, and innovation vary
from the birth of technologically progressive industries through maturity are
summarized.A model emphasizingdifferences infirm innovativecapabilities and
the importance of firm size in appropriating the returnsfrom innovation is de-
veloped to explain the regularities. Themodel also explains regularities regard-
ing the relationshipwithinindustriesbetweenfirm size andfirm innovativeeffort,
innovative productivity, cost, and profitability. It predicts that over timefirms
devote more effort to process innovation but the number of firms and the rate
and diversity of product innovationeventually wither. (JEL L10)
A similarviewhasemergedfromanumber
of disciplinaryperspectivesabouthow tech-
nologicallyprogressiveindustriesevolvefrom
birththroughmaturity.'Whenindustriesare
new,thereis a lot of entry,firns offermany
differentversionsof the industry'sproduct,
therateofproductinnovationishigh,andmar-
ket shareschangerapidly.Despitecontinued
marketgrowth,subsequentlyentryslows,exit
overtakesentryandthereis a shakeoutin the
numberof producers,therateof productin-
novationandthe diversityof competingver-
sionsof theproductdecline,increasingeffort
is devotedto improvingthe productionpro-
cess, and marketshares stabilize.In some
quarters,thisevolutionarypatternhascometo
be knownas theproductlife cycle (PLC).
Whilenumerousauthorshavecontributedto
this description,perhapsthe mostinfluential
havebeenWilliamJ.AbernathyandJamesM.
Utterback.2Buildingontheworkof DennisC.
MuellerandJohnE. Tilton(1969) andusing
the automobileindustryas a leading case,
theydepictthePLCasdrivenbythewaynew
technologiesevolve. Theystressthatwhena
productis introduced,thereisconsiderableun-
certaintyaboutuserpreferences(even among
the usersthemselves)and the technological
meansof satisfyingthem.As a result,many
firmsproducingdifferentvariantsof theprod-
uctenterthemarketandcompetitionfocuses
on productinnovation.As usersexperiment
withthealternativeversionsoftheproductand
producerslearn abouthow to improvethe
product,opportunitiesto improvetheproduct
aredepletedanda defactoproductstandard,
dubbeda dominantdesign,emerges.Produc-'
ers who areunableto produceefficientlythe
dominantdesignexit,contributingto a shake-
outinthenumberof producers.Thedepletion
of opportunitiesto improvethe productcou-
pled with locked-inof the dominantdesign
leadstoadecreaseinproductinnovation.This
in turnreducesproducers'fearsthatinvest-
mentsin the productionprocesswill be ren-
deredobsoleteby technologicalchangein the
* Department of Social and Decision Sciences, Car-
negie Mellon University, Pittsburgh,PA 15213. I thank
Wesley Cohen, Mark Kamlet, Jon Leland, John Miller,
RichardNelson, Ken Simons, PeterSwann,Bill Williams,
and participantsat the 1992 Conference of the Interna-
tionalJosephA. SchumpeterSociety, the 1992Conference
on MarketProcesses andthe Dynamics of CorporateNet-
works, WissenschaftszentrumBerlin, and the Industrial
Organization Seminars at the University of Maryland,
Berkeley, Penn State,andthe LondonSchool of Econom-
ics for helpfulcomments.Thepaperwas greatlyimproved
by the unstintingsuggestions of two anonymousreferees
and the co-editor, PrestonMcAfee.
'See, for example, Oliver E. Williamson's (1975) ac-
count of how economists depict the evolution of new in-
dustries, Kim B. Clark's (1985) description of how
technology andinternalfirmorganizationchange over the
course of industryevolution, andhow a business consult-
ant, Philip G. Drew (1987), describes the way business
schools depict the evolution of industries.
2 See in particularJames M. Utterbackand William J.
Abernathy(1975) and AbernathyandUtterback(1978).
562
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 563
product.Consequently,theyincreasetheirat-
tentionto the productionprocessandinvest
morein capital-intensivemethodsof produc-
tion,whichreinforcestheshakeoutof produc-
ers by increasingthe minimumefficientsize
firm.
Whilethisviewhashelpedtopopularizethe
PLC,itrestscriticallyonthenotionof adom-
inantdesign,an impreciseconceptthatdoes
not appearto applyto all new products,es-
peciallyones for whichbuyertastesare di-
verse(MichaelE.Porter,1983).Furthermore,
itincorporatessomequestionableassumptions
abouttechnologicalchange.It assumesthat
productandprocessinnovationareinextrica-
blylinkedandthatfirmswill notattendto the
productionprocess until productinnovation
hasslowedsufficiently.Yetthehistoryof the
automobileindustryandothers,suchas tires
andantibiotics,indicatesthatgreatimprove-
mentswere madein the productionprocess
wellbeforetheemergenceofanykindofdom-
inant design (S. Klepperand KennethL.
Simons, 1993). Indeed,many of these im-
provementswerebasedon humanandphysi-
cal investments that were not rendered
obsoleteby subsequentmajorproductinno-
vations.Thedominant-designview also min-
imizes the influenceof industrydemandon
incentivesto innovate,attributingthe slow-
downinproductinnovationandriseinprocess
innovationentirelyto thedepletionof oppor-
tunitiesforproductinnovationandthe emer-
genceof adominantdesign.Whiletherelative
importanceof demandandsupplyfactorshas
been hotly debated(David C. Moweryand
NathanRosenberg,1982), it has neverbeen
questionedthatdemandfactorsplay an im-
portantrolein shapingthe rateanddirection
of technologicalchange.
Thispaperproposesa new explanationfor
thePLC.Empiricalregularitiescharacterizing
thePLCarefirstidentified.A formalmodelis
then constructedto explainthe regularities.
Themodelbuildson recenttheoriesof indus-
tryevolution(RichardR. NelsonandSidney
G.Winter,1982;BoyanJovanovic,1982)and
effortstomodelthelinkbetweenmarketstruc-
ture and R&D (Nelson and Winter, 1978;
ParthaDasguptaand JosephStiglitz, 1980;
ThereseM. Flaherty,1980). The modelfo-
cuseson theroleof firminnovativecapabili-
ties and size in conditioningfirm R&D
spending,innovation,and marketstructure.
Followingvarioustheoreticalmodelsof asym-
metric industrystructure(Flaherty;Avner
ShakedandJohnSutton,1987), it incorpo-
ratesthe notionthatthe valueof a unitcost
reductionachievedthroughinnovationis pro-
portionalto the level of outputproducedby
the firm. Coupledwith convex adjustment
costs,thisimpartsanadvantageto theearliest
entrantswhicheventuallycausesa cessation
in entryanda shakeoutin thenumberof pro-
ducers.It also providesfirmswith a greater
incentiveto engagein processinnovationas
they grow, which leads to an increaseover
timeintheireffortstoimprovetheproduction
process.Firnsarealsoassumedtohavedifferent
capabilitiesthatleadthemto pursuedifferent
typesof productinnovations,athemepromoted
by Nelson (1981) and used by Wesley M.
CohenandKlepper(1992) to explaindiffer-
enceswithinindustriesinfirmR&Dintensities.
Thisprovidesthebasisforexplainingthedecline
inproductinnovationthatoccursovertime,link-
ingittothedeclineinthenumberofcompetitors
broughtaboutby theshakeoutof producers.It
is shownthatthemodelcanalsoexplainvarious
cross-sectionalregularitiesthathave accumu-
latedconcerningtherelationshipwithinindus-
triesbetweenfirmsize andfirmR&Deffort,
R&Dproductivity,cost,andprofitability.Thus,
themodelprovidesa unifiedexplanationfora
widerangeof temporalandcross-sectionalreg-
ularitiesconcerningindustryevolutionandfinn
behavior.
Thepaperis organizedas follows.In Sec-
tionI, theprominentfeaturesof thePLCare
summarized.InSectionII,themodelis spec-
ified.In SectionIII,preliminaryimplications
of themodelaredeveloped.InSectionIV,the
modelis shownto explainall the prominent
featuresof thePLC.In SectionV, themodel
is usedto explainvariouscross-sectionalreg-
ularitiesbetweenfirm size, R&D, and firm
performance.In SectionVI, the implications
of themodelarediscussedandextensionsof
themodelareconsidered.
I. TheNatureof theProductLifeCycle
The depictionof industryevolutioncon-
veyedin thePLCis baseduponcase studies
564 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
andquantitativeanalysesof the evolutionof
newindustries.Inthissection,six regularities
concerninghow entry,exit, marketstructure,
andtechnologicalchangevaryfromthebirthof
technologicallyprogressiveindustriesthrough
maturityaresummarized.Whileeveryitidustry
hasitsidiosyncrasies,theseregularitiesprovide
a compositepictureof theevolutionof techno-
logicallyprogressiveindustries.
Thefirsttworegularitiespertaintoentryand
exit. MichaelGortand Klepper(1982) and
KlepperandElizabethGraddy(1990) exam-
inetheannualtimepathinthenumberof pro-
ducersfor 46 majornew productsbeginning
with their commercialinception.Utterback
andFernandoF. Suarez(1993) alsoconsider
the timepathin the numberof producersas
wellasthepathsinthenumberof entrantsand
exits for 8 productssubjectto considerable
technologicalchange. Klepperand Simons
(1993) reviewthe entryandexit pathsfor 2
of the productsstudied by Utterbackand
Suarezand2 otherproductssubjecttoconsid-
erabletechnological change. Two patterns
emergefromthesestudiesconcerningthena-
tureof industryevolutionin technologically
progressiveindustries:
At thebeginningof theindustry,thenumber
of entrantsmayriseovertimeorit mayat-
taina peakat the startof the industryand
then declineover time, but in both cases
thenumberof entrantseventuallybecomes
small.
Thenumberof producersgrowsinitiallyand
thenreachesa peak,afterwhichit declines
steadilydespitecontinuedgrowthin indus-
tryoutput.3
EntrantsAccountfor MarketSharesof LargestFitmsStabilize--_
DisproportionateAmount
of ProductInnovation ProductR&D overtime
ProcessR&D overtimc
E
Rut
= >
pathI
Entrypath2 Numberofproducers
0 Time
FIGURE 1. TEMPORAL PATTERNS OF ENTRY, NUMBER OF
PRODUCERS, MARKET SHARES, AND INNOVATION
These patternsare illustratedin Figure1.
Two alternativepathsfor entryaredepicted.
Inbothcases,entryeventuallybecomessmall
andthenumberof firmsrisesinitiallyandthen
declinesovertime.Relatedto thesetwo pat-
ternsareregularitiesin the way firmmarket
shareschangeover time. Althoughmarket-
sharedataoveranextendedtimeperiodarenot
availableformanyproducts,EdwinMansfield
(1962) and Burton H. Klein (1977 pp. 89-
128) have examined how the marketsharesof
the leadingproducersof automobiles,tires,
aircraft,petroleum,and steel changedover
time.Theirfindings,whichaccordwithanum-
berof case studies,suggesta thirdregularity
whichis notedin Figure1:
Eventuallythe rateof changeof the market
sharesof thelargestfirmsdeclinesandthe
leadershipof theindustrystabilizes.
The otherthreeregularitiesaboutthe PLC
pertaintotechnologicalchange.Becausetech-
nologicalchangeis moredifficultto quantify,
theregularitiesarebasedon a numberof case
studies4andtwo samplesof innovationsfora
'These are general tendencies, and exceptions can al-
ways be found. Of greater significance is the possibility
thatthese patternsreflect a bias in the way new products
are typically defined. If these patterns tend to be inter-
ruptedby major innovations but the innovations are de-
finedascreatingnew productssubjectto theirown product
life cycles, the patternscould be artifactual.The bulk of
the new productsthathave been studied,however, did not
experience such majorinnovations until many years after
they were introduced,and their evolution was generally
characterized by long initial periods during which the
characteristicpatternsin entry and the number of firms
were observed.
'These include Abernathy(1978) andAbernathyet al.
(1983) for automobiles, Klein (1977) for automobilesand
aircraft,Tilton (1971) and Jerome Kraus(1973) for tran-
sistors, Kenneth Flamm (1988) and Philip Anderson and
Michael J. Tushman (1990) for computers, Arthur A.
Bright (1949) and James R. Bright (1958) for light
bulbs, Thomas J. Prusaand James A. Schmitz (1991) for
PC software, and Abernathy and Utterback (1978) and
Utterbackand Suarez (1993) for collections of products.
For furtherdetail, see Klepper(1992).
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 565
limited number of industries in the United
States (Utterback and Abernathy, 1975) and
the United Kingdom (C. De Bresson and J.
Townsend, 1981). These studies suggest that
for industrieswith rich opportunitiesfor both
product and process R&D, three patterns in
productand process innovation can be identi-
fied:5
The diversity of competing versions of the
product and the number of major product
innovations tend to reach a peak duringthe
growthin the numberof producersandthen
fall over time.
Over time, producersdevote increasing effort
to process relative to productinnovation.
During the period of growth in the numberof
producers,the most recent entrantsaccount
for a disproportionate share of product
innovations.
These three regularities are also noted in
Figure 1. Together,the six regularitieslaid out
above andsummarizedin Figure 1providethe
focus for the theoreticalanalysis of the paper.
II. TheModel
The model depicts the evolution from birth
throughmaturityof an industrywith rich op-
portunitiesfor productandprocess innovation.
Two aspects of innovation are featured.First,
following Jacob Schmookler (1966) and a
number of theoretical models (for example,
DasguptaandStiglitz,1980;ShakedandSutton,
1987), the demand for a firm's productis as-
sumed to condition its incentive to innovate.
This is assumed to be manifested differently
for process and product innovation. Process
innovation is principally designed to lower a
firm's average cost of production. Since the
value of a reductionin averagecost is propor-
tional to the total outputof the firm, it is as-
sumedthatthe incentiveforprocessinnovation
is conditioned by the total quantitydemanded
of the firm's product.Productinnovations, in
contrast,areoften designed to attractnew buy-
ers for a product. Accordingly, it is assumed
that the incentive for product innovation is
conditioned by the demand of new buyers.
Second, firmsareassumedto be randomlyen-
dowed with distinctive capabilities which in-
fluence the kinds of innovationsthey develop.
The idea of distinctive firm competencies lies
at the heatt of the business-strategy literature
(Porter, 1980) andits relevancefor innovation
appears prominently in many industry case
studies.6It is assumedthatthese differences in
capabilitiesmanifest themselves principallyin
product innovations, where firms often spe-
cialize in innovations that service distinctive
types of users (Eric von Hippel, 1988). In
contrast,process innovations tend to be incre-
mental and based on information that firms
commonly generatethroughproduction(com-
pare Bright, 1958; Samuel Hollander, 1965).
The model is stylized to highlight the two
featured aspects of innovation. It has the fol-
lowing structure. Time is discrete. In each
period, incumbent firms decide whether to
' The threepatternsare ascribedonly to productswith
richopportunitiesforboth productandprocess innovation
because the bulk of the products for which patterns in
innovation have been studied are, not surprisingly,ones
with such characteristics.Indeed,Abernathy(1978 p. 84),
K. Pavitt and R. Rothwell (1976), and Porter (1983 pp.
23-24), among others,contendthatproductswithoutrich
opportunitiesfor both productand process innovation do
not follow the prototypical PLC. Examples cited as ex-
ceptions to the PLC include synthetic fibers and plastics,
which are claimed to be relatively homogeneous and pri-
marily subjectto process but not productinnovation, and
heavy electrical equipment, which is produced in small
batches and is claimed to be subject primarilyto product
and not process innovation. While no evidence is pre-
sented to buttressthese claims and not all observers sub-
scribe to them (for example, see David A. Hounshell
[1988] regardingsynthetic fibers), it is importantto rec-
ognize that the evidence regardinginnovation during the
PLCis primarilybasedon productswithrichopportunities
for both productandprocess innovation.This is reflected
in the model, which presupposes that the joint natureof
productand process innovationdrives the PLC.
6Forexample, a numberof studiesemphasize how sig-
nificant innovations can be traced back to expertise ac-
quiredfortuitously.This is featuredin HughG. J.Aitken's
(1985) analysis of early radio innovations, Flamm's
(1988) discussion of the influence of government spon-
sored cryptographyefforts during World War II on sub-
sequent innovationby computerfirms, and Klein's (1977
pp. 89-109) discussion of the skills brought into the
automobile industry at the 'turnof the century by entre-
preneurs with experience in mass production and inter-
changeable partsmanufacture.
566 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
remainin the industryanda limited numberof
potential entrantsdecide whetherto enter.All
firmsproducea standardproduct.They decide
how muchprocess R&D to perform,which de-
terminesthe averagecost of the standardprod-
uct. They also decide how muchproductR&D
to perform. Firms randomly differ in their
productinnovationexpertise,which influences
their success at productR&D. In each period,
successful product innovators develop a dis-
tinctive product innovation which they com-
bine with the standardproduct to market a
unique, distinctive product. Distinctive prod-
ucts appealto all buyers, but only new buyers
pay the premiumsfor them, with each distinc-
tive product sold to a different class of new
buyers. All firms monitor the product inno-
vations of their rivals. This enables them to
imitateallproductinnovationsone periodafter
they areintroducedand incorporatethem into
the standardproductat no additionalproduc-
tion cost. When the last period's product in-
novations are incorporatedinto the standard
product,buyers of the distinctive productsbe-
come buyers of the standardproduct and the
demand for the standardproductby all other
buyers increases, causing the demand curve
for the standardproduct to shift to the right.
Producers share in the expansion in demand
for the standardproductin proportionto their
prior output and decide how much furtherto
expand their output subject to a cost of ad-
justment. All decisions are made to maximize
currentprofits, firms are price takers, and in
each period the price of the standardproduct
clears the market.
The model is formally specified as follows.
Ineachperiodt, thereareK,potentialentrants.
As firms enter and others randomly develop
the innovative capabilitiesrequiredto enter,K,
changes. A priorino restrictionsareplaced on
whether K, rises or falls over time; this may
differ across industriesand also within indus-
tries over time. Each potential entrantis ran-
domly endowed with innovative expertise
which it cannot modify over time. Let si de-
note the innovation expertise of firm i, which
it knows priorto entry, andsmax the maximum
possible innovationexpertise. To simplify the
dynamics of the model, it is assumed that in
each period there are one or more potential
entrantswith innovative expertise Smaxandthe
cumulativedistributionof innovativeexpertise
is the same for the potential entrantsin each
period. This distributionis denoted as H(s),
where H(s) is assumed to be continuous for
all s < smaxand H(Smax)= 1by definition.
The firm's innovative expertise influences
its success atproductR&D. The probabilityof
firm i developing a productinnovation in pe-
riod t is si + g (rdi,), where rdi,is its spending
on product R&D and the function g(rdi,) re-
flects the opportunitiesfor productinnovation.
Each successful innovatoradds its innovation
to the standardproductand marketsa distinc-
tive variantof the industry'sproduct,which it
sells at a price exceeding the price of the stan-
dardproduct,reflecting the value of its inno-
vation. Distinctive variants are assumed to
appealto all buyersbut only new buyers have
a positive demand for them at the prices
charged, with each distinctive variant pur-
chased by a differentclass of new buyers. Af-
ter one period, all product innovations are
copied and incorporated into the standard
product,so successful innovatorshave a one-
periodmonopolyovertheirdistinctivevariants.
Let G denote the one-period gross monopoly
profit(before subtractingthe amountspent on
productR&D) earnedby each seller of a dis-
tinctivevariant.It is assumedthatg' (rdi) > 0
and g"(rdit) < 0 for all rdit 2 0, reflecting
diminishing returns, and that g'(0)G > 1,
which ensures rdit> 0 for all i, t. In orderto
be able to imitatecostlessly the innovationsof
its rivals, which is requiredto market a dis-
tinctive productvariantand also the standard
product,firmsmonitorthe innovationsof their
rivals at a cost of F per period. Thus, if a firm
engaged in only product innovation and did
not producethe standardproduct,its expected
profitsin period t would be [si + g(rdit)] G -
rdit- F. To simplify the model, it is assumed
thatF > [si + g(rdit)] G - rditfor all rdit.This
ensures that in orderto have nonnegative ex-
pected profits,all firmsmustproducethe stan-
dardproduct.
Let Qt = f(pt) denote the total marketde-
mand for the standardproduct in period t,
where Qt is the quantity demanded,Pt is the
price of the standardproduct,andft(pt) is the
market demand schedule for the standard
productin period t. Over time,f (pt) shifts to
the rightat every price as last period's product
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 567
innovations are incorporatedinto the standard
product.It is assumed thatfi(p,) is continuous
anddownwardsloping for all t. Let Qitdenote
the outputof the standardproductby firmi in
periodt. Itis determinedas follows. Assuming
thatPt falls over time (this will be shown in
thenext section), the totalquantitydemanded,
Qt, expands over time. All firmssell the same
standardproductat the same price. New buy-
ers are assumed to choose a seller based on a
stochastic learningprocess in which the prob-
ability of a firmattractinga new buyeris pro-
portionalto its sales of the standardproductin
thepriorperiod,Qit - I. Itis assumedthatit is
optimal for a buyer to continue purchasing
fromthe same firmas long as the firmremains
in the market.Accordingly, it is assumed that
incumbents in period t experience a rise in
their sales of the standardproductfrom Qit- I
in period t - Ito Qit- I(Qt/Qt- I) in period t,
where Qt/Qt - l denotes the growthin the total
quantity demanded of the standard product
fromperiod t - 1 to t. If desired, the firmcan
expand its output further,resulting in an in-
crease in its marketshareof the standardprod-
uct relative to period t - 1. To do so, it must
incur an adjustmentcost of m(Aqit), where
Aqitis the expansion in its outputin period t
above Qit- I(Qt/Qt- ). The function m(Lqit)
is such thatm'(0) = 0, m'(Aqit) > 0 for all
zqit > 0, and m"(Aqit) > 0 for all Aqit ' 0,
with m' (Aqit) growing without bound as Aqit
increases, reflecting increasing marginal ad-
justment costs.7
The average cost of productionof the stan-
dardproductfor firmi is assumed to be inde-
pendent of Qit and equal to c - l(rcit), where
rcitis the amount spent on process R&D by
firm i in period t and the function l(rcit) re-
flects the opportunitiesfor process innovation.
Following Flaherty(1980), cost in period t is
a function only of process R&D in period t. It
is assumedthatas rcitincreases, l(rcit) asymp-
totically approaches an upper bound and
l'(rcit) > 0 and l"(rcit) < 0 for all rcit 2 0,
reflectingdiminishingreturns.Further,it is as-
sumed that 1'(0)QQm1,i> 1, where Qmninis the
smallest level of outputever producedby any
firm.This ensures rcit> 0 for all i, t.
Given the assumptions, the expected profit
of firmi in period t, E(IIit), can be expressed
as
(1) E(Hit) = [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit
+ [Qit_I(Qt/ Qt-l) + Aqit]
X [Pt - c + I(rcit)]
- rcit- m(Aqit) - F,
where [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit is the firm's
expected net profit from product R&D after
subtracting the cost of its product R&D,
I[Qit-l(QtlQt_l + Aqit [pt - c + l(rcit)I-
rcit- m(Aqit)is its netprofitfromproducing
thestandardproductaftersubtractingbothits
spendingonprocessR&Dandthecostsof ad-
justingits output,andF is the cost of moni-
toringtheinnovationsof itsrivals.Expression
(1) appliesto entrantsin periodt as well as
incumbents,with Qit- = 0 for entrants.All
firmsare assumedto be atomisticandprice
takers.In each periodt they can projectthe
market-clearingpriceforthestandardproduct,
Pt,butareuncertainaboutfuturepricesandthus
theirprospectsfor survival.Accordingly,it is
assumedtheydecidewhetherto be in the in-
dustryandif so,rdit,rcit,andAqit,tomaximize
currentexpected profits,E(nit). Let rdi,t,
rc*, and Aq* denote the profit-maximizing
choices of rdit,rci,, and qit and E(HI*t) the
expectedprofitsof the firmat thesechoices.
Potentialentrantsenterif E(n*) > 0, arein-
differentaboutenteringif E(HI*t) = 0, anddo
not enter if E(HI*) < 0, where Aqit defines
theirinitialoutputof the standardproductif
they enter.Similarly,incumbentsstayin the
industryif E(Hll*)> 0, areindifferentabout
stayingin if E(HI) =0, andexit if E(HI*) <
0. Onceincumbentsexit, theiroutputof the
standardproductis lost.
Theindustryis assumedto startin period1
whendemandandtechnologyfortheproduct
are such that there exists a price pi for
which the quantitysuppliedby firms with
7If a firmwantsto expand its marketshare,it will nor-
mally have to incur marketingcosts to attractcustomers
from its rivals. The assumptionthatm"(Aqi,)> 0 reflects
the idea thatthe morethe finn wantsto increaseits market
sharein any given period, the greaterthe marketingcosts
requiredfor expansion at the margin.
568 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
nonnegative expected profitsequals the quan-
tity demanded, Ql, where Q, > 0. Similarly,
in every subsequent period p, is assumed to
clear the market.This requiresthat the quan-
tity demandedin period t, Q, = f,(p,), equals
the quantitysupplied by producersin period t
takingp, as given:
(2) Q,= , {Qit-I(Qt/Qt-1) + /qit},
i,t
where the index i, t of the summationdenotes
thatthe summationis over firmsi in themarket
in period t. In terms of the actualmechanism
governing the change in price fromperiod t -
I to t, thedynamicsof themodel aresimplified
by assuming that for all incumbent firms in
period t, dE(H1*)/dp, > 0 for all prices pt
within a broad neighborhood of pt 8 with
the equilibriumprice constrainedto lie in this
broad neighborhood.The existence of such a
price in each period satisfying equation(2) is
demonstratedin the next section. As will be
shown, market clearing is achieved through
the effects of pt on Qt, Aqit, and on entryand
exit in period t.9
Themodelis stylizedtokeepittractableand
tohighlightthetwokeyfeaturesof innovation
thatunderlieit. Productinnovationsare as-
sumedto be introducedinto distinctivever-
sionsof theproductandthenincorporatedinto
the productsof all firms,whichconformsto
the way manyproductsevolve over time.'0
This preservesthe notionof an industryin
which all firms producethe same product
while allowingfor (limited) productdiffer-
entiation.Eachproductinnovationis assumed
tobe soldto adifferentclassof newbuyersto
reflecttheideathatfirmshavedifferentkinds
of innovativeexpertisethatleadthemto ser-
vice differentgroupsof buyers.Coupledwith
theassumptionthatproductinnovationsdonot
affect the demandfor the standardproduct,
this ensuresthatthe incentiveto engage in
productinnovationis determinedsolelybythe
demandof new buyers."Differencesin firm
innovativeabilitiesarestructuredso thatthey
do notaffectthefirm'soutputof thestandard
productnorthe amountspenton productor
processR&D.Consequently,thefirm'soutput
of thestandardproductis relatedto thefirm's
R&Dspendingonlythroughits effectson the
returnsfromprocessR&D,whichhighlights
the influenceof the demandfor the standard
productonprocessR&D.Opportunitiesforin-
novation,as reflectedin thefunctionsg(rdi,)
andl(rci,), are assumedconstantto abstract
fromtheeffectsof changingtechnologicalop-
portunitieson the firm'sR&Dspending.All
decisionsarebasedoncurrentexpectedprofits
andprocessinnovationsarenotcumulativeto
simplifythe dynamicsof the model and to
reflectthelimitedhorizonsof firmsinnewin-
dustries.Manyof these assumptionsarere-
consideredin the conclusion, where it is
arguedthatthe spiritandprincipalimplica-
tions of the model wouldnot changeif the
assumptionswererelaxed.
8Thisconditionrequiresthatineachperiodt,thelower
p, thenthelowerthemaximumpossibleexpectedprofits
of eachfirm,assumingthefirmcan sell as muchof the
standardproductasitwantsatp,.Thepriceofthestandard
productaffectsE(r,*) in twoways:throughitseffecton
theprofitperunitof thestandardproduct,p, - c + l(rci,),
andthroughitseffectoneachfirm'soutputofthestandard
productvia thetotalquantitydemandedof the standard
product,Qt.Thesetwo effects workin oppositedirec-
tions-the lowerpt thenthe lowerthe firm'sprofitper
unit on the standardproduct,ceterisparibus,but the
greaterthefirm'stotaloutputofthestandardproduct,cet-
erisparibus.Giventhatl(rcj,)is bounded,at sufficiently
low pricesE(rlH*)mustbe less thanzero for all firms,
henceatsufficientlylowpricesthefirsteffectmustdom-
inatethesecondanddE(rI,*)dpt> 0. Ifdft(pt)ldpt= 0 at
therelevantprices(thatis, thepriceelasticityof demand
equaledzero),thenptwouldhaveno effecton thefirm's
outputof thestandardp,roductandit is easyto see from
equation(1)thatdE(Hlit)ldpt> 0 forallprices.Moregen-
erally,if suitableconstraintsareplacedon the function
dft(pt)ldptattherelevantpricesthendE(rH*)/dpt> 0 for
allpriceswithina broadneighborhoodofpt
9 Notethatif exitoccursin periodt then1j, Qit-I <
li, t- I Qit-I = Q,_ ,, where the index i, t - 1 denotes
summationoverfirmsin themarketin periodt - 1. As
developedin thenextsection,exit will be necessaryfor
themarketto clearineachperiod.
'?Forexample,inautomobilesinnovationssuchasthe
electricstarterandtheinexpensiveclosedbodywerein-
troducedintodistinctivemodelsandthencopiedwidely
byallmanufacturers.
" Thisabstractsfromstrategicincentivesto innovate
associatedwith the preemptionof rivals (RichardJ.
GilbertandDavidM.G.Newbery,1982)andcannibalism
of priorinnovations(JenniferReinganum,1983,1985).
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 569
III. Preliminary Results
In order to facilitate the proof of later re-
sults, a series of intermediateimplications of
the model are developed as lemmas. In deriv-
ing these lemmas, it is assumed thatthere ex-
ists a price p, in each period that clears the
marketgiven the choices firmsmake abouten-
try, exit, rdi,,rci,, and Aqi, takingp, as given.
The existence of such a pathfor price is estab-
lished at the end of this section.
The firstresults pertainto firmsin the mar-
ket in periodt, including firmsthatenteredthe
market during period t as well as earlier en-
trants.Differentiating (1) with respect to rdi,,
rci,, and Aqi, establishes the following first-
orderconditions for an interiormaximum for
each firmi in the marketin period t:
(3) g'(rd1)G = 1
(4) [Qit- (Qt/Qt-i) + Aq*]l'(rc*) = 1
(5) m'(Aq*) =
pt
- c + l(rc *),
where optimal values aredenoted by an aster-
isk. Furthermore,for a firmto be in the market
in periodt, its expected profitsin periodt must
be nonnegative. Given the assumptionof F >
[si + g(rdi,)]G - rdi, for all rdi,, a necessary
condition for E(nit) 2 0 is thatfor each firm
i in the marketin period t:
(6) ~Pt- c + l(rcit)>
Assuming
-1"(rc*)[Qit-1(Qt/Qt-1)
+ Aq*]
X m(Aq*) > lP(rc*)2 to ensure that the joint
solutionof (4) and(5) forrc1,andAqi,is a max-
imum, the solutionsto equations(3)- (6) will
satisfy the second-order conditions. Conse-
quently, for each firmi andperiod t, rd* > 0,
rc* > 0, and Aq* > 0, with these choices
satisfying equations (3) - (6). Thus, all firms
in the marketin period t performproductand
process R&D and increase their marketshare
of the standardproductrelativeto periodt - 1.
Conditions (3) -(6) imply two results
which reflect the simplified nature of the
model.
LEMMA 1: For all i and t, rdi, = rd *, where
rd* satisfies g'(rd *)G = 1.
PROOF:
The profit-maximizing value of rdi,is de-
fined by equation (3), which is the same for
all firmsand does not change over time. Con-
sequently, all firms spend the same amount
rd* on product R&D, where rd* satisfies
(3).
Analogous to E(fl *), letVi=V
Qit- (Q
Qt-1) + Aq*][p, - c + l(rc*)] - rci*
m( Aq*) denote the firm's (incremental)
profitfromthe standardproduct.Lemma 1im-
plies that the firm's incrementalprofitearned
from product R&D in each period, [si +
g(rdi,)] G - rdi,,remains constant over time.
Consequently, changes in the firm's expected
profits over time arise only from changes in
Vi*. Accordingly, most of the analysis of the
model focuses on the standardproduct.
The second result indicates thatin each pe-
riod t, firms in each entry cohort make the
same choices for rci, and Aqi, and have the
same outputand incrementalprofits from the
standardproduct. Letting the values of these
variables for entry cohort k in period t be de-
notedasrc', Aqk, Q,k,andV k, thefollowing
result is established.
LEMMA 2: For allfirms i thatenteredinpe-
riod k and are still in the marketinperiod t >
k, rci, = rck, Aqit* = AqkI Qi = Qk, and
V = V t t
PROOF:
Since Qi - I = 0 for entrants in period t,
equations (4) and (5) imply rc* and Aq ,
hence Qitand Vi*, must be the same for all
entrantsin t. It then follows from (4) and (5)
thatrc*, Aq*, Qit,and V * must be the same
for these firmsin every period they are in the
market.
Lemmas 1 and 2 imply that in each period
t the expected profits of firms that entered in
the same period differ only accordingto their
product-iniovationexpertisesi. Consequently,
in each periodthe distributionof E(fli,) across
firmsin the same entrycohortwill be the same
as the distributionof si for these firms.
The firm's outputin the priorperiod, Qit- I,
will determine its choice of rci,and Aqi, and
hence Vit.This is reflected in Lemma 3.
570 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
LEMMA 3: For each firm i in the marketin
period t, the larger Qi -, then the larger rci,,
Aqi,, and Vi.
PROOF:
Differentiating (3) -(5) with respect to
Qit- 1andrearrangingyields
drc * / dQi,_
-
= g"(rd
*) Gm"(Aq
*)I
P(rc*)
x (Qt/ Qt_) / D
dzAq*ldQi,_
I
= g"(rd )Gl'(rci*)2
X(Qt/ Qt- ) / D
dVi*/dQit- I= a3Vi*/ a3Qit-I
= [p, - c + l(rci*t) ] (Qt / Qt- 1),
where D is the determinantof the matrix of
secondpartialsof E(ni,) withrespectto rdi,,
rci,, and Aqi, evaluated at rd*, rc*, and
Aq*. Since D < 0 based on the second-order
conditions andp, - c + I(rc*) > 0 based on
(6), each of these derivatives is positive.
Therefore,thelargerQit- Ithenthe greaterrci,,
Aqi,, and Vit.
Since Aq* is determined by Qit- I and
Aq* > 0 for all i, t, Lemmas 2 and 3 imply
that in each period t the age of the firm fully
determines rci,, Aqi,, Vi,, and Qit, with each
greater the older the firm. Coupled with
Lemma 1, this implies that in each period t
differencesacrossfirmsinE(ni,)arefullyde-
termined by two factors: the age of the firm
and its productinnovation expertise si.
Lemma 1 establishes the time pathof rdi,for
each firmwhile Lemmas2 and3 establishhow
rci,, Aqi,, Qit,and Vitvary across firmsin each
period. It is also possible to investigate how
rci,,Aqi,, Qit,and Vitchangeovertime for each
firm.For incumbents, Qitand rci,change over
time as follows.
LEMMA 4: For each firm i in the marketin
periods t - 1 and t, Qit > Qit- and rci, >
rci, -l.
PROOF:
Since Aqi, > 0 for all i, t, it follows that
Qit> Qit- Ifor all i, t. Rewritingequation(4)
as Qi,l'(rc*) = 1, it follows from Qit> Qit-
and l"(rci,) < 0 for all rci,thatrci,> rci,t- .
The time paths for Aqi, and Vitfor incum-
bents cannotbe so easily characterized.Equa-
tion (5) indicatesthatfor each incumbentAqi,
will change over time according to the time
path of p, - c + I(rci,), the firm's profitper
unit of the standardproduct.The change in Vit
over time will also depend on the time pathin
Pt - c + I(rci,). Lemma 4 implies that l(rci,)
rises over time, but Lemma 5 below indicates
p, falls over time. Consequently, without fur-
ther assumptions it cannot be determined
whetherAqi,and Vitgenerally rise or fall over
time for incumbents.
That pt must fall over time can be easily
established.
LEMMA 5: For each period t,pt < p.- I
PROOF:
Recall thatit was assumed thatfor each in-
cumbent firm i in period t, dE(n*)Idp, > O
for all prices p, within a broad neighborhood
of pt- I, with the equilibriumprice in period t
lying in this neighborhood.Lemma5 is estab-
lished by showing thatfor all pricesp, 2 pt-I
in this neighborhood,the marketcannot clear
in periodt. Supposep, = pt- I. Then, Qitmust
exceed Qi - Ifor all producersin period t - 1.
This implies E(n*) > E(n1*) 20 for all
producersin period t - 1 and hence that no
incumbent would exit in period t. The same
condition must be truefor all pricespt > p.- I
withinabroadneighborhoodofpt- Igiven that
dE(n* )Idp, > 0 forall suchprices.Butevery
firm that remains in the industrywill expand
its marketshare,hence themarketcannotclear
if all firmsremain in the industry.Therefore,
pt must be less thanpt- .
In order for every firm that remains in the
marketto expandits marketshare,some firms
must exit in every period.This will occuronly
if price falls over time. It mustfall sufficiently
in each period t that E(n*) falls below zero
for some firms in the marketin period t - 1,
causing these firmsto exit.
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 571
Using p, < p,- , it is possible to character-
ize how the size of entrants,Aq,, the process
R&D of entrants,rct, and the profits of en-
trantsfrom the standardproduct, Vt, change
over time. Let s' denote the minimumproduct
innovation expertise in period t among firms
thatenteredin period k ? t. It is also possible
to characterizehow st, the minimum product
innovation expertise among entrants,changes
over time. Over time, rc,, Aqt, V,, and s,
change as follows.
LEMMA 6: For all periods I > k, rc' <
rck, AqI < Aqk, VI < Vk , and sl > Sk.
PROOF:
The choices of rci,and Aqi, for entrantsin
period t must satisfy equations (3) - (6) with
Qit--= 0. These equations differ across pe-
riods only because pt falls over time. To see
how changesin pt affectrct, Aq,, andalso
V,, set Qi1 = 0 in (3 )-(5 ) anddifferentiate
with respect to pt. This yields
drci*/ dp, = g"(rd *)Gl'(rc)/ D > 0
dAq /dp,
-
g"(rd*)Gl"(rc*)Aq* /D > 0
dV /dp, = aV a/p, = Aq* > 0.
Given that pt < Pt- 1, it follows that rct,
Aq,, and V must fall over time. Furthermore,
if V falls over time, the marginalentrantmust
earn greaterincrementalprofits from product
innovation over time, which implies st must
rise over time.
Lemma 6 indicates that the minimum in-
novative expertise required for entry rises
over time. Lemma 7 indicates that it eventu-
ally rises to the point where no furtherentry
occurs.
LEMMA 7: Aftersome period, st >
sna,
and
nofirms enter the industry.
PROOF:
Recall that it was assumed that the distri-
bution of innovative expertise H(s) was such
thatatleast one potentialentrantin every entry
cohort had innovative expertise Smax. If St
'
Smax for all t then in every period E(fl*) 2 0
forpotentialentrantswith innovationexpertise
Smax,hence E(II*) > 0 for all prior entrants
with innovative expertise Smax.Consequently,
no incumbent with innovative expertise Smax
would ever exit the industry. Since Aqi, > 0
for all firms thatremain in the industry,firms
with innovativeexpertiseSmaxwill expandtheir
market share in every period. This cannot,
however, occur indefinitely, as eventually
these firms would capture the entire market
and would not be able to expand furtherwith-
out some of them exiting. This requires p,
eventuallyto fall to a level suchthatE(fI*) <
0 for some incumbentswith innovative exper-
tise smax.At this point E(H*) < 0 for all po-
tential entrantswith si = Smax. Since pt falls
over time, after this point E(II*) will con-
tinue to be negative for potentialentrantswith
Si = Smax, hence s will exceed Smaxandno fur-
therentry will occur.
One finalresultthatwill be useful concerns
how s' differs across entrycohortsin each pe-
riod. This is summarizedas follows.
LEMMA 8: In each period t, s' > s' for
I > k.
PROOF:
In each period, E(J7i,) 2 0 for producers.
Given that V * is lower the younger the firm
based on Lemma 3, it follows that the mini-
mum si requiredfor survival must be greater
for younger firms. Coupled with the fact that
entrants start with higher minimum product
innovation expertise than all prior entry co-
horts based on Lemma 6, it follows that the
younger the cohort of firms then the greater
the minimum productinnovation expertise of
the cohort.
The various lemmas indicate how: (1) the
price of the standard product changes over
time; (2) the initial values of rdi,, rcit, Aqi,,
and Vitchange over time for entrants;and (3)
the values of rdi,,rci,,andQitchangeover time
for incumbents. Summarizing results, over
time pt declines, rdi,remains the same for en-
trants and incumbents, rci,, Aqi,, and Vitde-
cline over time for entrants,st rises over time
572 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
for entrants,and rci,and Qt rise over time for
incumbents after entry. The other time paths,
which involve how Aqi,, V1t, and E(Ji,)
change over time for incumbents after entry,
cannot be characterized generally. The only
patternthat must hold is that in each period,
Vi,andE(Fi,) mustfallforsomefirms.
Itwas assumedthatapricep, existed in each
period such that the marketcleared given the
choices of firms takingp, as given. This will
now be establishedvia induction.It was as-
sumedthatsucha priceexistedinperiod1-
this was how period 1 was defined. Suppose
such a price exists in period t - 1. It will be
shown that a market-clearing price pt then
must exist in periodt given the choices of
firmstakingthispriceptas given.Giventhat
the market cleared in period t - 1, Qt- =
-i,-I Qit- , where the summation is over
firmsin themarketin periodt - 1. Inperiod
t, ptmustsatisfyequation(2), whichcanbe
expressedas
(7) f,(p,){ 1 - Y;Qit-I/ Qt- I
i7t
- X Aqit = 0,
i,t
wherethe summationis over firmsin the mar-
ketinperiodt. Intheproofof Lemma5 itwas
established thatpt must be less thanpt- and
mustinducesomefirmsto exit;otherwise1 -
Yi,tQit- 1/Qt- I = 0 since the marketclearedin
periodt - 1 andequation(7) wouldbe violated
giventhatAqi,> 0 foreachfirminthemarket.
Giventheassumptionof dE(nHt*)Idpt > 0, the
lower pt then the more firms for which
E(l*) < 0 andthusthegreaterthenumberof
finnsexitingin periodt. Themorefirmsthat
exitthenthegreater{I - Yi,tQi- 1/Qt-1} and
the smallerXi,tAqi,in equation(7). Further-
more,thesmallerpt thenthegreaterf (pt) and
the smallerAqt,for each firm,which reinforces
the effect of exit on the market-clearingcondi-
tion. Thus, as pt decreases relative to pt-I,
f (pt){I- Yi,t Q1t-I/QIQt}rises and Ei,t Aqit
falls in equation (7). Given that l(rc,t) is
bounded,ata low enoughprice E(nl* ) < 0 for
each firmand all firmswould exit the industry.
Thus,atalow enoughpricef (p,) I1 - Yjit Q,t-I
Q }-II - Yi,t Aqit > 0, whereasfor pricespt 2
p,_ 1,f(p,) {1 -Yi,t Qit- /Q,- | }-2i,tAqit <
0. Giventhatf,(pt)andAqi,arecontinuousfunc-
tions of p, and all firms are assumed to be
atomisticand indifferentaboutbeing in the in-
dustrywhen E(ll* ) = 0, it then follows that
theremustbe a pricept which satisfiesequation
(7) andthusclearsthe marketin periodt.'2
Note that the existence of such a path for
pricedoes notdependon positive entryin each
period, nordoes it dependon the time pathsin
the number of entrants,numberof exits, and
number of firms. These time paths are ad-
dressed in the next section.
IV. TheRegularitiesof thePLC
Six propositions are developed in this sec-
tion corresponding to each of the empirical
regularitiessummarizedin Section 2.
Considerthe firstregularityaboutentryover
time. Let Et denote the numberof entrantsin
periodt. The possible time pathsin Etimplied
by the model arecharacterizedin Proposition1.
PROPOSITION 1: Initially the number of
entrants may rise or decline, but eventually it
will decline to zero.
PROOF:
The entryprocess is such thatEt = Kt(1 -
H(st)). Lemma 6 indicatesst rises over time.
Hence Et will fall overtime unless Ktrises over
time at a sufficientrate,which cannotbe ruled
out a priori.Therefore,initially E, may rise or
2 The assumption that all firms are atomistic ensures
the continuity of f(p,){ 1 - .1j, Qit- ,IQt,- I-i, Aqi, as
a function of p, and hence the existence of a price pt sat-
isfying equation (7). A similar assumption is invoked in
Jovanovic and Glenn H. MacDonald (1994) and Hugo A.
Hopenhayn (1993) in their models of industryshakeouts
(these arediscussed furtherbelow). Alternatively,if firms
were nonatomisticthenthe quantitysupplied,Y,. Qi.- I(Q,I
Q,- ) + Yi,tAqi,, could exceed the quantity demanded,
f(p1), at all prices Pt insufficient to induce the marginal
firmto exit but could fall shortof the quantitydemanded
at all prices sufficient to induce the marginalfirmto exit.
Then, therewould be no price thatwould clearthe market
in periodt. Although beyond the scope of the paper,non-
atomisticfirmsmightbe accommodatedby allowing firms
to maintainbacklogs of unfilled ordersso thatunsatisfied
demand at the equilibriumprice in period t was satisfied
throughfirmexpansion in subsequentperiods.
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 573
fall overtime. Lemma7 indicatesthatin either
case, E, will eventually decline to 0.
Proposition1 can accountfor the two entry
patternsreflected in Figure 1. Intuitively, in
every period,incumbentshave a lower average
cost thanentrantsbecause they spend more on
process R&D due to the greater output over
whichtheycanapplythebenefitsof theirR&D.
Entrantscan nonethelessgain a foothold in the
industryif they can earnsufficientprofitsfrom
developinga distinctiveproductvariant,which
requiressufficientproduct-innovationexpertise
si. Over time, though, price is driven down
andthe advantageof incumbentsover entrants
grows, increasing the product-innovationex-
pertiserequiredfor entryto be profitable.This
reduces the percentage of potential entrants
that enter over time, although the number of
entrantscan rise at any time if the numberof
potential entrantsK, rises sufficiently. Even-
tually, price is driven to a level such that re-
gardlessof theirproduct-innovationexpertise,
theexpectedprofitsof all potentialentrantsare
less thanor equal to 0 and entry ceases.
The second regularityindicatesthatinitially
the total numberof firms rises but eventually
peaks and then declines steadily, as reflected
in Figure 1. Proposition 2 indicates how this
can be explained by the model.
PROPOSITION 2: Initially the number of
finns may rise over time, but eventually it will
decline steadily.
PROOF:
It was shown thatp, must fall over time in
Lemma 5, andby a sufficient amountto cause
some firms to exit in every period. Coupled
with Lemma 7, which indicates entry must
eventually stop, this implies that after some
period the numberof firms steadily declines.
To see how thenumberof firmscould riseover
time at some pointpriorto this, consider with-
outloss of generalitythechange in the number
of firmsbetween periods 1 and 2. This change
equalsthenumberof entrantsinperiod2, K2(1-
H(s2)), minus the numberof exits in period
2, K1(H(s )-H(s )). The only constraint
on the number of entrants and exits comes
from the requirement that the market must
clear in period 2. All incumbents that remain
in the industryin period 2 expandtheirmarket
share. Therefore, in order for the market to
clear in period 2, the total output of entrants
in period 2, K2(1 - H(s2))Aq2, mustbe less
thanthe outputexiters in period 2 would have
producedif they had remainedin the industry
andmaintainedtheirmarketshare,K1(H(s ) -
H(s 1)l) (Q2/Q1)Aq1. Since Aq2< Aq1based
on Lemma 6, this condition can be satisfied
even if K2(1 - H(s2)) > K1(H(s ) -
H(sl)). Thus, initially the number of firms
may rise. Note thatthe numberof firmscould
rise fromperiod 1 to 2 even if K2< K1,which
would ensure that the number of entrantsin
period 2, K2(1 - H(s2)), was less than the
number of entrants in period 1, K1( 1 -
H(s I)). Thus, the numberof firmscould rise
initially even if the numberof entrantsfell.
Intuitively, over time price falls, the more
innovative incumbentsexpand,andthe less in-
novative incumbentsexit and are replacedby
more innovative,smallerentrants.This can re-
sultin a rise in the numberof producers.How-
ever, as incumbentscontinueto grow theirad-
vantages eventually become insurmountable
andentryceases. Exit continues,though,asthe
largest firms with the greatest innovative ex-
pertise expandtheirmarketshareandpush the
less fit firmsout of the market.Consequently,
eventually the numberof firms declines over
time.
Considernext the thirdregularityregarding
how the market shares of the leaders change
over time. Proposition3 indicates thatthe rate
of change of the marketshares of all incum-
bents must eventually slow.
PROPOSITION 3: As eachfirm grows large,
eventually the change in its market share,
Aqi,/Q,, will decline over time.
PROOF:
Given that Q, is nondecreasing over time,
Aqi,/Q, will decline over time if Aqi,declines
over time. Equation (5) indicates that Aqi, is
based on the firm's profitmarginon the stan-
dardproduct,p, - c + I(rci,). Forincumbents
thatremainin the industry,rci,will grow over
time, causing l(rci,) to grow. Eventually,
though,I(rci,) will asymptoticallyapproachits
upper bound, and the rise in l(rci,) will
574 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
approachzero. In contrast,Lemma 5 indicates
thatp,will fall in every periodto accommodate
the desires of incumbents to expand. There-
fore, for incumbentsthatremainin the indus-
try, p, - c + l(rci,) will eventually decline,
causing the increase in their market share,
Aqi,/Q,, to decline.
Intuitively, in every period incumbents ex-
pand. The rate at which they expand depends
on theirprofitmarginon the standardproduct.
With the marginal product of process R&D
eventually approaching zero, all firms even-
tually experience a decline in theirprofitmar-
gin. This will induce them to decreasethe rate
atwhich they expandtheirmarketshare.Since
the largest firms perform the most process
R&D, they will be the firstto decreasethe rate
at which they expand theirmarketshare.Sub-
sequently, smaller firmswill follow.'
The otherthreeregularitiespertainto thena-
ture of innovation over the PLC. Regarding
firstthe trendover time in the rate of product
innovation, it is straightforwardto establish
the following.
PROPOSITION 4: Afterentryceases, the ex-
pected number of product innovations of all
finns, 1j, (si + g(rdi,)), declines over time.
PROOF:
Since rdi, = rd* for all firms according to
Lemma 1, si + g(rdi,) remains the same for
any firm i thatremains in the market.Conse-
quently, once entry ceases, li,t(si + g(rdi,))
declines over time as the number of firms
falls.
Proposition 4 explains the eventual decline
in the rate of product innovation in new in-
dustries reflected in the fourth regularity.
Since each firm performs a constant amount
of product innovation over time, once entry
ceases and the numberof firms declines then
the expected number of product innovations
must decline. Corresponding to this is a de-
cline in the number of distinctive variants of
the product for sale. This explains the other
part of the fourth regularity concerning the
decline in the numberof competing versions
of the product that eventually occurs in new
industries. Note that prior to the shakeout in
the numberof producers,the numberof firms
increases over time as more innovative en-
trantsdisplace larger, less innovative incum-
bents. This causes the number of competing
versions of the product to rise over time.
Thus, initially the marketinduces a rise in the
diversity of competing product versions,
which eventually gives way to a steady de-
cline in this diversity. In this sense, the emer-
gence of a "dominant design" for a product
can be interpretedas the result ratherthanthe
cause of the shakeout in the number of pro-
ducers. In effect, the private benefits of large
size eventually compromise the diversity of
competing product versions in the market.
Since all product innovations are introduced
in competing versions of the productandsub-
sequently incorporated into the standard
product, over time the rate of product inno-
vation in the standardproduct will also de-
cline as the numberof firms falls.
Considernext the trendover time in the ef-
fort devoted to process and product R&D. It
is easy to establish the following.
PROPOSITION 5: For each firm i that re-
mains in the market in period t, rci,/rdi, >
rci,- 1/rdi,- 1i
PROOF:
Foreach firm,Lemma 1indicatesrdi,is con-
stantover time andLemma4 indicatesthatrci,
rises over time. Hence rci,/rdi,must rise over
time.
1' Note, though, that there is nothing in the model to
ensurethatthe largestfirmsremainin the marketin every
period.Exit will occurin every period,andthereis nothing
in the model to rule out exit from the firstcohort, which
contains the largest finns. Nonetheless, it is possible to
establishthatthe largestcohortswill be subjectto the low-
est rateof exit in the following sense. In each cohort that
experiences exit, the firms with the least innovative ex-
pertise will exit. Eventually, whole entry cohorts become
extinct. This will occur for entry cohort k when sk, the
minimum innovation expertise requiredfor survival, ex-
ceeds Smax.Based on Lemma 8, sk will exceed Smaxfirstfor
the youngest cohorts,which always have the greatestmin-
imum product-innovation expertise. Thus, once entry
ceases the youngest cohorts, which are also the smallest,
will experiencethegreatestratesof exit. This accordswith
the findings of numerous studies (for example, David S.
Evans, 1987; Timothy Dunne et al., 1989).
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 575
Proposition5 establishes that over time
every firm that remainsin the marketin-
creasesits effortonprocessrelativeto prod-
uctR&D,whichexplainsthefifthregularity.
Intuitively,sincethereturnstoproductR&D
areindependentof firmsize whilethereturns
to processR&Darea directfunctionof firm
size, as firmsgrowtheyincreasetheireffort
on processrelativeto productR&D.This is
just anextremecase of the generalideathat
the returnsto productR&D areless depen-
denton the outputof the firm(priorto the
R&D) thanthe returnsto processR&D. In
this sense processandproductR&D,which
areoftencollapsedintoone basedon anap-
peal to a Lancasterianattributesframework,
aredifferent.
Proposition5 appliesto individualfirms.
Eventuallythe trendsat the firmlevel must
alsobe mirroredatthemarketlevel.Onceen-
try ceases, the smallestfirmsare dispropor-
tionatelydrivenfromthe marketgiven their
costdisadvantage.Thesefirmshavethehigh-
est ratioof productto processR&Dbecause
they conduct the least amountof process
R&D. Thus, as they disproportionatelyexit
andincumbentsincreasetheirlevelof process
relativetoproductR&D,theratioof totalpro-
cess to totalproductR&Dforallfirmsrises.'4
Note,though,thatonce entryceasesthetotal
processR&Dof all firmsmightdeclineover
time,just at a slowerratethanthedeclinein
totalproductR&D.'"
The last regularityconcerninginnovation
is thatentrantstendto accountfor a dispro-
portionateshareof productinnovationsrel-
ative to incumbents. Let ik = (i,t(si +
g(rdit))/N' denote the expected numberof
innovations per firm in period t of firms that
entered in period k, where N' is the number
of firms in period t that entered in period k
and the summation is over these firms. Prop-
osition 6 indicates thatik must be greaterthe
younger the cohort.
PROPOSITION 6: For all periods t, ik < ia
fork < 1.
PROOF:
Since all firms spend the same amount on
product R&D, the expected numberof inno-
vations per firm, si + g(rdi,), is determined
exclusively by si. This implies thaton average
the expected number of innovations per firm
in each entrycohortwill be determinedby the
averageinnovativeexpertiseof firmsin theco-
hort.Foreach periodt, Lemma8 indicatesthat
the minimuminnovative expertise of cohortk,
Sk, is greaterthe younger the cohort (that is,
the largerk). Therefore, the average value of
si will be greatertheyoungerthecohort,hence
ak< il for k < 1.
Proposition 6 implies that entrants will be
more innovative on average than incum-
bents, which explains the last regularity. In-
tuitively, the most recent entrantsaresmaller
than all other firms and thus earn the least
profits from the standard product. The only
way they survive given this disadvantage is
if they are more innovative on average than
incumbents. Thus, it is not necessary to ap-
peal to some kind of disadvantage of size in
innovation, or to entrants having a greater
incentive than incumbents to innovate be-
cause they have less to protect (compare
Reinganum, 1983, 1985), to explain the
greater innovativeness of entrants. Rather,
the greater innovativeness of entrants may
be attributable to the selection process gov-
erning the evolution of the market coupled
with an advantage of large firm size in ap-
propriatingthe returnsfrom R&D. Indeed, if
incumbents either had strategic disincentives
to innovate or were less efficient at innova-
tion because of their larger size, then oppor-
tunities for profitable entry would persist
over time, which is not consistent with the
first regularity concerning entry eventually
becoming small.
4 Priorto entry ceasing, there is a counteractingforce
at the level of the marketto the trendin the ratio of firm
process to product R&D: smaller, more innovative en-
trantsdisplacelarger,less innovativeincumbents.Because
theentrantsaresmaller,they havea higherratioof product
to process R&D than the incumbents, which contributes
toward a higher ratio of product to process R&D at the
marketlevel. Thus, it is possible thatpriorto entry ceas-
ing, the ratio of process to product R&D at the market
level might fall over time. Once entry ceases, however,
the ratio must rise.
I Whetherthetotalamountof processR&D of all firms
declines over time dependson therateat which incumbent
firmsexpandtheirprocess R&D relativeto therateof firm
exit, which is not determinedwithin the model.
576 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
V. Cross-Sectional Implications of the Model
In this section it is shown thatthe model can
explain various cross-sectional regularitiesre-
garding how within industries R&D effort,
R&D productivity, cost, and profitabilitydif-
fer across firms according to their size. Since
the model was not set up to explain these reg-
ularities, its ability to explain them can be
viewed as supportfor its account of the PLC.
A simple cross-sectional implication of the
model is thatlargerfirmsshouldperformmore
total R&D and also devote a greaterfraction
of their R&D to process innovation.
PROPOSITION 7: For each period t, the
larger the outputof thefirm at the start of the
period, Qit- 1,then the greater its total spend-
ing on R&D, rdi, + rci,, and the greater the
fraction of its total R&D devoted to process
innovation,rci,/(rdi, + rci,).
PROOF:
This follows directlyfromLemmas 1 and3.
There have been numerous studies of the
relationshipbetween total R&D spending and
contemporaneous firm size. It has been re-
peatedly found that R&D and contemporane-
ous firmsize areclosely related,with firmsize
explaining over 50 percent of the variationin
firm R&D in more R&D-intensive industries
(see Cohen and Klepper [1996b] for a review
of these studies). In terms of the composition
of firmR&D, F. M. Scherer (1991) analyzes
the patentsissued to firmsin theFederalTrade
Commission Line of Business Programin the
10-month period from June 1976 to March
1977. Assigning thesepatentsto business units
and classifying them according to whether
they are process or product patents, Scherer
finds that among business units with patents,
the fraction of patents that are process in-
creases with the sales of the business unit.
Based on the assumption that the returns to
process R&D aremore closely tied to the size
of the firm than the returnsto product R&D,
Cohen and Klepper (1996a) develop addi-
tional predictions at the level of the industry
aboutthe relationshipbetween the fraction of
patentsthatareprocess andbusiness unitsales.
Using Scherer's data, they find support for
Proposition 7 at the level of the industry as
well as for theirmore detailed predictions.
The intuitionbehindProposition7 is simple:
the largerthe firmthen the greaterthe returns
fromprocess R&D, hence thegreatertheeffort
devoted to R&D in generalandprocess in par-
ticular.Alternativelystated,the largerthe firm
then the greaterthe output over which it can
average the fixed costs of (process) R&D,
hence the greaterits R&D effort. This implies
that the close relationshipbetween R&D and
firmsize is indicative of an advantageof size.
In contrast, most studies have interpretedthe
close relationshipto indicate no advantageof
size. They note thatR&D does not tend to rise
morethanproportionallywith firmsize, which
implies that increasing the average firm size
would not increase total industryR&D spend-
ing. This has been widely interpretedto imply
there are no advantages of large firm size in
R&D (William L. Baldwin andJohnT. Scott,
1987 p. 111). But as Cohen and Klepper
(1996b) emphasize, without such an advan-
tage it is difficult to explain why there is a
close relationship between R&D and firm
size.16
In additionto predictionsaboutR&D effort
and firmsize, the model has distinctive impli-
cations abouthow firmsize andR&D produc-
tivity are related.
PROPOSITION 8: For each period t, the av-
erage product of process R&D, l(rci,)/rci,,
and the average product of product R&D,
(si + g(rdj,))/rdj,, vary inversely with the size
of thefirm,Qj.
6 Note that in the model there is no innate advantage
of firmsize in R&D, as Cohen andKlepper(1996b) point
out in a related setting. The advantageof large firm size
stems from the inability of firms to sell their innovations
in disembodied form and the costliness of rapid growth.
In the absence of these restrictions,successful innovations
could be embodied in the entire industryoutput through
the sale of the innovations and/or the expansion of suc-
cessful innovators, and the contemporaneoussize of the
firm would have no bearing on the firm's incentives to
conduct R&D. While many other models assume, either
implicitly or explicitly, that innovations cannot be sold
and thus link the returnsto innovation to the size of the
innovator,few assume any restrictionson firmgrowth.
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 577
PROOF:
Given thatl"(rci,) < 0 for all rci,,the larger
rci,then the lower will be l(rcj,)/rcj,. In each
periodt, the largerthe firmthen the greaterits
spending on process R&D. Therefore, l(rci,)/
rci, will vary inversely with Qt. Regarding
productR&D, Proposition6 indicates thatthe
expected number of innovations per firm is
greaterfor smallerfirms.Since all firmsspend
the same amounton productR&D, thisimplies
that (si + g(rdj,))/rdj, must be inversely re-
lated to the size of the firm, Qit.
Proposition8 is consistent with the findings
of studies that examine the relationship be-
tween totalR&D effort andthe numberof pat-
ents and/or innovationsperunitof R&D. John
Bound et al. (1984) find that for publicly
tradedfirms, the numberof patentsper dollar
of R&D is considerably greaterfor firmswith
smaller R&D budgets. Examining this rela-
tionship within industries using data from a
comprehensive census of innovations in 1982
conductedfor the Small Business Administra-
tion, Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch
(1991) generally find an inverse relationship
across firms between the number of innova-
tions perdollarof R&D andtotalR&D spend-
ing. If in addition total R&D spending does
not rise more than proportionally with firm
size within industries, as has generally been
found, then Proposition 8 furtherimplies that
the total productof R&D will not rise in pro-
portion to firm size. Equivalently stated,
within industrieslargerfirmswill account for
a disproportionatelysmall shareof process and
productinnovationsrelative to theirsize. This
is consistent with Acs and Audretsch's find-
ings (1988, 1991) based on the Small Busi-
ness Administrationdata, especially for more
R&D intensive industries, with Scherer's
(1965) findingsconcerning the rateof patent-
ing among large firms, and with the observa-
tions of Alice Patricia White (1983) for the
select group of dominantfirms she analyzes.
This interpretationruns counterto the con-
ventionalinterpretationof the inverserelation-
ship between R&D productivityand firmsize.
This finding has been widely interpretedas a
furthersign of the lack of an advantageof firm
size in R&D (see, for example, Acs and
Audretsch, 1991). Not only do large firmsnot
spend disproportionatelymore on R&D than
smaller firms, but they appearto get less out
of theirR&D spendingthansmallerfirms,sug-
gesting they areactually less efficient at R&D
than their smaller counterparts.This interpre-
tation, though, raises more questions than it
answers. If larger firms are less efficient at
R&D, why do they conduct more R&D than
smallerfirms?Even morefundamentally,how
are large firms able to survive and prosperin
R&D intensive industriesif they are less effi-
cient at R&D than smaller firms?
These questions arereadilyansweredby the
model. All firmshave the same R&D produc-
tivity in the model in the sense that the func-
tions g(rdi,) and l(rci,), which calibrate the
productivity of product and process R&D re-
spectively, are the same for all firms. The
lower average productivity of both product
andprocess R&D in largerfirmsis a reflection
of the competitive advantages conferred by
firmsize. By applyingtheir(process) R&D to
a larger level of output, larger firms are able
to appropriatea greaterfraction of the value
of their (process) R&D than smaller firms.
This induces them to undertakemore process
R&D than smaller firms. Given the diminish-
ing returnsto R&D, by undertakingmorepro-
cess R&D largerfirmsmarchfurtherdown the
marginal-productschedule of process R&D,
causing the average product of their process
R&D to be lower thanin smaller firms.At the
same time, by undertakingmoreprocess R&D
and getting a larger returnfrom their process
R&Dthansmallerfirms,theyearngreaterprof-
its fromprocess R&D thansmallerfirms.This
is why they prosperdespite the lower average
productivityof their R&D than smaller firms.
The greater profits they earn from process
R&D also enables them to survive with less
average product-innovation expertise than
smaller firms, which explains why they gen-
erate fewer product innovations per dollar of
productR&D than smaller firms.'7
'7 RichardJ. Rosen (1991) recently proposed an alter-
native explanationfor why large firms account for a dis-
proportionatelysmall shareof innovationsrelativeto their
sales which also relies on large size conferringan advan-
tage in appropriatingthe returnsfrom R&D. His expla-
nation, however, also relies on a stylized depiction of the
578 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
Themodelhasfurtherimplicationsregard-
ing how the advantagesconferredby size in
R&Dwill be reflectedin firmcost andprofit-
ability.It predictsthatlargerfirmswill have
loweraveragecost.
PROPOSITION 9: For each period t, firm
average cost c - l(rcj,) varies inversely with
Qit.
PROOF:
Sincerci,variesdirectdywithQitandP'(rci,)>
0 forallrci,,it followsdirectlythatc - l(rci,)
variesinverselywithQit.
Thispredictionis consistentwiththe find-
ingsof RichardE. CavesandDavidR.Barton
(1990), who use plantdatafromthe Census
of Manufacturerstoestimateproductionfunc-
tionsfor4-digitSICmanufacturingindustries.
Allowingproductivityto differacrossplants,
they findthatfor the averageindustrylarger
plantsaremoreproductivethansmallerplants.
In lightof thehighcorrelationbetweenplant
andbusinesssize,thisfindingis supportiveof
Proposition9.ConsistentwiththeroleofR&D
inthemodelinimpartingalowercosttolarger
firms,CavesandBarton(p. 126) findthere-
lationshipbetweenproductivityandplantsize
to be strongerin moreR&Dintensiveindus-
tries.Proposition9 is also consistentwithE.
RalphBiggadike's(1979 pp.65-66) findings
aboutentrants.Using detaileddataon new
businessunitsof asubsetof firmsinthePIMS
dataset,Biggadikefindsthatentrantstendto
startwith a pronouncedproduction-costdis-
advantagethatdeclinesover time as the en-
trantscapturea largershareof themarket.
Themodelhasfurtherimplicationsregard-
inghowtheadvantagesconferredbyfirmsize
in R&D will be reflectedin firmcost and
profitability.
PROPOSITION 10: The largest and most
profitablefirms will comefrom thefirst cohort
of entrants. These firms will increase their
marketshares over timeand consistentlyearn
supernormalprofits.
PROOF:
Firmsthatenteredin period1withinnova-
tive expertiseSmaxwill alwaysbe largerthan
all subsequententrantsandwill earngreater
profitsthanallotherfirms.Consequently,they
will consistentlyearnsupernormalprofitsand
will neverexit.SinceAqi,> 0 forall incum-
bents,overtimethesefirmswill alsoincrease
theirmarketshares.
Proposition10 implies that the market
sharesof thelargestandmostprofitablefirms
intheindustrywillnotdeclineovertime.Fur-
thermore,althoughthe profitsof these firms
maydeclineovertimeaspricefalls,theywill
consistentlyearnsupernormalprofits.These
predictions are consistent with Mueller's
(1986) findingsconcerningthepersistenceof
marketshareandprofitabilityamongthelarg-
estmanufacturingfirmsovertheperiod1950-
1972. Muellerfindsthata numberof these
firmsmaintainedtheirmarketsharesoverthis
22-yearperiod.Whiletheaverageprofitability
of thesefirmsdeclinedovertime,they were
still eaming supernormalreturnson invest-
mentin 1972.Consistentwiththeroleplayed
by R&Din themodelin conferringanadvan-
tagetolargerfirms,Muellerfindsthattheper-
sistenceof marketshareandprofitabilitywas
strongerforfirmsin moreR&D-intensivein-
dustries.Proposition10 also predictsthatthe
mostsuccessfulandlong-livedfirmswill dis-
proportionatelycome fromthe earliestentry
cohorts.Thisis consistentwiththefindingsof
KlepperandSimons(1993) concerningfour
productsthatexperiencedsharpshakeouts:au-
tos,tires,televisions,andpenicillin.Theyfind
thatthechancesof survivingatleast 10years
weresignificantlygreaterfor the earliesten-
trants,particularlyin autosandtires,andthat
on averagethelargestfirmsenteredearlier.
Insummary,thecross-sectionalregularities
indicatethatthelargerthefirmthenthegreater
its spendingon R&D,thegreaterthefraction
of itsR&Ddevotedtoprocessinnovation,the
smallerthenumberof patentsandinnovations
returnsto risky R&D projects which suggests, counterto
the evidence assembled in Mansfield (1981), that large
firms will account for a disproportionatelysmall shareof
riskier R&D. As the model indicates, as long as R&D is
subjectto diminishingreturnsandlargefirmsize provides
an advantage in appropriatingthe returnsto R&D, there
is little need to resort to other stylizations to account for
the disproportionatelysmall number of innovations ac-
counted for by largerfirms.
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 579
it generatesper dollar of R&D, and the lower
its averagecosts. Furthermore,earlierentrants
tend to grow larger and survive longer. Since
all of these patterns are predicted by the
model, they provide supportfor it. The extent
of the support,though, depends on the degree
to which these same patternscan be explained
by other theories, particularly theories that
can account for various features of the PLC.
The most relevant alternativetheories are the
dominantdesignview reviewedin the introduc-
tion (compare Utterbackand Suairez,1993),
which explains many featuresof the PLC, and
theories recently advanced in Jovanovic and
MacDonald(1994) and Hopenhayn(1993) to
explainshakeouts.
Each of these theories posits technology-
based mechanisms which increase exit and/or
make entryharder,contributingto a shakeout.
In Utterback and Suairez(1993) the mecha-
nism is a dominantdesign, which leads to exit
of firms less able to manage the production
process for the dominantdesign. In Jovanovic
and MacDonald (1994) it is a major (exoge-
nous) technological changewhich leads to exit
of firmsthatareunable to innovatein the new
regime. InHopenhayn(1993) it is a slowdown
in productinnovationthatfavors firmsthatin-
vest in process innovation, in the manner of
the dominantdesign theory.'8
While the theories do not directly address
the cross-sectional regularities,they can none-
theless be used to speak to them. In each the-
ory, the firms that prosper and remain in the
industryduringthe shakeoutare the betterin-
novators.1t might be expected these firms
would spend more on R&D, particularlypro-
cess R&D in the UtterbackandSuairez(1993)
and Hopenhayn (1993) models, have lower
costs, and grow to be larger. This could ex-
plain the cross-sectional regularitiesinvolving
firmsize and total R&D, the fraction of R&D
devoted to process innovation, and average
cost. The other two regularities,however, are
moredifficultforthe alternativetheoriesto ex-
plain.If largerfirmsarebetterinnovators,they
mightbe expected to generateatleast as many,
if not more, innovations per dollar of R&D
thanthe smaller finns. Yet the cross-sectional
regularitiesindicatethatthe numberof patents
and innovations per dollar of R&D declines
with firm size. In terms of the significance of
early entry, none of the theories emphasizes
the importanceof entrytiming in conditioning
the length of survival of firms that entered
priorto the shakeout.'9Yet the cross-sectional
regularities indicate that among products ex-
periencing sharp shakeouts, the date of entry
was an importantdeterminantof the length of
survival for the preshakeoutentrants.20
Thus, the alternativetheories cannotreadily
explain all theregularities.This does notimply
that the forces they feature are not operative.
Indeed, these forces are largely complemen-
taryto the ones featuredin the model. Judging
fromthe cross-sectional regularities,however,
the model appearsto captureimportantforces
that arenot presentin the other theories.
VI. ImplicationsandExtensions
The notion thatentry,exit, marketstructure,
and innovation follow a common patternfor
new productshas become partof the folklore
of a numberof disciplines, including econom-
ics. Although the features of this pattern are
based on a limited number of products and
much of the evidence is impressionistic, they
appear to resonate with our experience. De-
spite its popularity, though, there are many
skeptics about the PLC, both in terms of its
logic and its universality. The principal pur-
pose of this paper was to shore up its logical
18Hopenhayn(1993) also posits other,nontechnology-
basedmechanismsthatcould triggera shakeout.These are
not considered because they cannot address the cross-
sectional regularitiesinvolving R&D.
'9In eachtheorythe shakeoutis triggeredby events
whichchangethe basis for competitionamongincum-
bents,whichif anythingmightbeexpectedto undermine
thevalueof priorexperience.
20Moreover,itdoesnotappeartobetheshakeoutitself
whichaccountsforthiseffect.Klepper(1996)findsthat
differencesin survivalratesforthepreshakeoutentrants
weremostpronouncedwhentheywereolderandhadsur-
viveda numberof yearsof the shakeout.In themodel,
thiscanbe explainedby the selectionprocess(compare
Klepper,1996).Onaverage,laterentrantsarebetterin-
novators.Atyoungages,thiscanoffsetthedisadvantage
of lateentryfor firmsurvival,butas firmsage andthe
selectionprocesscontinuestooperate,eventuallylateren-
trantsmustexperiencehigherhazardrates.
580 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
foundations by showing how a simple model
could explain all the central features of the
PLC.
The proposed model groundsthe PLC with
two simple forces. One is that the ability to
appropriatethe returns to process R&D de-
pends centrally on the size of the firm. The
other is that firms possess different types of
expertise which lead them to pursue different
types of product innovations. The advantage
of size in process R&D causes firm process
R&D to rise over time andeventually puts en-
trantsat such a cost disadvantagethatentryis
foreclosed. After entry ceases, firms compete
on the basis of their size and also their inno-
vative prowess. As firmsexit and the number
of firmsfalls, the diversity of productR&D is
compromised, causing the numberof product
innovations and the diversity of competing
product variants to decline. The same two
forces also explain the relationshipwithin in-
dustries between firm size and total R&D
spending, relative spending on product and
process R&D, the productivity of R&D, av-
erage cost, andprofitability.The ability of the
model to explain these cross-sectional regu-
laritiesin additionto the temporalpatternsthat
define the PLCprovides supportfor its expla-
nationof the PLC.It also lends credenceto the
PLC as a leading case thatcapturesthe salient
features of the evolution of technologically
progressive industries.
A number of stylizations were invoked to
highlight the two key forces featured in the
model. Perhapsthe most noteworthywere the
assumptionsthat average cost was a function
of only contemporaneous process R&D, de-
cisions were made solely on the basis of short-
termprofits,andallinnovationswereultimately
embodied in the industry's standardproduct.
Although relaxing these assumptions would
complicate the model, it need not fundamen-
tally alter the ability of the model to explain
the PLC. Regarding process innovation, sup-
pose process improvements were allowed to
cumulate. If all process improvements were
assumed to be costlessly imitated one period
afterthey were introduced,firmdifferences in
average cost would still be a function of only
differences in contemporaneousfirmspending
on process R&D. Firm average costs would
equal c, - I (rci,), where c, reflects the cumu-
lative effect on cost of all past process inno-
vations by all firms. This change would not
fundamentallyaffect the model.2'Even if cost
differences across firms were allowed to cu-
mulate,it would only reinforcethe advantages
of the largest firms. If firms were allowed to
be forwardlooking, all firmswould accelerate
the growth in their output to take account of
the advantages of size in R&D and accord-
ingly undertakegreaterprocess R&D in each
period(Klepper, 1992). But given the costs of
expanding output, firms would still grow by
finite ratesin each period andit would still be
advantageousto enterearlier.Indeed,the firms
that would accelerate the growth in their out-
put the most would be those that expected to
survive longest, which would be the firmsthat
entered earliest with the greatest innovative
expertise. Thus, allowing firms to be forward
looking would notaltertheadvantagesof early
entryandgreaterinnovationexpertiseandthus
would not fundamentallyalter the model. Fi-
nally, suppose some productinnovationswere
not embodied in the standard product but
formed the basis for separateproductniches.
If all permanent product variants could be
costlessly imitated one period afterthey were
developed andprocess innovationlowered the
average cost of all product variants, then the
implications of the model would not change.
All firms would produce all product variants
andthe incentives for process R&D would de-
pend on the total outputof all variants.22
The depiction in the model of how market
structureand performance evolve over time
for new productsis differentfrom the conven-
tional industrial organization paradigm on
structureandperformance.Historically,indus-
trycharacteristicswere seen as shapingthe na-
ture of firm cost functions and barriers to
entry, which in turndeterminedstructureand
performance. With few exceptions, firm dif-
ferences within industrieswere thought to be
2' The only implicationof the model thatwould change
is Proposition 3, which would requirefurtherstructuring
of the model to establish.
22The only way the model would be fundamentallyal-
teredis if eachproductnicherequireditsown processR&D.
In this case, each productniche would be analogous to a
separateindustry,and the model would no longer be a
model of industryevolutionbut of industryfragmentation.
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 581
irrelevant(Mueller,1986pp.223-24). Inre-
cent years,however,it has been recognized
thatfirmdifferencesmaybe at the rootof a
numberof importantphenomena,suchas the
positivecorrelationacrossindustriesbetween
industryconcentrationratiosand mean firm
profitability(Harold Demsetz, 1973). The
modeltakesthis approacha step furtherby
embeddingdifferencesin firmcapabilitiesin
anevolutionarysettingin whichexpansionin
outputat anygiven momentis subjectto in-
creasingmarginalcostsandfirmsize imparts
an advantagein certaintypes of R&D. The
resultis a worldin whichinitialfirmdiffer-
encesgetmagnifiedas sizebegetssize,which
impartsanadvantageto earlyentryandleads
to aneventualdeclinein thenumberof firms
andtherateof productinnovation.23
The starknessof the modelprecludesany
departuresfromthisevolutionarypattern.This
can be remediedby allowing for random
eventsthataltertherelativestandingofincum-
bentsandpotentialentrants.Forexample,if
cohortsdifferin termsof the distributionof
theirinnovativeexpertiseor if the innovative
expertiseof incumbentsis underminedbycer-
taintypesof technologicalchanges,thenlater
entrantsmayleapfrogovertheindustryleaders
andthefirmsthateventuallydominatethein-
dustrymaynotcomefromtheearliestcohort
of entrants.24Someproductsaredescribedas
eventuallybecomingcommodities,whichcould
beaccountedforinthemodelbyallowingtech-
nologicalopportunitiesforinnovationeventually
to dryup.Incumbentfirmproductandprocess
R&Dwouldtheneventuallydeclinetozeroand
theadvantagesof earlyentrywouldeventually
be eliminated,allowingthenumberof firmsto
stabilizebeforethe shakeoutof producershad
runitsfullcourse.Themodelcouldalsobegen-
eralizedtoincludeotheractivities,suchasmar-
ketingandadvertising,thatcouldsubstitutefor
processR&D in impartingan advantageto
largerfirms (Sutton, 1991).25 While these
generalizationswould no doubt enrich the
modelandallowittoaccommodatedepartures
fromthePLCthathavebeenobservedinsome
technologicallyprogressiveindustries(com-
pareKlepper,1992), eveninitsstarkformthe
modelis ableto addressa widerangeof reg-
ularities.Itdemonstratesthatmanyaspectsof
industryevolutionand heterogeneitywithin
industriesin firmR&Deffortandprofitability
canbe explainedby couplingrandomdiffer-
ences in firmcapabilitieswith advantagesof
firmsize conferredby R&D.
REFERENCES
Abernathy, William J. The productivity di-
lemma.Baltimore:The JohnsHopkins Uni-
versity Press, 1978.
Abernathy,WilliamJ.;Clark,KimB.andKantrow,
AlanM. Industrialrenaissance:Producinga
competitivefiture for America. New York:
Basic Books, 1983.
Abernathy,WilliamJ. and Utterback,JamesM.
"Patternsof IndustrialInnovation." Tech-
nology Review,June/July 1978, 80, pp. 41-
47.
Acs, ZoltanJ. and Audretsch,DavidB. "Inno-
vation in Large and Small Firms." Ameri-
can Economic Review, September 1988,
78(4), pp. 678-90.
. "R&D, Finn Size, and Innovative
Activity," in Zoltan J. Acs and David B.
Audretsch,eds., Innovationand technolog-
ical change: An international comparison.
New York:HarvesterWheatseaf, 1991, pp.
39-59.
Aitken,HughG.J. Thecontinuouswave: Tech-
nology and American radio, 1900-1932.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
1985.
Anderson, Philip and Tushman, Michael L.
"Technological Discontinuities and Domi-
nant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Tech-
nological Change." AdministrativeScience
Quarterly, December 1990, 35(4), 604-
33.
23The welfare implications of these and other predic-
tions of the model are developed in Klepper(1992).
2 These andothergeneralizationsof the model arean-
alyzed in Klepper(1992).
25Indeed,for some industrieseven productR&D could
play this role, althoughit would seem as if firmsize plays
a more importantrole in conditioning the returmsto pro-
cess than product R&D. This issue, and others, such as
why firms are limited in their ability to control their in-
novation expertise, involve key aspects of the model that
merit furtherstudy.
582 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996
Baldwin, William L. and Scott, John T. Market
structure and technological change. Chur,
Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publish-
ers, 1987.
Biggadike,E. Ralph.Corporate diversification:
Entrystrategyandperformance.Cambridge,
MA: HarvardUniversityPress, 1979.
Bound, John; Cummins, Clint; Griliches, Zvi;
Hall, Bronwyn H. and Jaffe, Adam. "Who
Does R&D and Who Patents?" in Zvi
Griliches, ed., R&D, patents, and produc-
tivity.Chicago:University of Chicago Press
for the National Bureau of Economic Re-
search, 1984, pp. 21-54.
Bright,ArthurA. The electric lamp industry.
New York:Macmillan, 1949.
Bright,JamesR.Automationand management.
Boston: GraduateSchool of Business Ad-
ministration,HarvardUniversity, 1958.
Caves, Richard E. and Barton, David R. Effi-
ciency in U.S. manufacturing industries.
Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1990.
Clark,KimB. "The Interactionof Design Hi-
erarchies and MarketConcepts in Techno-
logical Evolution." Research Policy,
October 1985, 14(5), pp. 235-51.
Cohen, Wesley M. and Klepper, Steven. "The
Anatomy of IndustryR&D IntensityDistri-
butions." AmericanEconomicReview, Sep-
tember 1992, 82(4), pp. 773-99.
. "Firm Size and the Nature of Inno-
vation within Industries:The Case of Pro-
cess and Product R&D." Review of
Economics and Statistics, 1996a.
. "A Reprise of Size and R&D." Eco-
nomic Journal, forthcoming 1996b.
Dasgupta, Partha and Stiglitz, Joseph. "Indus-
trial Structureand the Natureof Innovative
Activity." Economic Journal, June 1980,
90(358), pp. 266-93.
De Bresson, C. and Townsend, J. "Multivariate
Models for Innovation: Looking at the
Abernathy-Utterback Model with Other
Data." Omega, 1981, 9(4), pp. 429-36.
Demsetz,Harold."Industry Structure,Market
Rivalry, and Public Policy." Journal of
Lawand Economics, April 1973,16(1), pp.
1-9.
Drew, Philip G. "Despite Shakeout, Imaging
IndustryNot Doomed to Being GreekTrag-
edy." Diagnostic Imaging, November
1987, 9, pp. 95-99.
Dunne,Timothy;Roberts,MarkJ. andSamuelson,
Larry. "The Growth and Failure of U.S.
ManufacturingPlants." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, November 1989,104(4), pp.
671-98.
Evans,DavidS. "Tests of AlternativeTheories
of Firm Growth." Journal of Political
Economy, August 1987, 95(4), pp. 657-
74.
Flaherty,M. Therese."Industry Structureand
Cost-Reducing Investment." Economet-
rica, July 1980, 48(5), pp. 1187-209.
Flamm, Kenneth. Creating the computer.
Washington, DC: The Brookings Institu-
tion, 1988.
Gilbert,RichardJ. and Newbery,DavidM. G.
"Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence
of Monopoly." American Economic Re-
view, June 1982, 72(3), pp. 514-26.
Gort,MichaelandKlepper,Steven."Time Paths
in the Diffusion of Product Innovations."
Economic Journal, September 1982,
92(367), pp. 630-53.
Hollander,Samuel.Thesources of increased ef-
ficiency: A study of Du Pont rayon plants.
Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1965.
Hopenhayn,HugoA. "The Shakeout." Work-
ing Paper No. 33, Universitat Pompeu Fa-
bra, 1993.
Hounshell,DavidA. "The Making of the Syn-
thetic Fiber Industryin the United States."
Mimeo, HarvardBusiness School, 1988.
Jovanovic,Boyan."Selection andtheEvolution
of Industry." Econometrica, May 1982,
50(3), pp. 649-70.
Jovanovic, Boyan and MacDonald,Glenn H.
"The Life Cycle of a Competitive Indus-
try." Journal of Political Economy, April
1994, 102(2), pp. 322-47.
Klein, BurtonH. Dynamic economics. Cam-
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1977.
Klepper,Steven."Entry, Exit, and Innovation
over the ProductLife Cycle: The Dynamics
of FirstMoverAdvantages,Declining Prod-
uct Innovation, and Market Failure."
Mimeo, CarnegieMellon University, 1992.
. "Evolution, Market Concentration,
andFirmSurvival." Mimeo, CarnegieMel-
lon University, 1996.
Klepper,Steven and Graddy,Elizabeth."The
Evolution of New Industriesand the Deter-
VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 583
minants of Market Structure." Rand Jour-
nal of Economics, Spring 1990, 21 (1), pp.
27-44.
Klepper,StevenandSimons,KennethL. "Tech-
nological ChangeandIndustryShakeouts."
Mimeo, CarnegieMellon University, 1993.
Kraus,Jerome. "An Economic Study of the
U.S. Semiconductor Industry." Ph.D. Dis-
sertation,New School for Social Research,
1973.
Mansfield,Edwin. "Entry, Gibrat's Law, In-
novation and the Growthof Firms." Amer-
ican Economic Review, December 1962,
52(5), pp. 1031-51.
. "Composition of R and D Expendi-
tures:Relationshipto Size of Firm,Concen-
tration,and Innovative Output." Review of
Economics and Statistics, November 1981,
63(4), pp. 610-15.
Mowery,DavidC.andRosenberg,Nathan.Inside
the black box: Technology and economics.
New York: Cambridge University Press,
1982.
Mueller,DennisC.Profitsin thelong run.Cam-
bridge:CambridgeUniversity Press, 1986.
Mueller,DennisC. andTilton,John. "Research
and Development Costs as a Barrierto En-
try." Canadian Journal of Economics, No-
vember 1969, 2(4), pp. 570-79.
Nelson,RichardR. "Assessing Private Enter-
prise: An Exegesis of Tangled Doctrine."
Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1981,
12(1), pp. 93-111.
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G.
"Forces Generating and Limiting Concen-
trationunderSchumpeterianCompetition."
Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1978,
9(2), pp. 524-48.
. An evolutionary theory of economic
change. Cambridge,MA: HarvardUniver-
sity Press, 1982.
Pavitt,K.andRothwell,R. "A Commenton 'A
Dynamic Model of Process and ProductIn-
novation.' " Omega, 1976, 4(4), pp. 375-
77.
Porter,MichaelE. Competitive strategy. New
York:The Free Press, 1980.
. "The Technological Dimension of
Competitive Strategy," in Richard S.
Rosenbloom, ed., Research on technologi-
cal innovation, management and policy.
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1983.
Prusa,ThomasJ. and Schmitz,JamesA. "Are
New Firms an ImportantSource of Inno-
vation?" Economics Letters, March 1991,
35(3), pp. 339-42.
Reinganum,Jennifer. "Uncertain Innovation
and the Persistence of Monopoly." Ameri-
can Economic Review, September 1983,
73(4), pp. 741-48.
. "Innovation and Industry Evolu-
tion." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
February1985, 100(1), pp. 81-99.
Rosen,RichardJ. "Research andDevelopment
with Asymmetric Firm Sizes." Rand Jour-
nal of Economics, Autumn 1991,22(3), pp.
411-29.
Scherer,F. M. "Firm Size, Market Structure,
Opportunity,andthe Outputof PatentedIn-
ventions." American Economic Review,
December 1965, 55(5), pp. 1097-125.
. "Changing Perspectives on the Firm
Size Problem," in Zoltan J. Acs and David
B. Audretsch, eds., Innovation and techno-
logical change: An international compari-
son. New York:HarvesterWheatseaf, 1991,
pp. 24-38.
Schmookler,Jacob. Invention and economic
growth. Cambridge,MA: HarvardUniver-
sity Press, 1966.
Shaked, Avner and Sutton, John. "Product Dif-
ferentiationandIndustrialStructure."Jour-
nal of Industrial Economics, December
1987, 36(2), pp. 131-46.
Sutton,John.Sunkcosts and marketstructure.
Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1991.
Tilton,JohnE. Internationaldiffusion of tech-
nology: Thecase of semiconductors.Wash-
ington, DC: The Brookings Institution,
1971.
Utterback, James M. and Abernathy, William J.
"A Dynamic Model of Process and Product
Innovation."Omega,1975,3(6), pp.639-56.
Utterback, James M. and Suairez, Fernando F.
"Innovation, Competition, and Industry
Structure."ResearchPolicy, February1993,
22(1), pp. 1-21.
von Hippel,Eric. The sources of innovation.
Oxford:Oxford University Press, 1988.
White,AlicePatricia.The dominantfirm. Ann
Arbor,MI: UMI Research Press, 1983.
Williamson,OliverE. Marketsand hierarchies:
Analysis and antitrust implications. New
York:The Free Press, 1975.

More Related Content

Similar to (Klepper 1996) steven klepper, “entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the

Trends in Advanced Manufacturing
Trends in Advanced ManufacturingTrends in Advanced Manufacturing
Trends in Advanced Manufacturing
umesh chikhale
 
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
Facultad Cea
 
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical 2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
Kassu Jilcha (PhD)
 
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical 2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
Kassu Jilcha (PhD)
 
A Passion for Manufacturing
A Passion for ManufacturingA Passion for Manufacturing
A Passion for Manufacturing
Webseology
 
Apparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
ApparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewofApparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
Apparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
NIFT
 
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
Trevor O'Malley
 
P l e a s e n o t e t h a t g ra y a re a s re f l e c t .docx
P l e a s e  n o t e  t h a t  g ra y  a re a s  re f l e c t .docxP l e a s e  n o t e  t h a t  g ra y  a re a s  re f l e c t .docx
P l e a s e n o t e t h a t g ra y a re a s re f l e c t .docx
aman341480
 

Similar to (Klepper 1996) steven klepper, “entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the (20)

Trends in Advanced Manufacturing
Trends in Advanced ManufacturingTrends in Advanced Manufacturing
Trends in Advanced Manufacturing
 
Lean manufacturimg system
Lean manufacturimg systemLean manufacturimg system
Lean manufacturimg system
 
The context of strategic hrm
The context of strategic hrmThe context of strategic hrm
The context of strategic hrm
 
America’s Real Manufacturing Advantage
America’s Real Manufacturing AdvantageAmerica’s Real Manufacturing Advantage
America’s Real Manufacturing Advantage
 
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
4. suarez & utterbach james dominant_designs.
 
Conjoint analysis a perfect link between
Conjoint analysis  a perfect link betweenConjoint analysis  a perfect link between
Conjoint analysis a perfect link between
 
Conjoint analysis a perfect link between
Conjoint analysis  a perfect link betweenConjoint analysis  a perfect link between
Conjoint analysis a perfect link between
 
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical 2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
 
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical 2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
 
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical 2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses  in ethiopian chemical
2015 lean phlosophy for global competitivenses in ethiopian chemical
 
Crystal ball of Manufacturing
Crystal ball of ManufacturingCrystal ball of Manufacturing
Crystal ball of Manufacturing
 
A Passion for Manufacturing
A Passion for ManufacturingA Passion for Manufacturing
A Passion for Manufacturing
 
Reconfiguration of supply_chain_at_volkswagen_group_to_develop_global
Reconfiguration of supply_chain_at_volkswagen_group_to_develop_globalReconfiguration of supply_chain_at_volkswagen_group_to_develop_global
Reconfiguration of supply_chain_at_volkswagen_group_to_develop_global
 
Apparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
ApparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewofApparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
Apparelproductdevelopmentanoverviewof
 
Future of manufacturing_driving_capabilities
Future of manufacturing_driving_capabilitiesFuture of manufacturing_driving_capabilities
Future of manufacturing_driving_capabilities
 
A comparative study of apqp and contemporary product design and devlopement s...
A comparative study of apqp and contemporary product design and devlopement s...A comparative study of apqp and contemporary product design and devlopement s...
A comparative study of apqp and contemporary product design and devlopement s...
 
A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF APQP AND CONTEMPORARY PRODUCT DESIGN AND DEVELOPMENT S...
A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF APQP AND CONTEMPORARY PRODUCT DESIGN AND DEVELOPMENT S...A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF APQP AND CONTEMPORARY PRODUCT DESIGN AND DEVELOPMENT S...
A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF APQP AND CONTEMPORARY PRODUCT DESIGN AND DEVELOPMENT S...
 
Advanced Manufacturing Systems: A Review
Advanced Manufacturing Systems: A Review Advanced Manufacturing Systems: A Review
Advanced Manufacturing Systems: A Review
 
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
Article Fluid Power Journal 2015
 
P l e a s e n o t e t h a t g ra y a re a s re f l e c t .docx
P l e a s e  n o t e  t h a t  g ra y  a re a s  re f l e c t .docxP l e a s e  n o t e  t h a t  g ra y  a re a s  re f l e c t .docx
P l e a s e n o t e t h a t g ra y a re a s re f l e c t .docx
 

More from Adam Higdon

More from Adam Higdon (9)

Case study ancestry.com
Case study   ancestry.comCase study   ancestry.com
Case study ancestry.com
 
Optimizing to maximum profit
Optimizing to maximum profitOptimizing to maximum profit
Optimizing to maximum profit
 
The most innovative guys in the room don't always win
The most innovative guys in the room don't always winThe most innovative guys in the room don't always win
The most innovative guys in the room don't always win
 
Harvard Corporate Finance Syllabus
Harvard Corporate Finance SyllabusHarvard Corporate Finance Syllabus
Harvard Corporate Finance Syllabus
 
Harvard edX Fundamentals of Neuroscience
Harvard edX Fundamentals of Neuroscience Harvard edX Fundamentals of Neuroscience
Harvard edX Fundamentals of Neuroscience
 
Angie's List success story!
Angie's List success story!Angie's List success story!
Angie's List success story!
 
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
(Akerlof 2003) george a. akerlof, “writing the ‘the market for 'lemons’
 
Adam Higdon Neuroalgorithmicmedia how algorithmic bidding in paid search mi...
Adam Higdon Neuroalgorithmicmedia   how algorithmic bidding in paid search mi...Adam Higdon Neuroalgorithmicmedia   how algorithmic bidding in paid search mi...
Adam Higdon Neuroalgorithmicmedia how algorithmic bidding in paid search mi...
 
The most innovative guys in the room don't always win
The most innovative guys in the room don't always winThe most innovative guys in the room don't always win
The most innovative guys in the room don't always win
 

Recently uploaded

Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
Klinik kandungan
 
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get CytotecAbortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
Abortion pills in Riyadh +966572737505 get cytotec
 
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFHAPPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
geloencina777
 

Recently uploaded (20)

GIFT City Overview India's Gateway to Global Finance
GIFT City Overview  India's Gateway to Global FinanceGIFT City Overview  India's Gateway to Global Finance
GIFT City Overview India's Gateway to Global Finance
 
Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
Jual obat aborsi Jogja ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugur kand...
 
fundamentals of corporate finance 11th canadian edition test bank.docx
fundamentals of corporate finance 11th canadian edition test bank.docxfundamentals of corporate finance 11th canadian edition test bank.docx
fundamentals of corporate finance 11th canadian edition test bank.docx
 
The Pfandbrief Roundtable 2024 - Covered Bonds
The Pfandbrief Roundtable 2024 - Covered BondsThe Pfandbrief Roundtable 2024 - Covered Bonds
The Pfandbrief Roundtable 2024 - Covered Bonds
 
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
 
Famous Kala Jadu, Black magic expert in Oman Or Kala ilam expert in Kuwait
Famous Kala Jadu, Black magic expert in Oman Or Kala ilam expert in KuwaitFamous Kala Jadu, Black magic expert in Oman Or Kala ilam expert in Kuwait
Famous Kala Jadu, Black magic expert in Oman Or Kala ilam expert in Kuwait
 
Famous Kala Jadu, Kala ilam specialist in USA and Bangali Amil baba in Saudi ...
Famous Kala Jadu, Kala ilam specialist in USA and Bangali Amil baba in Saudi ...Famous Kala Jadu, Kala ilam specialist in USA and Bangali Amil baba in Saudi ...
Famous Kala Jadu, Kala ilam specialist in USA and Bangali Amil baba in Saudi ...
 
Kala jadu specialist in USA (Kala ilam expert in france) Black magic expert i...
Kala jadu specialist in USA (Kala ilam expert in france) Black magic expert i...Kala jadu specialist in USA (Kala ilam expert in france) Black magic expert i...
Kala jadu specialist in USA (Kala ilam expert in france) Black magic expert i...
 
DIGITAL COMMERCE SHAPE VIETNAMESE SHOPPING HABIT IN 4.0 INDUSTRY
DIGITAL COMMERCE SHAPE VIETNAMESE SHOPPING HABIT IN 4.0 INDUSTRYDIGITAL COMMERCE SHAPE VIETNAMESE SHOPPING HABIT IN 4.0 INDUSTRY
DIGITAL COMMERCE SHAPE VIETNAMESE SHOPPING HABIT IN 4.0 INDUSTRY
 
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get CytotecAbortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
Abortion pills in Dammam Saudi Arabia | +966572737505 |Get Cytotec
 
Collecting banker, Capacity of collecting Banker, conditions under section 13...
Collecting banker, Capacity of collecting Banker, conditions under section 13...Collecting banker, Capacity of collecting Banker, conditions under section 13...
Collecting banker, Capacity of collecting Banker, conditions under section 13...
 
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFHAPPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
APPLIED ECONOMICS Sept 9FGHFGHFHGFGHFHGFHGFH
 
劳伦森大学毕业证
劳伦森大学毕业证劳伦森大学毕业证
劳伦森大学毕业证
 
20240419-SMC-submission-Annual-Superannuation-Performance-Test-–-design-optio...
20240419-SMC-submission-Annual-Superannuation-Performance-Test-–-design-optio...20240419-SMC-submission-Annual-Superannuation-Performance-Test-–-design-optio...
20240419-SMC-submission-Annual-Superannuation-Performance-Test-–-design-optio...
 
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
Certified Kala Jadu, Black magic specialist in Rawalpindi and Bangali Amil ba...
 
20240514-Calibre-Q1-2024-Conference-Call-Presentation.pdf
20240514-Calibre-Q1-2024-Conference-Call-Presentation.pdf20240514-Calibre-Q1-2024-Conference-Call-Presentation.pdf
20240514-Calibre-Q1-2024-Conference-Call-Presentation.pdf
 
Pension dashboards forum 1 May 2024 (1).pdf
Pension dashboards forum 1 May 2024 (1).pdfPension dashboards forum 1 May 2024 (1).pdf
Pension dashboards forum 1 May 2024 (1).pdf
 
MalaysianStates_AnalysisGDPandInvestment_web (1).pdf
MalaysianStates_AnalysisGDPandInvestment_web (1).pdfMalaysianStates_AnalysisGDPandInvestment_web (1).pdf
MalaysianStates_AnalysisGDPandInvestment_web (1).pdf
 
najoomi asli amil baba kala jadu expert rawalpindi bangladesh uk usa
najoomi asli amil baba kala jadu expert rawalpindi bangladesh uk usanajoomi asli amil baba kala jadu expert rawalpindi bangladesh uk usa
najoomi asli amil baba kala jadu expert rawalpindi bangladesh uk usa
 
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate PresentationStrategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
 

(Klepper 1996) steven klepper, “entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the

  • 1. American Economic Association Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle Author(s): Steven Klepper Reviewed work(s): Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 3 (Jun., 1996), pp. 562-583 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118212 . Accessed: 09/10/2012 08:02 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review. http://www.jstor.org
  • 2. Entry,Exit,Growth,and Innovationover the ProductLifeCycle By STEVEN KLEPPER* Regularities concerning how entry, exit, marketstructure, and innovation vary from the birth of technologically progressive industries through maturity are summarized.A model emphasizingdifferences infirm innovativecapabilities and the importance of firm size in appropriating the returnsfrom innovation is de- veloped to explain the regularities. Themodel also explains regularities regard- ing the relationshipwithinindustriesbetweenfirm size andfirm innovativeeffort, innovative productivity, cost, and profitability. It predicts that over timefirms devote more effort to process innovation but the number of firms and the rate and diversity of product innovationeventually wither. (JEL L10) A similarviewhasemergedfromanumber of disciplinaryperspectivesabouthow tech- nologicallyprogressiveindustriesevolvefrom birththroughmaturity.'Whenindustriesare new,thereis a lot of entry,firns offermany differentversionsof the industry'sproduct, therateofproductinnovationishigh,andmar- ket shareschangerapidly.Despitecontinued marketgrowth,subsequentlyentryslows,exit overtakesentryandthereis a shakeoutin the numberof producers,therateof productin- novationandthe diversityof competingver- sionsof theproductdecline,increasingeffort is devotedto improvingthe productionpro- cess, and marketshares stabilize.In some quarters,thisevolutionarypatternhascometo be knownas theproductlife cycle (PLC). Whilenumerousauthorshavecontributedto this description,perhapsthe mostinfluential havebeenWilliamJ.AbernathyandJamesM. Utterback.2Buildingontheworkof DennisC. MuellerandJohnE. Tilton(1969) andusing the automobileindustryas a leading case, theydepictthePLCasdrivenbythewaynew technologiesevolve. Theystressthatwhena productis introduced,thereisconsiderableun- certaintyaboutuserpreferences(even among the usersthemselves)and the technological meansof satisfyingthem.As a result,many firmsproducingdifferentvariantsof theprod- uctenterthemarketandcompetitionfocuses on productinnovation.As usersexperiment withthealternativeversionsoftheproductand producerslearn abouthow to improvethe product,opportunitiesto improvetheproduct aredepletedanda defactoproductstandard, dubbeda dominantdesign,emerges.Produc-' ers who areunableto produceefficientlythe dominantdesignexit,contributingto a shake- outinthenumberof producers.Thedepletion of opportunitiesto improvethe productcou- pled with locked-inof the dominantdesign leadstoadecreaseinproductinnovation.This in turnreducesproducers'fearsthatinvest- mentsin the productionprocesswill be ren- deredobsoleteby technologicalchangein the * Department of Social and Decision Sciences, Car- negie Mellon University, Pittsburgh,PA 15213. I thank Wesley Cohen, Mark Kamlet, Jon Leland, John Miller, RichardNelson, Ken Simons, PeterSwann,Bill Williams, and participantsat the 1992 Conference of the Interna- tionalJosephA. SchumpeterSociety, the 1992Conference on MarketProcesses andthe Dynamics of CorporateNet- works, WissenschaftszentrumBerlin, and the Industrial Organization Seminars at the University of Maryland, Berkeley, Penn State,andthe LondonSchool of Econom- ics for helpfulcomments.Thepaperwas greatlyimproved by the unstintingsuggestions of two anonymousreferees and the co-editor, PrestonMcAfee. 'See, for example, Oliver E. Williamson's (1975) ac- count of how economists depict the evolution of new in- dustries, Kim B. Clark's (1985) description of how technology andinternalfirmorganizationchange over the course of industryevolution, andhow a business consult- ant, Philip G. Drew (1987), describes the way business schools depict the evolution of industries. 2 See in particularJames M. Utterbackand William J. Abernathy(1975) and AbernathyandUtterback(1978). 562
  • 3. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 563 product.Consequently,theyincreasetheirat- tentionto the productionprocessandinvest morein capital-intensivemethodsof produc- tion,whichreinforcestheshakeoutof produc- ers by increasingthe minimumefficientsize firm. Whilethisviewhashelpedtopopularizethe PLC,itrestscriticallyonthenotionof adom- inantdesign,an impreciseconceptthatdoes not appearto applyto all new products,es- peciallyones for whichbuyertastesare di- verse(MichaelE.Porter,1983).Furthermore, itincorporatessomequestionableassumptions abouttechnologicalchange.It assumesthat productandprocessinnovationareinextrica- blylinkedandthatfirmswill notattendto the productionprocess until productinnovation hasslowedsufficiently.Yetthehistoryof the automobileindustryandothers,suchas tires andantibiotics,indicatesthatgreatimprove- mentswere madein the productionprocess wellbeforetheemergenceofanykindofdom- inant design (S. Klepperand KennethL. Simons, 1993). Indeed,many of these im- provementswerebasedon humanandphysi- cal investments that were not rendered obsoleteby subsequentmajorproductinno- vations.Thedominant-designview also min- imizes the influenceof industrydemandon incentivesto innovate,attributingthe slow- downinproductinnovationandriseinprocess innovationentirelyto thedepletionof oppor- tunitiesforproductinnovationandthe emer- genceof adominantdesign.Whiletherelative importanceof demandandsupplyfactorshas been hotly debated(David C. Moweryand NathanRosenberg,1982), it has neverbeen questionedthatdemandfactorsplay an im- portantrolein shapingthe rateanddirection of technologicalchange. Thispaperproposesa new explanationfor thePLC.Empiricalregularitiescharacterizing thePLCarefirstidentified.A formalmodelis then constructedto explainthe regularities. Themodelbuildson recenttheoriesof indus- tryevolution(RichardR. NelsonandSidney G.Winter,1982;BoyanJovanovic,1982)and effortstomodelthelinkbetweenmarketstruc- ture and R&D (Nelson and Winter, 1978; ParthaDasguptaand JosephStiglitz, 1980; ThereseM. Flaherty,1980). The modelfo- cuseson theroleof firminnovativecapabili- ties and size in conditioningfirm R&D spending,innovation,and marketstructure. Followingvarioustheoreticalmodelsof asym- metric industrystructure(Flaherty;Avner ShakedandJohnSutton,1987), it incorpo- ratesthe notionthatthe valueof a unitcost reductionachievedthroughinnovationis pro- portionalto the level of outputproducedby the firm. Coupledwith convex adjustment costs,thisimpartsanadvantageto theearliest entrantswhicheventuallycausesa cessation in entryanda shakeoutin thenumberof pro- ducers.It also providesfirmswith a greater incentiveto engagein processinnovationas they grow, which leads to an increaseover timeintheireffortstoimprovetheproduction process.Firnsarealsoassumedtohavedifferent capabilitiesthatleadthemto pursuedifferent typesof productinnovations,athemepromoted by Nelson (1981) and used by Wesley M. CohenandKlepper(1992) to explaindiffer- enceswithinindustriesinfirmR&Dintensities. Thisprovidesthebasisforexplainingthedecline inproductinnovationthatoccursovertime,link- ingittothedeclineinthenumberofcompetitors broughtaboutby theshakeoutof producers.It is shownthatthemodelcanalsoexplainvarious cross-sectionalregularitiesthathave accumu- latedconcerningtherelationshipwithinindus- triesbetweenfirmsize andfirmR&Deffort, R&Dproductivity,cost,andprofitability.Thus, themodelprovidesa unifiedexplanationfora widerangeof temporalandcross-sectionalreg- ularitiesconcerningindustryevolutionandfinn behavior. Thepaperis organizedas follows.In Sec- tionI, theprominentfeaturesof thePLCare summarized.InSectionII,themodelis spec- ified.In SectionIII,preliminaryimplications of themodelaredeveloped.InSectionIV,the modelis shownto explainall the prominent featuresof thePLC.In SectionV, themodel is usedto explainvariouscross-sectionalreg- ularitiesbetweenfirm size, R&D, and firm performance.In SectionVI, the implications of themodelarediscussedandextensionsof themodelareconsidered. I. TheNatureof theProductLifeCycle The depictionof industryevolutioncon- veyedin thePLCis baseduponcase studies
  • 4. 564 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 andquantitativeanalysesof the evolutionof newindustries.Inthissection,six regularities concerninghow entry,exit, marketstructure, andtechnologicalchangevaryfromthebirthof technologicallyprogressiveindustriesthrough maturityaresummarized.Whileeveryitidustry hasitsidiosyncrasies,theseregularitiesprovide a compositepictureof theevolutionof techno- logicallyprogressiveindustries. Thefirsttworegularitiespertaintoentryand exit. MichaelGortand Klepper(1982) and KlepperandElizabethGraddy(1990) exam- inetheannualtimepathinthenumberof pro- ducersfor 46 majornew productsbeginning with their commercialinception.Utterback andFernandoF. Suarez(1993) alsoconsider the timepathin the numberof producersas wellasthepathsinthenumberof entrantsand exits for 8 productssubjectto considerable technologicalchange. Klepperand Simons (1993) reviewthe entryandexit pathsfor 2 of the productsstudied by Utterbackand Suarezand2 otherproductssubjecttoconsid- erabletechnological change. Two patterns emergefromthesestudiesconcerningthena- tureof industryevolutionin technologically progressiveindustries: At thebeginningof theindustry,thenumber of entrantsmayriseovertimeorit mayat- taina peakat the startof the industryand then declineover time, but in both cases thenumberof entrantseventuallybecomes small. Thenumberof producersgrowsinitiallyand thenreachesa peak,afterwhichit declines steadilydespitecontinuedgrowthin indus- tryoutput.3 EntrantsAccountfor MarketSharesof LargestFitmsStabilize--_ DisproportionateAmount of ProductInnovation ProductR&D overtime ProcessR&D overtimc E Rut = > pathI Entrypath2 Numberofproducers 0 Time FIGURE 1. TEMPORAL PATTERNS OF ENTRY, NUMBER OF PRODUCERS, MARKET SHARES, AND INNOVATION These patternsare illustratedin Figure1. Two alternativepathsfor entryaredepicted. Inbothcases,entryeventuallybecomessmall andthenumberof firmsrisesinitiallyandthen declinesovertime.Relatedto thesetwo pat- ternsareregularitiesin the way firmmarket shareschangeover time. Althoughmarket- sharedataoveranextendedtimeperiodarenot availableformanyproducts,EdwinMansfield (1962) and Burton H. Klein (1977 pp. 89- 128) have examined how the marketsharesof the leadingproducersof automobiles,tires, aircraft,petroleum,and steel changedover time.Theirfindings,whichaccordwithanum- berof case studies,suggesta thirdregularity whichis notedin Figure1: Eventuallythe rateof changeof the market sharesof thelargestfirmsdeclinesandthe leadershipof theindustrystabilizes. The otherthreeregularitiesaboutthe PLC pertaintotechnologicalchange.Becausetech- nologicalchangeis moredifficultto quantify, theregularitiesarebasedon a numberof case studies4andtwo samplesof innovationsfora 'These are general tendencies, and exceptions can al- ways be found. Of greater significance is the possibility thatthese patternsreflect a bias in the way new products are typically defined. If these patterns tend to be inter- ruptedby major innovations but the innovations are de- finedascreatingnew productssubjectto theirown product life cycles, the patternscould be artifactual.The bulk of the new productsthathave been studied,however, did not experience such majorinnovations until many years after they were introduced,and their evolution was generally characterized by long initial periods during which the characteristicpatternsin entry and the number of firms were observed. 'These include Abernathy(1978) andAbernathyet al. (1983) for automobiles, Klein (1977) for automobilesand aircraft,Tilton (1971) and Jerome Kraus(1973) for tran- sistors, Kenneth Flamm (1988) and Philip Anderson and Michael J. Tushman (1990) for computers, Arthur A. Bright (1949) and James R. Bright (1958) for light bulbs, Thomas J. Prusaand James A. Schmitz (1991) for PC software, and Abernathy and Utterback (1978) and Utterbackand Suarez (1993) for collections of products. For furtherdetail, see Klepper(1992).
  • 5. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 565 limited number of industries in the United States (Utterback and Abernathy, 1975) and the United Kingdom (C. De Bresson and J. Townsend, 1981). These studies suggest that for industrieswith rich opportunitiesfor both product and process R&D, three patterns in productand process innovation can be identi- fied:5 The diversity of competing versions of the product and the number of major product innovations tend to reach a peak duringthe growthin the numberof producersandthen fall over time. Over time, producersdevote increasing effort to process relative to productinnovation. During the period of growth in the numberof producers,the most recent entrantsaccount for a disproportionate share of product innovations. These three regularities are also noted in Figure 1. Together,the six regularitieslaid out above andsummarizedin Figure 1providethe focus for the theoreticalanalysis of the paper. II. TheModel The model depicts the evolution from birth throughmaturityof an industrywith rich op- portunitiesfor productandprocess innovation. Two aspects of innovation are featured.First, following Jacob Schmookler (1966) and a number of theoretical models (for example, DasguptaandStiglitz,1980;ShakedandSutton, 1987), the demand for a firm's productis as- sumed to condition its incentive to innovate. This is assumed to be manifested differently for process and product innovation. Process innovation is principally designed to lower a firm's average cost of production. Since the value of a reductionin averagecost is propor- tional to the total outputof the firm, it is as- sumedthatthe incentiveforprocessinnovation is conditioned by the total quantitydemanded of the firm's product.Productinnovations, in contrast,areoften designed to attractnew buy- ers for a product. Accordingly, it is assumed that the incentive for product innovation is conditioned by the demand of new buyers. Second, firmsareassumedto be randomlyen- dowed with distinctive capabilities which in- fluence the kinds of innovationsthey develop. The idea of distinctive firm competencies lies at the heatt of the business-strategy literature (Porter, 1980) andits relevancefor innovation appears prominently in many industry case studies.6It is assumedthatthese differences in capabilitiesmanifest themselves principallyin product innovations, where firms often spe- cialize in innovations that service distinctive types of users (Eric von Hippel, 1988). In contrast,process innovations tend to be incre- mental and based on information that firms commonly generatethroughproduction(com- pare Bright, 1958; Samuel Hollander, 1965). The model is stylized to highlight the two featured aspects of innovation. It has the fol- lowing structure. Time is discrete. In each period, incumbent firms decide whether to ' The threepatternsare ascribedonly to productswith richopportunitiesforboth productandprocess innovation because the bulk of the products for which patterns in innovation have been studied are, not surprisingly,ones with such characteristics.Indeed,Abernathy(1978 p. 84), K. Pavitt and R. Rothwell (1976), and Porter (1983 pp. 23-24), among others,contendthatproductswithoutrich opportunitiesfor both productand process innovation do not follow the prototypical PLC. Examples cited as ex- ceptions to the PLC include synthetic fibers and plastics, which are claimed to be relatively homogeneous and pri- marily subjectto process but not productinnovation, and heavy electrical equipment, which is produced in small batches and is claimed to be subject primarilyto product and not process innovation. While no evidence is pre- sented to buttressthese claims and not all observers sub- scribe to them (for example, see David A. Hounshell [1988] regardingsynthetic fibers), it is importantto rec- ognize that the evidence regardinginnovation during the PLCis primarilybasedon productswithrichopportunities for both productandprocess innovation.This is reflected in the model, which presupposes that the joint natureof productand process innovationdrives the PLC. 6Forexample, a numberof studiesemphasize how sig- nificant innovations can be traced back to expertise ac- quiredfortuitously.This is featuredin HughG. J.Aitken's (1985) analysis of early radio innovations, Flamm's (1988) discussion of the influence of government spon- sored cryptographyefforts during World War II on sub- sequent innovationby computerfirms, and Klein's (1977 pp. 89-109) discussion of the skills brought into the automobile industry at the 'turnof the century by entre- preneurs with experience in mass production and inter- changeable partsmanufacture.
  • 6. 566 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 remainin the industryanda limited numberof potential entrantsdecide whetherto enter.All firmsproducea standardproduct.They decide how muchprocess R&D to perform,which de- terminesthe averagecost of the standardprod- uct. They also decide how muchproductR&D to perform. Firms randomly differ in their productinnovationexpertise,which influences their success at productR&D. In each period, successful product innovators develop a dis- tinctive product innovation which they com- bine with the standardproduct to market a unique, distinctive product. Distinctive prod- ucts appealto all buyers, but only new buyers pay the premiumsfor them, with each distinc- tive product sold to a different class of new buyers. All firms monitor the product inno- vations of their rivals. This enables them to imitateallproductinnovationsone periodafter they areintroducedand incorporatethem into the standardproductat no additionalproduc- tion cost. When the last period's product in- novations are incorporatedinto the standard product,buyers of the distinctive productsbe- come buyers of the standardproduct and the demand for the standardproductby all other buyers increases, causing the demand curve for the standardproduct to shift to the right. Producers share in the expansion in demand for the standardproductin proportionto their prior output and decide how much furtherto expand their output subject to a cost of ad- justment. All decisions are made to maximize currentprofits, firms are price takers, and in each period the price of the standardproduct clears the market. The model is formally specified as follows. Ineachperiodt, thereareK,potentialentrants. As firms enter and others randomly develop the innovative capabilitiesrequiredto enter,K, changes. A priorino restrictionsareplaced on whether K, rises or falls over time; this may differ across industriesand also within indus- tries over time. Each potential entrantis ran- domly endowed with innovative expertise which it cannot modify over time. Let si de- note the innovation expertise of firm i, which it knows priorto entry, andsmax the maximum possible innovationexpertise. To simplify the dynamics of the model, it is assumed that in each period there are one or more potential entrantswith innovative expertise Smaxandthe cumulativedistributionof innovativeexpertise is the same for the potential entrantsin each period. This distributionis denoted as H(s), where H(s) is assumed to be continuous for all s < smaxand H(Smax)= 1by definition. The firm's innovative expertise influences its success atproductR&D. The probabilityof firm i developing a productinnovation in pe- riod t is si + g (rdi,), where rdi,is its spending on product R&D and the function g(rdi,) re- flects the opportunitiesfor productinnovation. Each successful innovatoradds its innovation to the standardproductand marketsa distinc- tive variantof the industry'sproduct,which it sells at a price exceeding the price of the stan- dardproduct,reflecting the value of its inno- vation. Distinctive variants are assumed to appealto all buyersbut only new buyers have a positive demand for them at the prices charged, with each distinctive variant pur- chased by a differentclass of new buyers. Af- ter one period, all product innovations are copied and incorporated into the standard product,so successful innovatorshave a one- periodmonopolyovertheirdistinctivevariants. Let G denote the one-period gross monopoly profit(before subtractingthe amountspent on productR&D) earnedby each seller of a dis- tinctivevariant.It is assumedthatg' (rdi) > 0 and g"(rdit) < 0 for all rdit 2 0, reflecting diminishing returns, and that g'(0)G > 1, which ensures rdit> 0 for all i, t. In orderto be able to imitatecostlessly the innovationsof its rivals, which is requiredto market a dis- tinctive productvariantand also the standard product,firmsmonitorthe innovationsof their rivals at a cost of F per period. Thus, if a firm engaged in only product innovation and did not producethe standardproduct,its expected profitsin period t would be [si + g(rdit)] G - rdit- F. To simplify the model, it is assumed thatF > [si + g(rdit)] G - rditfor all rdit.This ensures that in orderto have nonnegative ex- pected profits,all firmsmustproducethe stan- dardproduct. Let Qt = f(pt) denote the total marketde- mand for the standardproduct in period t, where Qt is the quantity demanded,Pt is the price of the standardproduct,andft(pt) is the market demand schedule for the standard productin period t. Over time,f (pt) shifts to the rightat every price as last period's product
  • 7. VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 567 innovations are incorporatedinto the standard product.It is assumed thatfi(p,) is continuous anddownwardsloping for all t. Let Qitdenote the outputof the standardproductby firmi in periodt. Itis determinedas follows. Assuming thatPt falls over time (this will be shown in thenext section), the totalquantitydemanded, Qt, expands over time. All firmssell the same standardproductat the same price. New buy- ers are assumed to choose a seller based on a stochastic learningprocess in which the prob- ability of a firmattractinga new buyeris pro- portionalto its sales of the standardproductin thepriorperiod,Qit - I. Itis assumedthatit is optimal for a buyer to continue purchasing fromthe same firmas long as the firmremains in the market.Accordingly, it is assumed that incumbents in period t experience a rise in their sales of the standardproductfrom Qit- I in period t - Ito Qit- I(Qt/Qt- I) in period t, where Qt/Qt - l denotes the growthin the total quantity demanded of the standard product fromperiod t - 1 to t. If desired, the firmcan expand its output further,resulting in an in- crease in its marketshareof the standardprod- uct relative to period t - 1. To do so, it must incur an adjustmentcost of m(Aqit), where Aqitis the expansion in its outputin period t above Qit- I(Qt/Qt- ). The function m(Lqit) is such thatm'(0) = 0, m'(Aqit) > 0 for all zqit > 0, and m"(Aqit) > 0 for all Aqit ' 0, with m' (Aqit) growing without bound as Aqit increases, reflecting increasing marginal ad- justment costs.7 The average cost of productionof the stan- dardproductfor firmi is assumed to be inde- pendent of Qit and equal to c - l(rcit), where rcitis the amount spent on process R&D by firm i in period t and the function l(rcit) re- flects the opportunitiesfor process innovation. Following Flaherty(1980), cost in period t is a function only of process R&D in period t. It is assumedthatas rcitincreases, l(rcit) asymp- totically approaches an upper bound and l'(rcit) > 0 and l"(rcit) < 0 for all rcit 2 0, reflectingdiminishingreturns.Further,it is as- sumed that 1'(0)QQm1,i> 1, where Qmninis the smallest level of outputever producedby any firm.This ensures rcit> 0 for all i, t. Given the assumptions, the expected profit of firmi in period t, E(IIit), can be expressed as (1) E(Hit) = [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit + [Qit_I(Qt/ Qt-l) + Aqit] X [Pt - c + I(rcit)] - rcit- m(Aqit) - F, where [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit is the firm's expected net profit from product R&D after subtracting the cost of its product R&D, I[Qit-l(QtlQt_l + Aqit [pt - c + l(rcit)I- rcit- m(Aqit)is its netprofitfromproducing thestandardproductaftersubtractingbothits spendingonprocessR&Dandthecostsof ad- justingits output,andF is the cost of moni- toringtheinnovationsof itsrivals.Expression (1) appliesto entrantsin periodt as well as incumbents,with Qit- = 0 for entrants.All firmsare assumedto be atomisticandprice takers.In each periodt they can projectthe market-clearingpriceforthestandardproduct, Pt,butareuncertainaboutfuturepricesandthus theirprospectsfor survival.Accordingly,it is assumedtheydecidewhetherto be in the in- dustryandif so,rdit,rcit,andAqit,tomaximize currentexpected profits,E(nit). Let rdi,t, rc*, and Aq* denote the profit-maximizing choices of rdit,rci,, and qit and E(HI*t) the expectedprofitsof the firmat thesechoices. Potentialentrantsenterif E(n*) > 0, arein- differentaboutenteringif E(HI*t) = 0, anddo not enter if E(HI*) < 0, where Aqit defines theirinitialoutputof the standardproductif they enter.Similarly,incumbentsstayin the industryif E(Hll*)> 0, areindifferentabout stayingin if E(HI) =0, andexit if E(HI*) < 0. Onceincumbentsexit, theiroutputof the standardproductis lost. Theindustryis assumedto startin period1 whendemandandtechnologyfortheproduct are such that there exists a price pi for which the quantitysuppliedby firms with 7If a firmwantsto expand its marketshare,it will nor- mally have to incur marketingcosts to attractcustomers from its rivals. The assumptionthatm"(Aqi,)> 0 reflects the idea thatthe morethe finn wantsto increaseits market sharein any given period, the greaterthe marketingcosts requiredfor expansion at the margin.
  • 8. 568 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 nonnegative expected profitsequals the quan- tity demanded, Ql, where Q, > 0. Similarly, in every subsequent period p, is assumed to clear the market.This requiresthat the quan- tity demandedin period t, Q, = f,(p,), equals the quantitysupplied by producersin period t takingp, as given: (2) Q,= , {Qit-I(Qt/Qt-1) + /qit}, i,t where the index i, t of the summationdenotes thatthe summationis over firmsi in themarket in period t. In terms of the actualmechanism governing the change in price fromperiod t - I to t, thedynamicsof themodel aresimplified by assuming that for all incumbent firms in period t, dE(H1*)/dp, > 0 for all prices pt within a broad neighborhood of pt 8 with the equilibriumprice constrainedto lie in this broad neighborhood.The existence of such a price in each period satisfying equation(2) is demonstratedin the next section. As will be shown, market clearing is achieved through the effects of pt on Qt, Aqit, and on entryand exit in period t.9 Themodelis stylizedtokeepittractableand tohighlightthetwokeyfeaturesof innovation thatunderlieit. Productinnovationsare as- sumedto be introducedinto distinctivever- sionsof theproductandthenincorporatedinto the productsof all firms,whichconformsto the way manyproductsevolve over time.'0 This preservesthe notionof an industryin which all firms producethe same product while allowingfor (limited) productdiffer- entiation.Eachproductinnovationis assumed tobe soldto adifferentclassof newbuyersto reflecttheideathatfirmshavedifferentkinds of innovativeexpertisethatleadthemto ser- vice differentgroupsof buyers.Coupledwith theassumptionthatproductinnovationsdonot affect the demandfor the standardproduct, this ensuresthatthe incentiveto engage in productinnovationis determinedsolelybythe demandof new buyers."Differencesin firm innovativeabilitiesarestructuredso thatthey do notaffectthefirm'soutputof thestandard productnorthe amountspenton productor processR&D.Consequently,thefirm'soutput of thestandardproductis relatedto thefirm's R&Dspendingonlythroughits effectson the returnsfromprocessR&D,whichhighlights the influenceof the demandfor the standard productonprocessR&D.Opportunitiesforin- novation,as reflectedin thefunctionsg(rdi,) andl(rci,), are assumedconstantto abstract fromtheeffectsof changingtechnologicalop- portunitieson the firm'sR&Dspending.All decisionsarebasedoncurrentexpectedprofits andprocessinnovationsarenotcumulativeto simplifythe dynamicsof the model and to reflectthelimitedhorizonsof firmsinnewin- dustries.Manyof these assumptionsarere- consideredin the conclusion, where it is arguedthatthe spiritandprincipalimplica- tions of the model wouldnot changeif the assumptionswererelaxed. 8Thisconditionrequiresthatineachperiodt,thelower p, thenthelowerthemaximumpossibleexpectedprofits of eachfirm,assumingthefirmcan sell as muchof the standardproductasitwantsatp,.Thepriceofthestandard productaffectsE(r,*) in twoways:throughitseffecton theprofitperunitof thestandardproduct,p, - c + l(rci,), andthroughitseffectoneachfirm'soutputofthestandard productvia thetotalquantitydemandedof the standard product,Qt.Thesetwo effects workin oppositedirec- tions-the lowerpt thenthe lowerthe firm'sprofitper unit on the standardproduct,ceterisparibus,but the greaterthefirm'stotaloutputofthestandardproduct,cet- erisparibus.Giventhatl(rcj,)is bounded,at sufficiently low pricesE(rlH*)mustbe less thanzero for all firms, henceatsufficientlylowpricesthefirsteffectmustdom- inatethesecondanddE(rI,*)dpt> 0. Ifdft(pt)ldpt= 0 at therelevantprices(thatis, thepriceelasticityof demand equaledzero),thenptwouldhaveno effecton thefirm's outputof thestandardp,roductandit is easyto see from equation(1)thatdE(Hlit)ldpt> 0 forallprices.Moregen- erally,if suitableconstraintsareplacedon the function dft(pt)ldptattherelevantpricesthendE(rH*)/dpt> 0 for allpriceswithina broadneighborhoodofpt 9 Notethatif exitoccursin periodt then1j, Qit-I < li, t- I Qit-I = Q,_ ,, where the index i, t - 1 denotes summationoverfirmsin themarketin periodt - 1. As developedin thenextsection,exit will be necessaryfor themarketto clearineachperiod. '?Forexample,inautomobilesinnovationssuchasthe electricstarterandtheinexpensiveclosedbodywerein- troducedintodistinctivemodelsandthencopiedwidely byallmanufacturers. " Thisabstractsfromstrategicincentivesto innovate associatedwith the preemptionof rivals (RichardJ. GilbertandDavidM.G.Newbery,1982)andcannibalism of priorinnovations(JenniferReinganum,1983,1985).
  • 9. VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 569 III. Preliminary Results In order to facilitate the proof of later re- sults, a series of intermediateimplications of the model are developed as lemmas. In deriv- ing these lemmas, it is assumed thatthere ex- ists a price p, in each period that clears the marketgiven the choices firmsmake abouten- try, exit, rdi,,rci,, and Aqi, takingp, as given. The existence of such a pathfor price is estab- lished at the end of this section. The firstresults pertainto firmsin the mar- ket in periodt, including firmsthatenteredthe market during period t as well as earlier en- trants.Differentiating (1) with respect to rdi,, rci,, and Aqi, establishes the following first- orderconditions for an interiormaximum for each firmi in the marketin period t: (3) g'(rd1)G = 1 (4) [Qit- (Qt/Qt-i) + Aq*]l'(rc*) = 1 (5) m'(Aq*) = pt - c + l(rc *), where optimal values aredenoted by an aster- isk. Furthermore,for a firmto be in the market in periodt, its expected profitsin periodt must be nonnegative. Given the assumptionof F > [si + g(rdi,)]G - rdi, for all rdi,, a necessary condition for E(nit) 2 0 is thatfor each firm i in the marketin period t: (6) ~Pt- c + l(rcit)> Assuming -1"(rc*)[Qit-1(Qt/Qt-1) + Aq*] X m(Aq*) > lP(rc*)2 to ensure that the joint solutionof (4) and(5) forrc1,andAqi,is a max- imum, the solutionsto equations(3)- (6) will satisfy the second-order conditions. Conse- quently, for each firmi andperiod t, rd* > 0, rc* > 0, and Aq* > 0, with these choices satisfying equations (3) - (6). Thus, all firms in the marketin period t performproductand process R&D and increase their marketshare of the standardproductrelativeto periodt - 1. Conditions (3) -(6) imply two results which reflect the simplified nature of the model. LEMMA 1: For all i and t, rdi, = rd *, where rd* satisfies g'(rd *)G = 1. PROOF: The profit-maximizing value of rdi,is de- fined by equation (3), which is the same for all firmsand does not change over time. Con- sequently, all firms spend the same amount rd* on product R&D, where rd* satisfies (3). Analogous to E(fl *), letVi=V Qit- (Q Qt-1) + Aq*][p, - c + l(rc*)] - rci* m( Aq*) denote the firm's (incremental) profitfromthe standardproduct.Lemma 1im- plies that the firm's incrementalprofitearned from product R&D in each period, [si + g(rdi,)] G - rdi,,remains constant over time. Consequently, changes in the firm's expected profits over time arise only from changes in Vi*. Accordingly, most of the analysis of the model focuses on the standardproduct. The second result indicates thatin each pe- riod t, firms in each entry cohort make the same choices for rci, and Aqi, and have the same outputand incrementalprofits from the standardproduct. Letting the values of these variables for entry cohort k in period t be de- notedasrc', Aqk, Q,k,andV k, thefollowing result is established. LEMMA 2: For allfirms i thatenteredinpe- riod k and are still in the marketinperiod t > k, rci, = rck, Aqit* = AqkI Qi = Qk, and V = V t t PROOF: Since Qi - I = 0 for entrants in period t, equations (4) and (5) imply rc* and Aq , hence Qitand Vi*, must be the same for all entrantsin t. It then follows from (4) and (5) thatrc*, Aq*, Qit,and V * must be the same for these firmsin every period they are in the market. Lemmas 1 and 2 imply that in each period t the expected profits of firms that entered in the same period differ only accordingto their product-iniovationexpertisesi. Consequently, in each periodthe distributionof E(fli,) across firmsin the same entrycohortwill be the same as the distributionof si for these firms. The firm's outputin the priorperiod, Qit- I, will determine its choice of rci,and Aqi, and hence Vit.This is reflected in Lemma 3.
  • 10. 570 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 LEMMA 3: For each firm i in the marketin period t, the larger Qi -, then the larger rci,, Aqi,, and Vi. PROOF: Differentiating (3) -(5) with respect to Qit- 1andrearrangingyields drc * / dQi,_ - = g"(rd *) Gm"(Aq *)I P(rc*) x (Qt/ Qt_) / D dzAq*ldQi,_ I = g"(rd )Gl'(rci*)2 X(Qt/ Qt- ) / D dVi*/dQit- I= a3Vi*/ a3Qit-I = [p, - c + l(rci*t) ] (Qt / Qt- 1), where D is the determinantof the matrix of secondpartialsof E(ni,) withrespectto rdi,, rci,, and Aqi, evaluated at rd*, rc*, and Aq*. Since D < 0 based on the second-order conditions andp, - c + I(rc*) > 0 based on (6), each of these derivatives is positive. Therefore,thelargerQit- Ithenthe greaterrci,, Aqi,, and Vit. Since Aq* is determined by Qit- I and Aq* > 0 for all i, t, Lemmas 2 and 3 imply that in each period t the age of the firm fully determines rci,, Aqi,, Vi,, and Qit, with each greater the older the firm. Coupled with Lemma 1, this implies that in each period t differencesacrossfirmsinE(ni,)arefullyde- termined by two factors: the age of the firm and its productinnovation expertise si. Lemma 1 establishes the time pathof rdi,for each firmwhile Lemmas2 and3 establishhow rci,, Aqi,, Qit,and Vitvary across firmsin each period. It is also possible to investigate how rci,,Aqi,, Qit,and Vitchangeovertime for each firm.For incumbents, Qitand rci,change over time as follows. LEMMA 4: For each firm i in the marketin periods t - 1 and t, Qit > Qit- and rci, > rci, -l. PROOF: Since Aqi, > 0 for all i, t, it follows that Qit> Qit- Ifor all i, t. Rewritingequation(4) as Qi,l'(rc*) = 1, it follows from Qit> Qit- and l"(rci,) < 0 for all rci,thatrci,> rci,t- . The time paths for Aqi, and Vitfor incum- bents cannotbe so easily characterized.Equa- tion (5) indicatesthatfor each incumbentAqi, will change over time according to the time path of p, - c + I(rci,), the firm's profitper unit of the standardproduct.The change in Vit over time will also depend on the time pathin Pt - c + I(rci,). Lemma 4 implies that l(rci,) rises over time, but Lemma 5 below indicates p, falls over time. Consequently, without fur- ther assumptions it cannot be determined whetherAqi,and Vitgenerally rise or fall over time for incumbents. That pt must fall over time can be easily established. LEMMA 5: For each period t,pt < p.- I PROOF: Recall thatit was assumed thatfor each in- cumbent firm i in period t, dE(n*)Idp, > O for all prices p, within a broad neighborhood of pt- I, with the equilibriumprice in period t lying in this neighborhood.Lemma5 is estab- lished by showing thatfor all pricesp, 2 pt-I in this neighborhood,the marketcannot clear in periodt. Supposep, = pt- I. Then, Qitmust exceed Qi - Ifor all producersin period t - 1. This implies E(n*) > E(n1*) 20 for all producersin period t - 1 and hence that no incumbent would exit in period t. The same condition must be truefor all pricespt > p.- I withinabroadneighborhoodofpt- Igiven that dE(n* )Idp, > 0 forall suchprices.Butevery firm that remains in the industrywill expand its marketshare,hence themarketcannotclear if all firmsremain in the industry.Therefore, pt must be less thanpt- . In order for every firm that remains in the marketto expandits marketshare,some firms must exit in every period.This will occuronly if price falls over time. It mustfall sufficiently in each period t that E(n*) falls below zero for some firms in the marketin period t - 1, causing these firmsto exit.
  • 11. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 571 Using p, < p,- , it is possible to character- ize how the size of entrants,Aq,, the process R&D of entrants,rct, and the profits of en- trantsfrom the standardproduct, Vt, change over time. Let s' denote the minimumproduct innovation expertise in period t among firms thatenteredin period k ? t. It is also possible to characterizehow st, the minimum product innovation expertise among entrants,changes over time. Over time, rc,, Aqt, V,, and s, change as follows. LEMMA 6: For all periods I > k, rc' < rck, AqI < Aqk, VI < Vk , and sl > Sk. PROOF: The choices of rci,and Aqi, for entrantsin period t must satisfy equations (3) - (6) with Qit--= 0. These equations differ across pe- riods only because pt falls over time. To see how changesin pt affectrct, Aq,, andalso V,, set Qi1 = 0 in (3 )-(5 ) anddifferentiate with respect to pt. This yields drci*/ dp, = g"(rd *)Gl'(rc)/ D > 0 dAq /dp, - g"(rd*)Gl"(rc*)Aq* /D > 0 dV /dp, = aV a/p, = Aq* > 0. Given that pt < Pt- 1, it follows that rct, Aq,, and V must fall over time. Furthermore, if V falls over time, the marginalentrantmust earn greaterincrementalprofits from product innovation over time, which implies st must rise over time. Lemma 6 indicates that the minimum in- novative expertise required for entry rises over time. Lemma 7 indicates that it eventu- ally rises to the point where no furtherentry occurs. LEMMA 7: Aftersome period, st > sna, and nofirms enter the industry. PROOF: Recall that it was assumed that the distri- bution of innovative expertise H(s) was such thatatleast one potentialentrantin every entry cohort had innovative expertise Smax. If St ' Smax for all t then in every period E(fl*) 2 0 forpotentialentrantswith innovationexpertise Smax,hence E(II*) > 0 for all prior entrants with innovative expertise Smax.Consequently, no incumbent with innovative expertise Smax would ever exit the industry. Since Aqi, > 0 for all firms thatremain in the industry,firms with innovativeexpertiseSmaxwill expandtheir market share in every period. This cannot, however, occur indefinitely, as eventually these firms would capture the entire market and would not be able to expand furtherwith- out some of them exiting. This requires p, eventuallyto fall to a level suchthatE(fI*) < 0 for some incumbentswith innovative exper- tise smax.At this point E(H*) < 0 for all po- tential entrantswith si = Smax. Since pt falls over time, after this point E(II*) will con- tinue to be negative for potentialentrantswith Si = Smax, hence s will exceed Smaxandno fur- therentry will occur. One finalresultthatwill be useful concerns how s' differs across entrycohortsin each pe- riod. This is summarizedas follows. LEMMA 8: In each period t, s' > s' for I > k. PROOF: In each period, E(J7i,) 2 0 for producers. Given that V * is lower the younger the firm based on Lemma 3, it follows that the mini- mum si requiredfor survival must be greater for younger firms. Coupled with the fact that entrants start with higher minimum product innovation expertise than all prior entry co- horts based on Lemma 6, it follows that the younger the cohort of firms then the greater the minimum productinnovation expertise of the cohort. The various lemmas indicate how: (1) the price of the standard product changes over time; (2) the initial values of rdi,, rcit, Aqi,, and Vitchange over time for entrants;and (3) the values of rdi,,rci,,andQitchangeover time for incumbents. Summarizing results, over time pt declines, rdi,remains the same for en- trants and incumbents, rci,, Aqi,, and Vitde- cline over time for entrants,st rises over time
  • 12. 572 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 for entrants,and rci,and Qt rise over time for incumbents after entry. The other time paths, which involve how Aqi,, V1t, and E(Ji,) change over time for incumbents after entry, cannot be characterized generally. The only patternthat must hold is that in each period, Vi,andE(Fi,) mustfallforsomefirms. Itwas assumedthatapricep, existed in each period such that the marketcleared given the choices of firms takingp, as given. This will now be establishedvia induction.It was as- sumedthatsucha priceexistedinperiod1- this was how period 1 was defined. Suppose such a price exists in period t - 1. It will be shown that a market-clearing price pt then must exist in periodt given the choices of firmstakingthispriceptas given.Giventhat the market cleared in period t - 1, Qt- = -i,-I Qit- , where the summation is over firmsin themarketin periodt - 1. Inperiod t, ptmustsatisfyequation(2), whichcanbe expressedas (7) f,(p,){ 1 - Y;Qit-I/ Qt- I i7t - X Aqit = 0, i,t wherethe summationis over firmsin the mar- ketinperiodt. Intheproofof Lemma5 itwas established thatpt must be less thanpt- and mustinducesomefirmsto exit;otherwise1 - Yi,tQit- 1/Qt- I = 0 since the marketclearedin periodt - 1 andequation(7) wouldbe violated giventhatAqi,> 0 foreachfirminthemarket. Giventheassumptionof dE(nHt*)Idpt > 0, the lower pt then the more firms for which E(l*) < 0 andthusthegreaterthenumberof finnsexitingin periodt. Themorefirmsthat exitthenthegreater{I - Yi,tQi- 1/Qt-1} and the smallerXi,tAqi,in equation(7). Further- more,thesmallerpt thenthegreaterf (pt) and the smallerAqt,for each firm,which reinforces the effect of exit on the market-clearingcondi- tion. Thus, as pt decreases relative to pt-I, f (pt){I- Yi,t Q1t-I/QIQt}rises and Ei,t Aqit falls in equation (7). Given that l(rc,t) is bounded,ata low enoughprice E(nl* ) < 0 for each firmand all firmswould exit the industry. Thus,atalow enoughpricef (p,) I1 - Yjit Q,t-I Q }-II - Yi,t Aqit > 0, whereasfor pricespt 2 p,_ 1,f(p,) {1 -Yi,t Qit- /Q,- | }-2i,tAqit < 0. Giventhatf,(pt)andAqi,arecontinuousfunc- tions of p, and all firms are assumed to be atomisticand indifferentaboutbeing in the in- dustrywhen E(ll* ) = 0, it then follows that theremustbe a pricept which satisfiesequation (7) andthusclearsthe marketin periodt.'2 Note that the existence of such a path for pricedoes notdependon positive entryin each period, nordoes it dependon the time pathsin the number of entrants,numberof exits, and number of firms. These time paths are ad- dressed in the next section. IV. TheRegularitiesof thePLC Six propositions are developed in this sec- tion corresponding to each of the empirical regularitiessummarizedin Section 2. Considerthe firstregularityaboutentryover time. Let Et denote the numberof entrantsin periodt. The possible time pathsin Etimplied by the model arecharacterizedin Proposition1. PROPOSITION 1: Initially the number of entrants may rise or decline, but eventually it will decline to zero. PROOF: The entryprocess is such thatEt = Kt(1 - H(st)). Lemma 6 indicatesst rises over time. Hence Et will fall overtime unless Ktrises over time at a sufficientrate,which cannotbe ruled out a priori.Therefore,initially E, may rise or 2 The assumption that all firms are atomistic ensures the continuity of f(p,){ 1 - .1j, Qit- ,IQt,- I-i, Aqi, as a function of p, and hence the existence of a price pt sat- isfying equation (7). A similar assumption is invoked in Jovanovic and Glenn H. MacDonald (1994) and Hugo A. Hopenhayn (1993) in their models of industryshakeouts (these arediscussed furtherbelow). Alternatively,if firms were nonatomisticthenthe quantitysupplied,Y,. Qi.- I(Q,I Q,- ) + Yi,tAqi,, could exceed the quantity demanded, f(p1), at all prices Pt insufficient to induce the marginal firmto exit but could fall shortof the quantitydemanded at all prices sufficient to induce the marginalfirmto exit. Then, therewould be no price thatwould clearthe market in periodt. Although beyond the scope of the paper,non- atomisticfirmsmightbe accommodatedby allowing firms to maintainbacklogs of unfilled ordersso thatunsatisfied demand at the equilibriumprice in period t was satisfied throughfirmexpansion in subsequentperiods.
  • 13. VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 573 fall overtime. Lemma7 indicatesthatin either case, E, will eventually decline to 0. Proposition1 can accountfor the two entry patternsreflected in Figure 1. Intuitively, in every period,incumbentshave a lower average cost thanentrantsbecause they spend more on process R&D due to the greater output over whichtheycanapplythebenefitsof theirR&D. Entrantscan nonethelessgain a foothold in the industryif they can earnsufficientprofitsfrom developinga distinctiveproductvariant,which requiressufficientproduct-innovationexpertise si. Over time, though, price is driven down andthe advantageof incumbentsover entrants grows, increasing the product-innovationex- pertiserequiredfor entryto be profitable.This reduces the percentage of potential entrants that enter over time, although the number of entrantscan rise at any time if the numberof potential entrantsK, rises sufficiently. Even- tually, price is driven to a level such that re- gardlessof theirproduct-innovationexpertise, theexpectedprofitsof all potentialentrantsare less thanor equal to 0 and entry ceases. The second regularityindicatesthatinitially the total numberof firms rises but eventually peaks and then declines steadily, as reflected in Figure 1. Proposition 2 indicates how this can be explained by the model. PROPOSITION 2: Initially the number of finns may rise over time, but eventually it will decline steadily. PROOF: It was shown thatp, must fall over time in Lemma 5, andby a sufficient amountto cause some firms to exit in every period. Coupled with Lemma 7, which indicates entry must eventually stop, this implies that after some period the numberof firms steadily declines. To see how thenumberof firmscould riseover time at some pointpriorto this, consider with- outloss of generalitythechange in the number of firmsbetween periods 1 and 2. This change equalsthenumberof entrantsinperiod2, K2(1- H(s2)), minus the numberof exits in period 2, K1(H(s )-H(s )). The only constraint on the number of entrants and exits comes from the requirement that the market must clear in period 2. All incumbents that remain in the industryin period 2 expandtheirmarket share. Therefore, in order for the market to clear in period 2, the total output of entrants in period 2, K2(1 - H(s2))Aq2, mustbe less thanthe outputexiters in period 2 would have producedif they had remainedin the industry andmaintainedtheirmarketshare,K1(H(s ) - H(s 1)l) (Q2/Q1)Aq1. Since Aq2< Aq1based on Lemma 6, this condition can be satisfied even if K2(1 - H(s2)) > K1(H(s ) - H(sl)). Thus, initially the number of firms may rise. Note thatthe numberof firmscould rise fromperiod 1 to 2 even if K2< K1,which would ensure that the number of entrantsin period 2, K2(1 - H(s2)), was less than the number of entrants in period 1, K1( 1 - H(s I)). Thus, the numberof firmscould rise initially even if the numberof entrantsfell. Intuitively, over time price falls, the more innovative incumbentsexpand,andthe less in- novative incumbentsexit and are replacedby more innovative,smallerentrants.This can re- sultin a rise in the numberof producers.How- ever, as incumbentscontinueto grow theirad- vantages eventually become insurmountable andentryceases. Exit continues,though,asthe largest firms with the greatest innovative ex- pertise expandtheirmarketshareandpush the less fit firmsout of the market.Consequently, eventually the numberof firms declines over time. Considernext the thirdregularityregarding how the market shares of the leaders change over time. Proposition3 indicates thatthe rate of change of the marketshares of all incum- bents must eventually slow. PROPOSITION 3: As eachfirm grows large, eventually the change in its market share, Aqi,/Q,, will decline over time. PROOF: Given that Q, is nondecreasing over time, Aqi,/Q, will decline over time if Aqi,declines over time. Equation (5) indicates that Aqi, is based on the firm's profitmarginon the stan- dardproduct,p, - c + I(rci,). Forincumbents thatremainin the industry,rci,will grow over time, causing l(rci,) to grow. Eventually, though,I(rci,) will asymptoticallyapproachits upper bound, and the rise in l(rci,) will
  • 14. 574 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 approachzero. In contrast,Lemma 5 indicates thatp,will fall in every periodto accommodate the desires of incumbents to expand. There- fore, for incumbentsthatremainin the indus- try, p, - c + l(rci,) will eventually decline, causing the increase in their market share, Aqi,/Q,, to decline. Intuitively, in every period incumbents ex- pand. The rate at which they expand depends on theirprofitmarginon the standardproduct. With the marginal product of process R&D eventually approaching zero, all firms even- tually experience a decline in theirprofitmar- gin. This will induce them to decreasethe rate atwhich they expandtheirmarketshare.Since the largest firms perform the most process R&D, they will be the firstto decreasethe rate at which they expand theirmarketshare.Sub- sequently, smaller firmswill follow.' The otherthreeregularitiespertainto thena- ture of innovation over the PLC. Regarding firstthe trendover time in the rate of product innovation, it is straightforwardto establish the following. PROPOSITION 4: Afterentryceases, the ex- pected number of product innovations of all finns, 1j, (si + g(rdi,)), declines over time. PROOF: Since rdi, = rd* for all firms according to Lemma 1, si + g(rdi,) remains the same for any firm i thatremains in the market.Conse- quently, once entry ceases, li,t(si + g(rdi,)) declines over time as the number of firms falls. Proposition 4 explains the eventual decline in the rate of product innovation in new in- dustries reflected in the fourth regularity. Since each firm performs a constant amount of product innovation over time, once entry ceases and the numberof firms declines then the expected number of product innovations must decline. Corresponding to this is a de- cline in the number of distinctive variants of the product for sale. This explains the other part of the fourth regularity concerning the decline in the numberof competing versions of the product that eventually occurs in new industries. Note that prior to the shakeout in the numberof producers,the numberof firms increases over time as more innovative en- trantsdisplace larger, less innovative incum- bents. This causes the number of competing versions of the product to rise over time. Thus, initially the marketinduces a rise in the diversity of competing product versions, which eventually gives way to a steady de- cline in this diversity. In this sense, the emer- gence of a "dominant design" for a product can be interpretedas the result ratherthanthe cause of the shakeout in the number of pro- ducers. In effect, the private benefits of large size eventually compromise the diversity of competing product versions in the market. Since all product innovations are introduced in competing versions of the productandsub- sequently incorporated into the standard product, over time the rate of product inno- vation in the standardproduct will also de- cline as the numberof firms falls. Considernext the trendover time in the ef- fort devoted to process and product R&D. It is easy to establish the following. PROPOSITION 5: For each firm i that re- mains in the market in period t, rci,/rdi, > rci,- 1/rdi,- 1i PROOF: Foreach firm,Lemma 1indicatesrdi,is con- stantover time andLemma4 indicatesthatrci, rises over time. Hence rci,/rdi,must rise over time. 1' Note, though, that there is nothing in the model to ensurethatthe largestfirmsremainin the marketin every period.Exit will occurin every period,andthereis nothing in the model to rule out exit from the firstcohort, which contains the largest finns. Nonetheless, it is possible to establishthatthe largestcohortswill be subjectto the low- est rateof exit in the following sense. In each cohort that experiences exit, the firms with the least innovative ex- pertise will exit. Eventually, whole entry cohorts become extinct. This will occur for entry cohort k when sk, the minimum innovation expertise requiredfor survival, ex- ceeds Smax.Based on Lemma 8, sk will exceed Smaxfirstfor the youngest cohorts,which always have the greatestmin- imum product-innovation expertise. Thus, once entry ceases the youngest cohorts, which are also the smallest, will experiencethegreatestratesof exit. This accordswith the findings of numerous studies (for example, David S. Evans, 1987; Timothy Dunne et al., 1989).
  • 15. VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHEPRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 575 Proposition5 establishes that over time every firm that remainsin the marketin- creasesits effortonprocessrelativeto prod- uctR&D,whichexplainsthefifthregularity. Intuitively,sincethereturnstoproductR&D areindependentof firmsize whilethereturns to processR&Darea directfunctionof firm size, as firmsgrowtheyincreasetheireffort on processrelativeto productR&D.This is just anextremecase of the generalideathat the returnsto productR&D areless depen- denton the outputof the firm(priorto the R&D) thanthe returnsto processR&D. In this sense processandproductR&D,which areoftencollapsedintoone basedon anap- peal to a Lancasterianattributesframework, aredifferent. Proposition5 appliesto individualfirms. Eventuallythe trendsat the firmlevel must alsobe mirroredatthemarketlevel.Onceen- try ceases, the smallestfirmsare dispropor- tionatelydrivenfromthe marketgiven their costdisadvantage.Thesefirmshavethehigh- est ratioof productto processR&Dbecause they conduct the least amountof process R&D. Thus, as they disproportionatelyexit andincumbentsincreasetheirlevelof process relativetoproductR&D,theratioof totalpro- cess to totalproductR&Dforallfirmsrises.'4 Note,though,thatonce entryceasesthetotal processR&Dof all firmsmightdeclineover time,just at a slowerratethanthedeclinein totalproductR&D.'" The last regularityconcerninginnovation is thatentrantstendto accountfor a dispro- portionateshareof productinnovationsrel- ative to incumbents. Let ik = (i,t(si + g(rdit))/N' denote the expected numberof innovations per firm in period t of firms that entered in period k, where N' is the number of firms in period t that entered in period k and the summation is over these firms. Prop- osition 6 indicates thatik must be greaterthe younger the cohort. PROPOSITION 6: For all periods t, ik < ia fork < 1. PROOF: Since all firms spend the same amount on product R&D, the expected numberof inno- vations per firm, si + g(rdi,), is determined exclusively by si. This implies thaton average the expected number of innovations per firm in each entrycohortwill be determinedby the averageinnovativeexpertiseof firmsin theco- hort.Foreach periodt, Lemma8 indicatesthat the minimuminnovative expertise of cohortk, Sk, is greaterthe younger the cohort (that is, the largerk). Therefore, the average value of si will be greatertheyoungerthecohort,hence ak< il for k < 1. Proposition 6 implies that entrants will be more innovative on average than incum- bents, which explains the last regularity. In- tuitively, the most recent entrantsaresmaller than all other firms and thus earn the least profits from the standard product. The only way they survive given this disadvantage is if they are more innovative on average than incumbents. Thus, it is not necessary to ap- peal to some kind of disadvantage of size in innovation, or to entrants having a greater incentive than incumbents to innovate be- cause they have less to protect (compare Reinganum, 1983, 1985), to explain the greater innovativeness of entrants. Rather, the greater innovativeness of entrants may be attributable to the selection process gov- erning the evolution of the market coupled with an advantage of large firm size in ap- propriatingthe returnsfrom R&D. Indeed, if incumbents either had strategic disincentives to innovate or were less efficient at innova- tion because of their larger size, then oppor- tunities for profitable entry would persist over time, which is not consistent with the first regularity concerning entry eventually becoming small. 4 Priorto entry ceasing, there is a counteractingforce at the level of the marketto the trendin the ratio of firm process to product R&D: smaller, more innovative en- trantsdisplacelarger,less innovativeincumbents.Because theentrantsaresmaller,they havea higherratioof product to process R&D than the incumbents, which contributes toward a higher ratio of product to process R&D at the marketlevel. Thus, it is possible thatpriorto entry ceas- ing, the ratio of process to product R&D at the market level might fall over time. Once entry ceases, however, the ratio must rise. I Whetherthetotalamountof processR&D of all firms declines over time dependson therateat which incumbent firmsexpandtheirprocess R&D relativeto therateof firm exit, which is not determinedwithin the model.
  • 16. 576 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 V. Cross-Sectional Implications of the Model In this section it is shown thatthe model can explain various cross-sectional regularitiesre- garding how within industries R&D effort, R&D productivity, cost, and profitabilitydif- fer across firms according to their size. Since the model was not set up to explain these reg- ularities, its ability to explain them can be viewed as supportfor its account of the PLC. A simple cross-sectional implication of the model is thatlargerfirmsshouldperformmore total R&D and also devote a greaterfraction of their R&D to process innovation. PROPOSITION 7: For each period t, the larger the outputof thefirm at the start of the period, Qit- 1,then the greater its total spend- ing on R&D, rdi, + rci,, and the greater the fraction of its total R&D devoted to process innovation,rci,/(rdi, + rci,). PROOF: This follows directlyfromLemmas 1 and3. There have been numerous studies of the relationshipbetween total R&D spending and contemporaneous firm size. It has been re- peatedly found that R&D and contemporane- ous firmsize areclosely related,with firmsize explaining over 50 percent of the variationin firm R&D in more R&D-intensive industries (see Cohen and Klepper [1996b] for a review of these studies). In terms of the composition of firmR&D, F. M. Scherer (1991) analyzes the patentsissued to firmsin theFederalTrade Commission Line of Business Programin the 10-month period from June 1976 to March 1977. Assigning thesepatentsto business units and classifying them according to whether they are process or product patents, Scherer finds that among business units with patents, the fraction of patents that are process in- creases with the sales of the business unit. Based on the assumption that the returns to process R&D aremore closely tied to the size of the firm than the returnsto product R&D, Cohen and Klepper (1996a) develop addi- tional predictions at the level of the industry aboutthe relationshipbetween the fraction of patentsthatareprocess andbusiness unitsales. Using Scherer's data, they find support for Proposition 7 at the level of the industry as well as for theirmore detailed predictions. The intuitionbehindProposition7 is simple: the largerthe firmthen the greaterthe returns fromprocess R&D, hence thegreatertheeffort devoted to R&D in generalandprocess in par- ticular.Alternativelystated,the largerthe firm then the greaterthe output over which it can average the fixed costs of (process) R&D, hence the greaterits R&D effort. This implies that the close relationshipbetween R&D and firmsize is indicative of an advantageof size. In contrast, most studies have interpretedthe close relationshipto indicate no advantageof size. They note thatR&D does not tend to rise morethanproportionallywith firmsize, which implies that increasing the average firm size would not increase total industryR&D spend- ing. This has been widely interpretedto imply there are no advantages of large firm size in R&D (William L. Baldwin andJohnT. Scott, 1987 p. 111). But as Cohen and Klepper (1996b) emphasize, without such an advan- tage it is difficult to explain why there is a close relationship between R&D and firm size.16 In additionto predictionsaboutR&D effort and firmsize, the model has distinctive impli- cations abouthow firmsize andR&D produc- tivity are related. PROPOSITION 8: For each period t, the av- erage product of process R&D, l(rci,)/rci,, and the average product of product R&D, (si + g(rdj,))/rdj,, vary inversely with the size of thefirm,Qj. 6 Note that in the model there is no innate advantage of firmsize in R&D, as Cohen andKlepper(1996b) point out in a related setting. The advantageof large firm size stems from the inability of firms to sell their innovations in disembodied form and the costliness of rapid growth. In the absence of these restrictions,successful innovations could be embodied in the entire industryoutput through the sale of the innovations and/or the expansion of suc- cessful innovators, and the contemporaneoussize of the firm would have no bearing on the firm's incentives to conduct R&D. While many other models assume, either implicitly or explicitly, that innovations cannot be sold and thus link the returnsto innovation to the size of the innovator,few assume any restrictionson firmgrowth.
  • 17. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 577 PROOF: Given thatl"(rci,) < 0 for all rci,,the larger rci,then the lower will be l(rcj,)/rcj,. In each periodt, the largerthe firmthen the greaterits spending on process R&D. Therefore, l(rci,)/ rci, will vary inversely with Qt. Regarding productR&D, Proposition6 indicates thatthe expected number of innovations per firm is greaterfor smallerfirms.Since all firmsspend the same amounton productR&D, thisimplies that (si + g(rdj,))/rdj, must be inversely re- lated to the size of the firm, Qit. Proposition8 is consistent with the findings of studies that examine the relationship be- tween totalR&D effort andthe numberof pat- ents and/or innovationsperunitof R&D. John Bound et al. (1984) find that for publicly tradedfirms, the numberof patentsper dollar of R&D is considerably greaterfor firmswith smaller R&D budgets. Examining this rela- tionship within industries using data from a comprehensive census of innovations in 1982 conductedfor the Small Business Administra- tion, Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch (1991) generally find an inverse relationship across firms between the number of innova- tions perdollarof R&D andtotalR&D spend- ing. If in addition total R&D spending does not rise more than proportionally with firm size within industries, as has generally been found, then Proposition 8 furtherimplies that the total productof R&D will not rise in pro- portion to firm size. Equivalently stated, within industrieslargerfirmswill account for a disproportionatelysmall shareof process and productinnovationsrelative to theirsize. This is consistent with Acs and Audretsch's find- ings (1988, 1991) based on the Small Busi- ness Administrationdata, especially for more R&D intensive industries, with Scherer's (1965) findingsconcerning the rateof patent- ing among large firms, and with the observa- tions of Alice Patricia White (1983) for the select group of dominantfirms she analyzes. This interpretationruns counterto the con- ventionalinterpretationof the inverserelation- ship between R&D productivityand firmsize. This finding has been widely interpretedas a furthersign of the lack of an advantageof firm size in R&D (see, for example, Acs and Audretsch, 1991). Not only do large firmsnot spend disproportionatelymore on R&D than smaller firms, but they appearto get less out of theirR&D spendingthansmallerfirms,sug- gesting they areactually less efficient at R&D than their smaller counterparts.This interpre- tation, though, raises more questions than it answers. If larger firms are less efficient at R&D, why do they conduct more R&D than smallerfirms?Even morefundamentally,how are large firms able to survive and prosperin R&D intensive industriesif they are less effi- cient at R&D than smaller firms? These questions arereadilyansweredby the model. All firmshave the same R&D produc- tivity in the model in the sense that the func- tions g(rdi,) and l(rci,), which calibrate the productivity of product and process R&D re- spectively, are the same for all firms. The lower average productivity of both product andprocess R&D in largerfirmsis a reflection of the competitive advantages conferred by firmsize. By applyingtheir(process) R&D to a larger level of output, larger firms are able to appropriatea greaterfraction of the value of their (process) R&D than smaller firms. This induces them to undertakemore process R&D than smaller firms. Given the diminish- ing returnsto R&D, by undertakingmorepro- cess R&D largerfirmsmarchfurtherdown the marginal-productschedule of process R&D, causing the average product of their process R&D to be lower thanin smaller firms.At the same time, by undertakingmoreprocess R&D and getting a larger returnfrom their process R&Dthansmallerfirms,theyearngreaterprof- its fromprocess R&D thansmallerfirms.This is why they prosperdespite the lower average productivityof their R&D than smaller firms. The greater profits they earn from process R&D also enables them to survive with less average product-innovation expertise than smaller firms, which explains why they gen- erate fewer product innovations per dollar of productR&D than smaller firms.'7 '7 RichardJ. Rosen (1991) recently proposed an alter- native explanationfor why large firms account for a dis- proportionatelysmall shareof innovationsrelativeto their sales which also relies on large size conferringan advan- tage in appropriatingthe returnsfrom R&D. His expla- nation, however, also relies on a stylized depiction of the
  • 18. 578 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 Themodelhasfurtherimplicationsregard- ing how the advantagesconferredby size in R&Dwill be reflectedin firmcost andprofit- ability.It predictsthatlargerfirmswill have loweraveragecost. PROPOSITION 9: For each period t, firm average cost c - l(rcj,) varies inversely with Qit. PROOF: Sincerci,variesdirectdywithQitandP'(rci,)> 0 forallrci,,it followsdirectlythatc - l(rci,) variesinverselywithQit. Thispredictionis consistentwiththe find- ingsof RichardE. CavesandDavidR.Barton (1990), who use plantdatafromthe Census of Manufacturerstoestimateproductionfunc- tionsfor4-digitSICmanufacturingindustries. Allowingproductivityto differacrossplants, they findthatfor the averageindustrylarger plantsaremoreproductivethansmallerplants. In lightof thehighcorrelationbetweenplant andbusinesssize,thisfindingis supportiveof Proposition9.ConsistentwiththeroleofR&D inthemodelinimpartingalowercosttolarger firms,CavesandBarton(p. 126) findthere- lationshipbetweenproductivityandplantsize to be strongerin moreR&Dintensiveindus- tries.Proposition9 is also consistentwithE. RalphBiggadike's(1979 pp.65-66) findings aboutentrants.Using detaileddataon new businessunitsof asubsetof firmsinthePIMS dataset,Biggadikefindsthatentrantstendto startwith a pronouncedproduction-costdis- advantagethatdeclinesover time as the en- trantscapturea largershareof themarket. Themodelhasfurtherimplicationsregard- inghowtheadvantagesconferredbyfirmsize in R&D will be reflectedin firmcost and profitability. PROPOSITION 10: The largest and most profitablefirms will comefrom thefirst cohort of entrants. These firms will increase their marketshares over timeand consistentlyearn supernormalprofits. PROOF: Firmsthatenteredin period1withinnova- tive expertiseSmaxwill alwaysbe largerthan all subsequententrantsandwill earngreater profitsthanallotherfirms.Consequently,they will consistentlyearnsupernormalprofitsand will neverexit.SinceAqi,> 0 forall incum- bents,overtimethesefirmswill alsoincrease theirmarketshares. Proposition10 implies that the market sharesof thelargestandmostprofitablefirms intheindustrywillnotdeclineovertime.Fur- thermore,althoughthe profitsof these firms maydeclineovertimeaspricefalls,theywill consistentlyearnsupernormalprofits.These predictions are consistent with Mueller's (1986) findingsconcerningthepersistenceof marketshareandprofitabilityamongthelarg- estmanufacturingfirmsovertheperiod1950- 1972. Muellerfindsthata numberof these firmsmaintainedtheirmarketsharesoverthis 22-yearperiod.Whiletheaverageprofitability of thesefirmsdeclinedovertime,they were still eaming supernormalreturnson invest- mentin 1972.Consistentwiththeroleplayed by R&Din themodelin conferringanadvan- tagetolargerfirms,Muellerfindsthattheper- sistenceof marketshareandprofitabilitywas strongerforfirmsin moreR&D-intensivein- dustries.Proposition10 also predictsthatthe mostsuccessfulandlong-livedfirmswill dis- proportionatelycome fromthe earliestentry cohorts.Thisis consistentwiththefindingsof KlepperandSimons(1993) concerningfour productsthatexperiencedsharpshakeouts:au- tos,tires,televisions,andpenicillin.Theyfind thatthechancesof survivingatleast 10years weresignificantlygreaterfor the earliesten- trants,particularlyin autosandtires,andthat on averagethelargestfirmsenteredearlier. Insummary,thecross-sectionalregularities indicatethatthelargerthefirmthenthegreater its spendingon R&D,thegreaterthefraction of itsR&Ddevotedtoprocessinnovation,the smallerthenumberof patentsandinnovations returnsto risky R&D projects which suggests, counterto the evidence assembled in Mansfield (1981), that large firms will account for a disproportionatelysmall shareof riskier R&D. As the model indicates, as long as R&D is subjectto diminishingreturnsandlargefirmsize provides an advantage in appropriatingthe returnsto R&D, there is little need to resort to other stylizations to account for the disproportionatelysmall number of innovations ac- counted for by largerfirms.
  • 19. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 579 it generatesper dollar of R&D, and the lower its averagecosts. Furthermore,earlierentrants tend to grow larger and survive longer. Since all of these patterns are predicted by the model, they provide supportfor it. The extent of the support,though, depends on the degree to which these same patternscan be explained by other theories, particularly theories that can account for various features of the PLC. The most relevant alternativetheories are the dominantdesignview reviewedin the introduc- tion (compare Utterbackand Suairez,1993), which explains many featuresof the PLC, and theories recently advanced in Jovanovic and MacDonald(1994) and Hopenhayn(1993) to explainshakeouts. Each of these theories posits technology- based mechanisms which increase exit and/or make entryharder,contributingto a shakeout. In Utterback and Suairez(1993) the mecha- nism is a dominantdesign, which leads to exit of firms less able to manage the production process for the dominantdesign. In Jovanovic and MacDonald (1994) it is a major (exoge- nous) technological changewhich leads to exit of firmsthatareunable to innovatein the new regime. InHopenhayn(1993) it is a slowdown in productinnovationthatfavors firmsthatin- vest in process innovation, in the manner of the dominantdesign theory.'8 While the theories do not directly address the cross-sectional regularities,they can none- theless be used to speak to them. In each the- ory, the firms that prosper and remain in the industryduringthe shakeoutare the betterin- novators.1t might be expected these firms would spend more on R&D, particularlypro- cess R&D in the UtterbackandSuairez(1993) and Hopenhayn (1993) models, have lower costs, and grow to be larger. This could ex- plain the cross-sectional regularitiesinvolving firmsize and total R&D, the fraction of R&D devoted to process innovation, and average cost. The other two regularities,however, are moredifficultforthe alternativetheoriesto ex- plain.If largerfirmsarebetterinnovators,they mightbe expected to generateatleast as many, if not more, innovations per dollar of R&D thanthe smaller finns. Yet the cross-sectional regularitiesindicatethatthe numberof patents and innovations per dollar of R&D declines with firm size. In terms of the significance of early entry, none of the theories emphasizes the importanceof entrytiming in conditioning the length of survival of firms that entered priorto the shakeout.'9Yet the cross-sectional regularities indicate that among products ex- periencing sharp shakeouts, the date of entry was an importantdeterminantof the length of survival for the preshakeoutentrants.20 Thus, the alternativetheories cannotreadily explain all theregularities.This does notimply that the forces they feature are not operative. Indeed, these forces are largely complemen- taryto the ones featuredin the model. Judging fromthe cross-sectional regularities,however, the model appearsto captureimportantforces that arenot presentin the other theories. VI. ImplicationsandExtensions The notion thatentry,exit, marketstructure, and innovation follow a common patternfor new productshas become partof the folklore of a numberof disciplines, including econom- ics. Although the features of this pattern are based on a limited number of products and much of the evidence is impressionistic, they appear to resonate with our experience. De- spite its popularity, though, there are many skeptics about the PLC, both in terms of its logic and its universality. The principal pur- pose of this paper was to shore up its logical 18Hopenhayn(1993) also posits other,nontechnology- basedmechanismsthatcould triggera shakeout.These are not considered because they cannot address the cross- sectional regularitiesinvolving R&D. '9In eachtheorythe shakeoutis triggeredby events whichchangethe basis for competitionamongincum- bents,whichif anythingmightbeexpectedto undermine thevalueof priorexperience. 20Moreover,itdoesnotappeartobetheshakeoutitself whichaccountsforthiseffect.Klepper(1996)findsthat differencesin survivalratesforthepreshakeoutentrants weremostpronouncedwhentheywereolderandhadsur- viveda numberof yearsof the shakeout.In themodel, thiscanbe explainedby the selectionprocess(compare Klepper,1996).Onaverage,laterentrantsarebetterin- novators.Atyoungages,thiscanoffsetthedisadvantage of lateentryfor firmsurvival,butas firmsage andthe selectionprocesscontinuestooperate,eventuallylateren- trantsmustexperiencehigherhazardrates.
  • 20. 580 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 foundations by showing how a simple model could explain all the central features of the PLC. The proposed model groundsthe PLC with two simple forces. One is that the ability to appropriatethe returns to process R&D de- pends centrally on the size of the firm. The other is that firms possess different types of expertise which lead them to pursue different types of product innovations. The advantage of size in process R&D causes firm process R&D to rise over time andeventually puts en- trantsat such a cost disadvantagethatentryis foreclosed. After entry ceases, firms compete on the basis of their size and also their inno- vative prowess. As firmsexit and the number of firmsfalls, the diversity of productR&D is compromised, causing the numberof product innovations and the diversity of competing product variants to decline. The same two forces also explain the relationshipwithin in- dustries between firm size and total R&D spending, relative spending on product and process R&D, the productivity of R&D, av- erage cost, andprofitability.The ability of the model to explain these cross-sectional regu- laritiesin additionto the temporalpatternsthat define the PLCprovides supportfor its expla- nationof the PLC.It also lends credenceto the PLC as a leading case thatcapturesthe salient features of the evolution of technologically progressive industries. A number of stylizations were invoked to highlight the two key forces featured in the model. Perhapsthe most noteworthywere the assumptionsthat average cost was a function of only contemporaneous process R&D, de- cisions were made solely on the basis of short- termprofits,andallinnovationswereultimately embodied in the industry's standardproduct. Although relaxing these assumptions would complicate the model, it need not fundamen- tally alter the ability of the model to explain the PLC. Regarding process innovation, sup- pose process improvements were allowed to cumulate. If all process improvements were assumed to be costlessly imitated one period afterthey were introduced,firmdifferences in average cost would still be a function of only differences in contemporaneousfirmspending on process R&D. Firm average costs would equal c, - I (rci,), where c, reflects the cumu- lative effect on cost of all past process inno- vations by all firms. This change would not fundamentallyaffect the model.2'Even if cost differences across firms were allowed to cu- mulate,it would only reinforcethe advantages of the largest firms. If firms were allowed to be forwardlooking, all firmswould accelerate the growth in their output to take account of the advantages of size in R&D and accord- ingly undertakegreaterprocess R&D in each period(Klepper, 1992). But given the costs of expanding output, firms would still grow by finite ratesin each period andit would still be advantageousto enterearlier.Indeed,the firms that would accelerate the growth in their out- put the most would be those that expected to survive longest, which would be the firmsthat entered earliest with the greatest innovative expertise. Thus, allowing firms to be forward looking would notaltertheadvantagesof early entryandgreaterinnovationexpertiseandthus would not fundamentallyalter the model. Fi- nally, suppose some productinnovationswere not embodied in the standard product but formed the basis for separateproductniches. If all permanent product variants could be costlessly imitated one period afterthey were developed andprocess innovationlowered the average cost of all product variants, then the implications of the model would not change. All firms would produce all product variants andthe incentives for process R&D would de- pend on the total outputof all variants.22 The depiction in the model of how market structureand performance evolve over time for new productsis differentfrom the conven- tional industrial organization paradigm on structureandperformance.Historically,indus- trycharacteristicswere seen as shapingthe na- ture of firm cost functions and barriers to entry, which in turndeterminedstructureand performance. With few exceptions, firm dif- ferences within industrieswere thought to be 2' The only implicationof the model thatwould change is Proposition 3, which would requirefurtherstructuring of the model to establish. 22The only way the model would be fundamentallyal- teredis if eachproductnicherequireditsown processR&D. In this case, each productniche would be analogous to a separateindustry,and the model would no longer be a model of industryevolutionbut of industryfragmentation.
  • 21. VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCTLIFE CYCLE 581 irrelevant(Mueller,1986pp.223-24). Inre- cent years,however,it has been recognized thatfirmdifferencesmaybe at the rootof a numberof importantphenomena,suchas the positivecorrelationacrossindustriesbetween industryconcentrationratiosand mean firm profitability(Harold Demsetz, 1973). The modeltakesthis approacha step furtherby embeddingdifferencesin firmcapabilitiesin anevolutionarysettingin whichexpansionin outputat anygiven momentis subjectto in- creasingmarginalcostsandfirmsize imparts an advantagein certaintypes of R&D. The resultis a worldin whichinitialfirmdiffer- encesgetmagnifiedas sizebegetssize,which impartsanadvantageto earlyentryandleads to aneventualdeclinein thenumberof firms andtherateof productinnovation.23 The starknessof the modelprecludesany departuresfromthisevolutionarypattern.This can be remediedby allowing for random eventsthataltertherelativestandingofincum- bentsandpotentialentrants.Forexample,if cohortsdifferin termsof the distributionof theirinnovativeexpertiseor if the innovative expertiseof incumbentsis underminedbycer- taintypesof technologicalchanges,thenlater entrantsmayleapfrogovertheindustryleaders andthefirmsthateventuallydominatethein- dustrymaynotcomefromtheearliestcohort of entrants.24Someproductsaredescribedas eventuallybecomingcommodities,whichcould beaccountedforinthemodelbyallowingtech- nologicalopportunitiesforinnovationeventually to dryup.Incumbentfirmproductandprocess R&Dwouldtheneventuallydeclinetozeroand theadvantagesof earlyentrywouldeventually be eliminated,allowingthenumberof firmsto stabilizebeforethe shakeoutof producershad runitsfullcourse.Themodelcouldalsobegen- eralizedtoincludeotheractivities,suchasmar- ketingandadvertising,thatcouldsubstitutefor processR&D in impartingan advantageto largerfirms (Sutton, 1991).25 While these generalizationswould no doubt enrich the modelandallowittoaccommodatedepartures fromthePLCthathavebeenobservedinsome technologicallyprogressiveindustries(com- pareKlepper,1992), eveninitsstarkformthe modelis ableto addressa widerangeof reg- ularities.Itdemonstratesthatmanyaspectsof industryevolutionand heterogeneitywithin industriesin firmR&Deffortandprofitability canbe explainedby couplingrandomdiffer- ences in firmcapabilitieswith advantagesof firmsize conferredby R&D. REFERENCES Abernathy, William J. The productivity di- lemma.Baltimore:The JohnsHopkins Uni- versity Press, 1978. Abernathy,WilliamJ.;Clark,KimB.andKantrow, AlanM. Industrialrenaissance:Producinga competitivefiture for America. New York: Basic Books, 1983. Abernathy,WilliamJ. and Utterback,JamesM. "Patternsof IndustrialInnovation." Tech- nology Review,June/July 1978, 80, pp. 41- 47. Acs, ZoltanJ. and Audretsch,DavidB. "Inno- vation in Large and Small Firms." Ameri- can Economic Review, September 1988, 78(4), pp. 678-90. . "R&D, Finn Size, and Innovative Activity," in Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch,eds., Innovationand technolog- ical change: An international comparison. New York:HarvesterWheatseaf, 1991, pp. 39-59. Aitken,HughG.J. Thecontinuouswave: Tech- nology and American radio, 1900-1932. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985. Anderson, Philip and Tushman, Michael L. "Technological Discontinuities and Domi- nant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Tech- nological Change." AdministrativeScience Quarterly, December 1990, 35(4), 604- 33. 23The welfare implications of these and other predic- tions of the model are developed in Klepper(1992). 2 These andothergeneralizationsof the model arean- alyzed in Klepper(1992). 25Indeed,for some industrieseven productR&D could play this role, althoughit would seem as if firmsize plays a more importantrole in conditioning the returmsto pro- cess than product R&D. This issue, and others, such as why firms are limited in their ability to control their in- novation expertise, involve key aspects of the model that merit furtherstudy.
  • 22. 582 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996 Baldwin, William L. and Scott, John T. Market structure and technological change. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publish- ers, 1987. Biggadike,E. Ralph.Corporate diversification: Entrystrategyandperformance.Cambridge, MA: HarvardUniversityPress, 1979. Bound, John; Cummins, Clint; Griliches, Zvi; Hall, Bronwyn H. and Jaffe, Adam. "Who Does R&D and Who Patents?" in Zvi Griliches, ed., R&D, patents, and produc- tivity.Chicago:University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Re- search, 1984, pp. 21-54. Bright,ArthurA. The electric lamp industry. New York:Macmillan, 1949. Bright,JamesR.Automationand management. Boston: GraduateSchool of Business Ad- ministration,HarvardUniversity, 1958. Caves, Richard E. and Barton, David R. Effi- ciency in U.S. manufacturing industries. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1990. Clark,KimB. "The Interactionof Design Hi- erarchies and MarketConcepts in Techno- logical Evolution." Research Policy, October 1985, 14(5), pp. 235-51. Cohen, Wesley M. and Klepper, Steven. "The Anatomy of IndustryR&D IntensityDistri- butions." AmericanEconomicReview, Sep- tember 1992, 82(4), pp. 773-99. . "Firm Size and the Nature of Inno- vation within Industries:The Case of Pro- cess and Product R&D." Review of Economics and Statistics, 1996a. . "A Reprise of Size and R&D." Eco- nomic Journal, forthcoming 1996b. Dasgupta, Partha and Stiglitz, Joseph. "Indus- trial Structureand the Natureof Innovative Activity." Economic Journal, June 1980, 90(358), pp. 266-93. De Bresson, C. and Townsend, J. "Multivariate Models for Innovation: Looking at the Abernathy-Utterback Model with Other Data." Omega, 1981, 9(4), pp. 429-36. Demsetz,Harold."Industry Structure,Market Rivalry, and Public Policy." Journal of Lawand Economics, April 1973,16(1), pp. 1-9. Drew, Philip G. "Despite Shakeout, Imaging IndustryNot Doomed to Being GreekTrag- edy." Diagnostic Imaging, November 1987, 9, pp. 95-99. Dunne,Timothy;Roberts,MarkJ. andSamuelson, Larry. "The Growth and Failure of U.S. ManufacturingPlants." Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1989,104(4), pp. 671-98. Evans,DavidS. "Tests of AlternativeTheories of Firm Growth." Journal of Political Economy, August 1987, 95(4), pp. 657- 74. Flaherty,M. Therese."Industry Structureand Cost-Reducing Investment." Economet- rica, July 1980, 48(5), pp. 1187-209. Flamm, Kenneth. Creating the computer. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institu- tion, 1988. Gilbert,RichardJ. and Newbery,DavidM. G. "Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly." American Economic Re- view, June 1982, 72(3), pp. 514-26. Gort,MichaelandKlepper,Steven."Time Paths in the Diffusion of Product Innovations." Economic Journal, September 1982, 92(367), pp. 630-53. Hollander,Samuel.Thesources of increased ef- ficiency: A study of Du Pont rayon plants. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1965. Hopenhayn,HugoA. "The Shakeout." Work- ing Paper No. 33, Universitat Pompeu Fa- bra, 1993. Hounshell,DavidA. "The Making of the Syn- thetic Fiber Industryin the United States." Mimeo, HarvardBusiness School, 1988. Jovanovic,Boyan."Selection andtheEvolution of Industry." Econometrica, May 1982, 50(3), pp. 649-70. Jovanovic, Boyan and MacDonald,Glenn H. "The Life Cycle of a Competitive Indus- try." Journal of Political Economy, April 1994, 102(2), pp. 322-47. Klein, BurtonH. Dynamic economics. Cam- bridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977. Klepper,Steven."Entry, Exit, and Innovation over the ProductLife Cycle: The Dynamics of FirstMoverAdvantages,Declining Prod- uct Innovation, and Market Failure." Mimeo, CarnegieMellon University, 1992. . "Evolution, Market Concentration, andFirmSurvival." Mimeo, CarnegieMel- lon University, 1996. Klepper,Steven and Graddy,Elizabeth."The Evolution of New Industriesand the Deter-
  • 23. VOL.86 NO. 3 KLEPPER:INNOVATIONOVERTHE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 583 minants of Market Structure." Rand Jour- nal of Economics, Spring 1990, 21 (1), pp. 27-44. Klepper,StevenandSimons,KennethL. "Tech- nological ChangeandIndustryShakeouts." Mimeo, CarnegieMellon University, 1993. Kraus,Jerome. "An Economic Study of the U.S. Semiconductor Industry." Ph.D. Dis- sertation,New School for Social Research, 1973. Mansfield,Edwin. "Entry, Gibrat's Law, In- novation and the Growthof Firms." Amer- ican Economic Review, December 1962, 52(5), pp. 1031-51. . "Composition of R and D Expendi- tures:Relationshipto Size of Firm,Concen- tration,and Innovative Output." Review of Economics and Statistics, November 1981, 63(4), pp. 610-15. Mowery,DavidC.andRosenberg,Nathan.Inside the black box: Technology and economics. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982. Mueller,DennisC.Profitsin thelong run.Cam- bridge:CambridgeUniversity Press, 1986. Mueller,DennisC. andTilton,John. "Research and Development Costs as a Barrierto En- try." Canadian Journal of Economics, No- vember 1969, 2(4), pp. 570-79. Nelson,RichardR. "Assessing Private Enter- prise: An Exegesis of Tangled Doctrine." Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1981, 12(1), pp. 93-111. Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. "Forces Generating and Limiting Concen- trationunderSchumpeterianCompetition." Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1978, 9(2), pp. 524-48. . An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge,MA: HarvardUniver- sity Press, 1982. Pavitt,K.andRothwell,R. "A Commenton 'A Dynamic Model of Process and ProductIn- novation.' " Omega, 1976, 4(4), pp. 375- 77. Porter,MichaelE. Competitive strategy. New York:The Free Press, 1980. . "The Technological Dimension of Competitive Strategy," in Richard S. Rosenbloom, ed., Research on technologi- cal innovation, management and policy. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1983. Prusa,ThomasJ. and Schmitz,JamesA. "Are New Firms an ImportantSource of Inno- vation?" Economics Letters, March 1991, 35(3), pp. 339-42. Reinganum,Jennifer. "Uncertain Innovation and the Persistence of Monopoly." Ameri- can Economic Review, September 1983, 73(4), pp. 741-48. . "Innovation and Industry Evolu- tion." Quarterly Journal of Economics, February1985, 100(1), pp. 81-99. Rosen,RichardJ. "Research andDevelopment with Asymmetric Firm Sizes." Rand Jour- nal of Economics, Autumn 1991,22(3), pp. 411-29. Scherer,F. M. "Firm Size, Market Structure, Opportunity,andthe Outputof PatentedIn- ventions." American Economic Review, December 1965, 55(5), pp. 1097-125. . "Changing Perspectives on the Firm Size Problem," in Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch, eds., Innovation and techno- logical change: An international compari- son. New York:HarvesterWheatseaf, 1991, pp. 24-38. Schmookler,Jacob. Invention and economic growth. Cambridge,MA: HarvardUniver- sity Press, 1966. Shaked, Avner and Sutton, John. "Product Dif- ferentiationandIndustrialStructure."Jour- nal of Industrial Economics, December 1987, 36(2), pp. 131-46. Sutton,John.Sunkcosts and marketstructure. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1991. Tilton,JohnE. Internationaldiffusion of tech- nology: Thecase of semiconductors.Wash- ington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1971. Utterback, James M. and Abernathy, William J. "A Dynamic Model of Process and Product Innovation."Omega,1975,3(6), pp.639-56. Utterback, James M. and Suairez, Fernando F. "Innovation, Competition, and Industry Structure."ResearchPolicy, February1993, 22(1), pp. 1-21. von Hippel,Eric. The sources of innovation. Oxford:Oxford University Press, 1988. White,AlicePatricia.The dominantfirm. Ann Arbor,MI: UMI Research Press, 1983. Williamson,OliverE. Marketsand hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York:The Free Press, 1975.