SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Page 0
Fiscal policy relaxation in a depressed economy
Can there be a “Free Lunch” for Greece?
Dr. Platon Monokroussos
Group Chief Economist
Eurobank Ergasias S.A.
July, 2017
Page 1
 This study leans on the literature on regime-dependent fiscal multipliers and the existence of hysteresis effects to
demonstrate that, under certain conditions, a further relaxation of the agreed fiscal targets for Greece could not only
benefit the country’s growth outlook, but might also lead to improved (rather than worsened) fiscal dynamics in the
medium- and long-run.
 This, rather counter-intuitive, argument is based on the assumption that fiscal multipliers are higher (and more
persistent) than usual when the economy features a massive output gap as a result of a severe recession and also that a
cyclical boost in output caused by an expansionary fiscal policy move may have a permanent positive effect on future
potential output.
 Although quite diverse views continue to exist among professional economists and policy makers as regards the
quantitative and qualitative effects of fiscal policy, a more recent strand of the relevant literature appears to support the
regime-dependence of fiscal multipliers i.e., higher effects on output due to discretionary policy shocks in periods of deep
economic contractions than in normal economic times or expansions.
 As regards hysteresis, i.e. the notion that in a depressed economy featuring ample cyclical unemployment and excess
capacity, an expansionary fiscal policy shock could prove self-financing, i.e. instigate both an improvement in the future
potential output and a decline in the debt to GDP ratio in the medium- and long-term (and vice versa for the case of a
contractionary fiscal policy shock), the literature has proposed a host of mechanisms to substantiate the existence of
such effects.
 In the case of a fiscal policy-induced cyclical downturn in an economy already featuring a sizeable negative output gap,
such effects may include, inter alia, reduced labor force attachment on the part of the long-term unemployed, scarring
effects on young workers who have trouble beginning their careers, lower physical and human capital investments,
reduced R&D expenditure, and changes in managerial attitudes.
 In Greece, an unprecedented in size (and heavily front-loaded) fiscal consolidation programme has been implemented
since 2010 to engineer an internal devaluation and correct the earlier acute macroeconomic imbalances. This facilitated a
huge improvement in the country’s fiscal accounts, but it has broadly failed so far to stabilize public debt dynamics. And
this, despite the aforementioned fiscal adjustment as well as any beneficial effects stemming from the PSI operation and
the broadly concessional interest rates currently paid on official-sector loans.
 Indeed, over the period 2010-2016, the general government primary fiscal balance has improved by c. 14ppts-of-GDP
(and by 19.2ppts-of-GDP in cyclically adjusted terms), while the gross public debt to GDP ratio has increased by
52.3ppts. Furthermore, real GDP losses amounted to c. 25ppts, while real potential output was at the end of 2016 lower
by 13.7ppts relative to its end-2009 level (AMECO data).
Summary of views & key findings
Page 2
 In view of the aforementioned, the study provides a quantitative assessment of a number of scenarios for the evolution of
Greece’s GDP and other important variables such as the general government fiscal balance and the gross public debt
ratio under a hypothetical permanent relaxation of the agreed target for the primary surplus, to 2.2%-of-GDP from 2018
onwards.
 Assuming a range of (plausible) values for the short-term (impact) fiscal multiplier and for some other key parameters
used in the exercise (e.g. multiplier persistence and hysteresis coefficients), the study demonstrates that, under certain
conditions, the said fiscal policy intervention (relaxation of the primary surplus target) could lead to both higher GDP
levels and a lower debt to GDP ratio in the medium- and long-term relative to the current, no-policy-change baseline.
 It is important to note that in the self-financing fiscal relaxation scenarios presented in the study, the assumed values for
the above mentioned parameters broadly fall in the acceptable range of values for crisis episodes used in some recent
empirical studies conducted by the European Commission.
 Furthermore, the assumed values for the short-term multipliers are broadly in line with the multipliers for crisis-hit
economies reported in some recent empirical studies, including the ones published earlier by Eurobank Economic
Research (to our knowledge, the most comprehensive empirical studies for regime-dependent fiscal multipliers in Greece
published thus far).
 Although the empirical estimation of fiscal multipliers and the existence or not of hysteresis effects remain highly
debatable topics in leading academic and policy cycles, we believe that the present study constitutes a valuable addition
to the relevant debate.
 From a policy standpoint, we see value in revisiting/re-evaluating the agreed short-, medium- and long-run fiscal policy
path in Greece, with a view to minimizing the negative macroeconomic effects implied by the (still-demanding) targets for
the general government primary surplus.
Summary of views & key findings (continued)
Page 3
Part I
Fiscal policy relaxation in a depressed economy
Can there be a “Free Lunch” for Greece?
Page 4Source: AMECO (European Commission)
An unprecedented (and front-loaded) fiscal adjustment that inescapably
exacerbated the huge contraction of domestic output
Page 5
Structural Balance of General Government Excluding
Interest (% Potential GDP) in 2016
Source: AMECO (European Commission)
Greece currently features the highest structural fiscal balance in the EA
Page 6Source: EC Compliance Report - The Third Adjustment Programme for Greece, Second Review (Jun. 2017), Eurobank Economic Research
Gross public debt & gross financing needs (*)
(% of GDP)
European Commission’s baseline DSA scenario for Greece
EC baseline scenario
Key assumptions
(*) The depicted evolution of the public debt & GFN ratios may
deviate somewhat from what is projected in the Commission’s
DSA due to differences in some underlying assumptions
Nominal GDP growth
between 4.3% and 4.0% in 2018-
2030; 3.2% afterwards
General government primary
suplus (% GDP)
3.5% in 2018-2022; 3.0% in 2023;
2.5% in 2024; 2.2% afterwards
Privatization revenue
(full, projection horizon)
€17bn
Set aside for bank recap needs
(EUR bn)
none
Market refinancing rates (%)
5.10% in 2019; 5.50% 2021; slowly
converging thereafter towards 4.3%
by 2060
5%
7%
9%
11%
13%
15%
17%
19%
21%
23%
25%
80%
100%
120%
140%
160%
180%
200%
2017
2019
2021
2023
2025
2027
2029
2031
2033
2035
2037
2039
2041
2043
2045
2047
2049
2051
2053
2055
2057
2059
Debt (left axis) GFN (right axis)
Page 7Source: Eurobank Economic Research
How a fiscal policy intervention may affect the evolution of the debt ratio
Let us assume that a discretionary fiscal policy shock is implemented by the domestic authorities in the current
period e.g. the fiscal authority introduces measures aiming to improve (increase) the primary general government
balance by one unit.
The aforementioned intervention influences the debt to GDP ratio in the current period (and, maybe, in future periods if the
ensuing fiscal drag shows a certain degree of persistence) via the following three (3) channels:
― 1st numerator effect: fiscal intervention causes a one-to-one increase in the primary fiscal balance;
― 2nd numerator effect: the aforementioned effect is partially offset (and, in certain instances, more than outweighed) by the
impact of automatic stabilizers e.g. lower tax revenues/higher unemployment benefits due to the ensuing economic
contraction (fiscal drag);
― denominator effect: fiscal intervention causes a decline in economic activity and thus, it reduces the denominator of the
debt-to-GDP.
The first of the above mentioned effects tends to reduce the debt to GDP ratio, while the latter two tend to increase it.
 In periods when 1st numerator effect < 2nd numerator effect + denominator effect, the fiscal consolidation is self-
defeating.
 In periods when the above relationship holds for a fiscal relaxation, the said policy intervention is self-financing.
 In the case of Greece, the public debt to GDP ratio increased by c. 69.5ppts-of-GDP between 2008 and 2016, despite the
PSI exercise and the sharp improvement in the primary fiscal balance (by 9.3ppts-of-GDP) over that period.
 Clearly, the aforementioned analysis suggests that the fiscal consolidation programmes implemented in Greece over the
last several years have so far failed to stabilize the country’s public debt dynamics.
Page 8Source: Eurobank Economic Research, Bousard, J., Castro F. and Salto M. “Fiscal Multipliers and Public Debt Dynamics in Consolidation”
European Commission Economic Papers 460/July 2012
Greece: simulation exercise
Can a relaxation of the agreed medium-term fiscal target be self-financing?
In the following pages, we present the projected evolution of Greece’s gross public debt to GDP ratio under four (4)
hypothetical scenarios, denoted S1, S2, S3 & S4.
― All scenarios assume that the official target for the general government primary balance (as % of GDP) is adjusted to 2.2%,
from 2018 onwards (i.e., over the full projection horizon 2018-2060).
― For simplicity, the said intervention (in our case, fiscal relaxation vs. the assumed baseline) is hypothesized to be
exogenous, discretionary and of permanent nature i.e., not to be reversed by an offsetting policy move in the future.
― This compares with the following path for the primary balance to GDP ratio agreed at the Eurogroup of 15 June, 2017:
FY-2017: 1.75%; period 2018-2022: 3.5%; FY-2023: 3.0%; FY-2024: 2.5%; period 2025-2060: 2.2%.
― Crucially, the scenarios under examination incorporate different assumptions regarding: the first-year (impact) multiplier,
the degree of multiplier persistence and the long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation (herein, a proxy for
the existence of “hysteresis” effects).
― Furthermore, the market interest rate for refinancing Greek debt is assumed to increase by 3bps per 1ppt deviation of the
debt-to-GDP ratio from the 60% threshold. This is in line with what is assumed in the EC’s latest (June 2017) baseline
DSA analysis for Greece.
― In all scenarios under examination, the reaction of automatic stabilizers to the change in output growth caused by the
hypothesized policy intervention (herein, a permanent reduction in the primary balance to GDP target from 3.5% to 2.2%
from 2018 onwards) is captured by a cyclical semi-elasticity of government balance to the output gap of 0.42. This is in
line with the European Commission services’ calculations, as presented in Boussard et al., (2012).
Key parameter values used in the simulation exercise
 Fiscal multipliers are assumed to follow the convex, autoregressive decay path presented in page 10 of this document.
 The first-year (impact) multiplier is assumed to take the following discrete value: 0.75 (low), 1.5 (intermediate), 2.0 (high)
and 2.5 (very high). These are in line with the values assumed in some recent papers published by the European
Commission services (see e.g. Bousard et al., 2012) as well the estimates found in a couple of relevant empirical studies
for Greece, see e.g. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos, 2012 & 2013 (see also technical appendix of this document).
 α (persistence parameter): 0.30 (low), 0.60 (intermediate), 0.80 (high) and 0.90 (very high).
 β (long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation): 0.30 (high), 0.10 (intermediate), 0.0 (no long-term
impact).
 Parameters a and β are assumed to follow a normal distribution with the assumed values falling within the respective
ranges for crisis episodes reported in Boussard et al., (2012).
Page 9Source: Boussard et al. (2012); EC (2013), Eurobank Economic Research
Greece: simulation exercise
Assumed fiscal multipliers & key parameter values
scenario
acronym
Scenario
characteristics
m1
first-year (impact)
multiplier
α
persistence parameter
β
long-run impulse
response of GDP to fiscal
consolidation
fiscal target
adjusted to 2.2% of GDP
from 2018 onwards
S1
high impact multiplier
value/ high multiplier
persistence / positive long-
run GDP response to fiscal
relaxation
2.0 0.80 0.30 2.2%
S2
high impact multiplier
value/ high multiplier
persistence / positive long-
run GDP response to fiscal
relaxation
2.5 0.90 0.30 2.2%
S3
intermediate impact
multiplier value/
intermediate multiplier
persistence / positive long-
run GDP response to fiscal
relaxation
1.5 0.60 0.10 2.2%
S4
low impact multiplier
value/ low multiplier
persistence / no long-run
GDP response to fiscal
relaxation
0.75 0.30 0.00 2.2%
Page 10Source: Boussard et al. (2012); EC (2013), Eurobank Economic Research
Technical highlights
In order to incorporate multiplier persistence &
hysteresis in our simulation exercise we follow
Boussard et al. (2012)1 and European Commission
(2013)2 and assume:
Fiscal multipliers follow the following convex,
autoregressive decay path:3
mt,i = (m1 – β)αi-t + β, with t=1,...,τ and i = t, t+1,…,T
where,
m1 is the impact (i.e., first year) multiplier;
mt,i is the fiscal multiplier applying at time i to the
fiscal consolidation/relaxation done in year t (i ≥ t);
a: persistence parameter (0 <α < 1);
β: hysteresis parameter, representing the long-run
impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation/
relaxation (no assumption on the sign of β)
Α negative value of β indicates that “hysteresis” effects
are present (see e.g. de Long and Summers, 2012);
such a situation may arise when e.g. a cyclical
downturn today (vs. the assumed baseline) casts a
shadow (has a negative impact) on future potential
output.
By the same logic, a positive value of β represents a
situation in which a cyclical upturn boosts future
potential output.
For β = 0, it is assumed that there are no hysteresis
effects.
Multiplier assumptions
Modelling multiplier persistence & hysteresis
Stylized paths of GDP impulse responses
used in the simulation
1. “Fiscal Multipliers and Public Debt dynamics in Consolidations”
2. “Effects of fiscal consolidation envisaged in the 2013 Stability and
Convergence Programmes on public debt dynamics in EU Member
States”
3. This decay function reproduces relatively well the shape of the impulse-
response function by typical DSGE models for most of the permanent fiscal
shocks (see Bussard et al., 2012).
-0.4
-0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
t=1
t=2
t=3
t=4
t=5
t=6
t=7
t=8
t=9
t=10
t=11
t=12
t=13
t=14
t=15
t=16
t=17
t=18
t=19
t=20
m1=1.0; α=0.6; β=-0.2
m1=1.0; α=0.3; β=0
m1=1.0; α=0.6; β=0.2
Page 11Source: European Commission Compliance Report, The Third Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece, Second Review (Jun. 2017)
& Eurobank Economic Research
Simulation analysis - Scenarios S1, S2, S3, S4
Evolution of nominal GDP & gross public debt to GDP ratio
Green-shaded areas indicate a self-financing fiscal expansion
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2030 2040 2050 2060
Debt-to-GDP
ratio (%)
176.5 174.6 167.2 159.9 153.0 146.8 123.1 109.3 99.9 91.7
Nominal GDP
(€ bn)
181.2 187.7 195.2 203.0 210.9 219.2 287.8 397.7 545.0 746.8
Debt-to-GDP
ratio (%)
176.5 170.5 164.3 158.1 152.3 147.3 123.3 108.5 98.7 90.4
Nominal GDP
(€ bn)
181.2 192.6 199.5 206.7 214.2 222.1 289.1 398.6 545.8 747.5
Debt-to-GDP
ratio (%)
176.5 169.1 162.7 156.3 150.4 145.1 120.6 106.1 96.8 88.9
Nominal GDP
(€ bn)
181.2 193.8 200.8 208.1 215.6 223.4 290.0 399.0 545.9 747.6
Debt-to-GDP
ratio (%)
176.5 171.8 166.6 161.0 155.5 150.7 127.0 111.9 101.6 92.8
Nominal GDP
(€ bn)
181.2 191.4 197.5 204.5 211.9 219.8 288.0 398.0 545.3 747.0
Debt-to-GDP
ratio (%)
176.5 173.8 168.8 163.0 157.4 152.4 128.4 113.2 102.8 93.8
Nominal GDP
(€ bn)
181.2 189.5 195.8 203.2 211.0 219.2 287.8 397.7 545.0 746.8
European Commission
baseline
(June 2017)
Scenario S1
high impact multiplier/high
multiplier persistence /
positive long-run GDP response
to fiscal relaxation
Scenario S2
high impact multiplier/high
multiplier persistence /
positive long-run GDP response
to fiscal relaxation
Scenario S3
intermediate impact
multiplier/intermediate
multiplier persistence /
positive long-run GDP response
to fiscal relaxation
Scenario S4
low impact multiplier/low
multiplier persistence / no long-
run GDP response to fiscal
relaxation
Page 12
Part II
Technical Appendix & related literature
Page 13
Fiscal multipliers
Key definitions
The term fiscal multiplier refers to the ratio of a change in output (ΔΥ) to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance,
be it a change in government spending (ΔG) or a change in government revenue (ΔΤ) or a combination of the two.1
Depending on the time horizon considered, there are several relevant ratios that fit the term fiscal multiplier:
─ The impact multiplier, defined as the ratio of a contemporaneous change in output (at time t0) to an exogenous change in
the fiscal balance at time t0 i.e., ΔY(t0) / ΔG(to).
─ The multiplier at some future point in time (say, N period from now), defined as the ratio of a change in output at time
t0+N to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance at time t0 i.e., ΔY(t0 + N) / ΔG(to).
─ The cumulative multiplier, defined as the ratio of the cumulative change in output over an exogenous change in the fiscal
balance over a time horizon of N periods i.e., ΔY(t0 + i) / ΔG(to + i), with i = 0, 1,…,N.
─ The peak or maximum multiplier, defined as the ratio of the largest change in output over any time horizon N to an
exogenous change in the fiscal balance at time t0, i.e., max ΔY(t0 + N) / ΔG(to), for every N.
1. For a more extensive note on the relevant definitions and the determinants of fiscal multipliers see e.g. Spilimbergo et al. (2011), IMF Staff
Position Note (09/11).
Page 14
Determinants of fiscal multipliers
A bird’s eye view on the literature
Prior theoretical and empirical work on the response of main macroeconomic aggregates to exogenous fiscal shocks has
shown that the size and, in certain instances, the sign of the fiscal multiplier can be country-, estimation method-, and
economic conditions-specific. In general, it appears that quite diverse views continue to exist among economists and policy
makers as regards the quantitative and qualitative effects of fiscal policy.
As noted in e.g. Berti et al. (2013)1, many factors influence the size of fiscal multipliers. They can be grouped as follows:
i) the composition of the fiscal intervention and its credibility, as well as the fiscal rules adopted by the government; ii) the
effects of monetary policy on interest rates and the perceived riskiness of the sovereign; iii) the access of households and
companies to finance; iv) other economic factors, like price and wage flexibility, the exchange rate regime in which the
country operates and external demand.
Based on the existing literature, Berti et al. (2013) note that in case of financial crises fiscal multipliers tend to be larger than
usual (see, for instance, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2011). In particular, fiscal multipliers tend to be higher when
monetary policy is constrained by the liquidity trap (Christiano et al., 2011), economic agents are financially constrained
(Galí et al., 2007), important nominal price and wage rigidities are in place (Woodford, 2011; Andrés et al., 2012), economies
are relatively closed (Corsetti and Müller, 2012, and Ilzetzki et al., 2012) and exchange rates are irrevocably fixed, as in the
Euro Area (see, among others, Ilzetzki et al. ,2012, Corsetti et al., 2012, and Erceg and Lindé, 2012). When this is the case,
fiscal consolidation possibly entails short-term increases in the public debt-to-GDP ratio of the consolidating countries, due
to its short-term negative impact on economic activity. The higher the initial debt ratio and the greater the budget elasticity
to the cycle, the more likely this is.
One should anyway also consider that, as underlined in the literature, another key driver behind the impact of fiscal
consolidation is given by financial markets' perception of the possibility for a certain country to default on its sovereign. In
this sense, multipliers applying to consolidation efforts would not be large in instances where fiscal policy action lowers the
probability of default perceived by financial markets (see, for instance, Ilzetzki et al., 2012, Corsetti et al., 2012, and
Hernández de Cos and Moral Benito, 2013).
1. Berti K., F. Castro and M. Salto (2013) “Effects of fiscal consolidation envisaged in the 2013 Stability and Convergence Programmes on public
debt dynamics in EU Member States”, European Commission, Economic Papers 504/September 2013.
Page 15
Are fiscal multipliers regime-dependent?
Findings of a recent meta regression analysis
Compound cum. multipliers of fiscal impulses for different regimes (*)
“UPPER” for economic upturns (actual output > potential output)
“AVERAGE” (actual output in line with potential output)
“LOWER” for economic downturns (actual output < potential output)
(*) blue-bold bars: baseline specification; green-striped bars: specification with all
possible interactions
Gechert, S. and A. Rannenberg (2014) “Are Fiscal
Multipliers Regime-Dependent? A Meta Regression
Analysis” IMK Macroeconomic Policy Institute, WP
139/Sept. 2014.
The study analyzes whether estimated multiplier
effects are systematically higher if the economy suffers
a downturn.
For that purpose, a meta-regression analysis is
conducted based on a unique data set of 98 empirical
studies with more than 1800 observations on
multiplier effects.
Controlling for regime dependence of the multiplier, the
Study finds that multipliers significantly increase (by
about 0.6 to 0.8 units) during a downturn.
Moreover, spending multipliers significantly exceed tax
multipliers (by about 0.3 units) in normal times and
even more so during recessions.
Based on a broad array of empirical evidence, the
study concludes that in order to limit the adverse
consequences for growth, fiscal consolidation should
take place during the recovery and should be primarily
tax-based.
On the right side of this page, see relevant figure
presented in the aforementioned study
Page 16
How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers in Greece?
Findings of some recent empirical analyses
In two recent empirical studies on the macroeconomic effects of exogenous fiscal shocks in Greece, regime-
dependent fiscal multipliers are estimated for a range of key government revenue and expenditure categories; see
Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos, 20121 & 20132.
Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) employ a Multivariate Threshold Autoregressive Model (TVAR) to investigate the
time- and regime-dependent properties of Greece’s fiscal multiplies. Some of the most important findings of the
aforementioned study are summarized below:
― The response of real output to discretionary shocks in government current spending on goods and services and/or
government tax revenue depends on the regime in which the shock occurs as well as on the size and direction
(expansionary vs. contractionary) of the initial shock.
― In general, expansionary or contractionary shocks taking place in lower output regimes (economic downturns) appear to
have much larger effects on output - both on impact and on a cumulative basis - than shocks of similar sign and size
occurring in upper regimes (economic expansions).
― In lower regimes, the contractionary effects on output from a negative fiscal shock (spending cut or tax hike) rise with the
absolute size of the shock. The same applies for expansionary fiscal shocks (spending hikes or tax cuts). Similar effects
apply for fiscal shocks taking place in upper output regimes, though to a much lesser extent.
― Regarding the current fiscal adjustment programme in Greece, our empirical results appear to support the case for a more
gradual implementation profile of the agreed austerity package for 2013-2016. This is especially because, the
aforementioned programme is heavily front-loaded, relying mainly on steep cuts in government expenditure items that are
understood to have large fiscal multipliers e.g. wages and pensions.
― Given the overall size of Greece’s fiscal adjustment programme, our multiplier estimates suggest that Greek GDP will
decline by up to €1.89 cumulatively over a three-year period per €1 discretionary decrease in real government spending on
goods and services.
― Furthermore, our estimates argue in favor of higher public investment spending in the current depressionary environment
as a means of boosting short- and medium-term economic growth. In particular, our GIRF estimates imply among others
that for a 5% YoY positive discretionary shock in the public investment programme, real output rises by between €2.91
and €3.99 cumulatively over a 12 quarter period per €1 increase in real investment expenditure.
1. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2012) “Fiscal Multipliers in deep economic recessions and the case for a 2-year extension in Greece’s
austerity programme” Eurobank Economic Research, October 2012.
2. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) “Greek fiscal multipliers revisited: Government spending cuts vs. tax hikes and the role of public
investment expenditure” Eurobank Economic Research, March 2013.
Page 17
How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers in Greece?
Findings of some recent empirical studies
Source: Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) “Greek fiscal multipliers revisited:
Government spending cuts vs. tax hikes and the role of public investment expenditure”
Eurobank Economic Research, March 2013.
Output response to government current expenditure shocks
(G: real government spending on goods and services; T: real government taxes
net of transfers & property income; Y real output )
Page 18
On hysteresis and self-defeating/self-financing fiscal interventions
The specter of self-defeating consolidations was initially raised in Gros (2011)1, where a simple framework was utilized to
show that austerity could indeed increase the debt ratio in the short-run. In a similar vein, Delong and Summers (2012)2
suggest that in a depressed economy even a small amount of “hysteresis” - i.e., a small impact on potential output due to the
economic downturn – means, by simple arithmetic, that expansionary fiscal policy is likely to be self-financing. Although the
authors clarify that their argument “does not justify unsustainable fiscal policies, nor does it justify delaying the passage of
legislation to make unsustainable fiscal policies sustainable” it is clear that the notion of hysteresis takes particular
importance for fiscal consolidations undertaken during deep economic downturns, where multipliers are likely to be both
high and persistent i.e., their recessionary effects stretch well beyond the year when the fiscal adjustment is applied.
A number of mechanisms have been suggested in the literature to substantiate the notion of hysteresis. Some of these
include (see Delong and Summers, 2012):
― reduced labor force attachment on the part of the long-term unemployed;
― scarring effects on young workers who have trouble beginning their careers;
― reductions in government physical and human capital investments as social insurance expenditures make prior claims
on limited public financial resources;
― reduced investment both in research and development and in physical capital;
― reduced experimentation with business models and informational spillovers, and changes in managerial attitudes;
― other effects.
1. Gros, Daniel, 2012, "Can Austerity Be Self-defeating?" CEPS, Intereconomics : review of European economic policy.- Berlin : Springer, ISSN
1613-964X, ZDB-ID 2066476X. - Vol. 47.2012, 3, p. 175-184.
2. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring
2012, The Brookings Institution.
Page 19
Can an expansionary fiscal policy in a depressed economy be self-financing?
1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring
2012, The Brookings Institution.
“In a depressed economy, with short-term nominal interest rates at their zero lower bound [or with monetary policy being
constrained because of the institutional arrangements of the euro area - phase within brackets is our addition], ample cyclical
unemployment, and excess capacity, increased government purchases would be neither offset by the monetary authority
raising interest rates nor neutralized by supply-side bottlenecks. Then even a small amount of hysteresis—even a small
shadow cast on future potential output by the cyclical downturn—means, by simple arithmetic, that expansionary fiscal policy
is likely to be self-financing. Even if it is not, it is highly likely to pass the sensible benefit-cost test of raising the present value
of future potential output. Thus, at the zero bound, where the central bank cannot or will not but in any event does not perform
its full role in stabilization policy, fiscal policy has the stabilization policy mission that others have convincingly argued it lacks
in normal times. Whereas many economists have assumed that the path of potential output is invariant to even a deep
and prolonged downturn, the available evidence raises a strong fear that hysteresis is indeed a factor. Although nothing in
our analysis calls into question the importance of sustainable fiscal policies, it strongly suggests the need for caution
regarding the pace of fiscal consolidation.”
Delong and Summers (2012)1
Page 20
A reduced-form framework for assessing under what conditions fiscal
expansion is self-financing
1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring
2012, The Brookings Institution.
In line with Delong and Summers (2012)1, let us assume:
A temporary increase in government spending by ΔG, measured in percentage-point -of-potential-GDP-years.
A reduction of the present period’s output gap, Υn (“n” for “now”) by an amount ΔΥn (also measured in percentage point-
years), due to the aforementioned policy intervention:
(1) ΔΥn = μ*ΔG , where μ is the short-term (impact) multiplier coefficient
Financing this expansion of government purchases requires increasing the national debt by an amount ΔD, also measured in
percentage-point-of-potential-GDP-years. Given μ as before and assuming a baseline marginal tax-and-transfer rate t, the
required increase in the national debt is then:
(2) ΔD = (1-μτ)*ΔG.
If now the economy’s long-run growth rate is g and the real government borrowing rate is r, this additional debt ΔD imposes
on the government an annual financing burden in percentage points of a year’s potential GDP of:
(3) (r-g)*ΔD = (r-g)*(1-μτ)*ΔG , if it is to maintain a stable long-run debt-to-GDP ratio.
Assume next that in future periods production is determined by supply and that there is no gap between real aggregate
demand and potential output. Then, in a typical future period, potential and actual output Yf (where “f ” stands for “future”)
will be reduced by a hysteresis parameter η times the depth by which the economy is depressed in the present:
(4) ΔYf = η*ΔΥn = η*μ*ΔG.
A fiscal expansion undertaken to prevent hysteresis thus creates a fiscal dividend; it raises future tax collections by an
amount:
(5) τ*ΔYf = τ*η*μ*ΔG.
Equations (3) and (5) together imply that if:
(6) (r-g)*(1-μτ) - η*μ*τ ≤ 0,
then at the margin, transitory expansionary fiscal policy is self-financing.
Rearranging equation 6, we can show that this net future fiscal dividend from the present-period fiscal expansion DG arises
as long as r satisfies:
(7) r ≤ g + η*μ*τ / (1-μτ)
Page 21
Critical Values for the real effective interest rate on debt for a fiscal
expansion to be self-financing
1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring
2012, The Brookings Institution.
Parameter values for base case
Parameter Interpretation Value range
μ Present-period government spending multiplier 0-2.5
r Real government borrowing rate & social rate of time discount, per year 0.025-?
g Trend growth rate of potential GDP, per year 0.0095-0.0125
τ Marginal tax-and-transfer rate 0.33-0.40
η Hysteresis: proportional reduction in potential output from a temporary downturn 0.0-0.2
Critical Values of the Real Treasury Rate for Fiscal Expansion to Be Self-Financing
Hysteresis η μ = 0 μ = 0.5 μ = 1.0 μ=1.5 μ=2.0 μ=2.5
0.000 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00%
0.025 1.00% 1.53% 2.35% 3.76% 6.83% 18.50%
0.050 1.00% 2.06% 3.69% 6.53% 12.67% 36.00%
0.100 1.00% 3.12% 6.38% 12.05% 24.33% 71.00%
0.200 1.00% 5.24% 11.77% 23.11% 47.67% 141.00%
Critical real Treasury interest rate for individual value of
multiplier μ (% per year)
In line with Delong and Summers (2012)1,
Page 22
This document has been issued by Eurobank Ergasias S.A. (Eurobank) and may not be reproduced in any manner.
The information provided has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable but has not been verified by
Eurobank and the opinions expressed are exclusively of their author. This information does not constitute an
investment advice or any other advice or an offer to buy or sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy or sell or an offer
or a solicitation to execute transactions on the financial instruments mentioned. The investments discussed may
be unsuitable for investors, depending on their specific investment objectives, their needs, their investment
experience and financial position. No representation or warranty (express or implied) is made as to the accuracy,
completeness, correctness, timeliness or fairness of the information or opinions, all of which are subject to change
without notice. No responsibility or liability, whatsoever or howsoever arising, is accepted in relation to the
contents thereof by Eurobank or any of its directors, officers and employees.
Disclaimer

More Related Content

What's hot

Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception” Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
icgfmconference
 
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficitOTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
OTP Bank Ltd.
 
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνουγράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνουirisld
 
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥ
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥ
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥirisld
 
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνουγράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνουirisld
 
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3 The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
Swedbank
 
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
Congressional Budget Office
 
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
Alexander Decker
 
Greek Economic Outlook 2016
Greek Economic Outlook 2016Greek Economic Outlook 2016
Greek Economic Outlook 2016
Ilias Lekkos
 
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
Alexander Decker
 
Fomc Projection of US Economic data
Fomc Projection of US Economic data Fomc Projection of US Economic data
Fomc Projection of US Economic data
atul baride
 
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
Suomen Pankki
 
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
Congressional Budget Office
 
FOMC REPORT_JUNE
FOMC REPORT_JUNEFOMC REPORT_JUNE
FOMC REPORT_JUNECongyi Liu
 
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian FederationOECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
OECD Governance
 
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008Jean-Marc Lepain
 
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
Congressional Budget Office
 

What's hot (20)

Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception” Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
Lessons from the Hungarian “Exception”
 
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficitOTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
OTP Bank_Flash report 20170707_hu_deficit
 
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνουγράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γ.παπακωνσταντίνου
 
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥ
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥ
ΓΡΑΜΜΑ ΠΡΟΘΕΣΗΣ Γ.ΠΑΠΑΚΩΝΣΤΑΝΤΙΝΟΥ
 
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνουγράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνου
γράμμα πρόθεσης του γιώργου παπακωνσταντίνου
 
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3 The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
The Estonian Economy – 2010 November 3
 
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
How CBO Develops the Economic Projections Underlying Its Long-Term Budget Pro...
 
Budgeting in the Netherlands
Budgeting in the NetherlandsBudgeting in the Netherlands
Budgeting in the Netherlands
 
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
The impact of inflation, policy rate and government consumption expenditure o...
 
Greek Economic Outlook 2016
Greek Economic Outlook 2016Greek Economic Outlook 2016
Greek Economic Outlook 2016
 
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
Effects of inflation targeting policy on inflation rates and gross domestic p...
 
Fomc Projection of US Economic data
Fomc Projection of US Economic data Fomc Projection of US Economic data
Fomc Projection of US Economic data
 
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
Governor Olli Rehn: The Finnish economy in early summer 2020: The worst has n...
 
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
The Historical Decline in Real Interest Rates and Its Implications for CBO’s ...
 
FOMC REPORT_JUNE
FOMC REPORT_JUNEFOMC REPORT_JUNE
FOMC REPORT_JUNE
 
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian FederationOECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
OECD, 10th Meeting of CESEE Senior Budget Officials - Russian Federation
 
Note on relevant_factors_-_it
Note on relevant_factors_-_itNote on relevant_factors_-_it
Note on relevant_factors_-_it
 
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008
Lao PDR: Public Expenditure Mangement Review 2008
 
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
A Presentation on the Budgetary Implications of Economic Scenarios With Highe...
 
Global economy
Global economyGlobal economy
Global economy
 

Similar to Gr macro monitor july 2017

Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
petrwawrosz1
 
Report IMF for Greece - 20 july 2017
Report IMF for Greece -  20 july 2017Report IMF for Greece -  20 july 2017
Report IMF for Greece - 20 july 2017
ΟΤΟΕ
 
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal RevenueMeasurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
IJAEMSJORNAL
 
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
ilfattoquotidiano.it
 
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECDEconomic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
OECD Governance
 
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
JorgeAlbertoGuerra
 
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docxISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
christiandean12115
 
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0editorinchief
 
Fiscal Policy
Fiscal PolicyFiscal Policy
Fiscal Policy
Satyajit Chatterjee
 
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...Gamidi Saikiran
 
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
cealr
 
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyDebt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyLuyen Nguyen
 
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
erico wulf
 
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsMonetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsClaro Ganac
 
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisisCASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Center for Social and Economic Research
 
To the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 MarchTo the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 March
Swedbank
 
To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30
Swedbank
 
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the BudgetThe Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
Congressional Budget Office
 

Similar to Gr macro monitor july 2017 (20)

Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
 
Report IMF for Greece - 20 july 2017
Report IMF for Greece -  20 july 2017Report IMF for Greece -  20 july 2017
Report IMF for Greece - 20 july 2017
 
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal RevenueMeasurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
Measurement and Analysis of the Stability of Local Fiscal Revenue
 
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
Lettera Padoan Ue 21 novembre 2014
 
Download
DownloadDownload
Download
 
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECDEconomic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
Economic Environment - Christian KASTROP, OECD
 
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
Afonso et al 2022 - Do financial markets reward government spending efficienc...
 
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docxISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
ISSN 10757007, Studies on Russian Economic Development, 2014,.docx
 
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0
Cbo 2013 ltbo44521 ltbo 0
 
Fiscal Policy
Fiscal PolicyFiscal Policy
Fiscal Policy
 
9063081BMAN24091
9063081BMAN240919063081BMAN24091
9063081BMAN24091
 
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
30 ranjan kumar mohanty fiscal deficit economic growth nexus in india a coint...
 
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
Puerto Rico:
 Is there a way out with growth and dignity?
 
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyDebt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
 
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
Fiscal policy rules: Chilean Economy experience 2000-2010
 
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developmentsMonetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
Monetary and fiscal policy response and recent developments
 
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisisCASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
 
To the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 MarchTo the Point, 2010 March
To the Point, 2010 March
 
To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30To the Point, 2010, March 30
To the Point, 2010, March 30
 
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the BudgetThe Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
The Current Outlook for the Economy and the Budget
 

More from Panayotis Sofianopoulos

e_2034ada.pdf
e_2034ada.pdfe_2034ada.pdf
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσειςDigital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
a1039fek.pdf
a1039fek.pdfa1039fek.pdf
a_1021ada.pdf
a_1021ada.pdfa_1021ada.pdf
6092b-22.pdf
6092b-22.pdf6092b-22.pdf
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdf
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdfΑ1128_2022_FEK.pdf
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
a_1089_2022ada.pdf
a_1089_2022ada.pdfa_1089_2022ada.pdf
a_1089_2022ada.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
a1090_2022.pdf
a1090_2022.pdfa1090_2022.pdf
a1090_2022.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdfΥπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
2827b-22-2-8.pdf
2827b-22-2-8.pdf2827b-22-2-8.pdf
2827b-22-2-8.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
e2042-22.pdf
e2042-22.pdfe2042-22.pdf
a1056_2022.pdf
a1056_2022.pdfa1056_2022.pdf
a1056_2022.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
2152b-22-2-4.pdf
2152b-22-2-4.pdf2152b-22-2-4.pdf
2152b-22-2-4.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
e2040_2022.pdf
e2040_2022.pdfe2040_2022.pdf
e2040_2022.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
a1052_2022fek.pdf
a1052_2022fek.pdfa1052_2022fek.pdf
a1052_2022fek.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
1819b-22.pdf
1819b-22.pdf1819b-22.pdf
e_2031_2022ada.pdf
e_2031_2022ada.pdfe_2031_2022ada.pdf
e_2031_2022ada.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
aade 010422.pdf
aade 010422.pdfaade 010422.pdf
aade 010422.pdf
Panayotis Sofianopoulos
 
65a-22.pdf
65a-22.pdf65a-22.pdf

More from Panayotis Sofianopoulos (20)

e_2034ada.pdf
e_2034ada.pdfe_2034ada.pdf
e_2034ada.pdf
 
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσειςDigital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
Digital Marketing για μικρές και μεσαίες επιχειρήσεις
 
a1039fek.pdf
a1039fek.pdfa1039fek.pdf
a1039fek.pdf
 
a_1021ada.pdf
a_1021ada.pdfa_1021ada.pdf
a_1021ada.pdf
 
6092b-22.pdf
6092b-22.pdf6092b-22.pdf
6092b-22.pdf
 
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdf
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdfΑ1128_2022_FEK.pdf
Α1128_2022_FEK.pdf
 
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
69ΙΔ46ΜΤΛΡ-8Τ2.pdf
 
a_1089_2022ada.pdf
a_1089_2022ada.pdfa_1089_2022ada.pdf
a_1089_2022ada.pdf
 
a1090_2022.pdf
a1090_2022.pdfa1090_2022.pdf
a1090_2022.pdf
 
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdfΥπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
Υπόδειγμα ενημέρωσης για βεβαίωση ΕΠ.pdf
 
2827b-22-2-8.pdf
2827b-22-2-8.pdf2827b-22-2-8.pdf
2827b-22-2-8.pdf
 
e2042-22.pdf
e2042-22.pdfe2042-22.pdf
e2042-22.pdf
 
a1056_2022.pdf
a1056_2022.pdfa1056_2022.pdf
a1056_2022.pdf
 
2152b-22-2-4.pdf
2152b-22-2-4.pdf2152b-22-2-4.pdf
2152b-22-2-4.pdf
 
e2040_2022.pdf
e2040_2022.pdfe2040_2022.pdf
e2040_2022.pdf
 
a1052_2022fek.pdf
a1052_2022fek.pdfa1052_2022fek.pdf
a1052_2022fek.pdf
 
1819b-22.pdf
1819b-22.pdf1819b-22.pdf
1819b-22.pdf
 
e_2031_2022ada.pdf
e_2031_2022ada.pdfe_2031_2022ada.pdf
e_2031_2022ada.pdf
 
aade 010422.pdf
aade 010422.pdfaade 010422.pdf
aade 010422.pdf
 
65a-22.pdf
65a-22.pdf65a-22.pdf
65a-22.pdf
 

Recently uploaded

Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdfChương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
va2132004
 
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
DOT TECH
 
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
DOT TECH
 
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchangehow to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
DOT TECH
 
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptxIntro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
shetivia
 
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
ydubwyt
 
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdfWhich Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
Kezex (KZX)
 
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptxUSDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
marketing367770
 
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
DOT TECH
 
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
beulahfernandes8
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank of Ceylon PLC
 
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
lamluanvan.net Viết thuê luận văn
 
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
Antonis Zairis
 
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
DOT TECH
 
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
DOT TECH
 
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024 - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024  - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024  - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024 - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
Quotidiano Piemontese
 
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchangesWhat price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
DOT TECH
 
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
DOT TECH
 
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont BraunWebinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
FinTech Belgium
 
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securelyhow can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
DOT TECH
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdfChương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
Chương 6. Ancol - phenol - ether (1).pdf
 
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
what is the best method to sell pi coins in 2024
 
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
when will pi network coin be available on crypto exchange.
 
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchangehow to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
how to sell pi coins on Bitmart crypto exchange
 
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptxIntro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
Intro_Economics_ GPresentation Week 4.pptx
 
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
一比一原版BCU毕业证伯明翰城市大学毕业证成绩单如何办理
 
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdfWhich Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
Which Crypto to Buy Today for Short-Term in May-June 2024.pdf
 
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptxUSDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
USDA Loans in California: A Comprehensive Overview.pptx
 
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
how to sell pi coins in South Korea profitably.
 
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
The Evolution of Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs) in India: Challenges...
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - May 2024
 
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
This assessment plan proposal is to outline a structured approach to evaluati...
 
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
The new type of smart, sustainable entrepreneurship and the next day | Europe...
 
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
how to sell pi coins at high rate quickly.
 
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
The secret way to sell pi coins effortlessly.
 
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024 - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024  - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024  - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
Turin Startup Ecosystem 2024 - Ricerca sulle Startup e il Sistema dell'Innov...
 
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchangesWhat price will pi network be listed on exchanges
What price will pi network be listed on exchanges
 
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant onlinewhere can I find a legit pi merchant online
where can I find a legit pi merchant online
 
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont BraunWebinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
Webinar Exploring DORA for Fintechs - Simont Braun
 
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securelyhow can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
how can I sell/buy bulk pi coins securely
 

Gr macro monitor july 2017

  • 1. Page 0 Fiscal policy relaxation in a depressed economy Can there be a “Free Lunch” for Greece? Dr. Platon Monokroussos Group Chief Economist Eurobank Ergasias S.A. July, 2017
  • 2. Page 1  This study leans on the literature on regime-dependent fiscal multipliers and the existence of hysteresis effects to demonstrate that, under certain conditions, a further relaxation of the agreed fiscal targets for Greece could not only benefit the country’s growth outlook, but might also lead to improved (rather than worsened) fiscal dynamics in the medium- and long-run.  This, rather counter-intuitive, argument is based on the assumption that fiscal multipliers are higher (and more persistent) than usual when the economy features a massive output gap as a result of a severe recession and also that a cyclical boost in output caused by an expansionary fiscal policy move may have a permanent positive effect on future potential output.  Although quite diverse views continue to exist among professional economists and policy makers as regards the quantitative and qualitative effects of fiscal policy, a more recent strand of the relevant literature appears to support the regime-dependence of fiscal multipliers i.e., higher effects on output due to discretionary policy shocks in periods of deep economic contractions than in normal economic times or expansions.  As regards hysteresis, i.e. the notion that in a depressed economy featuring ample cyclical unemployment and excess capacity, an expansionary fiscal policy shock could prove self-financing, i.e. instigate both an improvement in the future potential output and a decline in the debt to GDP ratio in the medium- and long-term (and vice versa for the case of a contractionary fiscal policy shock), the literature has proposed a host of mechanisms to substantiate the existence of such effects.  In the case of a fiscal policy-induced cyclical downturn in an economy already featuring a sizeable negative output gap, such effects may include, inter alia, reduced labor force attachment on the part of the long-term unemployed, scarring effects on young workers who have trouble beginning their careers, lower physical and human capital investments, reduced R&D expenditure, and changes in managerial attitudes.  In Greece, an unprecedented in size (and heavily front-loaded) fiscal consolidation programme has been implemented since 2010 to engineer an internal devaluation and correct the earlier acute macroeconomic imbalances. This facilitated a huge improvement in the country’s fiscal accounts, but it has broadly failed so far to stabilize public debt dynamics. And this, despite the aforementioned fiscal adjustment as well as any beneficial effects stemming from the PSI operation and the broadly concessional interest rates currently paid on official-sector loans.  Indeed, over the period 2010-2016, the general government primary fiscal balance has improved by c. 14ppts-of-GDP (and by 19.2ppts-of-GDP in cyclically adjusted terms), while the gross public debt to GDP ratio has increased by 52.3ppts. Furthermore, real GDP losses amounted to c. 25ppts, while real potential output was at the end of 2016 lower by 13.7ppts relative to its end-2009 level (AMECO data). Summary of views & key findings
  • 3. Page 2  In view of the aforementioned, the study provides a quantitative assessment of a number of scenarios for the evolution of Greece’s GDP and other important variables such as the general government fiscal balance and the gross public debt ratio under a hypothetical permanent relaxation of the agreed target for the primary surplus, to 2.2%-of-GDP from 2018 onwards.  Assuming a range of (plausible) values for the short-term (impact) fiscal multiplier and for some other key parameters used in the exercise (e.g. multiplier persistence and hysteresis coefficients), the study demonstrates that, under certain conditions, the said fiscal policy intervention (relaxation of the primary surplus target) could lead to both higher GDP levels and a lower debt to GDP ratio in the medium- and long-term relative to the current, no-policy-change baseline.  It is important to note that in the self-financing fiscal relaxation scenarios presented in the study, the assumed values for the above mentioned parameters broadly fall in the acceptable range of values for crisis episodes used in some recent empirical studies conducted by the European Commission.  Furthermore, the assumed values for the short-term multipliers are broadly in line with the multipliers for crisis-hit economies reported in some recent empirical studies, including the ones published earlier by Eurobank Economic Research (to our knowledge, the most comprehensive empirical studies for regime-dependent fiscal multipliers in Greece published thus far).  Although the empirical estimation of fiscal multipliers and the existence or not of hysteresis effects remain highly debatable topics in leading academic and policy cycles, we believe that the present study constitutes a valuable addition to the relevant debate.  From a policy standpoint, we see value in revisiting/re-evaluating the agreed short-, medium- and long-run fiscal policy path in Greece, with a view to minimizing the negative macroeconomic effects implied by the (still-demanding) targets for the general government primary surplus. Summary of views & key findings (continued)
  • 4. Page 3 Part I Fiscal policy relaxation in a depressed economy Can there be a “Free Lunch” for Greece?
  • 5. Page 4Source: AMECO (European Commission) An unprecedented (and front-loaded) fiscal adjustment that inescapably exacerbated the huge contraction of domestic output
  • 6. Page 5 Structural Balance of General Government Excluding Interest (% Potential GDP) in 2016 Source: AMECO (European Commission) Greece currently features the highest structural fiscal balance in the EA
  • 7. Page 6Source: EC Compliance Report - The Third Adjustment Programme for Greece, Second Review (Jun. 2017), Eurobank Economic Research Gross public debt & gross financing needs (*) (% of GDP) European Commission’s baseline DSA scenario for Greece EC baseline scenario Key assumptions (*) The depicted evolution of the public debt & GFN ratios may deviate somewhat from what is projected in the Commission’s DSA due to differences in some underlying assumptions Nominal GDP growth between 4.3% and 4.0% in 2018- 2030; 3.2% afterwards General government primary suplus (% GDP) 3.5% in 2018-2022; 3.0% in 2023; 2.5% in 2024; 2.2% afterwards Privatization revenue (full, projection horizon) €17bn Set aside for bank recap needs (EUR bn) none Market refinancing rates (%) 5.10% in 2019; 5.50% 2021; slowly converging thereafter towards 4.3% by 2060 5% 7% 9% 11% 13% 15% 17% 19% 21% 23% 25% 80% 100% 120% 140% 160% 180% 200% 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027 2029 2031 2033 2035 2037 2039 2041 2043 2045 2047 2049 2051 2053 2055 2057 2059 Debt (left axis) GFN (right axis)
  • 8. Page 7Source: Eurobank Economic Research How a fiscal policy intervention may affect the evolution of the debt ratio Let us assume that a discretionary fiscal policy shock is implemented by the domestic authorities in the current period e.g. the fiscal authority introduces measures aiming to improve (increase) the primary general government balance by one unit. The aforementioned intervention influences the debt to GDP ratio in the current period (and, maybe, in future periods if the ensuing fiscal drag shows a certain degree of persistence) via the following three (3) channels: ― 1st numerator effect: fiscal intervention causes a one-to-one increase in the primary fiscal balance; ― 2nd numerator effect: the aforementioned effect is partially offset (and, in certain instances, more than outweighed) by the impact of automatic stabilizers e.g. lower tax revenues/higher unemployment benefits due to the ensuing economic contraction (fiscal drag); ― denominator effect: fiscal intervention causes a decline in economic activity and thus, it reduces the denominator of the debt-to-GDP. The first of the above mentioned effects tends to reduce the debt to GDP ratio, while the latter two tend to increase it.  In periods when 1st numerator effect < 2nd numerator effect + denominator effect, the fiscal consolidation is self- defeating.  In periods when the above relationship holds for a fiscal relaxation, the said policy intervention is self-financing.  In the case of Greece, the public debt to GDP ratio increased by c. 69.5ppts-of-GDP between 2008 and 2016, despite the PSI exercise and the sharp improvement in the primary fiscal balance (by 9.3ppts-of-GDP) over that period.  Clearly, the aforementioned analysis suggests that the fiscal consolidation programmes implemented in Greece over the last several years have so far failed to stabilize the country’s public debt dynamics.
  • 9. Page 8Source: Eurobank Economic Research, Bousard, J., Castro F. and Salto M. “Fiscal Multipliers and Public Debt Dynamics in Consolidation” European Commission Economic Papers 460/July 2012 Greece: simulation exercise Can a relaxation of the agreed medium-term fiscal target be self-financing? In the following pages, we present the projected evolution of Greece’s gross public debt to GDP ratio under four (4) hypothetical scenarios, denoted S1, S2, S3 & S4. ― All scenarios assume that the official target for the general government primary balance (as % of GDP) is adjusted to 2.2%, from 2018 onwards (i.e., over the full projection horizon 2018-2060). ― For simplicity, the said intervention (in our case, fiscal relaxation vs. the assumed baseline) is hypothesized to be exogenous, discretionary and of permanent nature i.e., not to be reversed by an offsetting policy move in the future. ― This compares with the following path for the primary balance to GDP ratio agreed at the Eurogroup of 15 June, 2017: FY-2017: 1.75%; period 2018-2022: 3.5%; FY-2023: 3.0%; FY-2024: 2.5%; period 2025-2060: 2.2%. ― Crucially, the scenarios under examination incorporate different assumptions regarding: the first-year (impact) multiplier, the degree of multiplier persistence and the long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation (herein, a proxy for the existence of “hysteresis” effects). ― Furthermore, the market interest rate for refinancing Greek debt is assumed to increase by 3bps per 1ppt deviation of the debt-to-GDP ratio from the 60% threshold. This is in line with what is assumed in the EC’s latest (June 2017) baseline DSA analysis for Greece. ― In all scenarios under examination, the reaction of automatic stabilizers to the change in output growth caused by the hypothesized policy intervention (herein, a permanent reduction in the primary balance to GDP target from 3.5% to 2.2% from 2018 onwards) is captured by a cyclical semi-elasticity of government balance to the output gap of 0.42. This is in line with the European Commission services’ calculations, as presented in Boussard et al., (2012). Key parameter values used in the simulation exercise  Fiscal multipliers are assumed to follow the convex, autoregressive decay path presented in page 10 of this document.  The first-year (impact) multiplier is assumed to take the following discrete value: 0.75 (low), 1.5 (intermediate), 2.0 (high) and 2.5 (very high). These are in line with the values assumed in some recent papers published by the European Commission services (see e.g. Bousard et al., 2012) as well the estimates found in a couple of relevant empirical studies for Greece, see e.g. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos, 2012 & 2013 (see also technical appendix of this document).  α (persistence parameter): 0.30 (low), 0.60 (intermediate), 0.80 (high) and 0.90 (very high).  β (long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation): 0.30 (high), 0.10 (intermediate), 0.0 (no long-term impact).  Parameters a and β are assumed to follow a normal distribution with the assumed values falling within the respective ranges for crisis episodes reported in Boussard et al., (2012).
  • 10. Page 9Source: Boussard et al. (2012); EC (2013), Eurobank Economic Research Greece: simulation exercise Assumed fiscal multipliers & key parameter values scenario acronym Scenario characteristics m1 first-year (impact) multiplier α persistence parameter β long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation fiscal target adjusted to 2.2% of GDP from 2018 onwards S1 high impact multiplier value/ high multiplier persistence / positive long- run GDP response to fiscal relaxation 2.0 0.80 0.30 2.2% S2 high impact multiplier value/ high multiplier persistence / positive long- run GDP response to fiscal relaxation 2.5 0.90 0.30 2.2% S3 intermediate impact multiplier value/ intermediate multiplier persistence / positive long- run GDP response to fiscal relaxation 1.5 0.60 0.10 2.2% S4 low impact multiplier value/ low multiplier persistence / no long-run GDP response to fiscal relaxation 0.75 0.30 0.00 2.2%
  • 11. Page 10Source: Boussard et al. (2012); EC (2013), Eurobank Economic Research Technical highlights In order to incorporate multiplier persistence & hysteresis in our simulation exercise we follow Boussard et al. (2012)1 and European Commission (2013)2 and assume: Fiscal multipliers follow the following convex, autoregressive decay path:3 mt,i = (m1 – β)αi-t + β, with t=1,...,τ and i = t, t+1,…,T where, m1 is the impact (i.e., first year) multiplier; mt,i is the fiscal multiplier applying at time i to the fiscal consolidation/relaxation done in year t (i ≥ t); a: persistence parameter (0 <α < 1); β: hysteresis parameter, representing the long-run impulse response of GDP to fiscal consolidation/ relaxation (no assumption on the sign of β) Α negative value of β indicates that “hysteresis” effects are present (see e.g. de Long and Summers, 2012); such a situation may arise when e.g. a cyclical downturn today (vs. the assumed baseline) casts a shadow (has a negative impact) on future potential output. By the same logic, a positive value of β represents a situation in which a cyclical upturn boosts future potential output. For β = 0, it is assumed that there are no hysteresis effects. Multiplier assumptions Modelling multiplier persistence & hysteresis Stylized paths of GDP impulse responses used in the simulation 1. “Fiscal Multipliers and Public Debt dynamics in Consolidations” 2. “Effects of fiscal consolidation envisaged in the 2013 Stability and Convergence Programmes on public debt dynamics in EU Member States” 3. This decay function reproduces relatively well the shape of the impulse- response function by typical DSGE models for most of the permanent fiscal shocks (see Bussard et al., 2012). -0.4 -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 t=1 t=2 t=3 t=4 t=5 t=6 t=7 t=8 t=9 t=10 t=11 t=12 t=13 t=14 t=15 t=16 t=17 t=18 t=19 t=20 m1=1.0; α=0.6; β=-0.2 m1=1.0; α=0.3; β=0 m1=1.0; α=0.6; β=0.2
  • 12. Page 11Source: European Commission Compliance Report, The Third Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece, Second Review (Jun. 2017) & Eurobank Economic Research Simulation analysis - Scenarios S1, S2, S3, S4 Evolution of nominal GDP & gross public debt to GDP ratio Green-shaded areas indicate a self-financing fiscal expansion 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2030 2040 2050 2060 Debt-to-GDP ratio (%) 176.5 174.6 167.2 159.9 153.0 146.8 123.1 109.3 99.9 91.7 Nominal GDP (€ bn) 181.2 187.7 195.2 203.0 210.9 219.2 287.8 397.7 545.0 746.8 Debt-to-GDP ratio (%) 176.5 170.5 164.3 158.1 152.3 147.3 123.3 108.5 98.7 90.4 Nominal GDP (€ bn) 181.2 192.6 199.5 206.7 214.2 222.1 289.1 398.6 545.8 747.5 Debt-to-GDP ratio (%) 176.5 169.1 162.7 156.3 150.4 145.1 120.6 106.1 96.8 88.9 Nominal GDP (€ bn) 181.2 193.8 200.8 208.1 215.6 223.4 290.0 399.0 545.9 747.6 Debt-to-GDP ratio (%) 176.5 171.8 166.6 161.0 155.5 150.7 127.0 111.9 101.6 92.8 Nominal GDP (€ bn) 181.2 191.4 197.5 204.5 211.9 219.8 288.0 398.0 545.3 747.0 Debt-to-GDP ratio (%) 176.5 173.8 168.8 163.0 157.4 152.4 128.4 113.2 102.8 93.8 Nominal GDP (€ bn) 181.2 189.5 195.8 203.2 211.0 219.2 287.8 397.7 545.0 746.8 European Commission baseline (June 2017) Scenario S1 high impact multiplier/high multiplier persistence / positive long-run GDP response to fiscal relaxation Scenario S2 high impact multiplier/high multiplier persistence / positive long-run GDP response to fiscal relaxation Scenario S3 intermediate impact multiplier/intermediate multiplier persistence / positive long-run GDP response to fiscal relaxation Scenario S4 low impact multiplier/low multiplier persistence / no long- run GDP response to fiscal relaxation
  • 13. Page 12 Part II Technical Appendix & related literature
  • 14. Page 13 Fiscal multipliers Key definitions The term fiscal multiplier refers to the ratio of a change in output (ΔΥ) to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance, be it a change in government spending (ΔG) or a change in government revenue (ΔΤ) or a combination of the two.1 Depending on the time horizon considered, there are several relevant ratios that fit the term fiscal multiplier: ─ The impact multiplier, defined as the ratio of a contemporaneous change in output (at time t0) to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance at time t0 i.e., ΔY(t0) / ΔG(to). ─ The multiplier at some future point in time (say, N period from now), defined as the ratio of a change in output at time t0+N to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance at time t0 i.e., ΔY(t0 + N) / ΔG(to). ─ The cumulative multiplier, defined as the ratio of the cumulative change in output over an exogenous change in the fiscal balance over a time horizon of N periods i.e., ΔY(t0 + i) / ΔG(to + i), with i = 0, 1,…,N. ─ The peak or maximum multiplier, defined as the ratio of the largest change in output over any time horizon N to an exogenous change in the fiscal balance at time t0, i.e., max ΔY(t0 + N) / ΔG(to), for every N. 1. For a more extensive note on the relevant definitions and the determinants of fiscal multipliers see e.g. Spilimbergo et al. (2011), IMF Staff Position Note (09/11).
  • 15. Page 14 Determinants of fiscal multipliers A bird’s eye view on the literature Prior theoretical and empirical work on the response of main macroeconomic aggregates to exogenous fiscal shocks has shown that the size and, in certain instances, the sign of the fiscal multiplier can be country-, estimation method-, and economic conditions-specific. In general, it appears that quite diverse views continue to exist among economists and policy makers as regards the quantitative and qualitative effects of fiscal policy. As noted in e.g. Berti et al. (2013)1, many factors influence the size of fiscal multipliers. They can be grouped as follows: i) the composition of the fiscal intervention and its credibility, as well as the fiscal rules adopted by the government; ii) the effects of monetary policy on interest rates and the perceived riskiness of the sovereign; iii) the access of households and companies to finance; iv) other economic factors, like price and wage flexibility, the exchange rate regime in which the country operates and external demand. Based on the existing literature, Berti et al. (2013) note that in case of financial crises fiscal multipliers tend to be larger than usual (see, for instance, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2011). In particular, fiscal multipliers tend to be higher when monetary policy is constrained by the liquidity trap (Christiano et al., 2011), economic agents are financially constrained (Galí et al., 2007), important nominal price and wage rigidities are in place (Woodford, 2011; Andrés et al., 2012), economies are relatively closed (Corsetti and Müller, 2012, and Ilzetzki et al., 2012) and exchange rates are irrevocably fixed, as in the Euro Area (see, among others, Ilzetzki et al. ,2012, Corsetti et al., 2012, and Erceg and Lindé, 2012). When this is the case, fiscal consolidation possibly entails short-term increases in the public debt-to-GDP ratio of the consolidating countries, due to its short-term negative impact on economic activity. The higher the initial debt ratio and the greater the budget elasticity to the cycle, the more likely this is. One should anyway also consider that, as underlined in the literature, another key driver behind the impact of fiscal consolidation is given by financial markets' perception of the possibility for a certain country to default on its sovereign. In this sense, multipliers applying to consolidation efforts would not be large in instances where fiscal policy action lowers the probability of default perceived by financial markets (see, for instance, Ilzetzki et al., 2012, Corsetti et al., 2012, and Hernández de Cos and Moral Benito, 2013). 1. Berti K., F. Castro and M. Salto (2013) “Effects of fiscal consolidation envisaged in the 2013 Stability and Convergence Programmes on public debt dynamics in EU Member States”, European Commission, Economic Papers 504/September 2013.
  • 16. Page 15 Are fiscal multipliers regime-dependent? Findings of a recent meta regression analysis Compound cum. multipliers of fiscal impulses for different regimes (*) “UPPER” for economic upturns (actual output > potential output) “AVERAGE” (actual output in line with potential output) “LOWER” for economic downturns (actual output < potential output) (*) blue-bold bars: baseline specification; green-striped bars: specification with all possible interactions Gechert, S. and A. Rannenberg (2014) “Are Fiscal Multipliers Regime-Dependent? A Meta Regression Analysis” IMK Macroeconomic Policy Institute, WP 139/Sept. 2014. The study analyzes whether estimated multiplier effects are systematically higher if the economy suffers a downturn. For that purpose, a meta-regression analysis is conducted based on a unique data set of 98 empirical studies with more than 1800 observations on multiplier effects. Controlling for regime dependence of the multiplier, the Study finds that multipliers significantly increase (by about 0.6 to 0.8 units) during a downturn. Moreover, spending multipliers significantly exceed tax multipliers (by about 0.3 units) in normal times and even more so during recessions. Based on a broad array of empirical evidence, the study concludes that in order to limit the adverse consequences for growth, fiscal consolidation should take place during the recovery and should be primarily tax-based. On the right side of this page, see relevant figure presented in the aforementioned study
  • 17. Page 16 How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers in Greece? Findings of some recent empirical analyses In two recent empirical studies on the macroeconomic effects of exogenous fiscal shocks in Greece, regime- dependent fiscal multipliers are estimated for a range of key government revenue and expenditure categories; see Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos, 20121 & 20132. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) employ a Multivariate Threshold Autoregressive Model (TVAR) to investigate the time- and regime-dependent properties of Greece’s fiscal multiplies. Some of the most important findings of the aforementioned study are summarized below: ― The response of real output to discretionary shocks in government current spending on goods and services and/or government tax revenue depends on the regime in which the shock occurs as well as on the size and direction (expansionary vs. contractionary) of the initial shock. ― In general, expansionary or contractionary shocks taking place in lower output regimes (economic downturns) appear to have much larger effects on output - both on impact and on a cumulative basis - than shocks of similar sign and size occurring in upper regimes (economic expansions). ― In lower regimes, the contractionary effects on output from a negative fiscal shock (spending cut or tax hike) rise with the absolute size of the shock. The same applies for expansionary fiscal shocks (spending hikes or tax cuts). Similar effects apply for fiscal shocks taking place in upper output regimes, though to a much lesser extent. ― Regarding the current fiscal adjustment programme in Greece, our empirical results appear to support the case for a more gradual implementation profile of the agreed austerity package for 2013-2016. This is especially because, the aforementioned programme is heavily front-loaded, relying mainly on steep cuts in government expenditure items that are understood to have large fiscal multipliers e.g. wages and pensions. ― Given the overall size of Greece’s fiscal adjustment programme, our multiplier estimates suggest that Greek GDP will decline by up to €1.89 cumulatively over a three-year period per €1 discretionary decrease in real government spending on goods and services. ― Furthermore, our estimates argue in favor of higher public investment spending in the current depressionary environment as a means of boosting short- and medium-term economic growth. In particular, our GIRF estimates imply among others that for a 5% YoY positive discretionary shock in the public investment programme, real output rises by between €2.91 and €3.99 cumulatively over a 12 quarter period per €1 increase in real investment expenditure. 1. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2012) “Fiscal Multipliers in deep economic recessions and the case for a 2-year extension in Greece’s austerity programme” Eurobank Economic Research, October 2012. 2. Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) “Greek fiscal multipliers revisited: Government spending cuts vs. tax hikes and the role of public investment expenditure” Eurobank Economic Research, March 2013.
  • 18. Page 17 How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers in Greece? Findings of some recent empirical studies Source: Monokroussos, P. and D. Thomakos (2013) “Greek fiscal multipliers revisited: Government spending cuts vs. tax hikes and the role of public investment expenditure” Eurobank Economic Research, March 2013. Output response to government current expenditure shocks (G: real government spending on goods and services; T: real government taxes net of transfers & property income; Y real output )
  • 19. Page 18 On hysteresis and self-defeating/self-financing fiscal interventions The specter of self-defeating consolidations was initially raised in Gros (2011)1, where a simple framework was utilized to show that austerity could indeed increase the debt ratio in the short-run. In a similar vein, Delong and Summers (2012)2 suggest that in a depressed economy even a small amount of “hysteresis” - i.e., a small impact on potential output due to the economic downturn – means, by simple arithmetic, that expansionary fiscal policy is likely to be self-financing. Although the authors clarify that their argument “does not justify unsustainable fiscal policies, nor does it justify delaying the passage of legislation to make unsustainable fiscal policies sustainable” it is clear that the notion of hysteresis takes particular importance for fiscal consolidations undertaken during deep economic downturns, where multipliers are likely to be both high and persistent i.e., their recessionary effects stretch well beyond the year when the fiscal adjustment is applied. A number of mechanisms have been suggested in the literature to substantiate the notion of hysteresis. Some of these include (see Delong and Summers, 2012): ― reduced labor force attachment on the part of the long-term unemployed; ― scarring effects on young workers who have trouble beginning their careers; ― reductions in government physical and human capital investments as social insurance expenditures make prior claims on limited public financial resources; ― reduced investment both in research and development and in physical capital; ― reduced experimentation with business models and informational spillovers, and changes in managerial attitudes; ― other effects. 1. Gros, Daniel, 2012, "Can Austerity Be Self-defeating?" CEPS, Intereconomics : review of European economic policy.- Berlin : Springer, ISSN 1613-964X, ZDB-ID 2066476X. - Vol. 47.2012, 3, p. 175-184. 2. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, The Brookings Institution.
  • 20. Page 19 Can an expansionary fiscal policy in a depressed economy be self-financing? 1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, The Brookings Institution. “In a depressed economy, with short-term nominal interest rates at their zero lower bound [or with monetary policy being constrained because of the institutional arrangements of the euro area - phase within brackets is our addition], ample cyclical unemployment, and excess capacity, increased government purchases would be neither offset by the monetary authority raising interest rates nor neutralized by supply-side bottlenecks. Then even a small amount of hysteresis—even a small shadow cast on future potential output by the cyclical downturn—means, by simple arithmetic, that expansionary fiscal policy is likely to be self-financing. Even if it is not, it is highly likely to pass the sensible benefit-cost test of raising the present value of future potential output. Thus, at the zero bound, where the central bank cannot or will not but in any event does not perform its full role in stabilization policy, fiscal policy has the stabilization policy mission that others have convincingly argued it lacks in normal times. Whereas many economists have assumed that the path of potential output is invariant to even a deep and prolonged downturn, the available evidence raises a strong fear that hysteresis is indeed a factor. Although nothing in our analysis calls into question the importance of sustainable fiscal policies, it strongly suggests the need for caution regarding the pace of fiscal consolidation.” Delong and Summers (2012)1
  • 21. Page 20 A reduced-form framework for assessing under what conditions fiscal expansion is self-financing 1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, The Brookings Institution. In line with Delong and Summers (2012)1, let us assume: A temporary increase in government spending by ΔG, measured in percentage-point -of-potential-GDP-years. A reduction of the present period’s output gap, Υn (“n” for “now”) by an amount ΔΥn (also measured in percentage point- years), due to the aforementioned policy intervention: (1) ΔΥn = μ*ΔG , where μ is the short-term (impact) multiplier coefficient Financing this expansion of government purchases requires increasing the national debt by an amount ΔD, also measured in percentage-point-of-potential-GDP-years. Given μ as before and assuming a baseline marginal tax-and-transfer rate t, the required increase in the national debt is then: (2) ΔD = (1-μτ)*ΔG. If now the economy’s long-run growth rate is g and the real government borrowing rate is r, this additional debt ΔD imposes on the government an annual financing burden in percentage points of a year’s potential GDP of: (3) (r-g)*ΔD = (r-g)*(1-μτ)*ΔG , if it is to maintain a stable long-run debt-to-GDP ratio. Assume next that in future periods production is determined by supply and that there is no gap between real aggregate demand and potential output. Then, in a typical future period, potential and actual output Yf (where “f ” stands for “future”) will be reduced by a hysteresis parameter η times the depth by which the economy is depressed in the present: (4) ΔYf = η*ΔΥn = η*μ*ΔG. A fiscal expansion undertaken to prevent hysteresis thus creates a fiscal dividend; it raises future tax collections by an amount: (5) τ*ΔYf = τ*η*μ*ΔG. Equations (3) and (5) together imply that if: (6) (r-g)*(1-μτ) - η*μ*τ ≤ 0, then at the margin, transitory expansionary fiscal policy is self-financing. Rearranging equation 6, we can show that this net future fiscal dividend from the present-period fiscal expansion DG arises as long as r satisfies: (7) r ≤ g + η*μ*τ / (1-μτ)
  • 22. Page 21 Critical Values for the real effective interest rate on debt for a fiscal expansion to be self-financing 1. Delong, J. Bradford & Summers, Lawrence H., 2012, "Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy “ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, The Brookings Institution. Parameter values for base case Parameter Interpretation Value range μ Present-period government spending multiplier 0-2.5 r Real government borrowing rate & social rate of time discount, per year 0.025-? g Trend growth rate of potential GDP, per year 0.0095-0.0125 τ Marginal tax-and-transfer rate 0.33-0.40 η Hysteresis: proportional reduction in potential output from a temporary downturn 0.0-0.2 Critical Values of the Real Treasury Rate for Fiscal Expansion to Be Self-Financing Hysteresis η μ = 0 μ = 0.5 μ = 1.0 μ=1.5 μ=2.0 μ=2.5 0.000 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 1.00% 0.025 1.00% 1.53% 2.35% 3.76% 6.83% 18.50% 0.050 1.00% 2.06% 3.69% 6.53% 12.67% 36.00% 0.100 1.00% 3.12% 6.38% 12.05% 24.33% 71.00% 0.200 1.00% 5.24% 11.77% 23.11% 47.67% 141.00% Critical real Treasury interest rate for individual value of multiplier μ (% per year) In line with Delong and Summers (2012)1,
  • 23. Page 22 This document has been issued by Eurobank Ergasias S.A. (Eurobank) and may not be reproduced in any manner. The information provided has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable but has not been verified by Eurobank and the opinions expressed are exclusively of their author. This information does not constitute an investment advice or any other advice or an offer to buy or sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy or sell or an offer or a solicitation to execute transactions on the financial instruments mentioned. The investments discussed may be unsuitable for investors, depending on their specific investment objectives, their needs, their investment experience and financial position. No representation or warranty (express or implied) is made as to the accuracy, completeness, correctness, timeliness or fairness of the information or opinions, all of which are subject to change without notice. No responsibility or liability, whatsoever or howsoever arising, is accepted in relation to the contents thereof by Eurobank or any of its directors, officers and employees. Disclaimer