SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 71
F A L L 2 0 1 7 I S S U E
Todd Haugh
The Trouble With
Corporate
Compliance
Programs
Companies with rigorous compliance programs hope such
programs will curtail employee wrongdoing. But to prevent
employee misconduct, companies also have to understand
how employees reach unethical decisions — and what affects
their decision-making processes.
Vol. 59, No. 1 Reprint #59110 http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs
SMR635
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs
PLEASE NOTE THAT GRAY AREAS REFLECT ARTWORK
THAT HAS BEEN INTENTIONALLY REMOVED.
THE SUBSTANTIVE CONTENT OF THE ARTICLE APPEARS
AS ORIGINALLY PUBLISHED.
MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS spend millions of dollars
per year on compliance.
In highly regulated industries such as health care and finance,
large companies spend much more,
sometimes hiring hundreds or even thousands of compliance
officers at a time.1 Siemens AG
reportedly spent more than $1 billion on an in-
ternal investigation related to a government
inquiry into the company’s payment of foreign
bribes.2 But the costs are not just financial. Com-
pliance programs are aimed at eliminating the
time-consuming and distracting regulatory and
legal processes that accompany ethical failures.
There is a belief on the part of corporate lead-
ers that when rigorous compliance programs are
in place, employee wrongdoing will largely dis-
appear. If something does go wrong, the hope is
that having a comprehensive program will help
convince regulators that the company’s compli-
ance and ethics initiatives were “effective” (the
standard set by U.S sentencing guidelines).3
Companies strive to make their programs as
“bulletproof ” as possible. Unfortunately, even
the most comprehensive programs won’t curtail
corporate wrongdoing or the government inter-
vention that follows. For instance, Volkswagen
AG’s compliance program didn’t stop employ-
ees from installing “defeat device” software to
cheat emissions tests, nor did Wells Fargo & Co.’s
The Trouble With
Corporate Compliance
Programs
B U S I N E S S E T H I C S
Companies with rigorous compliance programs hope such
programs will curtail employee wrongdoing. But to prevent
employee misconduct, companies also have to understand how
employees reach unethical decisions — and what affects their
decision-making processes.
BY TODD HAUGH
THE LEADING
QUESTION
How can
companies
increase the
effectiveness
of their
compliance
programs?
FINDINGS
�Most programs
don’t take into
account behavioral
compliance best
practices.
�Eliminating
rationalizations
is key to strengthen-
ing individual and
organizational
behavior.
FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW 55
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
56 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU
B U S I N E S S E T H I C S
policies prevent its employees from opening new cus-
tomer accounts without customers’ authorization.
More than 15 years after the Enron scandal, most
companies know very little about how employees
make ethical decisions or the psychological mecha-
nisms that cause them to perform unethical and
illegal acts. Even fewer companies have compliance
strategies aimed at curbing such behaviors.
The goal of this article is to pull together the bur-
geoning field of behavioral ethics, which provides
insight into how individuals make ethical decisions,
with the work of criminologists who study individ-
ual and corporate criminality. My aim is to help
business leaders see why their corporate compliance
efforts are falling short and how those efforts can be
improved. In addition, I will offer some practical and
cost-effective steps for improving compliance pro-
grams that focus on employee behavior — the best
way to make compliance truly effective.
Dual Systems of Thinking
Corporate compliance depends on the behavior of
individual employees. If employees, officers, and
managers always acted in a law-abiding and ethical
manner, compliance failures would rarely occur. Of
course, that is not realistic. That is why companies
need to be aware of how and why employees act the
way they do. This starts with understanding how
people make decisions generally and how that
translates into ethical decision-making.
Contrary to traditional economic theory, peo-
ple don’t make strictly rational decisions. Instead,
as the work of psychologists Daniel Kahneman and
Amos Tversky revealed, most decisions are influ-
enced by dual cognitive processes: intuitive and
reasoning.4 The intuitive process (which Kahneman
and Tversky refer to as System 1) is “fast, automatic,
effor tless, associative, and often emotionally
charged.”5 It operates by associative memory and
habit, which makes it difficult to control or modify.
A lot happens at once through System 1 — the
mind offers associations rapidly, one idea after an-
other, all linked effortlessly. The speed and ease by
which System 1 operates means that “most of the
work of associative thinking is silent, hidden from
our conscious selves.”6
The reasoning process (referred to as System 2)
is more serial and deliberate. It is engaged when we
use thought in an organized manner. We use it to
solve complex math problems, write a paragraph,
or contemplate multifaceted decisions when there
aren’t easy associations to make. System 2 thinking
gives us the “experience of agency, autonomy, and
volition.”7 Not surprisingly, the reasoning process
requires much more mental effort than using
intuition. Reasoning isn’t necessarily better than
intuitive thinking — you wouldn’t want to reason
your way through every one of your day-to-day
tasks — but for the most important decisions, it’s
critical. Yet, because System 2 thinking takes more
effort, our minds have developed to rely primarily
on System 1, reserving System 2 either for the most
challenging mental tasks or to correct errors in our
automatic thinking. This may seem fine, but re-
search shows that people often use System 2 to
justify their System 1 conclusions.8 Instead of cor-
recting errors, sometimes our reasoning process
reinforces our often flawed intuitions.
Although Kahneman and Tversky did not study
ethical decision-making directly, their findings are
critical to understanding how people make deci-
sions in an ethical context. Behavioral ethics
researchers have taken the insights of dual system
thinking and applied them to ethical decision-
making in business. They have found that while
most people intend to act ethically, good people
often do bad things.9 Indeed, research has found
that self-interest is associated with intuitive think-
ing.10 Despite this, most of us act ethically most of
the time. That is because System 2 is properly func-
tioning as an ethical monitor, jumping in to control
the automatic self-interest each of us possesses.11
Rationalizing Unethical Behavior
If System 2 is an ethical monitor, why does it seem
to fail so often? For example, what enabled VW em-
ployees to install the code used to defeat emissions
tests? Although behavioral ethics research helps us
understand how the brain works, it doesn’t explain
what allows the brain to take that critical step to-
ward unethical behavior.
This is where criminology, the study of crime
and criminals, comes in. Criminologists research-
ing white-collar crime have theorized that three
conditions are necessary for a corporate crime to
occur.12 First, an individual must possess a problem
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN
MANAGEMENT REVIEW 57
he or she feels cannot be solved by revealing it to
others. A “non-shareable problem” might be any-
thing from gambling debts to the prospect of job
loss — anything that the person is deeply con-
cerned about. Second, the individual must believe
that the problem can be solved in secret by violat-
ing a trust. As corporate leaders know, trust is an
essential element in any organization — almost
every principal-agent relationship is built upon it.
Third, the individual must have an internal dia-
logue about the problem and the unethical — even
illegal — solution that makes the trust violation
seem acceptable.13 The classic example is the banker
who tells himself he is only “borrowing” the em-
bezzled funds and will pay them back later.
The last step, which criminologists call “verbal-
izations” (and the rest of us usually refer to as
rationalizations or even excuses), is the crux of white-
collar crime. Criminologists don’t view verbalizations
as simple, after-the-fact excuses that offenders use to
relieve their culpability upon being caught. Instead,
they see them as “vocabularies of motive” — words
and phrases offenders use to make bad behavior seem
appropriate.14 This means that an offender’s rational-
izations are created before acting and actually allow
the bad act to proceed. As the criminologist who
developed rationalization theory puts it, “[t]he ra-
tionalization is [the offender’s] motivation.”15
Rationalizations, which have been identified in nu-
merous studies, permit white-collar offenders to act in
ways that they would otherwise deem unacceptable.
This is consistent with what we know about how
people make unethical decisions. Behavioral ethics
research does not suggest that everyone wants to act
ethically but fails to do so because of cognitive obsta-
cles. Rather, people default toward acting unethically
because they are driven by self-interest, and then they
find ways to convince themselves — consciously and
subconsciously — that they are acting ethically.16
This appears to be a case of System 2 justifying Sys-
tem 1 conclusions. It’s likely this process is a product
of our unique evolution. Although the ability to co-
operate with one another is one of humankind’s
greatest advantages, the best course of action from an
individual perspective is often to act in one’s self-
interest.17 Thus we have developed mechanisms to
deal with the countervailing aspects of living in our
“hypersocial” yet competitive world.18 One of the
mechanisms is to rationalize our behavior — to
reframe how we look at it in order to align our self-
perception as a “good person” with the unethical or
illegal behavior we are contemplating. There is no
better way to act self-interestedly while simultane-
ously projecting to others (and ourselves) that we are
good members of a cooperative society.
I believe that rationalization theory, which has
greatly influenced the study of both white-collar
crime and business ethics, explains what happens
when an individual’s ethical monitor is overcome.19
Essentially, rationalizations trick the System 2 reflec-
tive thinking process that normally intervenes to
contain our unethicality. Once this happens, there is
nothing to stop a person from committing an unethi-
cal or illegal act, regardless of the organizational
norms, business regulations, or criminal laws in place.
What are the most typical rationalizations? And
more importantly, how do we identify them? My re-
search suggests there are eight rationalizations most
commonly used by those committing unethical and
illegal acts within companies.20 (See “About the Re-
search.”) As part of an effective compliance program,
corporate leaders need to understand these rational-
izations and be able to identify their usage.
Denying Responsibility Offenders use this ratio-
nalization to relieve themselves of responsibility,
thereby mitigating social disapproval and a per-
sonal sense of failure. White-collar offenders deny
responsibility by pleading ignorance, suggesting
they were acting under orders, or contending that
larger economic conditions caused them to act
ABOUT THE RESEARCH
This article is part of my long-term study of the causes of
white-collar crime and
corporate wrongdoing. After approximately a decade
representing white-collar
defendants in state and federal court, advising companies on
corporate compli-
ance practices, and drafting guidelines to aid federal judges in
sentencing fraud
offenders, I found that the standard narratives of why
businesspeople commit
bad acts were misguided. This led me to criminological theory
and sociologist
Donald Cressey’s groundbreaking study of embezzlers, which
revealed the role
rationalizations play in violations of organizational trust. Using
Cressey’s research
as a point of departure, I have undertaken projects analyzing
sentencing dispari-
ties among economic crime defendants, professional athletes
who committed
and were victim to fraud, defendants convicted of the theft of
cultural heritage
resources, and numerous individual and corporate case studies
focused on the
behavioral aspects of white-collar and organizational crime.
Collectively, this re-
search has helped me identify prominent rationalizations used
by white-collar
offenders and confirmed the importance of behavioral insights
for effective cor-
porate compliance, white-collar sentencing, and criminal
legislation.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
58 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU
B U S I N E S S E T H I C S
illegally. This may be considered the “catch-all” ra-
tionalization leading to wrongful conduct.
Denying Injury This rationalization focuses on the
injury or harm caused by the illegal or unethical
act. If an act’s wrongfulness is a function of the
harm it causes, an offender often excuses his or her
behavior if no clear harm exists. Offenders employ
this rationalization when the victim is insured or
the harm is to the public or market as a whole, such
as in insider trading or antitrust cases.
Denying the Victim Denying the victim takes two
forms: when the offender argues that the victim’s ac-
tions were inappropriate and therefore the victim
deserved the harm; or when the victim is unknown
or not clearly defined. White-collar offenders often
use this rationalization when committing frauds
against the government, such as in false claims or tax
evasion cases.
Condemning the Condemners This rationaliza-
tion shifts attention away from the offender’s
conduct to the motives of others, such as regulators,
prosecutors, and government agencies. It can take
various forms: The offender calls his or her critics
hypocrites, argues that they are compelled by per-
sonal spite, asserts they are motivated by political
gain, or complains about selective enforcement.
Appealing to Higher Loyalties Individuals use
this rationalization when they are willing to sacri-
fice societal norms to advance the interests of a
group to which they belong. The actions are
needed, the offender argues, to protect a boss or
employee, shore up a failing business, or maximize
shareholder value. For example, if an employee ar-
gues that he or she committed a fraud not for
personal gain but to help the company, he is or she
is likely using this rationalization.
Using a Ledger Metaphor This rationalization is
based on a “behavioral balance sheet” whereby peo-
ple balance their negative actions against their
positive accomplishments, thus minimizing their
sense of moral guilt. Senior executives, particularly
those active in philanthropy, are especially prone to
this type of rationalization.
Claiming Entitlement People involved in em-
ployee theft and embezzlement cases frequently use
this rationalization in the belief that they deserve
the fruits of their illegal behavior. This rationaliza-
tion is also common in public corruption cases.
Claiming Relative Acceptability or Normality
This rationalization compares the offender’s bad
acts with those of others to relieve moral guilt. Tax
violators and those involved in real estate, account-
ing, and trading fraud often rationalize their
actions by citing the behavior of others. It may be
particularly prevalent when a negative organiza-
tional culture is strong and insulated.
How Rationalizations Undermine
Compliance Programs
There are plenty of practical examples illustrating
how employees rationalize behavior that leads to
compliance issues. The experiences of Intel Corp.
and Wells Fargo are instructive.
In the early 2000s, Intel adopted an aggressive ap-
proach to compliance in order to curb potential
antitrust violations by its sales executives.21 It de-
vised a program in which the company’s compliance
professionals periodically conducted random audits
in which they searched through papers, emails, and
other electronic records of managers, seizing any-
thing that might be sought as part of a government
investigation. If the company found irregularities, it
sometimes even held mock depositions of the of-
fending executives, using outside antitrust lawyers.
Intel’s general counsel explained that these role-
playing exercises served as a wake-up call, giving lax
executives the experience of being in the govern-
ment’s crosshairs. He boasted that Intel’s aggressive
approach to compliance was “the world’s best.”22
Yet Intel was unable to avoid government inter-
vention in its business. Intel spent years in private
antitrust litigation, and in 2009 the New York at-
torney general sued the company, arguing its
compliance program not only was ineffective but
had helped contribute to illegal anticompetitive
behavior by appearing to have communicated to
employees that the goal of the compliance initiatives
was to limit mention of illegal behavior, rather than
to eliminate the behavior.23 Based on my analysis of
employee emails revealed as part of the lawsuit, the
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN
MANAGEMENT REVIEW 59
company’s approach may have facilitated a host
of rationalizations, including two mentioned
above: denial of injury and denial of the victim. In
addition, employees more easily denied their re-
sponsibility, the catch-all rationalization, because
anticompetitive practices were seen as part of doing
business at Intel.
Wells Fargo’s recent difficulties appear to offer
another example of rationalized corporate wrong-
doing . The company’s fake-account scandal
demonstrates how executives can affect the context
in which employees make decisions regarding ethics.
Details of how exactly the bank’s ethics and compli-
ance program operated are still emerging, but
preliminary reports suggest it allowed an environ-
ment riddled by employee rationalizations. On the
heels of the bank’s $185 million settlement agree-
ment with the Consumer Financial Protection
Bureau, a number of former employees have re-
ported that despite ethics training and messages
from headquarters to not create fake accounts, the
bank’s aggressive sales culture drowned out any
explicit compliance measures. Essentially, the com-
pliance program failed to address the systemic
problem of managers pressuring employees to meet
unrealistic sales goals.24 “The reality was that people
had to meet their [sales] goals,” one former employee
explained. “They needed a paycheck.”25 This suggests
that employees, under pressure to meet unrealistic
goals, rationalized their conduct by denying respon-
sibility and claiming relative normality.
Combating Rationalizations
Behavioral science, coupled with criminological
insights, indicates there are complex, interwoven,
and deeply seated psychological processes at work
that can undermine even the best compliance pro-
gram. So what are companies to do? Is there a way
to do compliance better — one that solves some of
the problems created by the automaticity of
self-interest we all possess? Yes, but it requires a
fundamental shift in corporate thinking.
The best approaches to compliance focus not on
how government regulators will react to a compli-
ance initiative but on how employees — the real
“customers” of compliance — will be affected.
They consider the behavioral implications of the
compliance program at every turn, particularly
how company policies might foster or defeat em-
ployee rationalizations. While no program will
entirely change our cognitive processes or stop all
unethical behavior, there are three cost-effective
steps companies can take.
Hire a behavioral specialist. Although dual-
system thinking, rationalization, and behavioral
ethics theories have been around for decades, their
application to business and compliance is still in its
infancy. Hiring a behavioral specialist or develop-
ing someone internally to stay abreast of the
various fields and their increasing insights into eth-
ical decision-making is a good first step.
One of the tasks a behavioral specialist can take on
is to educate the organization, particularly the com-
pliance team and HR staff, on key takeaways from
current research in the fields of behavioral ethics,
behavioral economics, moral psychology, and crimi-
nology.26 Books on decision-making and dishonesty
by serious researchers, yet aimed at more general
readers, can be a helpful resource.27 A company’s
behavioral specialist should create a behavioral com-
pliance curriculum tailored to various groups of
employees, giving all members of the organization
insight into their ethical decision-making processes.
Such a curriculum can become the backbone of a
behaviorally cognizant compliance program.
Use behavioral best practices to eliminate ratio-
nalizations. To create compliance programs that
take advantage of behavioral insights instead of fall-
ing prey to them, companies must start to adopt
compliance practices driven by the behavioral
The compliance program failed to address the systemic
problem of managers pressuring employees to meet
unrealistic sales goals.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
60 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU
B U S I N E S S E T H I C S
science at the heart of criminology and behavioral
ethics. This will necessarily go beyond the traditional
law-driven compliance practices employed by the
vast majority of Fortune 500 companies.
If rationalizations are the crux of employee
wrongdoing, then compliance programs should be
aimed at eliminating them. One possibility is to ask
employees to sign a certification before they engage
in behavior that creates compliance risk. A group of
researchers working with an insurance company
asked customers to report how many miles they had
driven that year, according to the odometer.28 Re-
porting lower miles meant lower premiums. But
instead of simply asking for the number of miles, re-
searchers included a certification of honesty at the
top of the form. Customers who certified at the top
of the form, before providing their mileage number,
reported almost 2,500 more miles than those who
signed the same certification at the bottom of the
form, despite there being no difference in driving
habits.29 The certification was effective in reducing
dishonesty because it engaged morality at the mo-
ment of the decision to act ethically or unethically,
just before there was an opportunity to rationalize.
By triggering people’s System 2 ethical monitor at
the correct time, the potential for rationalization was
greatly reduced. Researchers found the same type of
results with tax deduction forms styled like those of
the U.S. Internal Revenue Service.30
A similar approach can be used by companies for
any expense report, conflict of interest form, or funds
authorization — anything in which an employee is
being asked to engage in behavior that creates com-
pliance risk. It’s up to companies to decide how
high-tech they want to get. JPMorgan Chase & Co.
has been developing software that monitors the ac-
tions of its traders, including emails and telephone
conversations, to ensure they “adhere to ‘personal
trading rules’ and risk limits,” and Credit Suisse
Group AG is also working on technology to monitor
traders’ behavior.31 JPMorgan’s effort is noteworthy
in that the software’s algorithms can generate alerts
if it appears that traders may be headed toward an
ethical or legal violation. Such “predictive monitor-
ing,” like a certification at the top of a paper form,
could be used by companies to intervene with a
prompt before a problematic behavior occurs, forc-
ing the employee’s System 2 reasoning system to
engage — and thus improving compliance.
Companies should also encourage employees to
openly discuss rationalizations and how they affect
ethical decision-making. This can be accomplished
through storytelling by employees and the company.
Employees should be encouraged, even required, to
meet periodically in small groups to explore the poten-
tial effects of compliance violations and white-collar
crimes. The idea is for employees, guided by compli-
ance professionals (or, better yet, senior managers), to
discuss topics such as what regulations are relevant to
the business, common compliance pitfalls, and how
some business practices produce externalities that
negatively impact stakeholders. When rationalizing
statements pop up, as they inevitably will, they should
be identified and flagged. Only after patterns of self-
exculpatory rationalization are openly discussed and
labeled as problematic will employees be able to inter-
nalize that knowledge and use it when presented with
an opportunity to act unethically.32
The company also should share stories of genu-
ine compliance successes. Compliance messaging is
most effective when it conveys that positive behaviors
are widely engaged in and approved of within a com-
pany.33 The reason is related to the claim of relative
normality rationalization, which allows individuals
to favorably compare their potential unethical act to
the unethical acts of others. Positive compliance mes-
saging combats this rationalization by demonstrating
that while there may be isolated compliance lapses,
the majority of the company is committed to making
ethical decisions.
Compliance messaging is most effective when it conveys
that positive behaviors are widely engaged in and approved
of within a company.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN
MANAGEMENT REVIEW 61
One company that has used storytelling and dis-
cussions effectively in its ethics program is Parsons
Corp., an international engineering and construc-
tion company based in Pasadena, California. The
company hosts an internal website where it has
posed hypothetical ethical problems and asked em-
ployees to vote on how they should be resolved. It
then has published the narrative comments anony-
mously and followed up with a detailed analysis by
the company’s ethics committee. Such practices
serve to unite employees around the company’s val-
ues as applied to real-life scenarios. Through the
narratives, employees themselves identify common
ethical traps and rationalizations.34 Periodically
posing ethics challenges and quizzes to employees
is one of a number of techniques Parsons uses in its
award-winning ethics and compliance program.35
Use incentives to influence behavior in the right
direction. Behavioral ethics research has shown that
even seemingly inconsequential factors can greatly
influence ethical decision-making. This is especially
true when considering how rationalizations can be
drawn from a company’s internal culture, a large part
of which depends on incentive structures. This is one
of the early lessons from Wells Fargo, where the social
and monetary incentives to cross-sell products
swamped the company’s compliance protocols.
What’s more, Wells Fargo is not an isolated example;
prior research has found that when major corporate
trust violations occur, the root cause often has less to
do with a rogue employee than with elements of the
organization that are “dysfunctional, conflicting, or
incongruent.”36 As a result, executives need to be
aware of the common forms of rationalization de-
scribed earlier in this article — and examine where in
their organizations conflicting incentives could foster
rationalization and wrongdoing.
To that end, business leaders can tap nonmonetary
incentives to aid in compliance. According to research,
praise and expressions of gratitude motivate more
than money, and social group interactions motivate
individual behavior more than almost anything.37
That means the most effective compliance likely
comes from something other than salary and bonus.
Research also shows that compliance is most effective
when employees perceive it not as a constraint but as
“the governing ethos of an organization.”38 The goal,
then, is for companies to build a corporate culture
that incentivizes the rejection of rationalizations
through the creation of shared values.
No compliance program will entirely eliminate
bad employee conduct. But behaviorally cognizant
programs, ones that seek to understand employee
decision-making and target the cognitive mecha-
nisms that foster unethicality, hold the promise of
achieving the primary goals of compliance: reducing
unethical and illegal behavior within the company.
Todd Haugh is an assistant professor of business law
and ethics at Indiana University’s Kelley School of Busi-
ness in Bloomington, Indiana, as well as a Jesse Fine
Fellow at the Poynter Center for the Study of Ethics and
American Institutions at Indiana University. Comment
on this article at http://sloanreview.mit.edu/x/59110, or
contact the author at [email protected]
REFERENCES
1. S.J. Griffith, “Corporate Governance in an Era of
Compliance,” William & Mary Law Review 57, no. 6
(May 2016) 2102-2103; and R.M. Steinberg, “The High
Cost of Non-Compliance: Reaping the Rewards of an
Effective Compliance Program” (February 2010,
www.securityexecutivecouncil.com.
2. P.J. Henning, “The Mounting Costs of Internal
Investigations,” The New York Times, March 5, 2012,
http://dealbook.nytimes.com.
3. United States Sentencing Guidelines Manual, chapter 8
(2016), www.ussc.gov.
4. Kahneman and Tversky’s work was popularized with
the publication of Kahenman’s 2011 book; see D. Kahne-
man, “Thinking, Fast and Slow” (New York: Farrar, Straus
and Giroux, 2011), 20-24. However, their work spanned
decades. See, for example, D. Kahneman, “Maps of
Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Econom-
ics,” American Economics Review 93, no. 5 (December
2003): 1449-1450.
Executives need to be aware of the common forms of
rationalization described earlier in this article — and examine
where in their organization conflicting incentives could foster
rationalization and wrongdoing.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
62 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017
SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU
B U S I N E S S E T H I C S
5. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1451.
6. Kahneman, “Thinking, Fast and Slow,” 52.
7. P.G. Hansen and A.M. Jespersen, “Nudge and the
Manipulation of Choice: A Framework for the Responsi-
ble Use of the Nudge Approach to Behaviour Change in
Public Policy,” European Journal of Risk Regulation 4,
no. 1 (March 2013): 13.
8. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1467.
9. R.A. Prentice, “Behavioral Ethics: Can It Help Lawyers
(and Others) Be Their Best Selves?” Notre Dame Journal
of Law, Ethics & Public Policy 29, no. 1 (2015): 36.
10. Y. Feldman, “Behavioral Ethics Meets Behavioral Law
and Economics,” in “The Oxford Handbook of Behavioral
Economics and the Law,” eds. E. Zamir and D. Teichman
(New York: Oxford University Press 2014), 8. See also
D.A. Moore and G. Loewenstein, “Self-Interest, Automa-
ticity, and the Psychology of Conflict of Interest,” Social
Justice Research 17, no. 2 (2004): 190.
11. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1467.
12. E.H. Sutherland, “White Collar Crime: The Uncut
Version” (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press,
1983), 240. For a succinct discussion of Sutherland’s
groundbreaking theories on white-collar crime, see E.H.
Sutherland and D.R. Cressey, “A Sociological Theory of
Criminal Behavior,” in “Delinquency, Crime, and Social
Process,” eds. D.R. Cressey and D.A. Ward (New York:
Harper & Row, 1969), 429-443.
13. D.R. Cressey, “The Respectable Criminal: Why Some
of Our Best Friends Are Crooks,” Criminologica 3, no. 1
(May 1965): 14-15.
14. Ibid.
15. D.R. Cressey, “Other People’s Money: A Study in the
Social Psychology of Embezzlement” (New York: Free
Press, 1953), 95.
16. Feldman, “Behavioral Ethics Meets Behavioral Law
and Economics,” 17.
17. E. Kolbert, “That’s What You Think: Why Reason and
Evidence Won’t Change Our Minds,” The New Yorker, Feb.
27, 2017, 66, citing H. Mercier and D. Sperber, “The Enigma
of Reason: A New Theory of Human Understanding” (Cam-
bridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 2017).
18. Mercier and Sperber, “The Enigma of Reason.”
19. S. Maruna and H. Copes, “What Have We Learned
from Five Decades of Neutralization Research?” Crime
and Justice 32 (2005): 222. See also B.E. Ashforth and
V. Anand, “The Normalization of Corruption in Organiza-
tions,” Research in Organizational Behavior 25 (2003): 2-5.
20. This section is adapted from a series of articles the
author has written concerning white-collar crime and
corporate compliance. See, for example, T. Haugh, “The
Criminalization of Compliance,” Notre Dame Law Review
92, no. 3 (April 2016): 1255-58; T. Haugh, “Overcriminal-
ization’s New Harm Paradigm,” Vanderbilt Law Review
68, no. 5 (October 2015): 1218-1222; T. Haugh, “Sentenc-
ing the Why of White Collar Crime,” Fordham Law
Review 82, no. 6 (2014): 3165-3169.
21. D.B. Yoffie and M. Kwak, “Playing by the Rules:
How Intel Avoids Antitrust Litigation,” Harvard Business
Review 79, no. 6 (June 2001): 120-121.
22. Ibid., 120.
23. Complaint, New York v. Intel Corp., No. 1:09-cv-00827-
UNA (D. Del. Nov. 4, 2009): 19-20.
24. “Independent Directors of the Board of Wells Fargo
& Company Sales Practices Investigations Report”
(April 10, 2017): 37-38.
25. M. Corkery and S. Cowley, “Wells Fargo Warned
Workers Against Sham Accounts, but ‘They Needed a
Paycheck,’” The New York Times, Sept. 16, 2016,
www.nytimes.com.
26. See, for example, D. De Cremer and A.E. Tenbrunsel,
eds., “Behavioral Business Ethics: Shaping an Emerging
Field” (New York: Routledge, 2011), 3-10.
27. R.H. Thaler and C.R. Sunstein, “Nudge: Improving
Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness” (New
Haven: Yale University Press, 2008); D. Ariely, “The Hon-
est Truth About Dishonesty” (New York: HarperCollins,
2012); and Kahneman, “Thinking, Fast and Slow.”
28. L.L. Shu, N. Mazar, F. Gino, D. Ariely, and M.H. Bazer-
man, “Signing at the Beginning Makes Ethics Salient and
Decreases Dishonest Self-Reports in Comparison to Sign-
ing at the End,” Psychological and Cognitive Sciences
109, no. 38 (Sept. 18, 2012): 15198.
29. Ibid.
30. Ariely, “The Honest Truth,” 45-48.
31. P. Crowe, “JP Morgan Is Working on a New Employee
Surveillance Program,” Business Insider, April 8, 2015,
www.businessinsider.com; and K. Scannell and H. Kuchler,
“Palantir and Credit Suisse Join Forces to Target Rogue
Traders,” Financial Times, March 22, 2016, www.ft.com.
32. J. Heath, “Business Ethics and Moral Motivation: A
Criminological Perspective,” Journal of Business Ethics
83, no. 4 (December 2008): 611.
33. R.B. Cialdini, L.J. Demaine, B.J. Sagarin, D.W. Barrett,
K. Rhoads, and P.L. Winter, “Managing Social Norms for
Persuasive Impact,” Social Influence 1, no.1 (2006): 13;
and S. Killingsworth, “Modeling the Message: Communi-
cating Compliance through Organizational Values and
Culture,” Georgetown Journal of Legal Ethics 25, no. 4
(fall 2012): 983.
34. Killingsworth, “Modeling the Message,” 983.
35. “Parsons: People. Planet. Progress. 2017 Corporate
Social Responsibility Report,” www.parsons.com, 51.
36. R.F. Hurley, N. Gillespie, D.L. Ferrin, and G. Dietz,
“Designing Trustworthy Organizations,” MIT Sloan
Management Review 54, no. 4 (summer 2013): 75-82.
37. A.M. Grant and F. Gino, “A Little Thanks Goes a Long
Way: Explaining Why Gratitude Expressions Motivate
Prosocial Behavior,” Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology 98, no. 6 (June 2010): 953; Cialdini et al.,
“Managing Social Norms for Persuasive Impact,” 13.
38. See L.S. Paine, “Managing for Organizational Integ-
rity,” Harvard Business Review 72, no. 2 (March-April
1994): 106-107.
Reprint 59110.
Copyright © Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2017.
All rights reserved.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
PDFs Reprints Permission to Copy Back Issues
Articles published in MIT Sloan Management Review are
copyrighted by the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology unless otherwise
specified at the end of an
article.
MIT Sloan Management Review articles, permissions, and back
issues can be
purchased on our Web site: sloanreview.mit.edu or you may
order through our
Business Service Center (9 a.m.-5 p.m. ET) at the phone
numbers listed below.
Paper reprints are available in quantities of 250 or more.
To reproduce or transmit one or more MIT Sloan Management
Review articles by
electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying or
archiving in any
information storage or retrieval system) requires written
permission.
To request permission, use our Web site: sloanreview.mit.edu
or
E-mail: [email protected]
Call (US and International):617-253-7170 Fax: 617-258-9739
Posting of full-text SMR articles on publicly accessible Internet
sites is
prohibited. To obtain permission to post articles on secure
and/or password-
protected intranet sites, e-mail your request to [email protected]
MITMIT SLSLOOAN MANAAN MANAGEMENGEMENT
REVIEWT REVIEW
LEADERSHIPLEADERSHIP
Copyright © Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2017. All
rights reserved. Reprint #59110 http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://sloanreview.mit.edu
http://sloanreview.mit.edu
mailto:[email protected]
mailto:[email protected]
http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjsd41d8cd98f00b204e9800998ecf8427e
-3.pdfThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsThe
Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsDual Systems of
ThinkingRationalizing Unethical BehaviorAbout the
ResearchDenying ResponsibilityDenying InjuryDenying the
VictimCondemning the CondemnersAppealing to Higher
LoyaltiesUsing a Ledger MetaphorClaiming
EntitlementClaiming Relative Acceptability or NormalityHow
Rationalizations Undermine Compliance ProgramsCombating
RationalizationsAbout the
AuthorReferencesd41d8cd98f00b204e9800998ecf8427e-
24.pdfFall 2017 IssueThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance
ProgramsThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance
ProgramsDual Systems of ThinkingRationalizing Unethical
BehaviorAbout the ResearchDenying ResponsibilityDenying
InjuryDenying the VictimCondemning the
CondemnersAppealing to Higher LoyaltiesUsing a Ledger
MetaphorClaiming EntitlementClaiming Relative Acceptability
or NormalityHow Rationalizations Undermine Compliance
ProgramsCombating RationalizationsAbout the
AuthorReferences
HBR.ORG DECEMBER 2015
REPRINT R1512B
THE BIG IDEA
What Is Disruptive
Innovation?
Twenty years after the introduction of the theory, we revisit
what it does—and doesn’t—explain.
by Clayton M. Christensen, Michael Raynor, and Rory
McDonald
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org
http://hbr.org/search/R1512B
THE BIG IDEA
WHAT IS
2 Harvard Business Review December 2015
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
Twenty years after the
introduction of the
theory, we revisit
what it does—and
doesn’t—explain.
BY CLAYTON M.
CHRISTENSEN,
MICHAEL RAYNOR,
AND RORY MCDONALD
Clayton M. Christensen is
the Kim B. Clark Professor
of Business Administration
at Harvard Business
School. Michael Raynor
is a director at Deloitte
Consulting LLP. Rory
McDonald is an assistant
professor at Harvard
Business School.
December 2015 Harvard Business Review 3
FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783-
7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org
The problem with conflating a disruptive in-
novation with any breakthrough that changes an
industry’s competitive patterns is that different
types of innovation require different strategic ap-
proaches. To put it another way, the lessons we’ve
learned about succeeding as a disruptive innovator
(or defending against a disruptive challenger) will
not apply to every company in a shifting market.
If we get sloppy with our labels or fail to integrate
insights from subsequent research and experience
into the original theory, then managers may end
up using the wrong tools for their context, reduc-
ing their chances of success. Over time, the theory’s
usefulness will be undermined.
This article is part of an effort to capture the state
of the art. We begin by exploring the basic tenets of
disruptive innovation and examining whether they
apply to Uber. Then we point out some common
pitfalls in the theory’s application, how these arise,
and why correctly using the theory matters. We go
on to trace major turning points in the evolution of
our thinking and make the case that what we have
learned allows us to more accurately predict which
businesses will grow.
First, a quick recap of the idea: “Disruption” de-
scribes a process whereby a smaller company with
fewer resources is able to successfully challenge
established incumbent businesses. Specifically, as
incumbents focus on improving their products
and services for their most demanding (and usually
most profitable) customers, they exceed the needs
of some segments and ignore the needs of others.
Entrants that prove disruptive begin by success-
fully targeting those overlooked segments, gaining a
foothold by delivering more-suitable functionality—
frequently at a lower price. Incumbents, chasing
higher profitability in more-demanding segments,
tend not to respond vigorously. Entrants then move
upmarket, delivering the performance that incum-
bents’ mainstream customers require, while pre-
serving the advantages that drove their early success.
When mainstream customers start adopting the en-
trants’ offerings in volume, disruption has occurred.
(See the exhibit “The Disruptive Innovation Model.”)
Is Uber a Disruptive Innovation?
Let’s consider Uber, the much-feted transportation
company whose mobile application connects con-
sumers who need rides with drivers who are willing
to provide them. Founded in 2009, the company has
Unfortunately, disruption theory is in danger of
becoming a victim of its own success. Despite broad
dissemination, the theory’s core concepts have
been widely misunderstood and its basic tenets fre-
quently misapplied. Furthermore, essential refine-
ments in the theory over the past 20 years appear to
have been overshadowed by the popularity of the
initial formulation. As a result, the theory is some-
times criticized for shortcomings that have already
been addressed.
There’s another troubling concern: In our expe-
rience, too many people who speak of “disruption”
have not read a serious book or article on the subject.
Too frequently, they use the term loosely to invoke
the concept of innovation in support of whatever it is
they wish to do. Many researchers, writers, and con-
sultants use “disruptive innovation” to describe any
situation in which an industry is shaken up and pre-
viously successful incumbents stumble. But that’s
much too broad a usage.
he theory of disruptive
innovation, introduced
in these pages in 1995,
has proved to be a
powerful way of thinking about
innovation-driven growth.
Many leaders of small,
entrepreneurial companies
praise it as their guiding star;
so do many executives at
large, well-established
organizations, including Intel,
Southern New Hampshire
University, and Salesforce.com.
THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION?
4 Harvard Business Review December 20154 Harvard
Business Review December 2015 COPYRIGHT © 2015
HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PUBLISHING
CORPORATION. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED.
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
enjoyed fantastic growth (it operates in hundreds of
cities in 60 countries and is still expanding). It has
reported tremendous financial success (the most
recent funding round implies an enterprise value in
the vicinity of $50 billion). And it has spawned a slew
of imitators (other start-ups are trying to emulate its
“market-making” business model). Uber is clearly
transforming the taxi business in the United States.
But is it disrupting the taxi business?
According to the theory, the answer is no. Uber’s
financial and strategic achievements do not qualify
the company as genuinely disruptive—although the
company is almost always described that way. Here
are two reasons why the label doesn’t fit.
Disruptive innovations originate in low-end
or new-market footholds. Disruptive innovations
are made possible because they get started in two
types of markets that incumbents overlook. Low-
end footholds exist because incumbents typically
try to provide their most profitable and demanding
customers with ever-improving products and ser-
vices, and they pay less attention to less-demanding
customers. In fact, incumbents’ offerings often over-
shoot the performance requirements of the latter.
This opens the door to a disrupter focused (at first)
on providing those low-end customers with a “good
enough” product.
In the case of new-market footholds, disrupt-
ers create a market where none existed. Put simply,
they find a way to turn nonconsumers into consum-
ers. For example, in the early days of photocopying
technology, Xerox targeted large corporations and
charged high prices in order to provide the perfor-
mance that those customers required. School librar-
ians, bowling-league operators, and other small
customers, priced out of the market, made do with
carbon paper or mimeograph machines. Then in
the late 1970s, new challengers introduced personal
Idea in Brief
THE ISSUE
The ideas summed up in the
phrase “disruptive innovation”
have become a powerful part
of business thinking—but
they’re in danger of losing
their usefulness because
they’ve been misunderstood
and misapplied.
THE RESPONSE
The leading authorities
on disruptive innovation
revisit the central tenets
of disruption theory, its
development over the past
20 years, and its limitations.
THE BOTTOM LINE
Does it matter whether Uber,
say, is a disruptive innovation
or something else entirely?
It does: We can’t manage
innovation effectively if we
don’t grasp its true nature.
copiers, offering an affordable solution to individu-
als and small organizations—and a new market was
created. From this relatively modest beginning, per-
sonal photocopier makers gradually built a major
position in the mainstream photocopier market that
Xerox valued.
A disruptive innovation, by definition, starts
from one of those two footholds. But Uber did not
originate in either one. It is difficult to claim that the
company found a low-end opportunity: That would
have meant taxi service providers had overshot the
needs of a material number of customers by mak-
ing cabs too plentiful, too easy to use, and too clean.
Neither did Uber primarily target nonconsumers—
people who found the existing alternatives so expen-
sive or inconvenient that they took public transit or
drove themselves instead: Uber was launched in San
Francisco (a well-served taxi market), and Uber’s
customers were generally people already in the habit
of hiring rides.
Uber has quite arguably been increasing total
demand—that’s what happens when you develop
a better, less-expensive solution to a widespread
customer need. But disrupters start by appealing to
low-end or unserved consumers and then migrate to
the mainstream market. Uber has gone in exactly the
opposite direction: building a position in the main-
stream market first and subsequently appealing to
historically overlooked segments.
Disruptive innovations don’t catch on with
mainstream customers until quality catches
up to their standards. Disruption theory differ-
entiates disruptive innovations from what are called
“sustaining innovations.” The latter make good prod-
ucts better in the eyes of an incumbent’s existing
customers: the fifth blade in a razor, the clearer TV
picture, better mobile phone reception. These im-
provements can be incremental advances or major
December 2015 Harvard Business Review 5
FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783-
7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org
breakthroughs, but they all enable firms to sell more
products to their most profitable customers.
Disruptive innovations, on the other hand, are
initially considered inferior by most of an incum-
bent’s customers. Typically, customers are not will-
ing to switch to the new offering merely because it
is less expensive. Instead, they wait until its quality
rises enough to satisfy them. Once that’s happened,
they adopt the new product and happily accept its
lower price. (This is how disruption drives prices
down in a market.)
Most of the elements of Uber’s strategy seem to
be sustaining innovations. Uber’s service has rarely
been described as inferior to existing taxis; in fact,
many would say it is better. Booking a ride requires
just a few taps on a smartphone; payment is cash-
less and convenient; and passengers can rate their
rides afterward, which helps ensure high standards.
Furthermore, Uber delivers service reliably and
punctually, and its pricing is usually competitive
with (or lower than) that of established taxi services.
And as is typical when incumbents face threats from
sustaining innovations, many of the taxi compa-
nies are motivated to respond. They are deploying
competitive technologies, such as hailing apps, and
contesting the legality of some of Uber’s services.
Why Getting It Right Matters
Readers may still be wondering, Why does it matter
what words we use to describe Uber? The company
has certainly thrown the taxi industry into disarray:
Isn’t that “disruptive” enough? No. Applying the
theory correctly is essential to realizing its benefits.
For example, small competitors that nibble away at
the periphery of your business very likely should be
ignored—unless they are on a disruptive trajectory,
in which case they are a potentially mortal threat.
And both of these challenges are fundamentally
different from efforts by competitors to woo your
bread-and-butter customers.
As the example of Uber shows, identifying true
disruptive innovation is tricky. Yet even executives
with a good understanding of disruption theory tend
to forget some of its subtler aspects when making
strategic decisions. We’ve observed four important
points that get overlooked or misunderstood:
1. Disruption is a process. The term “disrup-
tive innovation” is misleading when it is used to refer
to a product or service at one fixed point, rather than
to the evolution of that product or service over time.
The first minicomputers were disruptive not merely
because they were low-end upstarts when they ap-
peared on the scene, nor because they were later
heralded as superior to mainframes in many mar-
kets; they were disruptive by virtue of the path they
followed from the fringe to the mainstream.
Most every innovation—disruptive or not—
begins life as a small-scale experiment. Disrupters
tend to focus on getting the business model, rather
than merely the product, just right. When they suc-
ceed, their movement from the fringe (the low end
of the market or a new market) to the mainstream
erodes first the incumbents’ market share and then
their profitability. This process can take time, and
incumbents can get quite creative in the defense
of their established franchises. For example, more
than 50 years after the first discount department
store was opened, mainstream retail companies still
operate their traditional department-store formats.
Complete substitution, if it comes at all, may take
decades, because the incremental profit from stay-
ing with the old model for one more year trumps
proposals to write off the assets in one stroke.
The fact that disruption can take time helps to
explain why incumbents frequently overlook dis-
rupters. For example, when Netflix launched, in
1997, its initial service wasn’t appealing to most
of Blockbuster’s customers, who rented movies
(typically new releases) on impulse. Netflix had an
exclusively online interface and a large inventory of
isrupters first appeal to
low-end or unserved
customers and then
migrate to the mainstream
market. Uber has gone in the
opposite direction: building
a position in the mainstream
market first and then appealing
to historically overlooked segments.
THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION?
6 Harvard Business Review December 2015
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
movies, but delivery through the U.S. mail meant
selections took several days to arrive. The service ap-
pealed to only a few customer groups—movie buffs
who didn’t care about new releases, early adopters of
DVD players, and online shoppers. If Netflix had not
eventually begun to serve a broader segment of the
market, Blockbuster’s decision to ignore this com-
petitor would not have been a strategic blunder: The
two companies filled very different needs for their
(different) customers.
However, as new technologies allowed Netflix
to shift to streaming video over the internet, the
company did eventually become appealing to
Blockbuster’s core customers, offering a wider se-
lection of content with an all-you-can-watch, on-
demand, low-price, high-quality, highly convenient
approach. And it got there via a classically disruptive
path. If Netflix (like Uber) had begun by launching a
service targeted at a larger competitor’s core market,
Blockbuster’s response would very likely have been
a vigorous and perhaps successful counterattack.
But failing to respond effectively to the trajectory
that Netflix was on led Blockbuster to collapse.
2. Disrupters often build business models
that are very different from those of incum-
bents. Consider the health care industry. General
practitioners operating out of their offices often rely
on their years of experience and on test results to
interpret patients’ symptoms, make diagnoses, and
prescribe treatment. We call this a “solution shop”
business model. In contrast, a number of conve-
nient care clinics are taking a disruptive path by us-
ing what we call a “process” business model: They
follow standardized protocols to diagnose and treat
a small but increasing number of disorders.
One high-profile example of using an innova-
tive business model to effect a disruption is Apple’s
iPhone. The product that Apple debuted in 2007 was
a sustaining innovation in the smartphone market: It
targeted the same customers coveted by incumbents,
and its initial success is likely explained by product
superiority. The iPhone’s subsequent growth is bet-
ter explained by disruption—not of other smart-
phones but of the laptop as the primary access
point to the internet. This was achieved not merely
through product improvements but also through the
THE DISRUPTIVE
INNOVATION MODEL
This diagram contrasts product
performance trajectories (the red
lines showing how products or
services improve over time) with
customer demand trajectories
(the blue lines showing customers’
willingness to pay for performance).
As incumbent companies introduce
higher-quality products or services
(upper red line) to satisfy the
high end of the market (where
profitability is highest), they
overshoot the needs of low-end
customers and many mainstream
customers. This leaves an opening
for entrants to find footholds in
the less-profitable segments that
incumbents are neglecting. Entrants
on a disruptive trajectory (lower red
line) improve the performance of
their offerings and move upmarket
(where profitability is highest
for them, too) and challenge the
dominance of the incumbents.
HIGHER
LOWER
PR
O
D
U
C
T
PE
R
FO
R
M
A
N
C
E
TIME
INC
UM
BE
NT
’S S
US
TA
INI
NG
TR
AJ
EC
TO
RY
EN
TR
AN
T’S
DI
SR
UP
TIV
E T
RA
JEC
TO
RY
MAINST
REAM
LOW EN
D
OF THE
MARKE
T
LEAST P
ROFITA
BLE
PERFOR
MANCE
CUSTO
MERS W
ILL PAY
FOR
HIGH E
ND
OF THE
MARKE
T
MOST P
ROFITA
BLE
December 2015 Harvard Business Review 7
FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783-
7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org
introduction of a new business model. By building a
facilitated network connecting application develop-
ers with phone users, Apple changed the game. The
iPhone created a new market for internet access and
eventually was able to challenge laptops as main-
stream users’ device of choice for going online.
3. Some disruptive innovations succeed;
some don’t. A third common mistake is to focus
on the results achieved—to claim that a company
is disruptive by virtue of its success. But success is
not built into the definition of disruption: Not every
disruptive path leads to a triumph, and not every tri-
umphant newcomer follows a disruptive path.
For example, any number of internet-based re-
tailers pursued disruptive paths in the late 1990s, but
only a small number prospered. The failures are not
evidence of the deficiencies of disruption theory;
they are simply boundary markers for the theory’s
application. The theory says very little about how
to win in the foothold market, other than to play
the odds and avoid head-on competition with
better-resourced incumbents.
If we call every business success a “disruption,”
then companies that rise to the top in very differ-
ent ways will be seen as sources of insight into a
common strategy for succeeding. This creates a dan-
ger: Managers may mix and match behaviors that are
very likely inconsistent with one another and thus
unlikely to yield the hoped-for result. For example,
both Uber and Apple’s iPhone owe their success to
a platform-based model: Uber digitally connects
riders with drivers; the iPhone connects app devel-
opers with phone users. But Uber, true to its nature
as a sustaining innovation, has focused on expand-
ing its network and functionality in ways that make
it better than traditional taxis. Apple, on the other
hand, has followed a disruptive path by building
its ecosystem of app developers so as to make the
iPhone more like a personal computer.
4. The mantra “Disrupt or be disrupted”
can misguide us. Incumbent companies do
need to respond to disruption if it’s occurring, but
they should not overreact by dismantling a still-
profitable business. Instead, they should continue
to strengthen relationships with core customers
by investing in sustaining innovations. In addition,
they can create a new division focused solely on the
growth opportunities that arise from the disrup-
tion. Our research suggests that the success of this
new enterprise depends in large part on keeping
THE UBIQUITOUS
“DISRUPTIVE
INNOVATION”
“Disruptive innovation”
and “disruptive
technology” are now
part of the popular
business lexicon, as
suggested by the
dramatic growth in
the number of articles
using those phrases
in recent years.
SOURCE FACTIVA ANALYSIS OF A WIDE VARIETY OF
ENGLISH-LANGUAGE PUBLICATIONS
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
ARTICLES
THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION?
8 Harvard Business Review December 2015
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
it separate from the core business. That means that
for some time, incumbents will find themselves
managing two very different operations.
Of course, as the disruptive stand-alone business
grows, it may eventually steal customers from the
core. But corporate leaders should not try to solve
this problem before it is a problem.
What a Disruptive Innovation
Lens Can Reveal
It is rare that a technology or product is inherently
sustaining or disruptive. And when new technol-
ogy is developed, disruption theory does not dictate
what managers should do. Instead it helps them
make a strategic choice between taking a sustaining
path and taking a disruptive one.
The theory of disruption predicts that when an
entrant tackles incumbent competitors head-on, of-
fering better products or services, the incumbents
will accelerate their innovations to defend their
business. Either they will beat back the entrant by
offering even better services or products at compa-
rable prices, or one of them will acquire the entrant.
The data supports the theory’s prediction that en-
trants pursuing a sustaining strategy for a stand-
alone business will face steep odds: In Christensen’s
seminal study of the disk drive industry, only 6% of
sustaining entrants managed to succeed.
Uber’s strong performance therefore warrants ex-
planation. According to disruption theory, Uber is an
outlier, and we do not have a universal way to account
for such atypical outcomes. In Uber’s case, we believe
that the regulated nature of the taxi business is a large
part of the answer. Market entry and prices are closely
controlled in many jurisdictions. Consequently, taxi
companies have rarely innovated. Individual drivers
have few ways to innovate, except to defect to Uber.
So Uber is in a unique situation relative to taxis: It can
offer better quality and the competition will find it
hard to respond, at least in the short term.
To this point, we’ve addressed only whether or
not Uber is disruptive to the taxi business. The lim-
ousine or “black car” business is a different story,
and here Uber is far more likely to be on a disruptive
path. The company’s UberSELECT option provides
more-luxurious cars and is typically more expensive
than its standard service—but typically less expen-
sive than hiring a traditional limousine. This lower
price imposes some compromises, as UberSELECT
currently does not include one defining feature of
the leading incumbents in this market: acceptance
of advance reservations. Consequently, this offering
from Uber appeals to the low end of the limousine
service market: customers willing to sacrifice a mea-
sure of convenience for monetary savings. Should
Uber find ways to match or exceed incumbents’
performance levels without compromising its cost
and price advantage, the company appears to be
well positioned to move into the mainstream of the
limo business—and it will have done so in classically
disruptive fashion.
How Our Thinking About
Disruption Has Developed
Initially, the theory of disruptive innovation was
simply a statement about correlation. Empirical
findings showed that incumbents outperformed
entrants in a sustaining innovation context but un-
derperformed in a disruptive innovation context.
The reason for this correlation was not immediately
evident, but one by one, the elements of the theory
fell into place.
First, researchers realized that a company’s pro-
pensity for strategic change is profoundly affected
by the interests of customers who provide the re-
sources the firm needs to survive. In other words, in-
cumbents (sensibly) listen to their existing custom-
ers and concentrate on sustaining innovations as a
result. Researchers then arrived at a second insight:
ncumbent companies
should not overreact
to disruption by dismantling
a still-profitable business.
Instead they should strengthen
relationships with core
customers while also creating
a new division focused on
the growth opportunities that
arise from the disruption.
December 2015 Harvard Business Review 9
FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783-
7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org
Incumbents’ focus on their existing customers be-
comes institutionalized in internal processes that
make it difficult for even senior managers to shift
investment to disruptive innovations. For example,
interviews with managers of established companies
in the disk drive industry revealed that resource allo-
cation processes prioritized sustaining innovations
(which had high margins and targeted large markets
with well-known customers) while inadvertently
starving disruptive innovations (meant for smaller
markets with poorly defined customers).
Those two insights helped explain why in-
cumbents rarely responded effectively (if at all)
to disruptive innovations, but not why entrants
eventually moved upmarket to challenge incum-
bents, over and over again. It turns out, however,
that the same forces leading incumbents to ignore
early-stage disruptions also compel disrupters
ultimately to disrupt.
What we’ve realized is that, very often, low-end
and new-market footholds are populated not by a
lone would-be disrupter, but by several comparable
entrant firms whose products are simpler, more con-
venient, or less costly than those sold by incumbents.
The incumbents provide a de facto price umbrella,
allowing many of the entrants to enjoy profitable
growth within the foothold market. But that lasts
only for a time: As incumbents (rationally, but mis-
takenly) cede the foothold market, they effectively
remove the price umbrella, and price-based com-
petition among the entrants reigns. Some entrants
will founder, but the smart ones—the true disrupt-
ers—will improve their products and drive upmar-
ket, where, once again, they can compete at the
margin against higher-cost established competitors.
The disruptive effect drives every competitor—
incumbent and entrant—upmarket.
With those explanations in hand, the theory of
disruptive innovation went beyond simple corre-
lation to a theory of causation as well. The key ele-
ments of that theory have been tested and validated
through studies of many industries, including retail,
computers, printing, motorcycles, cars, semicon-
ductors, cardiovascular surgery, management edu-
cation, financial services, management consulting,
cameras, communications, and computer-aided
design software.
Making sense of anomalies. Additional re-
finements to the theory have been made to address
certain anomalies, or unexpected scenarios, that
the theory could not explain. For example, we origi-
nally assumed that any disruptive innovation took
root in the lowest tiers of an established market—
yet sometimes new entrants seemed to be compet-
ing in entirely new markets. This led to the distinc-
tion we discussed earlier between low-end and
new-market footholds.
Low-end disrupters (think steel minimills and
discount retailers) come in at the bottom of the mar-
ket and take hold within an existing value network
before moving upmarket and attacking that stratum
(think integrated steel mills and traditional retail-
ers). By contrast, new-market disruptions take hold
in a completely new value network and appeal to
customers who have previously gone without the
product. Consider the transistor pocket radio and
the PC: They were largely ignored by manufacturers
of tabletop radios and minicomputers, respectively,
because they were aimed at nonconsumers of those
goods. By postulating that there are two flavors of
foothold markets in which disruptive innovation
can begin, the theory has become more powerful
and practicable.
Another intriguing anomaly was the identifi-
cation of industries that have resisted the forces
of disruption, at least until very recently. Higher
education in the United States is one of these. Over
the years—indeed, over more than 100 years—new
kinds of institutions with different initial charters
have been created to address the needs of various
population segments, including nonconsumers.
Land-grant universities, teachers’ colleges, two-year
colleges, and so on were initially launched to serve
those for whom a traditional four-year liberal arts
education was out of reach or unnecessary.
s there a novel technology or
business model that allows
entrants in higher education to
follow a disruptive path? The
answer seems to be yes, and the
enabling innovation is online learning.
THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION?
10 Harvard Business Review December 2015
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
Many of these new entrants strived to improve
over time, compelled by analogues of the pursuit of
profitability: a desire for growth, prestige, and the
capacity to do greater good. Thus they made costly
investments in research, dormitories, athletic fa-
cilities, faculty, and so on, seeking to emulate more-
elite institutions. Doing so has increased their level
of performance in some ways—they can provide
richer learning and living environments for students,
for example. Yet the relative standing of higher-
education institutions remains largely unchanged:
With few exceptions, the top 20 are still the top 20,
and the next 50 are still in that second tier, decade
after decade.
Because both incumbents and newcomers are
seemingly following the same game plan, it is per-
haps no surprise that incumbents are able to main-
tain their positions. What has been missing—until
recently—is experimentation with new models that
successfully appeal to today’s nonconsumers of
higher education.
The question now is whether there is a novel
technology or business model that allows new en-
trants to move upmarket without emulating the in-
cumbents’ high costs—that is, to follow a disruptive
path. The answer seems to be yes, and the enabling
innovation is online learning, which is becoming
broadly available. Real tuition for online courses is
falling, and accessibility and quality are improving.
Innovators are making inroads into the mainstream
market at a stunning pace.
Will online education disrupt the incumbents’
model? And if so, when? In other words, will on-
line education’s trajectory of improvement in-
tersect with the needs of the mainstream mar-
ket? We’ve come to realize that the steepness
of any disruptive trajectory is a function of how
quickly the enabling technology improves. In
the steel industry, continuous-casting technol-
ogy improved quite slowly, and it took more than
40 years before the minimill Nucor matched the
revenue of the largest integrated steelmakers. In
contrast, the digital technologies that allowed
personal computers to disrupt minicomputers
improved much more quickly; Compaq was able to
increase revenue more than tenfold and reach parity
with the industry leader, DEC, in only 12 years.
Understanding what drives the rate of disruption
is helpful for predicting outcomes, but it doesn’t al-
ter the way disruptions should be managed. Rapid
disruptions are not fundamentally different from any
others; they don’t have different causal mechanisms
and don’t require conceptually different responses.
Similarly, it is a mistake to assume that the strat-
egies adopted by some high-profile entrants con-
stitute a special kind of disruption. Often these are
simply miscategorized. Tesla Motors is a current
and salient example. One might be tempted to say
the company is disruptive. But its foothold is in the
high end of the auto market (with customers willing
to spend $70,000 or more on a car), and this segment
is not uninteresting to incumbents. Tesla’s entry, not
surprisingly, has elicited significant attention and in-
vestment from established competitors. If disruption
theory is correct, Tesla’s future holds either acquisi-
tion by a much larger incumbent or a years-long and
hard-fought battle for market significance.
We still have a lot to learn. We are eager to
keep expanding and refining the theory of disruptive
innovation, and much work lies ahead. For example,
universally effective responses to disruptive threats
remain elusive. Our current belief is that companies
should create a separate division that operates un-
der the protection of senior leadership to explore
and exploit a new disruptive model. Sometimes this
works—and sometimes it doesn’t. In certain cases,
a failed response to a disruptive threat cannot be
attrib uted to a lack of understanding, insufficient
executive attention, or inadequate financial invest-
ment. The challenges that arise from being an in-
cumbent and an entrant simultaneously have yet to
be fully specified; how best to meet those challenges
is still to be discovered.
Disruption theory does not, and never will, ex-
plain everything about innovation specifically or
business success generally. Far too many other
forces are in play, each of which will reward further
study. Integrating them all into a comprehensive
theory of business success is an ambitious goal, one
we are unlikely to attain anytime soon.
But there is cause for hope: Empirical tests show
that using disruptive theory makes us measurably
and significantly more accurate in our predictions
of which fledgling businesses will succeed. As an
ever-growing community of researchers and practi-
tioners continues to build on disruption theory and
integrate it with other perspectives, we will come
to an even better understanding of what helps firms
innovate successfully.
HBR Reprint R1512B
December 2015 Harvard Business Review 11
FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783-
7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG
For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in
BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California -
Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
http://hbr.org/search/R1512B
http://hbr.org

More Related Content

Similar to F A L L 2 0 1 7 I S S U ETodd HaughThe Trouble With.docx

AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance Industry
AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance IndustryAML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance Industry
AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance IndustryRachel Hamilton
 
Advanced analytics
Advanced analyticsAdvanced analytics
Advanced analyticsTom Keeley
 
Advanced Analytics
Advanced AnalyticsAdvanced Analytics
Advanced AnalyticsTom Keeley
 
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...Gradytl
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)Louise Denham
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Louise Denham
 
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510James C. Roberts III
 
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docx
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docxThe Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docx
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docxmehek4
 
Analytics trends deloitte
Analytics trends deloitteAnalytics trends deloitte
Analytics trends deloitteMani Kansal
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Louise Denham
 
What's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleWhat's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleJyoti Pandey
 
What's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleWhat's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleJyoti Pandey
 
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docx
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docxReply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docx
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docxaudeleypearl
 

Similar to F A L L 2 0 1 7 I S S U ETodd HaughThe Trouble With.docx (14)

AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance Industry
AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance IndustryAML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance Industry
AML and OFAC Compliance for the Insurance Industry
 
Advanced analytics
Advanced analyticsAdvanced analytics
Advanced analytics
 
Advanced Analytics
Advanced AnalyticsAdvanced Analytics
Advanced Analytics
 
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...
Whitepaper: Misconduct Rarely Happens in Isolation: How You Can Detect Critic...
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)
Human rights proforestpillarii_ld_edit (2)
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
 
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510
Blog Global Capital Social Media Policy 012510
 
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docx
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docxThe Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docx
The Corporate Ethics CommitteeIn some organizations, ethics is m.docx
 
Analytics trends deloitte
Analytics trends deloitteAnalytics trends deloitte
Analytics trends deloitte
 
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
Human rights proforestpillarii_draft1
 
01-2016-Risk-management-regarding-smes-TONDI
01-2016-Risk-management-regarding-smes-TONDI01-2016-Risk-management-regarding-smes-TONDI
01-2016-Risk-management-regarding-smes-TONDI
 
What's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleWhat's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos article
 
What's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos articleWhat's your approach. ethikos article
What's your approach. ethikos article
 
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docx
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docxReply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docx
Reply to the threads of 2 classmates who offer views different tha.docx
 

More from lmelaine

Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docx
Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docxJan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docx
Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docxlmelaine
 
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docx
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docxJan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docx
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docxlmelaine
 
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docx
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docxJames RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docx
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docxlmelaine
 
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docx
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docxJacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docx
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docxlmelaine
 
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docx
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docxIve been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docx
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docxlmelaine
 
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docx
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docxIt’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docx
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docxlmelaine
 
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docx
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docxIts meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docx
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docxlmelaine
 
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docx
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docxJaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docx
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docxlmelaine
 
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docx
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docxIve got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docx
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docxlmelaine
 
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docx
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docxIt is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docx
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docxlmelaine
 
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docx
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docxit is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docx
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docxlmelaine
 
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docx
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docxIt is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docx
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docxlmelaine
 
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docx
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docxIts a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docx
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docxlmelaine
 
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docx
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docxitively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docx
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docxlmelaine
 
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docx
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docxIT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docx
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docxlmelaine
 
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docx
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docxIt is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docx
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docxlmelaine
 
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docxIT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docxlmelaine
 
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docx
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docxIt should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docx
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docxlmelaine
 
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docxIT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docxlmelaine
 
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docx
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docxIt seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docx
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docxlmelaine
 

More from lmelaine (20)

Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docx
Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docxJan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docx
Jan 18, 2013 at 217pmNo unread replies.No replies.Post yo.docx
 
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docx
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docxJan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docx
Jan 10, 20141.Definition of law A set of rules and proced.docx
 
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docx
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docxJames RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docx
James RiverJewelryProjectQuesti.docx
 
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docx
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docxJacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docx
Jacob claims the employer violated his rights. In your opinion, what.docx
 
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docx
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docxIve been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docx
Ive been promised A+ papers in the past but so far I have not seen .docx
 
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docx
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docxIt’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docx
It’s easy to dismiss the works from the Dada movement as silly. Cons.docx
 
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docx
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docxIts meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docx
Its meaning is still debated. It could be a symbol of the city of Fl.docx
 
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docx
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docxJaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docx
Jaffe and Jordan want to use financial planning models to prepar.docx
 
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docx
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docxIve got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docx
Ive got this assinment due and was wondering if anyone has done any.docx
 
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docx
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docxIt is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docx
It is thought that a metabolic waste product produced by a certain g.docx
 
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docx
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docxit is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docx
it is not the eassay it is about anwering the question with 2,3 pa.docx
 
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docx
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docxIt is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docx
It is now time to select sources and take some notes. You will nee.docx
 
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docx
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docxIts a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docx
Its a linear equations question...Neilsen Media Research surveys .docx
 
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docx
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docxitively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docx
itively impact job satisfactionWeek 3 - Learning Team Paper - Due .docx
 
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docx
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docxIT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docx
IT205 Management of Information SystemsHello, I am looking for he.docx
 
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docx
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docxIt is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docx
It is not an online course so i cannot share any login details. No d.docx
 
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docxIT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 1Using the case provided, analyze the busi.docx
 
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docx
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docxIt should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docx
It should be in API format.Research paper should be on Ethernet .docx
 
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docxIT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docx
IT Strategic Plan, Part 2Using the case provided, build on Part .docx
 
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docx
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docxIt seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docx
It seems most everything we buy these days has the label made in Ch.docx
 

Recently uploaded

Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...christianmathematics
 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxheathfieldcps1
 
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan FellowsOn National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan FellowsMebane Rash
 
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxSeal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxnegromaestrong
 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptxMaritesTamaniVerdade
 
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptxDyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptxcallscotland1987
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Jisc
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...pradhanghanshyam7136
 
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseSpellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseAnaAcapella
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptRamjanShidvankar
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxAmanpreet Kaur
 
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfUGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfNirmal Dwivedi
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfagholdier
 
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in DelhiRussian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhikauryashika82
 
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxPython Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxRamakrishna Reddy Bijjam
 
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docxPoojaSen20
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfPoh-Sun Goh
 
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfSherif Taha
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
 
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptxThe basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
The basics of sentences session 3pptx.pptx
 
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan FellowsOn National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
On National Teacher Day, meet the 2024-25 Kenan Fellows
 
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptxSeal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
Seal of Good Local Governance (SGLG) 2024Final.pptx
 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
 
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptxDyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
Dyslexia AI Workshop for Slideshare.pptx
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
 
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseSpellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
 
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.pptApplication orientated numerical on hev.ppt
Application orientated numerical on hev.ppt
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
 
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfUGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in DelhiRussian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
Russian Escort Service in Delhi 11k Hotel Foreigner Russian Call Girls in Delhi
 
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docxPython Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
Python Notes for mca i year students osmania university.docx
 
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
PROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docxPROCESS      RECORDING        FORMAT.docx
PROCESS RECORDING FORMAT.docx
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
 
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdfFood safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
Food safety_Challenges food safety laboratories_.pdf
 
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptxAsian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
 

F A L L 2 0 1 7 I S S U ETodd HaughThe Trouble With.docx

  • 1. F A L L 2 0 1 7 I S S U E Todd Haugh The Trouble With Corporate Compliance Programs Companies with rigorous compliance programs hope such programs will curtail employee wrongdoing. But to prevent employee misconduct, companies also have to understand how employees reach unethical decisions — and what affects their decision-making processes. Vol. 59, No. 1 Reprint #59110 http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs SMR635 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs PLEASE NOTE THAT GRAY AREAS REFLECT ARTWORK THAT HAS BEEN INTENTIONALLY REMOVED. THE SUBSTANTIVE CONTENT OF THE ARTICLE APPEARS AS ORIGINALLY PUBLISHED.
  • 2. MULTINATIONAL CORPORATIONS spend millions of dollars per year on compliance. In highly regulated industries such as health care and finance, large companies spend much more, sometimes hiring hundreds or even thousands of compliance officers at a time.1 Siemens AG reportedly spent more than $1 billion on an in- ternal investigation related to a government inquiry into the company’s payment of foreign bribes.2 But the costs are not just financial. Com- pliance programs are aimed at eliminating the time-consuming and distracting regulatory and legal processes that accompany ethical failures. There is a belief on the part of corporate lead- ers that when rigorous compliance programs are in place, employee wrongdoing will largely dis- appear. If something does go wrong, the hope is that having a comprehensive program will help convince regulators that the company’s compli- ance and ethics initiatives were “effective” (the
  • 3. standard set by U.S sentencing guidelines).3 Companies strive to make their programs as “bulletproof ” as possible. Unfortunately, even the most comprehensive programs won’t curtail corporate wrongdoing or the government inter- vention that follows. For instance, Volkswagen AG’s compliance program didn’t stop employ- ees from installing “defeat device” software to cheat emissions tests, nor did Wells Fargo & Co.’s The Trouble With Corporate Compliance Programs B U S I N E S S E T H I C S Companies with rigorous compliance programs hope such programs will curtail employee wrongdoing. But to prevent employee misconduct, companies also have to understand how employees reach unethical decisions — and what affects their decision-making processes. BY TODD HAUGH THE LEADING QUESTION How can companies increase the
  • 4. effectiveness of their compliance programs? FINDINGS �Most programs don’t take into account behavioral compliance best practices. �Eliminating rationalizations is key to strengthen- ing individual and organizational behavior. FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW 55 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. 56 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017 SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU B U S I N E S S E T H I C S policies prevent its employees from opening new cus-
  • 5. tomer accounts without customers’ authorization. More than 15 years after the Enron scandal, most companies know very little about how employees make ethical decisions or the psychological mecha- nisms that cause them to perform unethical and illegal acts. Even fewer companies have compliance strategies aimed at curbing such behaviors. The goal of this article is to pull together the bur- geoning field of behavioral ethics, which provides insight into how individuals make ethical decisions, with the work of criminologists who study individ- ual and corporate criminality. My aim is to help business leaders see why their corporate compliance efforts are falling short and how those efforts can be improved. In addition, I will offer some practical and cost-effective steps for improving compliance pro- grams that focus on employee behavior — the best way to make compliance truly effective.
  • 6. Dual Systems of Thinking Corporate compliance depends on the behavior of individual employees. If employees, officers, and managers always acted in a law-abiding and ethical manner, compliance failures would rarely occur. Of course, that is not realistic. That is why companies need to be aware of how and why employees act the way they do. This starts with understanding how people make decisions generally and how that translates into ethical decision-making. Contrary to traditional economic theory, peo- ple don’t make strictly rational decisions. Instead, as the work of psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky revealed, most decisions are influ- enced by dual cognitive processes: intuitive and reasoning.4 The intuitive process (which Kahneman and Tversky refer to as System 1) is “fast, automatic, effor tless, associative, and often emotionally charged.”5 It operates by associative memory and
  • 7. habit, which makes it difficult to control or modify. A lot happens at once through System 1 — the mind offers associations rapidly, one idea after an- other, all linked effortlessly. The speed and ease by which System 1 operates means that “most of the work of associative thinking is silent, hidden from our conscious selves.”6 The reasoning process (referred to as System 2) is more serial and deliberate. It is engaged when we use thought in an organized manner. We use it to solve complex math problems, write a paragraph, or contemplate multifaceted decisions when there aren’t easy associations to make. System 2 thinking gives us the “experience of agency, autonomy, and volition.”7 Not surprisingly, the reasoning process requires much more mental effort than using intuition. Reasoning isn’t necessarily better than intuitive thinking — you wouldn’t want to reason
  • 8. your way through every one of your day-to-day tasks — but for the most important decisions, it’s critical. Yet, because System 2 thinking takes more effort, our minds have developed to rely primarily on System 1, reserving System 2 either for the most challenging mental tasks or to correct errors in our automatic thinking. This may seem fine, but re- search shows that people often use System 2 to justify their System 1 conclusions.8 Instead of cor- recting errors, sometimes our reasoning process reinforces our often flawed intuitions. Although Kahneman and Tversky did not study ethical decision-making directly, their findings are critical to understanding how people make deci- sions in an ethical context. Behavioral ethics researchers have taken the insights of dual system thinking and applied them to ethical decision- making in business. They have found that while
  • 9. most people intend to act ethically, good people often do bad things.9 Indeed, research has found that self-interest is associated with intuitive think- ing.10 Despite this, most of us act ethically most of the time. That is because System 2 is properly func- tioning as an ethical monitor, jumping in to control the automatic self-interest each of us possesses.11 Rationalizing Unethical Behavior If System 2 is an ethical monitor, why does it seem to fail so often? For example, what enabled VW em- ployees to install the code used to defeat emissions tests? Although behavioral ethics research helps us understand how the brain works, it doesn’t explain what allows the brain to take that critical step to- ward unethical behavior. This is where criminology, the study of crime and criminals, comes in. Criminologists research- ing white-collar crime have theorized that three
  • 10. conditions are necessary for a corporate crime to occur.12 First, an individual must possess a problem For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW 57 he or she feels cannot be solved by revealing it to others. A “non-shareable problem” might be any- thing from gambling debts to the prospect of job loss — anything that the person is deeply con- cerned about. Second, the individual must believe that the problem can be solved in secret by violat- ing a trust. As corporate leaders know, trust is an essential element in any organization — almost every principal-agent relationship is built upon it. Third, the individual must have an internal dia- logue about the problem and the unethical — even
  • 11. illegal — solution that makes the trust violation seem acceptable.13 The classic example is the banker who tells himself he is only “borrowing” the em- bezzled funds and will pay them back later. The last step, which criminologists call “verbal- izations” (and the rest of us usually refer to as rationalizations or even excuses), is the crux of white- collar crime. Criminologists don’t view verbalizations as simple, after-the-fact excuses that offenders use to relieve their culpability upon being caught. Instead, they see them as “vocabularies of motive” — words and phrases offenders use to make bad behavior seem appropriate.14 This means that an offender’s rational- izations are created before acting and actually allow the bad act to proceed. As the criminologist who developed rationalization theory puts it, “[t]he ra- tionalization is [the offender’s] motivation.”15 Rationalizations, which have been identified in nu-
  • 12. merous studies, permit white-collar offenders to act in ways that they would otherwise deem unacceptable. This is consistent with what we know about how people make unethical decisions. Behavioral ethics research does not suggest that everyone wants to act ethically but fails to do so because of cognitive obsta- cles. Rather, people default toward acting unethically because they are driven by self-interest, and then they find ways to convince themselves — consciously and subconsciously — that they are acting ethically.16 This appears to be a case of System 2 justifying Sys- tem 1 conclusions. It’s likely this process is a product of our unique evolution. Although the ability to co- operate with one another is one of humankind’s greatest advantages, the best course of action from an individual perspective is often to act in one’s self- interest.17 Thus we have developed mechanisms to deal with the countervailing aspects of living in our
  • 13. “hypersocial” yet competitive world.18 One of the mechanisms is to rationalize our behavior — to reframe how we look at it in order to align our self- perception as a “good person” with the unethical or illegal behavior we are contemplating. There is no better way to act self-interestedly while simultane- ously projecting to others (and ourselves) that we are good members of a cooperative society. I believe that rationalization theory, which has greatly influenced the study of both white-collar crime and business ethics, explains what happens when an individual’s ethical monitor is overcome.19 Essentially, rationalizations trick the System 2 reflec- tive thinking process that normally intervenes to contain our unethicality. Once this happens, there is nothing to stop a person from committing an unethi- cal or illegal act, regardless of the organizational norms, business regulations, or criminal laws in place.
  • 14. What are the most typical rationalizations? And more importantly, how do we identify them? My re- search suggests there are eight rationalizations most commonly used by those committing unethical and illegal acts within companies.20 (See “About the Re- search.”) As part of an effective compliance program, corporate leaders need to understand these rational- izations and be able to identify their usage. Denying Responsibility Offenders use this ratio- nalization to relieve themselves of responsibility, thereby mitigating social disapproval and a per- sonal sense of failure. White-collar offenders deny responsibility by pleading ignorance, suggesting they were acting under orders, or contending that larger economic conditions caused them to act ABOUT THE RESEARCH This article is part of my long-term study of the causes of white-collar crime and corporate wrongdoing. After approximately a decade representing white-collar defendants in state and federal court, advising companies on
  • 15. corporate compli- ance practices, and drafting guidelines to aid federal judges in sentencing fraud offenders, I found that the standard narratives of why businesspeople commit bad acts were misguided. This led me to criminological theory and sociologist Donald Cressey’s groundbreaking study of embezzlers, which revealed the role rationalizations play in violations of organizational trust. Using Cressey’s research as a point of departure, I have undertaken projects analyzing sentencing dispari- ties among economic crime defendants, professional athletes who committed and were victim to fraud, defendants convicted of the theft of cultural heritage resources, and numerous individual and corporate case studies focused on the behavioral aspects of white-collar and organizational crime. Collectively, this re- search has helped me identify prominent rationalizations used by white-collar offenders and confirmed the importance of behavioral insights for effective cor- porate compliance, white-collar sentencing, and criminal legislation. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
  • 16. 58 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017 SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU B U S I N E S S E T H I C S illegally. This may be considered the “catch-all” ra- tionalization leading to wrongful conduct. Denying Injury This rationalization focuses on the injury or harm caused by the illegal or unethical act. If an act’s wrongfulness is a function of the harm it causes, an offender often excuses his or her behavior if no clear harm exists. Offenders employ this rationalization when the victim is insured or the harm is to the public or market as a whole, such as in insider trading or antitrust cases. Denying the Victim Denying the victim takes two forms: when the offender argues that the victim’s ac- tions were inappropriate and therefore the victim deserved the harm; or when the victim is unknown or not clearly defined. White-collar offenders often use this rationalization when committing frauds against the government, such as in false claims or tax
  • 17. evasion cases. Condemning the Condemners This rationaliza- tion shifts attention away from the offender’s conduct to the motives of others, such as regulators, prosecutors, and government agencies. It can take various forms: The offender calls his or her critics hypocrites, argues that they are compelled by per- sonal spite, asserts they are motivated by political gain, or complains about selective enforcement. Appealing to Higher Loyalties Individuals use this rationalization when they are willing to sacri- fice societal norms to advance the interests of a group to which they belong. The actions are needed, the offender argues, to protect a boss or employee, shore up a failing business, or maximize shareholder value. For example, if an employee ar- gues that he or she committed a fraud not for personal gain but to help the company, he is or she is likely using this rationalization.
  • 18. Using a Ledger Metaphor This rationalization is based on a “behavioral balance sheet” whereby peo- ple balance their negative actions against their positive accomplishments, thus minimizing their sense of moral guilt. Senior executives, particularly those active in philanthropy, are especially prone to this type of rationalization. Claiming Entitlement People involved in em- ployee theft and embezzlement cases frequently use this rationalization in the belief that they deserve the fruits of their illegal behavior. This rationaliza- tion is also common in public corruption cases. Claiming Relative Acceptability or Normality This rationalization compares the offender’s bad acts with those of others to relieve moral guilt. Tax violators and those involved in real estate, account- ing, and trading fraud often rationalize their actions by citing the behavior of others. It may be particularly prevalent when a negative organiza-
  • 19. tional culture is strong and insulated. How Rationalizations Undermine Compliance Programs There are plenty of practical examples illustrating how employees rationalize behavior that leads to compliance issues. The experiences of Intel Corp. and Wells Fargo are instructive. In the early 2000s, Intel adopted an aggressive ap- proach to compliance in order to curb potential antitrust violations by its sales executives.21 It de- vised a program in which the company’s compliance professionals periodically conducted random audits in which they searched through papers, emails, and other electronic records of managers, seizing any- thing that might be sought as part of a government investigation. If the company found irregularities, it sometimes even held mock depositions of the of- fending executives, using outside antitrust lawyers. Intel’s general counsel explained that these role-
  • 20. playing exercises served as a wake-up call, giving lax executives the experience of being in the govern- ment’s crosshairs. He boasted that Intel’s aggressive approach to compliance was “the world’s best.”22 Yet Intel was unable to avoid government inter- vention in its business. Intel spent years in private antitrust litigation, and in 2009 the New York at- torney general sued the company, arguing its compliance program not only was ineffective but had helped contribute to illegal anticompetitive behavior by appearing to have communicated to employees that the goal of the compliance initiatives was to limit mention of illegal behavior, rather than to eliminate the behavior.23 Based on my analysis of employee emails revealed as part of the lawsuit, the For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
  • 21. SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW 59 company’s approach may have facilitated a host of rationalizations, including two mentioned above: denial of injury and denial of the victim. In addition, employees more easily denied their re- sponsibility, the catch-all rationalization, because anticompetitive practices were seen as part of doing business at Intel. Wells Fargo’s recent difficulties appear to offer another example of rationalized corporate wrong- doing . The company’s fake-account scandal demonstrates how executives can affect the context in which employees make decisions regarding ethics. Details of how exactly the bank’s ethics and compli- ance program operated are still emerging, but preliminary reports suggest it allowed an environ- ment riddled by employee rationalizations. On the
  • 22. heels of the bank’s $185 million settlement agree- ment with the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, a number of former employees have re- ported that despite ethics training and messages from headquarters to not create fake accounts, the bank’s aggressive sales culture drowned out any explicit compliance measures. Essentially, the com- pliance program failed to address the systemic problem of managers pressuring employees to meet unrealistic sales goals.24 “The reality was that people had to meet their [sales] goals,” one former employee explained. “They needed a paycheck.”25 This suggests that employees, under pressure to meet unrealistic goals, rationalized their conduct by denying respon- sibility and claiming relative normality. Combating Rationalizations Behavioral science, coupled with criminological insights, indicates there are complex, interwoven,
  • 23. and deeply seated psychological processes at work that can undermine even the best compliance pro- gram. So what are companies to do? Is there a way to do compliance better — one that solves some of the problems created by the automaticity of self-interest we all possess? Yes, but it requires a fundamental shift in corporate thinking. The best approaches to compliance focus not on how government regulators will react to a compli- ance initiative but on how employees — the real “customers” of compliance — will be affected. They consider the behavioral implications of the compliance program at every turn, particularly how company policies might foster or defeat em- ployee rationalizations. While no program will entirely change our cognitive processes or stop all unethical behavior, there are three cost-effective steps companies can take.
  • 24. Hire a behavioral specialist. Although dual- system thinking, rationalization, and behavioral ethics theories have been around for decades, their application to business and compliance is still in its infancy. Hiring a behavioral specialist or develop- ing someone internally to stay abreast of the various fields and their increasing insights into eth- ical decision-making is a good first step. One of the tasks a behavioral specialist can take on is to educate the organization, particularly the com- pliance team and HR staff, on key takeaways from current research in the fields of behavioral ethics, behavioral economics, moral psychology, and crimi- nology.26 Books on decision-making and dishonesty by serious researchers, yet aimed at more general readers, can be a helpful resource.27 A company’s behavioral specialist should create a behavioral com- pliance curriculum tailored to various groups of
  • 25. employees, giving all members of the organization insight into their ethical decision-making processes. Such a curriculum can become the backbone of a behaviorally cognizant compliance program. Use behavioral best practices to eliminate ratio- nalizations. To create compliance programs that take advantage of behavioral insights instead of fall- ing prey to them, companies must start to adopt compliance practices driven by the behavioral The compliance program failed to address the systemic problem of managers pressuring employees to meet unrealistic sales goals. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. 60 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017 SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU B U S I N E S S E T H I C S science at the heart of criminology and behavioral
  • 26. ethics. This will necessarily go beyond the traditional law-driven compliance practices employed by the vast majority of Fortune 500 companies. If rationalizations are the crux of employee wrongdoing, then compliance programs should be aimed at eliminating them. One possibility is to ask employees to sign a certification before they engage in behavior that creates compliance risk. A group of researchers working with an insurance company asked customers to report how many miles they had driven that year, according to the odometer.28 Re- porting lower miles meant lower premiums. But instead of simply asking for the number of miles, re- searchers included a certification of honesty at the top of the form. Customers who certified at the top of the form, before providing their mileage number, reported almost 2,500 more miles than those who signed the same certification at the bottom of the
  • 27. form, despite there being no difference in driving habits.29 The certification was effective in reducing dishonesty because it engaged morality at the mo- ment of the decision to act ethically or unethically, just before there was an opportunity to rationalize. By triggering people’s System 2 ethical monitor at the correct time, the potential for rationalization was greatly reduced. Researchers found the same type of results with tax deduction forms styled like those of the U.S. Internal Revenue Service.30 A similar approach can be used by companies for any expense report, conflict of interest form, or funds authorization — anything in which an employee is being asked to engage in behavior that creates com- pliance risk. It’s up to companies to decide how high-tech they want to get. JPMorgan Chase & Co. has been developing software that monitors the ac- tions of its traders, including emails and telephone
  • 28. conversations, to ensure they “adhere to ‘personal trading rules’ and risk limits,” and Credit Suisse Group AG is also working on technology to monitor traders’ behavior.31 JPMorgan’s effort is noteworthy in that the software’s algorithms can generate alerts if it appears that traders may be headed toward an ethical or legal violation. Such “predictive monitor- ing,” like a certification at the top of a paper form, could be used by companies to intervene with a prompt before a problematic behavior occurs, forc- ing the employee’s System 2 reasoning system to engage — and thus improving compliance. Companies should also encourage employees to openly discuss rationalizations and how they affect ethical decision-making. This can be accomplished through storytelling by employees and the company. Employees should be encouraged, even required, to meet periodically in small groups to explore the poten-
  • 29. tial effects of compliance violations and white-collar crimes. The idea is for employees, guided by compli- ance professionals (or, better yet, senior managers), to discuss topics such as what regulations are relevant to the business, common compliance pitfalls, and how some business practices produce externalities that negatively impact stakeholders. When rationalizing statements pop up, as they inevitably will, they should be identified and flagged. Only after patterns of self- exculpatory rationalization are openly discussed and labeled as problematic will employees be able to inter- nalize that knowledge and use it when presented with an opportunity to act unethically.32 The company also should share stories of genu- ine compliance successes. Compliance messaging is most effective when it conveys that positive behaviors are widely engaged in and approved of within a com- pany.33 The reason is related to the claim of relative
  • 30. normality rationalization, which allows individuals to favorably compare their potential unethical act to the unethical acts of others. Positive compliance mes- saging combats this rationalization by demonstrating that while there may be isolated compliance lapses, the majority of the company is committed to making ethical decisions. Compliance messaging is most effective when it conveys that positive behaviors are widely engaged in and approved of within a company. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU FALL 2017 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW 61 One company that has used storytelling and dis- cussions effectively in its ethics program is Parsons Corp., an international engineering and construc-
  • 31. tion company based in Pasadena, California. The company hosts an internal website where it has posed hypothetical ethical problems and asked em- ployees to vote on how they should be resolved. It then has published the narrative comments anony- mously and followed up with a detailed analysis by the company’s ethics committee. Such practices serve to unite employees around the company’s val- ues as applied to real-life scenarios. Through the narratives, employees themselves identify common ethical traps and rationalizations.34 Periodically posing ethics challenges and quizzes to employees is one of a number of techniques Parsons uses in its award-winning ethics and compliance program.35 Use incentives to influence behavior in the right direction. Behavioral ethics research has shown that even seemingly inconsequential factors can greatly influence ethical decision-making. This is especially
  • 32. true when considering how rationalizations can be drawn from a company’s internal culture, a large part of which depends on incentive structures. This is one of the early lessons from Wells Fargo, where the social and monetary incentives to cross-sell products swamped the company’s compliance protocols. What’s more, Wells Fargo is not an isolated example; prior research has found that when major corporate trust violations occur, the root cause often has less to do with a rogue employee than with elements of the organization that are “dysfunctional, conflicting, or incongruent.”36 As a result, executives need to be aware of the common forms of rationalization de- scribed earlier in this article — and examine where in their organizations conflicting incentives could foster rationalization and wrongdoing. To that end, business leaders can tap nonmonetary incentives to aid in compliance. According to research,
  • 33. praise and expressions of gratitude motivate more than money, and social group interactions motivate individual behavior more than almost anything.37 That means the most effective compliance likely comes from something other than salary and bonus. Research also shows that compliance is most effective when employees perceive it not as a constraint but as “the governing ethos of an organization.”38 The goal, then, is for companies to build a corporate culture that incentivizes the rejection of rationalizations through the creation of shared values. No compliance program will entirely eliminate bad employee conduct. But behaviorally cognizant programs, ones that seek to understand employee decision-making and target the cognitive mecha- nisms that foster unethicality, hold the promise of achieving the primary goals of compliance: reducing unethical and illegal behavior within the company.
  • 34. Todd Haugh is an assistant professor of business law and ethics at Indiana University’s Kelley School of Busi- ness in Bloomington, Indiana, as well as a Jesse Fine Fellow at the Poynter Center for the Study of Ethics and American Institutions at Indiana University. Comment on this article at http://sloanreview.mit.edu/x/59110, or contact the author at [email protected] REFERENCES 1. S.J. Griffith, “Corporate Governance in an Era of Compliance,” William & Mary Law Review 57, no. 6 (May 2016) 2102-2103; and R.M. Steinberg, “The High Cost of Non-Compliance: Reaping the Rewards of an Effective Compliance Program” (February 2010, www.securityexecutivecouncil.com. 2. P.J. Henning, “The Mounting Costs of Internal Investigations,” The New York Times, March 5, 2012, http://dealbook.nytimes.com. 3. United States Sentencing Guidelines Manual, chapter 8 (2016), www.ussc.gov. 4. Kahneman and Tversky’s work was popularized with the publication of Kahenman’s 2011 book; see D. Kahne- man, “Thinking, Fast and Slow” (New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2011), 20-24. However, their work spanned decades. See, for example, D. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Econom- ics,” American Economics Review 93, no. 5 (December 2003): 1449-1450. Executives need to be aware of the common forms of rationalization described earlier in this article — and examine where in their organization conflicting incentives could foster rationalization and wrongdoing.
  • 35. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. 62 MIT SLOAN MANAGEMENT REVIEW FALL 2017 SLOANREVIEW.MIT.EDU B U S I N E S S E T H I C S 5. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1451. 6. Kahneman, “Thinking, Fast and Slow,” 52. 7. P.G. Hansen and A.M. Jespersen, “Nudge and the Manipulation of Choice: A Framework for the Responsi- ble Use of the Nudge Approach to Behaviour Change in Public Policy,” European Journal of Risk Regulation 4, no. 1 (March 2013): 13. 8. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1467. 9. R.A. Prentice, “Behavioral Ethics: Can It Help Lawyers (and Others) Be Their Best Selves?” Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics & Public Policy 29, no. 1 (2015): 36. 10. Y. Feldman, “Behavioral Ethics Meets Behavioral Law and Economics,” in “The Oxford Handbook of Behavioral Economics and the Law,” eds. E. Zamir and D. Teichman (New York: Oxford University Press 2014), 8. See also D.A. Moore and G. Loewenstein, “Self-Interest, Automa- ticity, and the Psychology of Conflict of Interest,” Social
  • 36. Justice Research 17, no. 2 (2004): 190. 11. Kahneman, “Maps of Bounded Rationality,” 1467. 12. E.H. Sutherland, “White Collar Crime: The Uncut Version” (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1983), 240. For a succinct discussion of Sutherland’s groundbreaking theories on white-collar crime, see E.H. Sutherland and D.R. Cressey, “A Sociological Theory of Criminal Behavior,” in “Delinquency, Crime, and Social Process,” eds. D.R. Cressey and D.A. Ward (New York: Harper & Row, 1969), 429-443. 13. D.R. Cressey, “The Respectable Criminal: Why Some of Our Best Friends Are Crooks,” Criminologica 3, no. 1 (May 1965): 14-15. 14. Ibid. 15. D.R. Cressey, “Other People’s Money: A Study in the Social Psychology of Embezzlement” (New York: Free Press, 1953), 95. 16. Feldman, “Behavioral Ethics Meets Behavioral Law and Economics,” 17. 17. E. Kolbert, “That’s What You Think: Why Reason and Evidence Won’t Change Our Minds,” The New Yorker, Feb. 27, 2017, 66, citing H. Mercier and D. Sperber, “The Enigma of Reason: A New Theory of Human Understanding” (Cam- bridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 2017). 18. Mercier and Sperber, “The Enigma of Reason.” 19. S. Maruna and H. Copes, “What Have We Learned from Five Decades of Neutralization Research?” Crime
  • 37. and Justice 32 (2005): 222. See also B.E. Ashforth and V. Anand, “The Normalization of Corruption in Organiza- tions,” Research in Organizational Behavior 25 (2003): 2-5. 20. This section is adapted from a series of articles the author has written concerning white-collar crime and corporate compliance. See, for example, T. Haugh, “The Criminalization of Compliance,” Notre Dame Law Review 92, no. 3 (April 2016): 1255-58; T. Haugh, “Overcriminal- ization’s New Harm Paradigm,” Vanderbilt Law Review 68, no. 5 (October 2015): 1218-1222; T. Haugh, “Sentenc- ing the Why of White Collar Crime,” Fordham Law Review 82, no. 6 (2014): 3165-3169. 21. D.B. Yoffie and M. Kwak, “Playing by the Rules: How Intel Avoids Antitrust Litigation,” Harvard Business Review 79, no. 6 (June 2001): 120-121. 22. Ibid., 120. 23. Complaint, New York v. Intel Corp., No. 1:09-cv-00827- UNA (D. Del. Nov. 4, 2009): 19-20. 24. “Independent Directors of the Board of Wells Fargo & Company Sales Practices Investigations Report” (April 10, 2017): 37-38. 25. M. Corkery and S. Cowley, “Wells Fargo Warned Workers Against Sham Accounts, but ‘They Needed a Paycheck,’” The New York Times, Sept. 16, 2016, www.nytimes.com. 26. See, for example, D. De Cremer and A.E. Tenbrunsel, eds., “Behavioral Business Ethics: Shaping an Emerging Field” (New York: Routledge, 2011), 3-10.
  • 38. 27. R.H. Thaler and C.R. Sunstein, “Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness” (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2008); D. Ariely, “The Hon- est Truth About Dishonesty” (New York: HarperCollins, 2012); and Kahneman, “Thinking, Fast and Slow.” 28. L.L. Shu, N. Mazar, F. Gino, D. Ariely, and M.H. Bazer- man, “Signing at the Beginning Makes Ethics Salient and Decreases Dishonest Self-Reports in Comparison to Sign- ing at the End,” Psychological and Cognitive Sciences 109, no. 38 (Sept. 18, 2012): 15198. 29. Ibid. 30. Ariely, “The Honest Truth,” 45-48. 31. P. Crowe, “JP Morgan Is Working on a New Employee Surveillance Program,” Business Insider, April 8, 2015, www.businessinsider.com; and K. Scannell and H. Kuchler, “Palantir and Credit Suisse Join Forces to Target Rogue Traders,” Financial Times, March 22, 2016, www.ft.com. 32. J. Heath, “Business Ethics and Moral Motivation: A Criminological Perspective,” Journal of Business Ethics 83, no. 4 (December 2008): 611. 33. R.B. Cialdini, L.J. Demaine, B.J. Sagarin, D.W. Barrett, K. Rhoads, and P.L. Winter, “Managing Social Norms for Persuasive Impact,” Social Influence 1, no.1 (2006): 13; and S. Killingsworth, “Modeling the Message: Communi- cating Compliance through Organizational Values and Culture,” Georgetown Journal of Legal Ethics 25, no. 4 (fall 2012): 983. 34. Killingsworth, “Modeling the Message,” 983.
  • 39. 35. “Parsons: People. Planet. Progress. 2017 Corporate Social Responsibility Report,” www.parsons.com, 51. 36. R.F. Hurley, N. Gillespie, D.L. Ferrin, and G. Dietz, “Designing Trustworthy Organizations,” MIT Sloan Management Review 54, no. 4 (summer 2013): 75-82. 37. A.M. Grant and F. Gino, “A Little Thanks Goes a Long Way: Explaining Why Gratitude Expressions Motivate Prosocial Behavior,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 98, no. 6 (June 2010): 953; Cialdini et al., “Managing Social Norms for Persuasive Impact,” 13. 38. See L.S. Paine, “Managing for Organizational Integ- rity,” Harvard Business Review 72, no. 2 (March-April 1994): 106-107. Reprint 59110. Copyright © Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2017. All rights reserved. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. PDFs Reprints Permission to Copy Back Issues Articles published in MIT Sloan Management Review are copyrighted by the Massachusetts Institute of Technology unless otherwise specified at the end of an article.
  • 40. MIT Sloan Management Review articles, permissions, and back issues can be purchased on our Web site: sloanreview.mit.edu or you may order through our Business Service Center (9 a.m.-5 p.m. ET) at the phone numbers listed below. Paper reprints are available in quantities of 250 or more. To reproduce or transmit one or more MIT Sloan Management Review articles by electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying or archiving in any information storage or retrieval system) requires written permission. To request permission, use our Web site: sloanreview.mit.edu or E-mail: [email protected] Call (US and International):617-253-7170 Fax: 617-258-9739 Posting of full-text SMR articles on publicly accessible Internet sites is prohibited. To obtain permission to post articles on secure and/or password- protected intranet sites, e-mail your request to [email protected] MITMIT SLSLOOAN MANAAN MANAGEMENGEMENT REVIEWT REVIEW LEADERSHIPLEADERSHIP Copyright © Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2017. All rights reserved. Reprint #59110 http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjs For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020.
  • 41. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://sloanreview.mit.edu http://sloanreview.mit.edu mailto:[email protected] mailto:[email protected] http://mitsmr.com/2gNaJjsd41d8cd98f00b204e9800998ecf8427e -3.pdfThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsDual Systems of ThinkingRationalizing Unethical BehaviorAbout the ResearchDenying ResponsibilityDenying InjuryDenying the VictimCondemning the CondemnersAppealing to Higher LoyaltiesUsing a Ledger MetaphorClaiming EntitlementClaiming Relative Acceptability or NormalityHow Rationalizations Undermine Compliance ProgramsCombating RationalizationsAbout the AuthorReferencesd41d8cd98f00b204e9800998ecf8427e- 24.pdfFall 2017 IssueThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsThe Trouble With Corporate Compliance ProgramsDual Systems of ThinkingRationalizing Unethical BehaviorAbout the ResearchDenying ResponsibilityDenying InjuryDenying the VictimCondemning the CondemnersAppealing to Higher LoyaltiesUsing a Ledger MetaphorClaiming EntitlementClaiming Relative Acceptability or NormalityHow Rationalizations Undermine Compliance ProgramsCombating RationalizationsAbout the AuthorReferences HBR.ORG DECEMBER 2015 REPRINT R1512B THE BIG IDEA
  • 42. What Is Disruptive Innovation? Twenty years after the introduction of the theory, we revisit what it does—and doesn’t—explain. by Clayton M. Christensen, Michael Raynor, and Rory McDonald For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org http://hbr.org/search/R1512B THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS 2 Harvard Business Review December 2015 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. Twenty years after the introduction of the theory, we revisit what it does—and
  • 43. doesn’t—explain. BY CLAYTON M. CHRISTENSEN, MICHAEL RAYNOR, AND RORY MCDONALD Clayton M. Christensen is the Kim B. Clark Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School. Michael Raynor is a director at Deloitte Consulting LLP. Rory McDonald is an assistant professor at Harvard Business School. December 2015 Harvard Business Review 3 FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783- 7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org The problem with conflating a disruptive in- novation with any breakthrough that changes an industry’s competitive patterns is that different
  • 44. types of innovation require different strategic ap- proaches. To put it another way, the lessons we’ve learned about succeeding as a disruptive innovator (or defending against a disruptive challenger) will not apply to every company in a shifting market. If we get sloppy with our labels or fail to integrate insights from subsequent research and experience into the original theory, then managers may end up using the wrong tools for their context, reduc- ing their chances of success. Over time, the theory’s usefulness will be undermined. This article is part of an effort to capture the state of the art. We begin by exploring the basic tenets of disruptive innovation and examining whether they apply to Uber. Then we point out some common pitfalls in the theory’s application, how these arise, and why correctly using the theory matters. We go on to trace major turning points in the evolution of our thinking and make the case that what we have learned allows us to more accurately predict which businesses will grow. First, a quick recap of the idea: “Disruption” de- scribes a process whereby a smaller company with fewer resources is able to successfully challenge established incumbent businesses. Specifically, as incumbents focus on improving their products and services for their most demanding (and usually most profitable) customers, they exceed the needs of some segments and ignore the needs of others. Entrants that prove disruptive begin by success- fully targeting those overlooked segments, gaining a foothold by delivering more-suitable functionality— frequently at a lower price. Incumbents, chasing higher profitability in more-demanding segments,
  • 45. tend not to respond vigorously. Entrants then move upmarket, delivering the performance that incum- bents’ mainstream customers require, while pre- serving the advantages that drove their early success. When mainstream customers start adopting the en- trants’ offerings in volume, disruption has occurred. (See the exhibit “The Disruptive Innovation Model.”) Is Uber a Disruptive Innovation? Let’s consider Uber, the much-feted transportation company whose mobile application connects con- sumers who need rides with drivers who are willing to provide them. Founded in 2009, the company has Unfortunately, disruption theory is in danger of becoming a victim of its own success. Despite broad dissemination, the theory’s core concepts have been widely misunderstood and its basic tenets fre- quently misapplied. Furthermore, essential refine- ments in the theory over the past 20 years appear to have been overshadowed by the popularity of the initial formulation. As a result, the theory is some- times criticized for shortcomings that have already been addressed. There’s another troubling concern: In our expe- rience, too many people who speak of “disruption” have not read a serious book or article on the subject. Too frequently, they use the term loosely to invoke the concept of innovation in support of whatever it is they wish to do. Many researchers, writers, and con- sultants use “disruptive innovation” to describe any situation in which an industry is shaken up and pre- viously successful incumbents stumble. But that’s much too broad a usage.
  • 46. he theory of disruptive innovation, introduced in these pages in 1995, has proved to be a powerful way of thinking about innovation-driven growth. Many leaders of small, entrepreneurial companies praise it as their guiding star; so do many executives at large, well-established organizations, including Intel, Southern New Hampshire University, and Salesforce.com. THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION? 4 Harvard Business Review December 20154 Harvard Business Review December 2015 COPYRIGHT © 2015 HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PUBLISHING CORPORATION. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. enjoyed fantastic growth (it operates in hundreds of cities in 60 countries and is still expanding). It has reported tremendous financial success (the most recent funding round implies an enterprise value in the vicinity of $50 billion). And it has spawned a slew
  • 47. of imitators (other start-ups are trying to emulate its “market-making” business model). Uber is clearly transforming the taxi business in the United States. But is it disrupting the taxi business? According to the theory, the answer is no. Uber’s financial and strategic achievements do not qualify the company as genuinely disruptive—although the company is almost always described that way. Here are two reasons why the label doesn’t fit. Disruptive innovations originate in low-end or new-market footholds. Disruptive innovations are made possible because they get started in two types of markets that incumbents overlook. Low- end footholds exist because incumbents typically try to provide their most profitable and demanding customers with ever-improving products and ser- vices, and they pay less attention to less-demanding customers. In fact, incumbents’ offerings often over- shoot the performance requirements of the latter. This opens the door to a disrupter focused (at first) on providing those low-end customers with a “good enough” product. In the case of new-market footholds, disrupt- ers create a market where none existed. Put simply, they find a way to turn nonconsumers into consum- ers. For example, in the early days of photocopying technology, Xerox targeted large corporations and charged high prices in order to provide the perfor- mance that those customers required. School librar- ians, bowling-league operators, and other small customers, priced out of the market, made do with carbon paper or mimeograph machines. Then in
  • 48. the late 1970s, new challengers introduced personal Idea in Brief THE ISSUE The ideas summed up in the phrase “disruptive innovation” have become a powerful part of business thinking—but they’re in danger of losing their usefulness because they’ve been misunderstood and misapplied. THE RESPONSE The leading authorities on disruptive innovation revisit the central tenets of disruption theory, its development over the past 20 years, and its limitations. THE BOTTOM LINE Does it matter whether Uber, say, is a disruptive innovation or something else entirely? It does: We can’t manage innovation effectively if we don’t grasp its true nature. copiers, offering an affordable solution to individu- als and small organizations—and a new market was created. From this relatively modest beginning, per- sonal photocopier makers gradually built a major position in the mainstream photocopier market that Xerox valued.
  • 49. A disruptive innovation, by definition, starts from one of those two footholds. But Uber did not originate in either one. It is difficult to claim that the company found a low-end opportunity: That would have meant taxi service providers had overshot the needs of a material number of customers by mak- ing cabs too plentiful, too easy to use, and too clean. Neither did Uber primarily target nonconsumers— people who found the existing alternatives so expen- sive or inconvenient that they took public transit or drove themselves instead: Uber was launched in San Francisco (a well-served taxi market), and Uber’s customers were generally people already in the habit of hiring rides. Uber has quite arguably been increasing total demand—that’s what happens when you develop a better, less-expensive solution to a widespread customer need. But disrupters start by appealing to low-end or unserved consumers and then migrate to the mainstream market. Uber has gone in exactly the opposite direction: building a position in the main- stream market first and subsequently appealing to historically overlooked segments. Disruptive innovations don’t catch on with mainstream customers until quality catches up to their standards. Disruption theory differ- entiates disruptive innovations from what are called “sustaining innovations.” The latter make good prod- ucts better in the eyes of an incumbent’s existing customers: the fifth blade in a razor, the clearer TV picture, better mobile phone reception. These im- provements can be incremental advances or major
  • 50. December 2015 Harvard Business Review 5 FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783- 7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org breakthroughs, but they all enable firms to sell more products to their most profitable customers. Disruptive innovations, on the other hand, are initially considered inferior by most of an incum- bent’s customers. Typically, customers are not will- ing to switch to the new offering merely because it is less expensive. Instead, they wait until its quality rises enough to satisfy them. Once that’s happened, they adopt the new product and happily accept its lower price. (This is how disruption drives prices down in a market.) Most of the elements of Uber’s strategy seem to be sustaining innovations. Uber’s service has rarely been described as inferior to existing taxis; in fact, many would say it is better. Booking a ride requires just a few taps on a smartphone; payment is cash- less and convenient; and passengers can rate their rides afterward, which helps ensure high standards. Furthermore, Uber delivers service reliably and punctually, and its pricing is usually competitive
  • 51. with (or lower than) that of established taxi services. And as is typical when incumbents face threats from sustaining innovations, many of the taxi compa- nies are motivated to respond. They are deploying competitive technologies, such as hailing apps, and contesting the legality of some of Uber’s services. Why Getting It Right Matters Readers may still be wondering, Why does it matter what words we use to describe Uber? The company has certainly thrown the taxi industry into disarray: Isn’t that “disruptive” enough? No. Applying the theory correctly is essential to realizing its benefits. For example, small competitors that nibble away at the periphery of your business very likely should be ignored—unless they are on a disruptive trajectory, in which case they are a potentially mortal threat. And both of these challenges are fundamentally different from efforts by competitors to woo your bread-and-butter customers. As the example of Uber shows, identifying true disruptive innovation is tricky. Yet even executives with a good understanding of disruption theory tend to forget some of its subtler aspects when making strategic decisions. We’ve observed four important points that get overlooked or misunderstood: 1. Disruption is a process. The term “disrup- tive innovation” is misleading when it is used to refer to a product or service at one fixed point, rather than to the evolution of that product or service over time. The first minicomputers were disruptive not merely because they were low-end upstarts when they ap-
  • 52. peared on the scene, nor because they were later heralded as superior to mainframes in many mar- kets; they were disruptive by virtue of the path they followed from the fringe to the mainstream. Most every innovation—disruptive or not— begins life as a small-scale experiment. Disrupters tend to focus on getting the business model, rather than merely the product, just right. When they suc- ceed, their movement from the fringe (the low end of the market or a new market) to the mainstream erodes first the incumbents’ market share and then their profitability. This process can take time, and incumbents can get quite creative in the defense of their established franchises. For example, more than 50 years after the first discount department store was opened, mainstream retail companies still operate their traditional department-store formats. Complete substitution, if it comes at all, may take decades, because the incremental profit from stay- ing with the old model for one more year trumps proposals to write off the assets in one stroke. The fact that disruption can take time helps to explain why incumbents frequently overlook dis- rupters. For example, when Netflix launched, in 1997, its initial service wasn’t appealing to most of Blockbuster’s customers, who rented movies (typically new releases) on impulse. Netflix had an exclusively online interface and a large inventory of isrupters first appeal to low-end or unserved customers and then migrate to the mainstream
  • 53. market. Uber has gone in the opposite direction: building a position in the mainstream market first and then appealing to historically overlooked segments. THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION? 6 Harvard Business Review December 2015 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. movies, but delivery through the U.S. mail meant selections took several days to arrive. The service ap- pealed to only a few customer groups—movie buffs who didn’t care about new releases, early adopters of DVD players, and online shoppers. If Netflix had not eventually begun to serve a broader segment of the market, Blockbuster’s decision to ignore this com- petitor would not have been a strategic blunder: The two companies filled very different needs for their (different) customers. However, as new technologies allowed Netflix to shift to streaming video over the internet, the company did eventually become appealing to Blockbuster’s core customers, offering a wider se- lection of content with an all-you-can-watch, on- demand, low-price, high-quality, highly convenient approach. And it got there via a classically disruptive
  • 54. path. If Netflix (like Uber) had begun by launching a service targeted at a larger competitor’s core market, Blockbuster’s response would very likely have been a vigorous and perhaps successful counterattack. But failing to respond effectively to the trajectory that Netflix was on led Blockbuster to collapse. 2. Disrupters often build business models that are very different from those of incum- bents. Consider the health care industry. General practitioners operating out of their offices often rely on their years of experience and on test results to interpret patients’ symptoms, make diagnoses, and prescribe treatment. We call this a “solution shop” business model. In contrast, a number of conve- nient care clinics are taking a disruptive path by us- ing what we call a “process” business model: They follow standardized protocols to diagnose and treat a small but increasing number of disorders. One high-profile example of using an innova- tive business model to effect a disruption is Apple’s iPhone. The product that Apple debuted in 2007 was a sustaining innovation in the smartphone market: It targeted the same customers coveted by incumbents, and its initial success is likely explained by product superiority. The iPhone’s subsequent growth is bet- ter explained by disruption—not of other smart- phones but of the laptop as the primary access point to the internet. This was achieved not merely through product improvements but also through the THE DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION MODEL This diagram contrasts product performance trajectories (the red
  • 55. lines showing how products or services improve over time) with customer demand trajectories (the blue lines showing customers’ willingness to pay for performance). As incumbent companies introduce higher-quality products or services (upper red line) to satisfy the high end of the market (where profitability is highest), they overshoot the needs of low-end customers and many mainstream customers. This leaves an opening for entrants to find footholds in the less-profitable segments that incumbents are neglecting. Entrants on a disruptive trajectory (lower red line) improve the performance of their offerings and move upmarket (where profitability is highest for them, too) and challenge the dominance of the incumbents. HIGHER LOWER PR O D U C T
  • 58. PERFOR MANCE CUSTO MERS W ILL PAY FOR HIGH E ND OF THE MARKE T MOST P ROFITA BLE December 2015 Harvard Business Review 7 FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783- 7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org
  • 59. introduction of a new business model. By building a facilitated network connecting application develop- ers with phone users, Apple changed the game. The iPhone created a new market for internet access and eventually was able to challenge laptops as main- stream users’ device of choice for going online. 3. Some disruptive innovations succeed; some don’t. A third common mistake is to focus on the results achieved—to claim that a company is disruptive by virtue of its success. But success is not built into the definition of disruption: Not every disruptive path leads to a triumph, and not every tri- umphant newcomer follows a disruptive path. For example, any number of internet-based re- tailers pursued disruptive paths in the late 1990s, but only a small number prospered. The failures are not evidence of the deficiencies of disruption theory; they are simply boundary markers for the theory’s application. The theory says very little about how to win in the foothold market, other than to play the odds and avoid head-on competition with better-resourced incumbents. If we call every business success a “disruption,” then companies that rise to the top in very differ- ent ways will be seen as sources of insight into a common strategy for succeeding. This creates a dan- ger: Managers may mix and match behaviors that are very likely inconsistent with one another and thus unlikely to yield the hoped-for result. For example, both Uber and Apple’s iPhone owe their success to a platform-based model: Uber digitally connects
  • 60. riders with drivers; the iPhone connects app devel- opers with phone users. But Uber, true to its nature as a sustaining innovation, has focused on expand- ing its network and functionality in ways that make it better than traditional taxis. Apple, on the other hand, has followed a disruptive path by building its ecosystem of app developers so as to make the iPhone more like a personal computer. 4. The mantra “Disrupt or be disrupted” can misguide us. Incumbent companies do need to respond to disruption if it’s occurring, but they should not overreact by dismantling a still- profitable business. Instead, they should continue to strengthen relationships with core customers by investing in sustaining innovations. In addition, they can create a new division focused solely on the growth opportunities that arise from the disrup- tion. Our research suggests that the success of this new enterprise depends in large part on keeping THE UBIQUITOUS “DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION” “Disruptive innovation” and “disruptive technology” are now part of the popular business lexicon, as suggested by the dramatic growth in the number of articles using those phrases in recent years.
  • 61. SOURCE FACTIVA ANALYSIS OF A WIDE VARIETY OF ENGLISH-LANGUAGE PUBLICATIONS 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 ARTICLES THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION? 8 Harvard Business Review December 2015 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. it separate from the core business. That means that for some time, incumbents will find themselves managing two very different operations. Of course, as the disruptive stand-alone business grows, it may eventually steal customers from the
  • 62. core. But corporate leaders should not try to solve this problem before it is a problem. What a Disruptive Innovation Lens Can Reveal It is rare that a technology or product is inherently sustaining or disruptive. And when new technol- ogy is developed, disruption theory does not dictate what managers should do. Instead it helps them make a strategic choice between taking a sustaining path and taking a disruptive one. The theory of disruption predicts that when an entrant tackles incumbent competitors head-on, of- fering better products or services, the incumbents will accelerate their innovations to defend their business. Either they will beat back the entrant by offering even better services or products at compa- rable prices, or one of them will acquire the entrant. The data supports the theory’s prediction that en- trants pursuing a sustaining strategy for a stand- alone business will face steep odds: In Christensen’s seminal study of the disk drive industry, only 6% of sustaining entrants managed to succeed. Uber’s strong performance therefore warrants ex- planation. According to disruption theory, Uber is an outlier, and we do not have a universal way to account for such atypical outcomes. In Uber’s case, we believe that the regulated nature of the taxi business is a large part of the answer. Market entry and prices are closely controlled in many jurisdictions. Consequently, taxi companies have rarely innovated. Individual drivers have few ways to innovate, except to defect to Uber. So Uber is in a unique situation relative to taxis: It can offer better quality and the competition will find it
  • 63. hard to respond, at least in the short term. To this point, we’ve addressed only whether or not Uber is disruptive to the taxi business. The lim- ousine or “black car” business is a different story, and here Uber is far more likely to be on a disruptive path. The company’s UberSELECT option provides more-luxurious cars and is typically more expensive than its standard service—but typically less expen- sive than hiring a traditional limousine. This lower price imposes some compromises, as UberSELECT currently does not include one defining feature of the leading incumbents in this market: acceptance of advance reservations. Consequently, this offering from Uber appeals to the low end of the limousine service market: customers willing to sacrifice a mea- sure of convenience for monetary savings. Should Uber find ways to match or exceed incumbents’ performance levels without compromising its cost and price advantage, the company appears to be well positioned to move into the mainstream of the limo business—and it will have done so in classically disruptive fashion. How Our Thinking About Disruption Has Developed Initially, the theory of disruptive innovation was simply a statement about correlation. Empirical findings showed that incumbents outperformed entrants in a sustaining innovation context but un- derperformed in a disruptive innovation context. The reason for this correlation was not immediately evident, but one by one, the elements of the theory fell into place.
  • 64. First, researchers realized that a company’s pro- pensity for strategic change is profoundly affected by the interests of customers who provide the re- sources the firm needs to survive. In other words, in- cumbents (sensibly) listen to their existing custom- ers and concentrate on sustaining innovations as a result. Researchers then arrived at a second insight: ncumbent companies should not overreact to disruption by dismantling a still-profitable business. Instead they should strengthen relationships with core customers while also creating a new division focused on the growth opportunities that arise from the disruption. December 2015 Harvard Business Review 9 FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783- 7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org Incumbents’ focus on their existing customers be- comes institutionalized in internal processes that
  • 65. make it difficult for even senior managers to shift investment to disruptive innovations. For example, interviews with managers of established companies in the disk drive industry revealed that resource allo- cation processes prioritized sustaining innovations (which had high margins and targeted large markets with well-known customers) while inadvertently starving disruptive innovations (meant for smaller markets with poorly defined customers). Those two insights helped explain why in- cumbents rarely responded effectively (if at all) to disruptive innovations, but not why entrants eventually moved upmarket to challenge incum- bents, over and over again. It turns out, however, that the same forces leading incumbents to ignore early-stage disruptions also compel disrupters ultimately to disrupt. What we’ve realized is that, very often, low-end and new-market footholds are populated not by a lone would-be disrupter, but by several comparable entrant firms whose products are simpler, more con- venient, or less costly than those sold by incumbents. The incumbents provide a de facto price umbrella, allowing many of the entrants to enjoy profitable growth within the foothold market. But that lasts only for a time: As incumbents (rationally, but mis- takenly) cede the foothold market, they effectively remove the price umbrella, and price-based com- petition among the entrants reigns. Some entrants will founder, but the smart ones—the true disrupt- ers—will improve their products and drive upmar- ket, where, once again, they can compete at the margin against higher-cost established competitors.
  • 66. The disruptive effect drives every competitor— incumbent and entrant—upmarket. With those explanations in hand, the theory of disruptive innovation went beyond simple corre- lation to a theory of causation as well. The key ele- ments of that theory have been tested and validated through studies of many industries, including retail, computers, printing, motorcycles, cars, semicon- ductors, cardiovascular surgery, management edu- cation, financial services, management consulting, cameras, communications, and computer-aided design software. Making sense of anomalies. Additional re- finements to the theory have been made to address certain anomalies, or unexpected scenarios, that the theory could not explain. For example, we origi- nally assumed that any disruptive innovation took root in the lowest tiers of an established market— yet sometimes new entrants seemed to be compet- ing in entirely new markets. This led to the distinc- tion we discussed earlier between low-end and new-market footholds. Low-end disrupters (think steel minimills and discount retailers) come in at the bottom of the mar- ket and take hold within an existing value network before moving upmarket and attacking that stratum (think integrated steel mills and traditional retail- ers). By contrast, new-market disruptions take hold in a completely new value network and appeal to customers who have previously gone without the product. Consider the transistor pocket radio and the PC: They were largely ignored by manufacturers of tabletop radios and minicomputers, respectively,
  • 67. because they were aimed at nonconsumers of those goods. By postulating that there are two flavors of foothold markets in which disruptive innovation can begin, the theory has become more powerful and practicable. Another intriguing anomaly was the identifi- cation of industries that have resisted the forces of disruption, at least until very recently. Higher education in the United States is one of these. Over the years—indeed, over more than 100 years—new kinds of institutions with different initial charters have been created to address the needs of various population segments, including nonconsumers. Land-grant universities, teachers’ colleges, two-year colleges, and so on were initially launched to serve those for whom a traditional four-year liberal arts education was out of reach or unnecessary. s there a novel technology or business model that allows entrants in higher education to follow a disruptive path? The answer seems to be yes, and the enabling innovation is online learning. THE BIG IDEA WHAT IS DISRUPTIVE INNOVATION? 10 Harvard Business Review December 2015 For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020.
  • 68. Many of these new entrants strived to improve over time, compelled by analogues of the pursuit of profitability: a desire for growth, prestige, and the capacity to do greater good. Thus they made costly investments in research, dormitories, athletic fa- cilities, faculty, and so on, seeking to emulate more- elite institutions. Doing so has increased their level of performance in some ways—they can provide richer learning and living environments for students, for example. Yet the relative standing of higher- education institutions remains largely unchanged: With few exceptions, the top 20 are still the top 20, and the next 50 are still in that second tier, decade after decade. Because both incumbents and newcomers are seemingly following the same game plan, it is per- haps no surprise that incumbents are able to main- tain their positions. What has been missing—until recently—is experimentation with new models that successfully appeal to today’s nonconsumers of higher education. The question now is whether there is a novel technology or business model that allows new en- trants to move upmarket without emulating the in- cumbents’ high costs—that is, to follow a disruptive path. The answer seems to be yes, and the enabling innovation is online learning, which is becoming broadly available. Real tuition for online courses is falling, and accessibility and quality are improving. Innovators are making inroads into the mainstream market at a stunning pace.
  • 69. Will online education disrupt the incumbents’ model? And if so, when? In other words, will on- line education’s trajectory of improvement in- tersect with the needs of the mainstream mar- ket? We’ve come to realize that the steepness of any disruptive trajectory is a function of how quickly the enabling technology improves. In the steel industry, continuous-casting technol- ogy improved quite slowly, and it took more than 40 years before the minimill Nucor matched the revenue of the largest integrated steelmakers. In contrast, the digital technologies that allowed personal computers to disrupt minicomputers improved much more quickly; Compaq was able to increase revenue more than tenfold and reach parity with the industry leader, DEC, in only 12 years. Understanding what drives the rate of disruption is helpful for predicting outcomes, but it doesn’t al- ter the way disruptions should be managed. Rapid disruptions are not fundamentally different from any others; they don’t have different causal mechanisms and don’t require conceptually different responses. Similarly, it is a mistake to assume that the strat- egies adopted by some high-profile entrants con- stitute a special kind of disruption. Often these are simply miscategorized. Tesla Motors is a current and salient example. One might be tempted to say the company is disruptive. But its foothold is in the high end of the auto market (with customers willing to spend $70,000 or more on a car), and this segment is not uninteresting to incumbents. Tesla’s entry, not surprisingly, has elicited significant attention and in-
  • 70. vestment from established competitors. If disruption theory is correct, Tesla’s future holds either acquisi- tion by a much larger incumbent or a years-long and hard-fought battle for market significance. We still have a lot to learn. We are eager to keep expanding and refining the theory of disruptive innovation, and much work lies ahead. For example, universally effective responses to disruptive threats remain elusive. Our current belief is that companies should create a separate division that operates un- der the protection of senior leadership to explore and exploit a new disruptive model. Sometimes this works—and sometimes it doesn’t. In certain cases, a failed response to a disruptive threat cannot be attrib uted to a lack of understanding, insufficient executive attention, or inadequate financial invest- ment. The challenges that arise from being an in- cumbent and an entrant simultaneously have yet to be fully specified; how best to meet those challenges is still to be discovered. Disruption theory does not, and never will, ex- plain everything about innovation specifically or business success generally. Far too many other forces are in play, each of which will reward further study. Integrating them all into a comprehensive theory of business success is an ambitious goal, one we are unlikely to attain anytime soon. But there is cause for hope: Empirical tests show that using disruptive theory makes us measurably and significantly more accurate in our predictions of which fledgling businesses will succeed. As an ever-growing community of researchers and practi- tioners continues to build on disruption theory and
  • 71. integrate it with other perspectives, we will come to an even better understanding of what helps firms innovate successfully. HBR Reprint R1512B December 2015 Harvard Business Review 11 FOR ARTICLE REPRINTS CALL 800-988-0886 OR 617-783- 7500, OR VISIT HBR.ORG For the exclusive use of L. BING, 2020. This document is authorized for use only by LINTING BING in BUS 109-030 taught by Paul Kirwan, University of California - Riverside from Jan 2020 to Mar 2020. http://hbr.org/search/R1512B http://hbr.org