SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Vol 25 Issue 10 Oct 2003
A journal concerning the management of technology, copyrights and trade names
European
Intellectual
Property
Review
Intellectual Property and Competition:
Does the Essential Facilities Doctrine
Shed Any New Light?
GregoryV.S. McCurdy
mcnviscj
SWEET & tVIAXWELL
ISSN 0142-0461
472 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.I.P.R.
For years, legal scholars and practitioners on both sides
of the Atlantic have grappled with the complexities that
may arise in applying competition law to commercial
disputes involving intellectual property (“IP”). In a
handful of recent cases, plaintiffs have invoked a novel
competition law and antitrust theory known as the
“essential facilities” doctrine to challenge a defendant’s
exercise of its IP rights. Plaintiffs in these cases typically
contend that the defendant’s refusal to provide access to
certain IP under reasonable terms unlawfully impeded
the plaintiff’s ability to compete in a downstream
market.
The essential facilities doctrine first arose in the
United States in an effort to analyse refusals to deal
involving physical facilities and tangible assets. It has
gradually been adapted for similar purposes in Europe.
But attempts by plaintiffs to extend it to the analysis of
situations involving refusals to license intangible intel
lectual property rights are more recent, and thus far less
successful, at least in the courts. This raises the ques
tion whether the doctrine offers any significant advance
over traditional refusal-to-deal analysis, and specifically
whether the doctrine sheds any new light on the proper
competitive boundaries on refusing to license intangible
property rights like copyrights and patents.
The author is not sure that he can fully answer those
questions here. But the proper foundation for any con
structive discussion is a solid overview of how the doc
trine has, and has not, developed in the courts. Because
the author is a US practitioner, and because during his
time in Europe he has heard many there invoke the US
experience to ascribe a broader scope, and more
“potency”, to the doctrine in the IF context than it has
really achieved, he plans to focus primarily on the US
case law and offer only a limited comparison to the EU
body of decisions.
Greg McC’urdy is an attorney at Microsoft Corporation based in
Seattle, Washinxson, United States, where he manages US and Inter
national commercial and competition law disputes. Mr MoCurdy
graduated from Harvard University and studied law at NYU and
Kings College London. He practiced lass in New York befare joining
Microsoft’s legal department in Paris where he was based from
2000-2002. The views expressed herein are solely those of the author
and de not necessarfy represent the position of Microsoft Corpora-
The first part of this article examines how US courts
have interpreted the essential facilities doctrine in vari
ous contexts, including a limited number of cases in
which plaintiffs have sought, unsuccessfully, to use the
doctrine as a basis for attacking a defendant’s exercise
of its IP rights, This survey shows that, of those courts
that have accepted the essential facilities doctrine, they
have tended to interpret the doctrine narrowly and have
been reluctant to extend it beyond situations in which
the defendant’s control of the facility in question ena
bled it effectively to eliminate competition in the down
stream market. Merely possessing an advantage, even a
considerable one, is not enough, and the ability of a
plaintiff or others to achieve even quite small gains in
market share without access to the facility will normally
be enough to defeat an essential facilities claim. It also
suggests that a defendant’s otherwise lawful invocation
of its intellectual property rights will rarely, if ever, form
the basis of a successful claim.
The second part of the article then discusses, much
more briefly, the development of the essential facilities
doctrine in EU decisions and suggests that a similarly
narrow interpretation of the doctrine may be emerging
in Europe as well.
The Essent& FacWties Doctrine under US
Law
Although the contours of the essential facilities doctrine
are, in the words of one federal appeals court, “still far
from clear”,1 courts that have endorsed the doctrine
generally view it as a specific instance of the broader
category of antitrust claims based on unlawful refusals
to deal. Essential facilities claims typically arise where
an actual or potential monopolist refuses to provide a
competitor access to a facility that is alleged to be
“essential” to competition. Plaintiffs often invoke the
doctrine to support a claim that a vertically integrated
monopolist should be required to share a specific input
with its competitors in a downstream market.2
Thus:
“[t]he essential facility claim is about the duty to deal of
a monopolist who is able to supply an input for itself in a
fashion that is so superior to anything else available that
others cannot succeed unless they can access this firm’s
input as well.”
By controlling an essential facility, a monopolist is
alleged to be able to extend its monopoly “from one
stage of production to another and from one market
into another”.4
As a “recent addition to antitrust jurisprudence”,5
I City ofAnaheim uS Cal Edison Co 955 F. 2d 1373, 1379 (9th
Cir. 1992).
2 Because most essential facilities claims focus on the actions
of a single firm, rather than on an unlawful agreement or combi
nation, such claims usually arise under s.2 of the Sherman Act.
See, e.g., Alaska Airlines, Inc. v United Airlines, Inc., 948 F. 2d
536, 542 (9th Cir. 1991), cert, denied, 503 U.S. 977 (1992).
3 lilA Phillip P. Areeda and Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
Law ¶ 771a, at p.174.
4 MIC’ommunications Corp vAT&To 708 F. 2d 1081, 1132
(7th Cir, 1983), cert, denied, 464 U.S. 891 (1983),
5 TGA Bldg Co v Northwestern Res Co 873 F. Supp. 29, 39
‘rex. 1995).
Intellectual Property and
Competition: Does the
Essential Facilities
Doctrine Shed Any New
Light?
GREGORY V. S. MCCURDY
Microsoft Corporation, Redmond, WA, USA
voW: EI TSR Issue to C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMTT’Ei) ASSET CONTRJEUTORSJ
MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.LP.R 473
the essential facilities doctrine has never been expressly
endorsed by the US Supreme Court° and has been
disparaged by leading antitrust scholars. For instance,
Professors Areeda and Hovenkamp (authors of the
leading treatise on US antitrust law) have criticised the
doctrine on the ground that requiring a firm to offer its
competitors access to a key upstream asset generally
does not help consumers, because price and output
generally remain the same while the right to share in the
monopoly reduces the incentive of competitors to
develop competing upstream assetst: “Forcing a firm to
share its inputs with a rival is an exceptionally drastic
antitrust remedy, having the consequences of preserv
ing the monopoly and often of turning the defendant’s
facility into what amounts to a public utility. “
Areeda
and Hovenkamp conclude that: “the ‘essential facility’
doctrine is both harmful and unnecessary and should
be abandoned”.9
Despite this rather tenuous foundation, it is not
uncommon for plaintiffs to raise essential facilities argu
ments in the context of broader challenges to alleged
anti-competitive activity. The leading formulation of
the essential facilities doctrine, first articulated by the
Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit in M’I Com
munications, requires the plaintiff to show:
(1) control of the essential facility by a monopo
list;
(2) a competitor’s inability practically or reasonably
to duplicate the essential facility;
(3) the denial of the use of the facility to a com
petitor; and
(4) feasibility of providing the facility)0
Also, courts refuse to recognise essential facilities claims
unless the plaintiff and defendant actually compete in a
downstream market. For instance, in America Online,
Inc v Greatdeals. nez,” a distributor of unsolicited bulk
email messages—commonly known as “spam”
—claimed that AOL’s efforts to block its messages from
reaching AOL subscribers constituted denial of access
to an essential facility (the facility in this case being
AOL’s Internet access nodes).’2 In rejecting this claim,
the court held that “[t]he essential facilities doctrine is
inapplicable where the alleged monopolist and the
6 Us courts often trace the essential facilities doctrine to three
Supreme Court decisions, United States v Terminal RailroadAsso
c,anon 224 U.S. 383 (1912) involved control of a railroad bridge
crossing the Mississippi River at the only point where a bridge
could be built to serve that part,cular region Associated Press e
United States 326 U.S 1 (1945) involved admission and access to
the Associated Press wire ‘ervice from which citl and reg,onal
newspapers could obtain national and international ne s stories.
Otter Tail Power Coo United States 410 U.S. 366 (1973). involved
access to an electrical power transmission line which constituted
a natural monopoly within a traditionally regulated industry
None of these dec,s,ons, hossever, expressly endorses an essen
tal facilities doctrine The first two cases concerned agreements
among competitors held illegal under s. 1 of the Sherman Act.
Otter Tad. uhile involving un,lateral conduct, irnolved a number
of ,ue geris isSues and does not actually endorse the essential
fac,,ues dcctrute a,
7 Areeda and Hmenkornp. 3 abase. 771h. at
cc
s
at
41C1,n.4thosc,atU3f .1c3
C 49F Sorr 2c1S5 EU To
plaintiff do not compete”,’3 and noted that the distrib
utor had “fail[ed] to allege or plead any facts from
which the court could infer that [the distributor] and
AOL are competitors”.’4
Although the MCI articulation of the essential facili
ties doctrine, on its own, could conceivably be inter
preted to encompass a broad range of conduct, US
courts have read the doctrine narrowly. The following
survey of cases examines how courts in the United States
have applied the doctrine in various factual scenarios.
Control of an essential facility
The first element of the MCI test examines whether the
facility to which the plaintiff was denied access is in fact
“essential”. In addressing this issue, courts have held
that a facility will be deemed essential “only if control of
the facility carries with it the power to eliminate com
petition in the downstream market”,’5 or if denial of
access to the facility “inflicts a severe handicap on
potential market entrants”)’ At least one court has
also suggested that, to establish a successful essential
facilities claim, “[t]he power to eliminate competition
must not be momentary, but must be at least relatively
permanent”.’6
In practice, courts generally deem a facility to be
essential only if denial of access to the facility eliminates
even the possibility of competition in the downstream
market, Thus, in MCI and Covad Communications, the
defendants’ refusal to provide plaintiffs with access to
defendants’ local telephone exchanges (i.e. the “local
loop”) made it impossible for plaintiffs to offer tele
communications services to potential customers,
thereby totally excluding plaintiffs from the relevant
downstream markets.’7 Likewise, a defendant’s refusal
13 ibid.
14 ibid. Accord Intergraph Corp v Intel Corp, 195 F. 3d 1346,
1356—1357 (Fed. Cit. 1999) (holding that, under essential facili
ties doctrine: “there must be a market in which plaintiff and
defendant compete, such that a monopolist extends its monop
oly to the downstream market by refusing access to the facility it
controls”).
15 Paladin Associates, Inc v Montana Power Go 328 F. 3d 1145,
1163 (9th Cit. 2003) (citingAlaska Airlines, Inc v UnitedAirlines,
Inc 948 F. 2d 536, 544 (9th Cir, 1991), cert. denied, 503 U.S. 977
(1992)); accord Covad Communications Co v BellSouth Carp 299
F. 3d 1272, 1284 (11th Cir. 2002) (holding that essential facility
is one “without [access to] which a competitor cannot enter or
compete in a market”).
iSa Fishman v Wirtz 807 F. 2d 520, 539 (7th Cir. 1986).
Despite the superficial differences between these two formula
tions (i.e. eliminate competition v severe handicap), in practice
courts often conflate them. See, e.g., Advanced Health-Care Servs
Inc v Giles Mem’l Hasp 846 F. Supp. 488, 498 WD. Va. 1994)
(“Plaintiff must show that this denial [to the facility in question]
inflicted a ‘severe handicap’ that threatened to eliminate com
petition in the market ) (quoting Twin Labs Inc v Weider
Health & Fitness 900 F. 2d 566, 569—570 (2d Cir. 1990)).
16 AlaskaAirlines, 948 F. 2d at 544 nil.
17 See MCI, n.4 above, 1133 (involving provision of long-
distance and related telephone services); Covad Communications,
0.15 above, at i286—l288 (involving provision of DSL internet
access serv,ce’u accord Metranet Services Core u U S. ITaSi Corn—
municatio’,s 329 F. 3d 986. 1010—1013 (9th Cd. 2003) (holding
that the plaintiff adduced sufficient evidence that the defer.
oanrs- pricing policy for access to local loop macic it meoss-ibie
for the plaintiff to compete profitably svrth the defendant in
telecommunications services marker to w,thstand motion for
fi005 0 IrK ISSUE it C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiT 1) AXIs CONTRIBUTORSj
474 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] ELP.R.
to lease its stadium to a competing potential purchaser
of a professional sports franchise was deemed denial to
an essential facility where the sport’s governing body
refused to award the franchise to any party that could
not secure such a lease (a decision based in part on
defendant’s behind-the-scenes lobbying of the govern
ing body).’8
Where, by contrast, access to the facility in question
is not a pre-requisite to participation in the downstream
market, courts generally hold that such facilities are
non-essential—with little regard for the financial hard
ship that defendant’s actions impose on competitors.
Thus, in City ofAnaheim, a utility’s facility for accessing
an inexpensive source of electricity was deemed non
essential even though the utility’s refusal to grant access
to competitors in certain retail markets gave the utility a
substantial competitive advantage in those markets.’9
Similarly, in Alaska Airlines, the court held that the
defendant airlines’ proprietary computerised reserva
tions systems were not essential facilities—despite the
defendants’ ability to use these facilities to extract sub
stantial bookings fees from its competitors—as the sys
tems did not actually give defendants the “power to
eliminate competition in the downstream air transporta
tion market”.2°
Finally, proof that a defendant’s competitors were
able to increase market share without access to the
facility in question—regardless of the impact that denial
to the facility may have had on the plaintiff—will almost
always prove fatal to an essential facilities claim.2’
lnabWty to duphcate
The second element of the MCI test examines whether
competitors could “practically or reasonably. . . dupli
cate the essential facility”.22 As the Ninth Circuit has
noted, this inquiry is really a subset of the first MCI
element, as the inability to duplicate the facility “is
effectively part of the definition of what is an essential
facility in the first place. That is to say, if the facility can
be reasonably or practically duplicated it is highly
unlikely, even impossible, that it will be found to be
essential at all”.23 Nevertheless, most courts address the
first and second elements of the MCI test separately.
Here again, courts tend to construe this element nar
rowly, and the mere fact that duplication of the facility
would be costly or burdensome is usually deemed insuf
ficient to satisfy this element. Rather, plaintiffs tend to
succeed only where duplication of the facility would be
nearly impossible. As the Second Circuit has
observed:
18 See Fishman, n.15a above, at 539—540.
19 See City ofAnaheim, n.j above, at 1380—1381; accord Mid
west Gas Servs, Inc v Indiana Gas Co 317 F. 3d 703, 7 13—714
(7th Cir. 2003) (holding that direct interconnect to the defer,
dant’s gas pipeline was not an essential facility where the plaintiff
could access pipeline through a more expensive, indirect route.
reasoning that “the most economical route is not an essential
facility when other routes are available”).
20 Alaska Airlines, n,16 above, at 544—545 (emphasis added).
21 See, e.g., Twin Labs Ins, n,15a above, at 569—570;Advanced
HeaitlwGarc Servo ins, ni Sa above, at 498,
22 MGI, n,4 above, at 1132.
23 City ofAnahelin, n. I above, at 1380.
“A leading antitrust commentator would limit the analy
sis to ‘facilities that are a natural monopoly, facilities
whose duplication is forbidden by law, and perhaps those
that are publicly subsidized and thus could not practica
bly be built privately.’ Most of the successful essential
facility claims fall within the categories stated by this
commentator. In cases finding liability in other catego
ries, however, the facility in question was more than dom
inant; it was effectively the only one in town.”24
In Laurel Sand ‘ Gravel, Inc v CSX’ Transportation,
Inc,25 the court held that a national railroad’s refusal to
permit the plaintiff, a competing “shortline” railroad, to
use 1,700 feet of track did not support an essential
facilities claim, as the plaintiff could have built alter
native tracks or purchased rail service from the national
railroad.26 The court reached this conclusion despite
evidence that either alternative would have prevented
plaintiff from profitably offering competitive rates to
certain customers. Similarly, in Olympia Equipment
Leasing v Western Union Telephone Co,27 the court held
that defendant’s abrupt demand that its salesforce not
refer competing products to potential customers did not
support an essential facilities claim, as competitors
could simply hire their own salespeople.28 Evidence that
the defendant’s actions ultimately drove the plaintiff out
of business was deemed insufficient to establish an ina
bility to duplicate.
Plaintiffs that have succeeded in satisfying the second
element of the MCI test typically show that duplicating
the facility in question would have been nearly impos
sible. For instance, the courts in both MCI and Covad
Communications noted that neither plaintiff would have
been likely to obtain regulatory approval to duplicate
the type of local loop facilities to which they sought
access. 29
Denial of use of the facility
The third element of the MCI test examines whether
the defendant denied “use of the facility to a com
petitor”.3° Although proof of outright refusal to deal is
normally sufficient, courts have also indicated that
proof that the defendant “fail[ed] to make access to that
facility available to its competitors on fair and reasonable
terms” may also be adequate to support a finding for the
plaintiff.3’
Despite the apparent breadth of the “fair and reason
able terms” formulation, courts generally tend to look
for some evidence of bad faith that amounts to an effec
tive refusal to deal.32 Allegations that plaintiff’s access
24 Twin Labs, n. l5a above, at 569 (citations om,tted).
25 924 F. 2d 539 (4th C,r. 1991), cert. denied, 502 US. 814
(1991),
26 ibid. at 544—545.
27 797 F. 2d 370 (7th Cir, 1986), sew, denied, 480 US. 934
(1987).
28 tbzd. at 376—379
29 See MGI, n.4 above, at 1133; Cot ad Communzeations, n.15
abes.o. a: :285
30 MCI, n4 sOme, at 1133
31 Gonad Comnmovations, n,15 above, at 1287 (emphinzs by the
‘arr (quoting United States v ATdyT 524 F Supç 1336.
1352—1353 (DDC 198i))
32 See, e.g., Fishman, n,I Sn aoove, at 540 (holding that offer of
‘,sce to sports arena “did not show that [defendant] we” willing
t’ deal with [pUnnfl] on non’.diacriminatory terms
[2003: ErniE ISSUE 10 C SWEET & MAXWELL LLMTUEI) [AND CONTRIBUTORS)
MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] ELP.R. 475
to the facility was more expensive andior burdensome
than defendant’s access will normally be insufficient,
For instance, in Advanced Health-Care, the court held
that a hospital’s decision to grant in-hospital office
space and direct patient contact to one medical equip
ment provider (in exchange for a percentage of sales)
and to deny such access to the provider’s competitors
did not amount to a denial of access to hospital
patients.33 And inAlaska Airlines, the court held that the
booking fees charged by the defendant airlines to their
competitors for use of the defendants’ computerised
reservations systems did not constitute a denial of
access, on the ground that—given the plaintiffs’ con
tinued use of these systems—it was clear that “neither
[defendant has] ever set this fee at a level that would
drive their competitors away”.34
Feasibility of providing the facility
The fourth and final element of the MCI test examines
the feasibility of the defendant’s providing access to the
essential facility.35 As in other areas of antitrust liability,
a defendant that offers a legitimate business justification
for its refusal to provide access will normally avoid
liability.36
Laurel Sand illustrates the extent to which courts will
defer to a defendant’s real-world business needs in eval
uating feasibility. In denying an essential facilities claim
based on a railroad’s refusal to allow a competitor to use
of a portion of its tracks, the court stated:
“The feasibility of providing access to the tracks must be
analyzed not in terms of all the possibilities of [defen
dant] as a railroad, but in the context of its normal course
of business. There is no evidence that [defendant] rents
track to subsidiary railroads. Within its existing course of
business, providing rail transportation service, it is not
feasible for [defendant] to rent track to [plaintifi].
[Defendant] has articulated a number of legitimate busi
ness reasons for refusing trackage rights, including alter
ing its relationship to ‘feeder’ lines, upon which it relies
for profitable traffic. As the district court noted, for
[defendant] to rent track, it would alter its relationship to
feeder railroads and transform itself into a ‘toll collec
tor.’ “ar
US Essential Facilities Cases InvoMng P
Relatively few US cases have involved essential facilities
claims based on a company’s handling of its intellectual
property. Of those that exist, most do not directly
33 See n.15a above, at 498.
34 See n.15 above, at 545.
35 See n.4 above, 708 F. 2d at 1133.
36 See, e.g.. City ofAnaheim, 0.1 above, at 1380 (holding that
“the fourth element [of the MCI test] basically raises the familiar
question of whether there is a legitimate business justification tor
the refusal to provide the facihtv”).
37 ni.25 above, at 545 see ado o1d:md Health-Care Seree,
ni3a above, at 498 (holding that the plantiffs proposai that the
deteneant hospital give med,cal dev,ce dealers in-hospta1 Occess
to atients on a rotating basic was not leastn!c gIven the hospc
address whether—and if so under what circum
stances—a company’s handling of its own IP may merit
treating such IP as an essential facility.38
Perhaps the most instructive case in this area to date
is Data General C’orp v Grumman Systems Support
c’orp. °
In this case, Data General (“DG”), which man
ufactured computer systems and offered maintenance
services for these systems, developed a proprietary soft
ware program, dubbed the “MV/ADEX”, that it used
to diagnose and repair customer systems. When DG
learned that Grumman, a third-party provider of com
puter repair services, was using the MV/ADEX without
DG’s permission, DG sought and obtained a prelimi
nary injunction against Grumman prohibiting such use.
In response, Grumman challenged DG’s licensing of
MV!ADEX, contending that the diagnostic program
was an essential facility and that DG’s refusal to license
the program to Grumman was an unlawful effort to
monopolise the market for maintenance and repair of
DG computer systems.
In rejecting Grumman’s essential facilities claim, the
court offered a detailed perspective on the boundaries
of the essential facilities doctrine when used to chal
lenge a rightholder’s handling of its own intellectual
property:
“The bottleneck which DG is alleged to control is the
understanding of its own computer systems. Presumably,
if [Grumman and similar competitors] were provided
with all the schematic information about the system, they
would be able to produce a diagnostic that is as fully
capable as MV!ADEX, It is DG’s position as the manu
facturer that allegedly gives it the capability to produce
the alleged essential facility. The case law has consistently
affirmed that a manufacturer is under no obligation to
pre-disclose or disclose its knowledge about its products
so that competition may arise in the related peripheral
hardware, software, and repair services markets. The
underlying thrust of Grumman’s essential facilities claim
is that if it cannot force DG to share its knowledge, the
essential facilities doctrine requires DG to share the fruits
of its knowledge. As the First Circuit stated in a different
factual context, ‘[t]his view of the essential facilities doc
trine, however, considerably overstates its scope.’ “°
The court went on to conclude that DG’s:
“superior knowledge in the design of DG computers is
insufficient to invoke the essential facilities doctrine; a
better mousetrap is not necessarily an essential
facility. . . If manufacturers of complex and innovative
systems were required to share with competitors the
development of accessories, because they had a possibly
absolute advantage through producing the system, the
incentives of copyright and patent laws would be severely
undermined. Not only would the manufacturer, who is in
the best position to create these accessories, have less
incentive to do so, but also the impetus for competitors to
reverse engineer and produce competing solutions would
be reduced.”4’
38 See. e.g., Teiecemm Thchnical Serrs, Inc v Siemens Robs Corn
rnumcarzens, Inc 66 F. Supp. 2d 1306, 1318-4319 (ND, Ga.
1a9a thrd rg .Fe ‘sen is scoI,”ee dcc rev “pt0 cab c ne
C s ..— .ruc ..g..r’ .. “
cc it
Sc r,.ne 45 23 9 — . c,.. -
list (do. l904.
40 ihd, 192 (cliationsonutced;
i2003] ELP.R. ISSUE 10 C SWEET & MAXWEU.. UMOTED AXD CONTRIBUTORSI
476 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] E.LP.R
A sensible reading of the court’s opinion would seem
to suggest that plaintiffs seeking to establish an essential
facilities claim based on a firm’s handling of its own IP
may be required to show that the defendant’s control
over the downstream market in which the plaintiff com
petes extends above and beyond the control that natu
rally flows from the exercise ofthe IP rights themselves.
Such an interpretation finds support in more recent
cases in which plaintiffs sought, unsuccessfully, to rely
on essential facilities arguments to challenge refusals to
license involving v1icrosoft and Intel. In In re Microsoft
Corp Antitrust Litigation,42 the plaintiffs, as part of a
broader set of anti-trust claims, alleged that the “specifi
cations for the Windows operating system” constituted
an essential facility and, accordingly, that Microsoft was
under a duty to disclose information about the specifica
tions to potential competitors. The court granted sum
mary judgment for Microsoft on this claim, observing:
“[T)o require one company to provide its intellectual
property to a competitor would significantly chill innova
tion. [Citations to cases including Data General omitted]
Morevoer, because the software development industry is
dynamic and involves continuous innovation, a require
ment that Microsoft disclose significant information to its
competitors would be unworkable. Who would deter
mine what information is “significant?” At the least, the
determination would have to be subject to judicial scru
tiny by judges who lack the competence—either as direct
decisionmakers or as reviewing authorities—to decide the
technical issues involved. Delay and confusion would be
inevitable, and the software process would be strangu
lated.”43
The court went on to explain that even if it assumed the
essential facilities doctrine was properly applicable to
Windows specifications, the plaintiffs could not succeed
in the absence of showing that Microsoft in fact denied
access. Instead, the plaintiffs had argued that Microsoft
provided only partial or late access to Windows specifi
cations through its acknowledged programs for provid
ing Windows information to independent software
developers, and could in theory have denied access
entirely. The court concluded that even if Microsoft had
used its superior knowledge of its own APIs to obtain a
“first mover advantage” in software applications mar
kets, “the essential facility doctrine has never been
interpreted to deny a person the right to gain temporary
benefits from innovations to its own products”.44
Likewise, in David L. Aidridge Co v Microsoft Corp,”
a producer of disk cache software claimed that Micro
soft’s alleged failure to disclose certain design details
about Windows 95 constituted a refusal to provide
access to an essential facility. In rejecting that claim, the
court held that the plaintiff had failed to prove that
Vindows 95 was an essential facility, or that Microsoft
illegally denied the plaintiff access to Windows 9546
42 — F. Supp. 2d (D. Md., slip op. June 6, 2003) (Motz
J,),
43 ibid. at 2.
44 ibid. at 4.
45 995 F. Supp. 728 (S.D. Thx, 1998).
46 ibid. at 752—756. The court in A.ldridge assumed, for pur
poses of its analysis, that Microsoft held monopoly power in the
worldwide market for personal computer operating systems, but
emphasised that it was .making “no independent finding or hold
ing that Microsoft is a monopolist” (at 752, n.140),
Among other things, the court reasoned that a facility is
“essential” only if it is necessary for the plaintiff’s
“competitive viability,” and observed that plaintiff had
“present[edj no evidence that the entire relevant secon
dary product market for disk cache programs has dis
appeared” .
In the case of Intergraph Corp v Intel Corp,48 Inter
graph, a manufacturer of computer workstations, sued
Intel for patent infringement, which prompted Intel to
terminate Intergraph’s access to advance proprietary
information concerning Intel’s future generations of
CPU microchips (which Intel provided to certain “stra
tegic” customers under non-disclosure agreements,
therefore qualifying such information for trade secret
protection),49 Intergraph claimed that Intel’s actions
deprived it of an essential facility without which it could
not compete.5° The district court accepted Intergraph’s
essential facilities claim and issued a preliminary
injunction requiring Intel to disclose a range of proprie
tary information and other intellectual property.5’
On appeal, the Federal Circuit reversed and vacated
the preliminary injunction.52 The court reasoned that
the essential facilities doctrine provided no basis for
overriding Intergraph’s right to withhold its intellectual
property when Intel did not compete with Intergraph in
the downstream workstation market.53 The court
observed that, under essential facilities doctrine, “there
must be a market in which plaintiff and defendant com
pete, such that a monopolist extends its monopoly to
the downstream market by refusing access to the facility
it controls”.4
In so holding, the court also set forth its views on the
limits of the essential facilities doctrine in cases where a
plaintiff seeks to acquire access to a defendant’s propri
etary information:
“The courts have well understood that the essential
facility theory is not an invitation to demand access to the
property or privileges of another, on pain of antitrust
penalties and compulsion; thus the courts have required
anticompetitive action by a monopolist that is intended to
‘eliminate competition in the downstream market,’ This
understanding is seriously strained by the district court’s
holding that ‘reasonable and timely access to critical busi
ness information that is necessary to compete is an essen
tial facility,’ although the asserted competition is in a
different market. A non-competitor’s asserted need for a
manufacturer’s business information does not convert
the withholding of that information into an antitrust
violation. “s’
The court concluded:
“The notion that [the] withholding of technical informa
tion and samples of pre-release chips violates the Sher
man Act, based on essential facility jurisprudence, is an
47 ibid. at 752 (citing Fishman, n.15 above, at 539, and TGA
Bldg, n.5 above, at 39).
48 195 F. 3d 1346 (Fed. Cir. 1999),
49 ibid. at 1349—1350.
50 ibid. at 1350, 1356—1358.
51 See Intergraph Corp a Intel Carp, 3 F. Supp. 2d 1255 N.D.
Ala, 1998).
52 See Intergraph carp, n,48 above, at 1367.
53 ibid. at 1357—1358.
54 ibid. at 1357.
55 ibid. at 1357 (citations omitted).
[SaM] E.I.P.R ISSUE 100 SWEET & MAXWELL UMflt) [AND CONTRIBIJTORSI
MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] E.LP.R 477
unwarranted extension of precedent and can not be sup
ported on the premises presented. The district court
erred in holding that Intel’s superior microprocessor
product and Intergraph’s dependency thereon converted
Intel’s special customer benefits into an ‘essential facility’
under the Sherman Act. The court’s ruling of antitrust
violation can not be sustained on this ground.”
These cases suggest that US courts will generally be
reluctant to accept the essential facilities doctrine as a
valid basis for compelling an intellectual property right-
holder to license its IP to competitors in a downstream
market. With such a limited number of cases to exam
ine, however, it may be premature to say that a US court
will never condemn a refusal to license IP to competitors
under an essential facilities analysis. But case law in the
non-IP area suggests, at a minimum, that it would need
to be impossible, or nearly so, for competitors to attain
any market share in a properly defined relevant market
without such a licence.
In the meantime, however, it seems likely that US
cases examining the proper boundary between antitrust
law and intellectual property rights will continue to
focus more heavily upon the debate between the posi
tions staked out by the respective appellate courts in
Image Technieal Services Inc v Eastman Kodak,57 on the
one hand, and the Federal Circuit in CSU, L.L.C. v
Xerox Corp, on the other. In Kodak, the Ninth Circuit
indicated that a defendant’s exercise of its IP rights will
be presumed to provide a valid business justification for
conduct that has an anticompetitiVe effect, but that this
presumption may be rebutted with evidence that the
defendant’s handling of its IP was in fact a “pre
text[j . . . to mask anticompetitive conduct”.59 In
Xerox, the Federal Circuit expressly rejected such reli
ance on a defendant’s subjective motivation in gauging
the lawfulness of its exercise of IF rights.°° Instead, the
court held:
“In the absence of any indication of illegal tying, fraud on
the Patent and Trademark Office, or sham litigation, the
patent holder may enforce the statutory right to exclude
others from making, using, or selling the claimed inven
tion free from liability under the antitrust laws. We there
fore will not inquire into his subjective motivation for
exerting his statutory rights, even though his refusal to
sell or license his patented invention may have an anti-
competitive effect, so long as that anticompetitive effect is
not illegally extended beyond the statutory patent
grant.”
Thus both Kodak and Xerox endorse that view that the
ownership and exercise of IF rights constitutes a legit
imate business justification that will presumptively
defeat an allegation of anti-competitive conduct based
on a rightholder’S refusal to license its IP to competitors
(although these courts disagree on the type of evidence
that may rebut this presumption). This position strikes
one as having greater analytical force than the essential
facilities doctrine in the IP context, as it compels courts
56 ibid ar 1357—1358
57 125 F. 3a 1195 19th Cir 1997), cr dnzed. 523 U $ 1094
(1998
58 2o3 F 3d 1322 Fed Ci 2002,, er d’nzed 531 U ,14
0 1,
59 See I’ncçs Tetho”ai Sarzs i2 F 3d at 1219—122’
6 Se’i Sc e at13
01 b;J ‘t 1a2’-128
to focus more directly on the real substance of when, if
ever, it is appropriate for antitrust law to place limits on
the exercise of the core right of intellectual property
—specifically, the right to exclude others.
The Essential Facilities Doctrine under EU
Law
Having devoted most of the available space to an over
view of US essential facilities case law, the following
comparison to development of the concept in EU. deci
sions is necessarily truncated. Hopefully, it is useful for
discussion despite its brevity.
Decisions of the European Commission
On the European side, the Commission introduced the
analytical term “essential facilities” into EU competi
tion law only quite recently in a line of decisions during
the 1 990s involving transportation infrastructure. The
Commission first used the full term “essential facility”
explicitly in 1992 in an interim measures decision in
B&I Line plc v Sealink Harbours Ltd and Sealink Stena
Ltd.62 The Commission found that Sealink held a domi
nant position in a market for provision of port services
between the United Kingdom and Ireland by control
ling the only suitable port on the UK side, and abused
it by granting preferential treatment to its own ferries
versus those of its competitors. The Commission stated
Sealink’s violation of Art.86 as follows:
“A dominant undertaking which both owns or controls
and itself uses an essential facility, i.e. a facility or infra
structure without access to which competitors cannot
provide services to their customers, and which refuses
access to that facility or grants access to competitors only
on terms less favorable than those which it gives its own
services, thereby placing the competitors at a competitive
disadvantage, infringes Article 86.”'’
A number of similar decisions followed, including Port
of Rodby,6’ Sea Containers v Stena Sealink,’5 Brussels
Airport,66 and Frankfurt Airport.67
One example on facts that did not involve ports or
airports is La Poste/SWIFT + GUF,85 but even here, the
case involved the conclusion that SWIFT was an
“essential facility” because it was the only operator in
the world of an international network for transfer pay
ment messages, and anyone denied membership would
be completely excluded from the international transfer
market.
Because the Commission’s essential facilities deci
sions in the 1990s occurred in the context oftransporta
tion infrastructure bottlenecks akin to Terminal
Railroad, where access to the facility was clearly an
absolute precondition to entry, they did little to shed
light on whether the concept of “essential” should be
62 Case 137/34.174 [1992] 5 C,ML,R. 255.
63 ibid. at 12 (emphasic addcd.
64 CommissiOn Decision No 94 119 [1994] 03 L55 52
65 Case IV;34.689, [1994] 03 L15i 8; [1995] 4 CM.LR 84
(port owner oneratmg arty reftised a cc s to e fert’
oitrant)
66 i935’ 03. L2l68
67 Commis’O’ Deci,102 98 190 [199I 03, 1,72 11.3 1atr
curt pera’or d med aces .0 tnde?e .dUE. baegaee hand e a,
8 Ca 1V3ft’20 [1997 0’ 3’56 I
120031 El PR. ISSUE C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiTED [A2’D cOciTRiBtiTOEft
47S MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.I.P.R.
given any broader scope in other goods and services
cases or intellectual propertyr cases.69 However, the
Court of First Instance and tite ECJ have also stepped
in, and it is here where the degree of convergence with
the U.S. doctrine becomes nsa st apparent.
Decisions of the ECJ and the Court of First
Instance
In 1997, the Court of First Instance in Tierce Ladbroke
SA v EC Commission,7° faced a case involving a refusal
to license copyrights in whicit the complainant relied
both on the 1995 ECJ decision in Magill,7’ and on
essential facilities arguments. A Belgian betting oper
ator complained of the refusal of a French race course
society to license it to displiy televised coverage of
French horse races in its betting establishments. In a
parallel to the US Intergraph decision, the court
declared that the refusal to license could not be
regarded as anti-competitive in circumstances where
the defendants were not theni selves competing in the
downstream betting market in which Tierce Ladbroke
was operating. More importantly, however, the court
stated that even if this were not a factor, the refusal to
license could not be held to e an abuse within the
meaning of Magill because:
“the televised broadcasting of horse races, although con
stituting an additional, and indeed suitable service for
bettors, it is not in itself indisj’ensable for the exercise of
the bookmakers main activity, namely the taking of bets,
as is evidenced by the fact that the applicant [Tierce
Ladbroke] is present on the Belgian betting market and
occupies a significant position as regard bets on French
races.“72
A few months later, the Court of First Instance fol
lowed its own Tierce Ladbrokc reasoning in European
69 However, it was not lost oroornplamants in refusal to deal
cases that the Commission tended to state the basis for these
decisions in more general tenis, somewhat divorced from
the absolute nature of the factual settings. For example, in the
XXVth Report on Competitiosa Policy (1995), at point 40, the
Commission states: “Where a dominant company owns or con
trols a facility access to which it essential to enable its com
petitors to carry on business, it way not deny them access, and
it must grant access on a non-discriminatory basis.” This can be
read to mean an essential facility controls the ability of all com
petitors to carry on business. Ic. the XXV1th Report en Com
petition Policy (1996), at point 5,the Commission formulated
it this way: “Examples of such illegal behavior include: refusal to
deal as a means of eliminating acomnpetitor by a firm that is the
sole or dominant source of supply of a product or that controls
access to an essential technology or infrastructure . . .“ For a
more complete account of the development of the Commission’s
thinking, see John Temple Laag, “Defining Legitimate Com
petition: Companies’ Duties to Scapply Competitors and Access
to Essential Facilities” Decesnbor 1994) 18 Ferdham Int’l L,J,
437; and John Temple Lang, ‘S4edia, Multimedia and Euro
pean Community Antitrust Law” (April 1998) 21 Fordham In’
LI. 1296.
Cave T-534 03 (997 5 CM.L.R. 349.
1 Cases C- 241 & 242/9] R RTH end ITP Covv:vvdssi’n 119951
I II CR 743 (19951 4 C.M.L& 118.
Night Services v EC commission.73 Faced with claims
that the defendant’s refusal to deal in a non-IP context
violated the essential facilities principle, the Court
declared that, “under the case law on the application of
Article 86”, locomotives and train crews belonging to
the parties to a joint venture could not be considered
“essential” to competition in a downstream market, jus
tifying imposition of a duty of non-discriminatory
access, “unless there are no viable alternatives available
to potential competitors”.
The general analysis applied by the Court of First
Instance in Tierce Ladbroke was confirmed a year later
by the ECJ in Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co KG v Media-
print Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenuerlag GmbH & Co KG.74
Oscar Bronner was the Austrian publisher of a national
daily newspaper holding between 3.6 and 6 per cent of
the Austrian market. Mediaprint was the much larger
publisher of two national daily newspapers holding a
combined market share of between 42 and 46.8 per cent
of the market. In addition, Mediaprint had established
a nationwide home delivery network designed to get its
papers on readers’ doorsteps early in the morning.
Oscar Bronner sought access to Mediaprint’s distribu
tion system and was refused; it invoked the essential
facilities doctrine in its subsequent court challenge.
In his opinion, Advocate General Jacobs noted that
the ECJ had yet to refer expressly to the essential facili
ties doctrine by name, while it had “come to play an
important role” in the Commission’s practice,75 He
urged the ECJ to reject Oscar Bronner’s claims:
“In the long term it is generally procornpetitive and in the
interests of consumers to allow a company to retain for its
own use facilities that it has developed for the purpose of
its business... . [T]he incentive for a dominant under
taking to invest in efficient facilities would be reduced if its
competitors were, upon request, able to share the benefits.
Thus the mere fact that by retaining a facility for its own
use a dominant undertaking retains an advantage over a
competitor cannot justify requiring access to it.”7°
He went on to recommend that the ECJ order access:
“only in cases in which the dominant undertaking has a
genuine stranglehold on the related market. That might
be the case for example where duplication of the facility
is impossible or extremely difficult owing to physical,
geographical or legal constraints or is highly undesirable
for reasons of public policy. It is not sufficient that the
undertaking’s control over a facility should give it a com
petitive advantage.”77
The Court did not expressly adopt all of the Advocate
General’s reasoning, but it did closely follow the sub
stance of his recommendation. The Court addressed
73 Joined Cases T374—375, 384 & 388/94 [1998] 5 C,M.L.R,
718.
74 Case C—7/97 [1199] 4 C.M.L.R, 112.
75 The Advocate General provides a fasric comprehensive
reveow of prIor ECJ decismons, the Tzerce Ladbreke decujon,
Lemnmass:on iecesvons. Jonas aempee Lnngs 0994 J’ordiaeam sub
messlon, arid US case law.
76 Advocate Geveerai’v Oocvcen
77 CL’ at 65.
(2003] 0.1.0.10 ISSUE 100 SWEET & MAXWELL UAUThD (AND CONTRIBUTORS]
MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] BIER. 479
the application of its own earlier refusal to deal deci
sions in Commerciil Solvents,78 Telemarketing79 and
Magill to the effect on downstream competition in the
daily newspaper market in the event that Mediaprint
were found to have a dominant position in a market for
home delivery services. First, as to Commercial Solvents
and Telemarketing, the Court stated that while those
cases held:
“the refusal by an undertaking holding a dominant posi
don in a given market to supply an undertaking with
which it was in competition in a neighboring market with
raw materials, and services respectively, which were indis
pensable to carrying on the rival’s business, to constitute
an abuse, it should be noted, first, that the Court did so to
the extent that the conduct in question was likely to elim
inate allcompetition on the part ofthe undertaking.”°
Thus, under this formulation, the competitive effect
must be more than simply to disadvantage downstream
competition—the handicap must be absolute, Likewise,
with respect to Magill, the Court summarised the test as
follows:
“In MAGILL the Court found such exceptional circum
stances in the fact that the refusal in question concerned
a product.. the supply of which was indispensable for
carrying on the business in question.. . the fact that such
refusal prevented the appearance of a new product for
which there was a potential consumer demand, the fact
that it was not justified by objective considerations, and
that it was likely to exclude all competition in the secon
dary market”
Thus, in the Court’s view, “even if” Magill was applic
able outside the intellectual property context, Oscar
Bronner would have to show that the refusal to allow
access to the home delivery scheme would “be likely to
eliminate all competition in the daily newspaper market
on the part of the person requesting the service”, that
the refusal could not be objectively justified, and that
the service be “indispensable” to Oscar Bronner’s daily
newspaper business “with no actual or potential sub
stitute”.
The Court found that Oscar Bronner’s claim could
not succeed given the fact that Oscar Bronner and oth
ers were, in fact, presently competing on the daily news
paper market despite their lack of access to
Mediaprint’s network:
“In the first place, it is undisputed that other methods of
distributing daily newspapers. . even though they may
be less advantageous for the distribution of certain news
papers, exist and are used by the publishers of those daily
newspapers.”
Thus the effect ofthe refusal to supply did not eliminate
or prevent competition entirely, and so for the same
reason access to the facility could not be considered
essential or indispensable.
The Court’s treatment of Magill in the Oscar Bronner
decision certainly seems to cast doubt on whether the
Court is likely to accept an essential facilities argument
as a basis for widening the scope of circumstances when
compulsory licensing of copyrights is allowed on com
petition law grounds. On the one hand, the court was
reluctant to say that the same rules apply in Ii? and non
IP contexts, hedging with its “even if” statement on
applying Magill to Oscar Bronner’s claim. If so, and if
the essential facilities argument becomes recognised as
a valid argument with a somewhat lower standard in
non-IP contexts, then it does not necessarily cross over
into the distinct IP context. On the other hand, when
the court proceeded on its “what if” basis, it seemed to
indicate that Oscar Bronner’s claim failed under
Magill’s exceptional circumstances test for much the
same reason that it failed under the proposed essential
facilities analysis—the plaintiff was able to gain at least
some access to the downstream or related market
despite the refusal to deal. Viewed in this light, the
court could be understood as saying that it does not
matter whether one applies Magiil’s “exceptional cir
cumstances” holding or some version of the essential
facilities doctrine: both mquiries set the hurdle at the
same height, and the plaintiff clearly trips on it if the
defendant’s conduct does not have the effect of elim
inating competition in the relevant downstream mar-
ket,
Conclus!on
If one reads the foregoing decisions ofthe Court of First
Instance and the ECJ, and particularly Oscar Bronner, as
the author does, then it is relatively easy to understand
the author’s view that the treatment of the “essential
facilities” doctrine by the European and US courts is
converging in the direction of a requirement that the
facility in question be virtually indispensable to com
petition in the relevant downstream market, such that a
refusal to deal would cut off any possibility of com
petition.
This narrow scope seems particularly appropriate
when attempts are made to apply the doctrine to the
exercise of intellectual property rights. The author
tends to agree with the words of US commentators who
have stated that the term “essential facility” is “just an
epithet describing the monopolist’s situation: The
monopolist possesses something the plaintiffwants. It is
not an independent tool of analysis, but only a label”.8’
Just as the United States is left at the end of the second
section above considering the relative merits ofthe posi
tions put forward in Xerox and Kodak, so the EU is
better off considering the proper scope of the “excep
tional circumstan es” test set forth in Magill than seek
irg broaden the rca h of the essential facil tics
2 0 R 168 0 1 SWEET & MAXW 2 UM)TED [ANT) ONTRIB TORI,]
480 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAIPRCPBRTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] EJP.R.
This position, the author weuLd submit, finds support
in the recent decision by the Prsident of the Court of
First Instance in IMS Health inc z BC Cornmission2 In
staying the Commission’s ixiterini order requiring a
copyright holder to license its proprietary data-report
ing system to competitors in the market in which the
defendant was alleged to be doixtinant (rather than in a
related downstream market), the President issued a
decision strongly suggesting that Magill’s “exceptional
circumstances” inquiry provides the proper framework
82 Case T—184’OI [2001] 4 C]4LR. 2.
for analysing competition law challenges to a righthold
er’s refusal to license.83 Because the Commission subse
quently withdrew its order in IMS Health, the question
whether Magill’s “exceptional circumstances” test
—rather than a new test based on some version of the
essential facilities doctrine—provides the proper frame
work for analysis in such cases will need to await further
clarification by the courts.
83 See Areeda and Hovenkamp, n.5 above, at ¶j 94-106. A
procedural challenge to the President of the Court of First
Instance’s stay of the Commission’s interim order was in turn
rejected by the President of the European Court of Justice See
NDC Health Corp v IMS Health mc, Case C—481!01 [2002] 5
CMLR, 1.
[253] ICIER ISSUE IC © SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiTED [AND CONTRIBUTORS]

More Related Content

Similar to Eipr article

2009 Nciia Presentation
2009 Nciia Presentation2009 Nciia Presentation
2009 Nciia Presentationthe nciia
 
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_Center
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_CenterPatent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_Center
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_CenterKrishan Thakker
 
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
Knobbe Martens - Intellectual Property Law
 
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock Theory
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock TheoryPatent Eligibility's Common Stock Theory
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock TheoryRobert DeWitty
 
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market PowerIntellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
Moses Muchiri
 
TOPIC II. Intellectual Property Fair Dealing.ppt
TOPIC II. Intellectual  Property Fair Dealing.pptTOPIC II. Intellectual  Property Fair Dealing.ppt
TOPIC II. Intellectual Property Fair Dealing.ppt
JacksonMagooge
 
Conflict of laws in IPR
Conflict of laws in IPRConflict of laws in IPR
Conflict of laws in IPRRia Tandon
 
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF  Virtually all of the cases in thi.docxFORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF  Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
budbarber38650
 
Copyright fair use doctrine
Copyright fair use doctrineCopyright fair use doctrine
Copyright fair use doctrine
Greenberg - Lieberman
 
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDF
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDFARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDF
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDFChristina P. Mott
 
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docxCase 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
annandleola
 
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent lawIs there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
Kathleen Broughton
 
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Victoria Sievers
 
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Victoria Sievers
 
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LR
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LRFranklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LR
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LRAdam Kuhn
 
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docxCOPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
maxinesmith73660
 
Conjoint survey paper
Conjoint survey paperConjoint survey paper
Conjoint survey paperJaeWon Lee
 

Similar to Eipr article (20)

2009 Nciia Presentation
2009 Nciia Presentation2009 Nciia Presentation
2009 Nciia Presentation
 
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_Center
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_CenterPatent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_Center
Patent_Rights_in_the_U.S.-Is_the_Pendulum_Finally_Swinging_Back_to_Center
 
Federal Circuit Review | July 2013
Federal Circuit Review | July 2013Federal Circuit Review | July 2013
Federal Circuit Review | July 2013
 
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
Federal Circuit Review | June 2013
 
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock Theory
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock TheoryPatent Eligibility's Common Stock Theory
Patent Eligibility's Common Stock Theory
 
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market PowerIntellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
Intellectual Property Rights: Between Exclusivity and Market Power
 
TOPIC II. Intellectual Property Fair Dealing.ppt
TOPIC II. Intellectual  Property Fair Dealing.pptTOPIC II. Intellectual  Property Fair Dealing.ppt
TOPIC II. Intellectual Property Fair Dealing.ppt
 
Conflict of laws in IPR
Conflict of laws in IPRConflict of laws in IPR
Conflict of laws in IPR
 
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF  Virtually all of the cases in thi.docxFORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF  Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
FORMAT FOR CASE BRIEF Virtually all of the cases in thi.docx
 
Copyright fair use doctrine
Copyright fair use doctrineCopyright fair use doctrine
Copyright fair use doctrine
 
June's ARTICLES
June's ARTICLESJune's ARTICLES
June's ARTICLES
 
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDF
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDFARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDF
ARTICLE_ Multifactors_ Multiconfusion_ Refining _Likeli.PDF
 
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docxCase 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
Case 24-7United States v. Microsoft CorporationUnited States Cou.docx
 
Side Bar Sprin 2012
Side Bar Sprin 2012Side Bar Sprin 2012
Side Bar Sprin 2012
 
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent lawIs there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
Is there more damage than remedy in reforming patent law
 
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
 
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
Online Enforcement of IP Rights by Injunctions Against ISPs: The English Cour...
 
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LR
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LRFranklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LR
Franklyn and Kuhn - Owning Oneself in a World of Others - Final Wake Forest LR
 
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docxCOPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
COPYRIGHT INFRINGEMENTWhen a copyright holder pursues a party th.docx
 
Conjoint survey paper
Conjoint survey paperConjoint survey paper
Conjoint survey paper
 

Recently uploaded

Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quizAgrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
gaelcabigunda
 
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John CavittRoles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
johncavitthouston
 
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
Wendy Couture
 
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptxThe Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
nehatalele22st
 
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.docNotes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
BRELGOSIMAT
 
EMPLOYMENT LAW AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
EMPLOYMENT LAW  AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptxEMPLOYMENT LAW  AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
EMPLOYMENT LAW AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
MwaiMapemba
 
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptxHighlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
anjalidixit21
 
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
Knowyourright
 
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense CounselMilitary Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
Thomas (Tom) Jasper
 
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal CourtAbdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
Gabe Whitley
 
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptxBharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
ShivkumarIyer18
 
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the NetherlandsHow to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
BridgeWest.eu
 
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
9ib5wiwt
 
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
9ib5wiwt
 
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
o6ov5dqmf
 
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot CitizenshipThe Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
BridgeWest.eu
 
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdfALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
46adnanshahzad
 
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdfDonald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
ssuser5750e1
 
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
Daffodil International University
 
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of DissolutionWINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
KHURRAMWALI
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quizAgrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
Agrarian Reform Policies in the Philippines: a quiz
 
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John CavittRoles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
Roles of a Bankruptcy Lawyer John Cavitt
 
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
Business and Corporate Case Update (2024)
 
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptxThe Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
The Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934.pptx
 
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.docNotes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
Notes-on-Prescription-Obligations-and-Contracts.doc
 
EMPLOYMENT LAW AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
EMPLOYMENT LAW  AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptxEMPLOYMENT LAW  AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
EMPLOYMENT LAW AN OVERVIEW in Malawi.pptx
 
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptxHighlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
Highlights_of_Bhartiya_Nyaya_Sanhita.pptx
 
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
Car Accident Injury Do I Have a Case....
 
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense CounselMilitary Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
Military Commissions details LtCol Thomas Jasper as Detailed Defense Counsel
 
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal CourtAbdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
Abdul Hakim Shabazz Deposition Hearing in Federal Court
 
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptxBharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
Bharatiya Nagarik Suraksha Sanhita power.pptx
 
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the NetherlandsHow to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
How to Obtain Permanent Residency in the Netherlands
 
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
定制(nus毕业证书)新加坡国立大学毕业证学位证书实拍图原版一模一样
 
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
1比1制作(swansea毕业证书)英国斯旺西大学毕业证学位证书托业成绩单原版一模一样
 
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
一比一原版麻省理工学院毕业证(MIT毕业证)成绩单如何办理
 
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot CitizenshipThe Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
The Main Procedures for Obtaining Cypriot Citizenship
 
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdfALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
ALL EYES ON RAFAH BUT WHY Explain more.pdf
 
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdfDonald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
Donald_J_Trump_katigoritirio_stormi_daniels.pdf
 
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
ADR in criminal proceeding in Bangladesh with global perspective.
 
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of DissolutionWINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
WINDING UP of COMPANY, Modes of Dissolution
 

Eipr article

  • 1. Vol 25 Issue 10 Oct 2003 A journal concerning the management of technology, copyrights and trade names European Intellectual Property Review Intellectual Property and Competition: Does the Essential Facilities Doctrine Shed Any New Light? GregoryV.S. McCurdy mcnviscj SWEET & tVIAXWELL ISSN 0142-0461
  • 2.
  • 3. 472 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.I.P.R. For years, legal scholars and practitioners on both sides of the Atlantic have grappled with the complexities that may arise in applying competition law to commercial disputes involving intellectual property (“IP”). In a handful of recent cases, plaintiffs have invoked a novel competition law and antitrust theory known as the “essential facilities” doctrine to challenge a defendant’s exercise of its IP rights. Plaintiffs in these cases typically contend that the defendant’s refusal to provide access to certain IP under reasonable terms unlawfully impeded the plaintiff’s ability to compete in a downstream market. The essential facilities doctrine first arose in the United States in an effort to analyse refusals to deal involving physical facilities and tangible assets. It has gradually been adapted for similar purposes in Europe. But attempts by plaintiffs to extend it to the analysis of situations involving refusals to license intangible intel lectual property rights are more recent, and thus far less successful, at least in the courts. This raises the ques tion whether the doctrine offers any significant advance over traditional refusal-to-deal analysis, and specifically whether the doctrine sheds any new light on the proper competitive boundaries on refusing to license intangible property rights like copyrights and patents. The author is not sure that he can fully answer those questions here. But the proper foundation for any con structive discussion is a solid overview of how the doc trine has, and has not, developed in the courts. Because the author is a US practitioner, and because during his time in Europe he has heard many there invoke the US experience to ascribe a broader scope, and more “potency”, to the doctrine in the IF context than it has really achieved, he plans to focus primarily on the US case law and offer only a limited comparison to the EU body of decisions. Greg McC’urdy is an attorney at Microsoft Corporation based in Seattle, Washinxson, United States, where he manages US and Inter national commercial and competition law disputes. Mr MoCurdy graduated from Harvard University and studied law at NYU and Kings College London. He practiced lass in New York befare joining Microsoft’s legal department in Paris where he was based from 2000-2002. The views expressed herein are solely those of the author and de not necessarfy represent the position of Microsoft Corpora- The first part of this article examines how US courts have interpreted the essential facilities doctrine in vari ous contexts, including a limited number of cases in which plaintiffs have sought, unsuccessfully, to use the doctrine as a basis for attacking a defendant’s exercise of its IP rights, This survey shows that, of those courts that have accepted the essential facilities doctrine, they have tended to interpret the doctrine narrowly and have been reluctant to extend it beyond situations in which the defendant’s control of the facility in question ena bled it effectively to eliminate competition in the down stream market. Merely possessing an advantage, even a considerable one, is not enough, and the ability of a plaintiff or others to achieve even quite small gains in market share without access to the facility will normally be enough to defeat an essential facilities claim. It also suggests that a defendant’s otherwise lawful invocation of its intellectual property rights will rarely, if ever, form the basis of a successful claim. The second part of the article then discusses, much more briefly, the development of the essential facilities doctrine in EU decisions and suggests that a similarly narrow interpretation of the doctrine may be emerging in Europe as well. The Essent& FacWties Doctrine under US Law Although the contours of the essential facilities doctrine are, in the words of one federal appeals court, “still far from clear”,1 courts that have endorsed the doctrine generally view it as a specific instance of the broader category of antitrust claims based on unlawful refusals to deal. Essential facilities claims typically arise where an actual or potential monopolist refuses to provide a competitor access to a facility that is alleged to be “essential” to competition. Plaintiffs often invoke the doctrine to support a claim that a vertically integrated monopolist should be required to share a specific input with its competitors in a downstream market.2 Thus: “[t]he essential facility claim is about the duty to deal of a monopolist who is able to supply an input for itself in a fashion that is so superior to anything else available that others cannot succeed unless they can access this firm’s input as well.” By controlling an essential facility, a monopolist is alleged to be able to extend its monopoly “from one stage of production to another and from one market into another”.4 As a “recent addition to antitrust jurisprudence”,5 I City ofAnaheim uS Cal Edison Co 955 F. 2d 1373, 1379 (9th Cir. 1992). 2 Because most essential facilities claims focus on the actions of a single firm, rather than on an unlawful agreement or combi nation, such claims usually arise under s.2 of the Sherman Act. See, e.g., Alaska Airlines, Inc. v United Airlines, Inc., 948 F. 2d 536, 542 (9th Cir. 1991), cert, denied, 503 U.S. 977 (1992). 3 lilA Phillip P. Areeda and Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 771a, at p.174. 4 MIC’ommunications Corp vAT&To 708 F. 2d 1081, 1132 (7th Cir, 1983), cert, denied, 464 U.S. 891 (1983), 5 TGA Bldg Co v Northwestern Res Co 873 F. Supp. 29, 39 ‘rex. 1995). Intellectual Property and Competition: Does the Essential Facilities Doctrine Shed Any New Light? GREGORY V. S. MCCURDY Microsoft Corporation, Redmond, WA, USA voW: EI TSR Issue to C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMTT’Ei) ASSET CONTRJEUTORSJ
  • 4.
  • 5. MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.LP.R 473 the essential facilities doctrine has never been expressly endorsed by the US Supreme Court° and has been disparaged by leading antitrust scholars. For instance, Professors Areeda and Hovenkamp (authors of the leading treatise on US antitrust law) have criticised the doctrine on the ground that requiring a firm to offer its competitors access to a key upstream asset generally does not help consumers, because price and output generally remain the same while the right to share in the monopoly reduces the incentive of competitors to develop competing upstream assetst: “Forcing a firm to share its inputs with a rival is an exceptionally drastic antitrust remedy, having the consequences of preserv ing the monopoly and often of turning the defendant’s facility into what amounts to a public utility. “ Areeda and Hovenkamp conclude that: “the ‘essential facility’ doctrine is both harmful and unnecessary and should be abandoned”.9 Despite this rather tenuous foundation, it is not uncommon for plaintiffs to raise essential facilities argu ments in the context of broader challenges to alleged anti-competitive activity. The leading formulation of the essential facilities doctrine, first articulated by the Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit in M’I Com munications, requires the plaintiff to show: (1) control of the essential facility by a monopo list; (2) a competitor’s inability practically or reasonably to duplicate the essential facility; (3) the denial of the use of the facility to a com petitor; and (4) feasibility of providing the facility)0 Also, courts refuse to recognise essential facilities claims unless the plaintiff and defendant actually compete in a downstream market. For instance, in America Online, Inc v Greatdeals. nez,” a distributor of unsolicited bulk email messages—commonly known as “spam” —claimed that AOL’s efforts to block its messages from reaching AOL subscribers constituted denial of access to an essential facility (the facility in this case being AOL’s Internet access nodes).’2 In rejecting this claim, the court held that “[t]he essential facilities doctrine is inapplicable where the alleged monopolist and the 6 Us courts often trace the essential facilities doctrine to three Supreme Court decisions, United States v Terminal RailroadAsso c,anon 224 U.S. 383 (1912) involved control of a railroad bridge crossing the Mississippi River at the only point where a bridge could be built to serve that part,cular region Associated Press e United States 326 U.S 1 (1945) involved admission and access to the Associated Press wire ‘ervice from which citl and reg,onal newspapers could obtain national and international ne s stories. Otter Tail Power Coo United States 410 U.S. 366 (1973). involved access to an electrical power transmission line which constituted a natural monopoly within a traditionally regulated industry None of these dec,s,ons, hossever, expressly endorses an essen tal facilities doctrine The first two cases concerned agreements among competitors held illegal under s. 1 of the Sherman Act. Otter Tad. uhile involving un,lateral conduct, irnolved a number of ,ue geris isSues and does not actually endorse the essential fac,,ues dcctrute a, 7 Areeda and Hmenkornp. 3 abase. 771h. at cc s at 41C1,n.4thosc,atU3f .1c3 C 49F Sorr 2c1S5 EU To plaintiff do not compete”,’3 and noted that the distrib utor had “fail[ed] to allege or plead any facts from which the court could infer that [the distributor] and AOL are competitors”.’4 Although the MCI articulation of the essential facili ties doctrine, on its own, could conceivably be inter preted to encompass a broad range of conduct, US courts have read the doctrine narrowly. The following survey of cases examines how courts in the United States have applied the doctrine in various factual scenarios. Control of an essential facility The first element of the MCI test examines whether the facility to which the plaintiff was denied access is in fact “essential”. In addressing this issue, courts have held that a facility will be deemed essential “only if control of the facility carries with it the power to eliminate com petition in the downstream market”,’5 or if denial of access to the facility “inflicts a severe handicap on potential market entrants”)’ At least one court has also suggested that, to establish a successful essential facilities claim, “[t]he power to eliminate competition must not be momentary, but must be at least relatively permanent”.’6 In practice, courts generally deem a facility to be essential only if denial of access to the facility eliminates even the possibility of competition in the downstream market, Thus, in MCI and Covad Communications, the defendants’ refusal to provide plaintiffs with access to defendants’ local telephone exchanges (i.e. the “local loop”) made it impossible for plaintiffs to offer tele communications services to potential customers, thereby totally excluding plaintiffs from the relevant downstream markets.’7 Likewise, a defendant’s refusal 13 ibid. 14 ibid. Accord Intergraph Corp v Intel Corp, 195 F. 3d 1346, 1356—1357 (Fed. Cit. 1999) (holding that, under essential facili ties doctrine: “there must be a market in which plaintiff and defendant compete, such that a monopolist extends its monop oly to the downstream market by refusing access to the facility it controls”). 15 Paladin Associates, Inc v Montana Power Go 328 F. 3d 1145, 1163 (9th Cit. 2003) (citingAlaska Airlines, Inc v UnitedAirlines, Inc 948 F. 2d 536, 544 (9th Cir, 1991), cert. denied, 503 U.S. 977 (1992)); accord Covad Communications Co v BellSouth Carp 299 F. 3d 1272, 1284 (11th Cir. 2002) (holding that essential facility is one “without [access to] which a competitor cannot enter or compete in a market”). iSa Fishman v Wirtz 807 F. 2d 520, 539 (7th Cir. 1986). Despite the superficial differences between these two formula tions (i.e. eliminate competition v severe handicap), in practice courts often conflate them. See, e.g., Advanced Health-Care Servs Inc v Giles Mem’l Hasp 846 F. Supp. 488, 498 WD. Va. 1994) (“Plaintiff must show that this denial [to the facility in question] inflicted a ‘severe handicap’ that threatened to eliminate com petition in the market ) (quoting Twin Labs Inc v Weider Health & Fitness 900 F. 2d 566, 569—570 (2d Cir. 1990)). 16 AlaskaAirlines, 948 F. 2d at 544 nil. 17 See MCI, n.4 above, 1133 (involving provision of long- distance and related telephone services); Covad Communications, 0.15 above, at i286—l288 (involving provision of DSL internet access serv,ce’u accord Metranet Services Core u U S. ITaSi Corn— municatio’,s 329 F. 3d 986. 1010—1013 (9th Cd. 2003) (holding that the plaintiff adduced sufficient evidence that the defer. oanrs- pricing policy for access to local loop macic it meoss-ibie for the plaintiff to compete profitably svrth the defendant in telecommunications services marker to w,thstand motion for fi005 0 IrK ISSUE it C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiT 1) AXIs CONTRIBUTORSj
  • 6. 474 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] ELP.R. to lease its stadium to a competing potential purchaser of a professional sports franchise was deemed denial to an essential facility where the sport’s governing body refused to award the franchise to any party that could not secure such a lease (a decision based in part on defendant’s behind-the-scenes lobbying of the govern ing body).’8 Where, by contrast, access to the facility in question is not a pre-requisite to participation in the downstream market, courts generally hold that such facilities are non-essential—with little regard for the financial hard ship that defendant’s actions impose on competitors. Thus, in City ofAnaheim, a utility’s facility for accessing an inexpensive source of electricity was deemed non essential even though the utility’s refusal to grant access to competitors in certain retail markets gave the utility a substantial competitive advantage in those markets.’9 Similarly, in Alaska Airlines, the court held that the defendant airlines’ proprietary computerised reserva tions systems were not essential facilities—despite the defendants’ ability to use these facilities to extract sub stantial bookings fees from its competitors—as the sys tems did not actually give defendants the “power to eliminate competition in the downstream air transporta tion market”.2° Finally, proof that a defendant’s competitors were able to increase market share without access to the facility in question—regardless of the impact that denial to the facility may have had on the plaintiff—will almost always prove fatal to an essential facilities claim.2’ lnabWty to duphcate The second element of the MCI test examines whether competitors could “practically or reasonably. . . dupli cate the essential facility”.22 As the Ninth Circuit has noted, this inquiry is really a subset of the first MCI element, as the inability to duplicate the facility “is effectively part of the definition of what is an essential facility in the first place. That is to say, if the facility can be reasonably or practically duplicated it is highly unlikely, even impossible, that it will be found to be essential at all”.23 Nevertheless, most courts address the first and second elements of the MCI test separately. Here again, courts tend to construe this element nar rowly, and the mere fact that duplication of the facility would be costly or burdensome is usually deemed insuf ficient to satisfy this element. Rather, plaintiffs tend to succeed only where duplication of the facility would be nearly impossible. As the Second Circuit has observed: 18 See Fishman, n.15a above, at 539—540. 19 See City ofAnaheim, n.j above, at 1380—1381; accord Mid west Gas Servs, Inc v Indiana Gas Co 317 F. 3d 703, 7 13—714 (7th Cir. 2003) (holding that direct interconnect to the defer, dant’s gas pipeline was not an essential facility where the plaintiff could access pipeline through a more expensive, indirect route. reasoning that “the most economical route is not an essential facility when other routes are available”). 20 Alaska Airlines, n,16 above, at 544—545 (emphasis added). 21 See, e.g., Twin Labs Ins, n,15a above, at 569—570;Advanced HeaitlwGarc Servo ins, ni Sa above, at 498, 22 MGI, n,4 above, at 1132. 23 City ofAnahelin, n. I above, at 1380. “A leading antitrust commentator would limit the analy sis to ‘facilities that are a natural monopoly, facilities whose duplication is forbidden by law, and perhaps those that are publicly subsidized and thus could not practica bly be built privately.’ Most of the successful essential facility claims fall within the categories stated by this commentator. In cases finding liability in other catego ries, however, the facility in question was more than dom inant; it was effectively the only one in town.”24 In Laurel Sand ‘ Gravel, Inc v CSX’ Transportation, Inc,25 the court held that a national railroad’s refusal to permit the plaintiff, a competing “shortline” railroad, to use 1,700 feet of track did not support an essential facilities claim, as the plaintiff could have built alter native tracks or purchased rail service from the national railroad.26 The court reached this conclusion despite evidence that either alternative would have prevented plaintiff from profitably offering competitive rates to certain customers. Similarly, in Olympia Equipment Leasing v Western Union Telephone Co,27 the court held that defendant’s abrupt demand that its salesforce not refer competing products to potential customers did not support an essential facilities claim, as competitors could simply hire their own salespeople.28 Evidence that the defendant’s actions ultimately drove the plaintiff out of business was deemed insufficient to establish an ina bility to duplicate. Plaintiffs that have succeeded in satisfying the second element of the MCI test typically show that duplicating the facility in question would have been nearly impos sible. For instance, the courts in both MCI and Covad Communications noted that neither plaintiff would have been likely to obtain regulatory approval to duplicate the type of local loop facilities to which they sought access. 29 Denial of use of the facility The third element of the MCI test examines whether the defendant denied “use of the facility to a com petitor”.3° Although proof of outright refusal to deal is normally sufficient, courts have also indicated that proof that the defendant “fail[ed] to make access to that facility available to its competitors on fair and reasonable terms” may also be adequate to support a finding for the plaintiff.3’ Despite the apparent breadth of the “fair and reason able terms” formulation, courts generally tend to look for some evidence of bad faith that amounts to an effec tive refusal to deal.32 Allegations that plaintiff’s access 24 Twin Labs, n. l5a above, at 569 (citations om,tted). 25 924 F. 2d 539 (4th C,r. 1991), cert. denied, 502 US. 814 (1991), 26 ibid. at 544—545. 27 797 F. 2d 370 (7th Cir, 1986), sew, denied, 480 US. 934 (1987). 28 tbzd. at 376—379 29 See MGI, n.4 above, at 1133; Cot ad Communzeations, n.15 abes.o. a: :285 30 MCI, n4 sOme, at 1133 31 Gonad Comnmovations, n,15 above, at 1287 (emphinzs by the ‘arr (quoting United States v ATdyT 524 F Supç 1336. 1352—1353 (DDC 198i)) 32 See, e.g., Fishman, n,I Sn aoove, at 540 (holding that offer of ‘,sce to sports arena “did not show that [defendant] we” willing t’ deal with [pUnnfl] on non’.diacriminatory terms [2003: ErniE ISSUE 10 C SWEET & MAXWELL LLMTUEI) [AND CONTRIBUTORS)
  • 7. MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] ELP.R. 475 to the facility was more expensive andior burdensome than defendant’s access will normally be insufficient, For instance, in Advanced Health-Care, the court held that a hospital’s decision to grant in-hospital office space and direct patient contact to one medical equip ment provider (in exchange for a percentage of sales) and to deny such access to the provider’s competitors did not amount to a denial of access to hospital patients.33 And inAlaska Airlines, the court held that the booking fees charged by the defendant airlines to their competitors for use of the defendants’ computerised reservations systems did not constitute a denial of access, on the ground that—given the plaintiffs’ con tinued use of these systems—it was clear that “neither [defendant has] ever set this fee at a level that would drive their competitors away”.34 Feasibility of providing the facility The fourth and final element of the MCI test examines the feasibility of the defendant’s providing access to the essential facility.35 As in other areas of antitrust liability, a defendant that offers a legitimate business justification for its refusal to provide access will normally avoid liability.36 Laurel Sand illustrates the extent to which courts will defer to a defendant’s real-world business needs in eval uating feasibility. In denying an essential facilities claim based on a railroad’s refusal to allow a competitor to use of a portion of its tracks, the court stated: “The feasibility of providing access to the tracks must be analyzed not in terms of all the possibilities of [defen dant] as a railroad, but in the context of its normal course of business. There is no evidence that [defendant] rents track to subsidiary railroads. Within its existing course of business, providing rail transportation service, it is not feasible for [defendant] to rent track to [plaintifi]. [Defendant] has articulated a number of legitimate busi ness reasons for refusing trackage rights, including alter ing its relationship to ‘feeder’ lines, upon which it relies for profitable traffic. As the district court noted, for [defendant] to rent track, it would alter its relationship to feeder railroads and transform itself into a ‘toll collec tor.’ “ar US Essential Facilities Cases InvoMng P Relatively few US cases have involved essential facilities claims based on a company’s handling of its intellectual property. Of those that exist, most do not directly 33 See n.15a above, at 498. 34 See n.15 above, at 545. 35 See n.4 above, 708 F. 2d at 1133. 36 See, e.g.. City ofAnaheim, 0.1 above, at 1380 (holding that “the fourth element [of the MCI test] basically raises the familiar question of whether there is a legitimate business justification tor the refusal to provide the facihtv”). 37 ni.25 above, at 545 see ado o1d:md Health-Care Seree, ni3a above, at 498 (holding that the plantiffs proposai that the deteneant hospital give med,cal dev,ce dealers in-hospta1 Occess to atients on a rotating basic was not leastn!c gIven the hospc address whether—and if so under what circum stances—a company’s handling of its own IP may merit treating such IP as an essential facility.38 Perhaps the most instructive case in this area to date is Data General C’orp v Grumman Systems Support c’orp. ° In this case, Data General (“DG”), which man ufactured computer systems and offered maintenance services for these systems, developed a proprietary soft ware program, dubbed the “MV/ADEX”, that it used to diagnose and repair customer systems. When DG learned that Grumman, a third-party provider of com puter repair services, was using the MV/ADEX without DG’s permission, DG sought and obtained a prelimi nary injunction against Grumman prohibiting such use. In response, Grumman challenged DG’s licensing of MV!ADEX, contending that the diagnostic program was an essential facility and that DG’s refusal to license the program to Grumman was an unlawful effort to monopolise the market for maintenance and repair of DG computer systems. In rejecting Grumman’s essential facilities claim, the court offered a detailed perspective on the boundaries of the essential facilities doctrine when used to chal lenge a rightholder’s handling of its own intellectual property: “The bottleneck which DG is alleged to control is the understanding of its own computer systems. Presumably, if [Grumman and similar competitors] were provided with all the schematic information about the system, they would be able to produce a diagnostic that is as fully capable as MV!ADEX, It is DG’s position as the manu facturer that allegedly gives it the capability to produce the alleged essential facility. The case law has consistently affirmed that a manufacturer is under no obligation to pre-disclose or disclose its knowledge about its products so that competition may arise in the related peripheral hardware, software, and repair services markets. The underlying thrust of Grumman’s essential facilities claim is that if it cannot force DG to share its knowledge, the essential facilities doctrine requires DG to share the fruits of its knowledge. As the First Circuit stated in a different factual context, ‘[t]his view of the essential facilities doc trine, however, considerably overstates its scope.’ “° The court went on to conclude that DG’s: “superior knowledge in the design of DG computers is insufficient to invoke the essential facilities doctrine; a better mousetrap is not necessarily an essential facility. . . If manufacturers of complex and innovative systems were required to share with competitors the development of accessories, because they had a possibly absolute advantage through producing the system, the incentives of copyright and patent laws would be severely undermined. Not only would the manufacturer, who is in the best position to create these accessories, have less incentive to do so, but also the impetus for competitors to reverse engineer and produce competing solutions would be reduced.”4’ 38 See. e.g., Teiecemm Thchnical Serrs, Inc v Siemens Robs Corn rnumcarzens, Inc 66 F. Supp. 2d 1306, 1318-4319 (ND, Ga. 1a9a thrd rg .Fe ‘sen is scoI,”ee dcc rev “pt0 cab c ne C s ..— .ruc ..g..r’ .. “ cc it Sc r,.ne 45 23 9 — . c,.. - list (do. l904. 40 ihd, 192 (cliationsonutced; i2003] ELP.R. ISSUE 10 C SWEET & MAXWEU.. UMOTED AXD CONTRIBUTORSI
  • 8. 476 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] E.LP.R A sensible reading of the court’s opinion would seem to suggest that plaintiffs seeking to establish an essential facilities claim based on a firm’s handling of its own IP may be required to show that the defendant’s control over the downstream market in which the plaintiff com petes extends above and beyond the control that natu rally flows from the exercise ofthe IP rights themselves. Such an interpretation finds support in more recent cases in which plaintiffs sought, unsuccessfully, to rely on essential facilities arguments to challenge refusals to license involving v1icrosoft and Intel. In In re Microsoft Corp Antitrust Litigation,42 the plaintiffs, as part of a broader set of anti-trust claims, alleged that the “specifi cations for the Windows operating system” constituted an essential facility and, accordingly, that Microsoft was under a duty to disclose information about the specifica tions to potential competitors. The court granted sum mary judgment for Microsoft on this claim, observing: “[T)o require one company to provide its intellectual property to a competitor would significantly chill innova tion. [Citations to cases including Data General omitted] Morevoer, because the software development industry is dynamic and involves continuous innovation, a require ment that Microsoft disclose significant information to its competitors would be unworkable. Who would deter mine what information is “significant?” At the least, the determination would have to be subject to judicial scru tiny by judges who lack the competence—either as direct decisionmakers or as reviewing authorities—to decide the technical issues involved. Delay and confusion would be inevitable, and the software process would be strangu lated.”43 The court went on to explain that even if it assumed the essential facilities doctrine was properly applicable to Windows specifications, the plaintiffs could not succeed in the absence of showing that Microsoft in fact denied access. Instead, the plaintiffs had argued that Microsoft provided only partial or late access to Windows specifi cations through its acknowledged programs for provid ing Windows information to independent software developers, and could in theory have denied access entirely. The court concluded that even if Microsoft had used its superior knowledge of its own APIs to obtain a “first mover advantage” in software applications mar kets, “the essential facility doctrine has never been interpreted to deny a person the right to gain temporary benefits from innovations to its own products”.44 Likewise, in David L. Aidridge Co v Microsoft Corp,” a producer of disk cache software claimed that Micro soft’s alleged failure to disclose certain design details about Windows 95 constituted a refusal to provide access to an essential facility. In rejecting that claim, the court held that the plaintiff had failed to prove that Vindows 95 was an essential facility, or that Microsoft illegally denied the plaintiff access to Windows 9546 42 — F. Supp. 2d (D. Md., slip op. June 6, 2003) (Motz J,), 43 ibid. at 2. 44 ibid. at 4. 45 995 F. Supp. 728 (S.D. Thx, 1998). 46 ibid. at 752—756. The court in A.ldridge assumed, for pur poses of its analysis, that Microsoft held monopoly power in the worldwide market for personal computer operating systems, but emphasised that it was .making “no independent finding or hold ing that Microsoft is a monopolist” (at 752, n.140), Among other things, the court reasoned that a facility is “essential” only if it is necessary for the plaintiff’s “competitive viability,” and observed that plaintiff had “present[edj no evidence that the entire relevant secon dary product market for disk cache programs has dis appeared” . In the case of Intergraph Corp v Intel Corp,48 Inter graph, a manufacturer of computer workstations, sued Intel for patent infringement, which prompted Intel to terminate Intergraph’s access to advance proprietary information concerning Intel’s future generations of CPU microchips (which Intel provided to certain “stra tegic” customers under non-disclosure agreements, therefore qualifying such information for trade secret protection),49 Intergraph claimed that Intel’s actions deprived it of an essential facility without which it could not compete.5° The district court accepted Intergraph’s essential facilities claim and issued a preliminary injunction requiring Intel to disclose a range of proprie tary information and other intellectual property.5’ On appeal, the Federal Circuit reversed and vacated the preliminary injunction.52 The court reasoned that the essential facilities doctrine provided no basis for overriding Intergraph’s right to withhold its intellectual property when Intel did not compete with Intergraph in the downstream workstation market.53 The court observed that, under essential facilities doctrine, “there must be a market in which plaintiff and defendant com pete, such that a monopolist extends its monopoly to the downstream market by refusing access to the facility it controls”.4 In so holding, the court also set forth its views on the limits of the essential facilities doctrine in cases where a plaintiff seeks to acquire access to a defendant’s propri etary information: “The courts have well understood that the essential facility theory is not an invitation to demand access to the property or privileges of another, on pain of antitrust penalties and compulsion; thus the courts have required anticompetitive action by a monopolist that is intended to ‘eliminate competition in the downstream market,’ This understanding is seriously strained by the district court’s holding that ‘reasonable and timely access to critical busi ness information that is necessary to compete is an essen tial facility,’ although the asserted competition is in a different market. A non-competitor’s asserted need for a manufacturer’s business information does not convert the withholding of that information into an antitrust violation. “s’ The court concluded: “The notion that [the] withholding of technical informa tion and samples of pre-release chips violates the Sher man Act, based on essential facility jurisprudence, is an 47 ibid. at 752 (citing Fishman, n.15 above, at 539, and TGA Bldg, n.5 above, at 39). 48 195 F. 3d 1346 (Fed. Cir. 1999), 49 ibid. at 1349—1350. 50 ibid. at 1350, 1356—1358. 51 See Intergraph Corp a Intel Carp, 3 F. Supp. 2d 1255 N.D. Ala, 1998). 52 See Intergraph carp, n,48 above, at 1367. 53 ibid. at 1357—1358. 54 ibid. at 1357. 55 ibid. at 1357 (citations omitted). [SaM] E.I.P.R ISSUE 100 SWEET & MAXWELL UMflt) [AND CONTRIBIJTORSI
  • 9. MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] E.LP.R 477 unwarranted extension of precedent and can not be sup ported on the premises presented. The district court erred in holding that Intel’s superior microprocessor product and Intergraph’s dependency thereon converted Intel’s special customer benefits into an ‘essential facility’ under the Sherman Act. The court’s ruling of antitrust violation can not be sustained on this ground.” These cases suggest that US courts will generally be reluctant to accept the essential facilities doctrine as a valid basis for compelling an intellectual property right- holder to license its IP to competitors in a downstream market. With such a limited number of cases to exam ine, however, it may be premature to say that a US court will never condemn a refusal to license IP to competitors under an essential facilities analysis. But case law in the non-IP area suggests, at a minimum, that it would need to be impossible, or nearly so, for competitors to attain any market share in a properly defined relevant market without such a licence. In the meantime, however, it seems likely that US cases examining the proper boundary between antitrust law and intellectual property rights will continue to focus more heavily upon the debate between the posi tions staked out by the respective appellate courts in Image Technieal Services Inc v Eastman Kodak,57 on the one hand, and the Federal Circuit in CSU, L.L.C. v Xerox Corp, on the other. In Kodak, the Ninth Circuit indicated that a defendant’s exercise of its IP rights will be presumed to provide a valid business justification for conduct that has an anticompetitiVe effect, but that this presumption may be rebutted with evidence that the defendant’s handling of its IP was in fact a “pre text[j . . . to mask anticompetitive conduct”.59 In Xerox, the Federal Circuit expressly rejected such reli ance on a defendant’s subjective motivation in gauging the lawfulness of its exercise of IF rights.°° Instead, the court held: “In the absence of any indication of illegal tying, fraud on the Patent and Trademark Office, or sham litigation, the patent holder may enforce the statutory right to exclude others from making, using, or selling the claimed inven tion free from liability under the antitrust laws. We there fore will not inquire into his subjective motivation for exerting his statutory rights, even though his refusal to sell or license his patented invention may have an anti- competitive effect, so long as that anticompetitive effect is not illegally extended beyond the statutory patent grant.” Thus both Kodak and Xerox endorse that view that the ownership and exercise of IF rights constitutes a legit imate business justification that will presumptively defeat an allegation of anti-competitive conduct based on a rightholder’S refusal to license its IP to competitors (although these courts disagree on the type of evidence that may rebut this presumption). This position strikes one as having greater analytical force than the essential facilities doctrine in the IP context, as it compels courts 56 ibid ar 1357—1358 57 125 F. 3a 1195 19th Cir 1997), cr dnzed. 523 U $ 1094 (1998 58 2o3 F 3d 1322 Fed Ci 2002,, er d’nzed 531 U ,14 0 1, 59 See I’ncçs Tetho”ai Sarzs i2 F 3d at 1219—122’ 6 Se’i Sc e at13 01 b;J ‘t 1a2’-128 to focus more directly on the real substance of when, if ever, it is appropriate for antitrust law to place limits on the exercise of the core right of intellectual property —specifically, the right to exclude others. The Essential Facilities Doctrine under EU Law Having devoted most of the available space to an over view of US essential facilities case law, the following comparison to development of the concept in EU. deci sions is necessarily truncated. Hopefully, it is useful for discussion despite its brevity. Decisions of the European Commission On the European side, the Commission introduced the analytical term “essential facilities” into EU competi tion law only quite recently in a line of decisions during the 1 990s involving transportation infrastructure. The Commission first used the full term “essential facility” explicitly in 1992 in an interim measures decision in B&I Line plc v Sealink Harbours Ltd and Sealink Stena Ltd.62 The Commission found that Sealink held a domi nant position in a market for provision of port services between the United Kingdom and Ireland by control ling the only suitable port on the UK side, and abused it by granting preferential treatment to its own ferries versus those of its competitors. The Commission stated Sealink’s violation of Art.86 as follows: “A dominant undertaking which both owns or controls and itself uses an essential facility, i.e. a facility or infra structure without access to which competitors cannot provide services to their customers, and which refuses access to that facility or grants access to competitors only on terms less favorable than those which it gives its own services, thereby placing the competitors at a competitive disadvantage, infringes Article 86.”'’ A number of similar decisions followed, including Port of Rodby,6’ Sea Containers v Stena Sealink,’5 Brussels Airport,66 and Frankfurt Airport.67 One example on facts that did not involve ports or airports is La Poste/SWIFT + GUF,85 but even here, the case involved the conclusion that SWIFT was an “essential facility” because it was the only operator in the world of an international network for transfer pay ment messages, and anyone denied membership would be completely excluded from the international transfer market. Because the Commission’s essential facilities deci sions in the 1990s occurred in the context oftransporta tion infrastructure bottlenecks akin to Terminal Railroad, where access to the facility was clearly an absolute precondition to entry, they did little to shed light on whether the concept of “essential” should be 62 Case 137/34.174 [1992] 5 C,ML,R. 255. 63 ibid. at 12 (emphasic addcd. 64 CommissiOn Decision No 94 119 [1994] 03 L55 52 65 Case IV;34.689, [1994] 03 L15i 8; [1995] 4 CM.LR 84 (port owner oneratmg arty reftised a cc s to e fert’ oitrant) 66 i935’ 03. L2l68 67 Commis’O’ Deci,102 98 190 [199I 03, 1,72 11.3 1atr curt pera’or d med aces .0 tnde?e .dUE. baegaee hand e a, 8 Ca 1V3ft’20 [1997 0’ 3’56 I 120031 El PR. ISSUE C SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiTED [A2’D cOciTRiBtiTOEft
  • 10. 47S MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [20031 E.I.P.R. given any broader scope in other goods and services cases or intellectual propertyr cases.69 However, the Court of First Instance and tite ECJ have also stepped in, and it is here where the degree of convergence with the U.S. doctrine becomes nsa st apparent. Decisions of the ECJ and the Court of First Instance In 1997, the Court of First Instance in Tierce Ladbroke SA v EC Commission,7° faced a case involving a refusal to license copyrights in whicit the complainant relied both on the 1995 ECJ decision in Magill,7’ and on essential facilities arguments. A Belgian betting oper ator complained of the refusal of a French race course society to license it to displiy televised coverage of French horse races in its betting establishments. In a parallel to the US Intergraph decision, the court declared that the refusal to license could not be regarded as anti-competitive in circumstances where the defendants were not theni selves competing in the downstream betting market in which Tierce Ladbroke was operating. More importantly, however, the court stated that even if this were not a factor, the refusal to license could not be held to e an abuse within the meaning of Magill because: “the televised broadcasting of horse races, although con stituting an additional, and indeed suitable service for bettors, it is not in itself indisj’ensable for the exercise of the bookmakers main activity, namely the taking of bets, as is evidenced by the fact that the applicant [Tierce Ladbroke] is present on the Belgian betting market and occupies a significant position as regard bets on French races.“72 A few months later, the Court of First Instance fol lowed its own Tierce Ladbrokc reasoning in European 69 However, it was not lost oroornplamants in refusal to deal cases that the Commission tended to state the basis for these decisions in more general tenis, somewhat divorced from the absolute nature of the factual settings. For example, in the XXVth Report on Competitiosa Policy (1995), at point 40, the Commission states: “Where a dominant company owns or con trols a facility access to which it essential to enable its com petitors to carry on business, it way not deny them access, and it must grant access on a non-discriminatory basis.” This can be read to mean an essential facility controls the ability of all com petitors to carry on business. Ic. the XXV1th Report en Com petition Policy (1996), at point 5,the Commission formulated it this way: “Examples of such illegal behavior include: refusal to deal as a means of eliminating acomnpetitor by a firm that is the sole or dominant source of supply of a product or that controls access to an essential technology or infrastructure . . .“ For a more complete account of the development of the Commission’s thinking, see John Temple Laag, “Defining Legitimate Com petition: Companies’ Duties to Scapply Competitors and Access to Essential Facilities” Decesnbor 1994) 18 Ferdham Int’l L,J, 437; and John Temple Lang, ‘S4edia, Multimedia and Euro pean Community Antitrust Law” (April 1998) 21 Fordham In’ LI. 1296. Cave T-534 03 (997 5 CM.L.R. 349. 1 Cases C- 241 & 242/9] R RTH end ITP Covv:vvdssi’n 119951 I II CR 743 (19951 4 C.M.L& 118. Night Services v EC commission.73 Faced with claims that the defendant’s refusal to deal in a non-IP context violated the essential facilities principle, the Court declared that, “under the case law on the application of Article 86”, locomotives and train crews belonging to the parties to a joint venture could not be considered “essential” to competition in a downstream market, jus tifying imposition of a duty of non-discriminatory access, “unless there are no viable alternatives available to potential competitors”. The general analysis applied by the Court of First Instance in Tierce Ladbroke was confirmed a year later by the ECJ in Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co KG v Media- print Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenuerlag GmbH & Co KG.74 Oscar Bronner was the Austrian publisher of a national daily newspaper holding between 3.6 and 6 per cent of the Austrian market. Mediaprint was the much larger publisher of two national daily newspapers holding a combined market share of between 42 and 46.8 per cent of the market. In addition, Mediaprint had established a nationwide home delivery network designed to get its papers on readers’ doorsteps early in the morning. Oscar Bronner sought access to Mediaprint’s distribu tion system and was refused; it invoked the essential facilities doctrine in its subsequent court challenge. In his opinion, Advocate General Jacobs noted that the ECJ had yet to refer expressly to the essential facili ties doctrine by name, while it had “come to play an important role” in the Commission’s practice,75 He urged the ECJ to reject Oscar Bronner’s claims: “In the long term it is generally procornpetitive and in the interests of consumers to allow a company to retain for its own use facilities that it has developed for the purpose of its business... . [T]he incentive for a dominant under taking to invest in efficient facilities would be reduced if its competitors were, upon request, able to share the benefits. Thus the mere fact that by retaining a facility for its own use a dominant undertaking retains an advantage over a competitor cannot justify requiring access to it.”7° He went on to recommend that the ECJ order access: “only in cases in which the dominant undertaking has a genuine stranglehold on the related market. That might be the case for example where duplication of the facility is impossible or extremely difficult owing to physical, geographical or legal constraints or is highly undesirable for reasons of public policy. It is not sufficient that the undertaking’s control over a facility should give it a com petitive advantage.”77 The Court did not expressly adopt all of the Advocate General’s reasoning, but it did closely follow the sub stance of his recommendation. The Court addressed 73 Joined Cases T374—375, 384 & 388/94 [1998] 5 C,M.L.R, 718. 74 Case C—7/97 [1199] 4 C.M.L.R, 112. 75 The Advocate General provides a fasric comprehensive reveow of prIor ECJ decismons, the Tzerce Ladbreke decujon, Lemnmass:on iecesvons. Jonas aempee Lnngs 0994 J’ordiaeam sub messlon, arid US case law. 76 Advocate Geveerai’v Oocvcen 77 CL’ at 65. (2003] 0.1.0.10 ISSUE 100 SWEET & MAXWELL UAUThD (AND CONTRIBUTORS]
  • 11. MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] BIER. 479 the application of its own earlier refusal to deal deci sions in Commerciil Solvents,78 Telemarketing79 and Magill to the effect on downstream competition in the daily newspaper market in the event that Mediaprint were found to have a dominant position in a market for home delivery services. First, as to Commercial Solvents and Telemarketing, the Court stated that while those cases held: “the refusal by an undertaking holding a dominant posi don in a given market to supply an undertaking with which it was in competition in a neighboring market with raw materials, and services respectively, which were indis pensable to carrying on the rival’s business, to constitute an abuse, it should be noted, first, that the Court did so to the extent that the conduct in question was likely to elim inate allcompetition on the part ofthe undertaking.”° Thus, under this formulation, the competitive effect must be more than simply to disadvantage downstream competition—the handicap must be absolute, Likewise, with respect to Magill, the Court summarised the test as follows: “In MAGILL the Court found such exceptional circum stances in the fact that the refusal in question concerned a product.. the supply of which was indispensable for carrying on the business in question.. . the fact that such refusal prevented the appearance of a new product for which there was a potential consumer demand, the fact that it was not justified by objective considerations, and that it was likely to exclude all competition in the secon dary market” Thus, in the Court’s view, “even if” Magill was applic able outside the intellectual property context, Oscar Bronner would have to show that the refusal to allow access to the home delivery scheme would “be likely to eliminate all competition in the daily newspaper market on the part of the person requesting the service”, that the refusal could not be objectively justified, and that the service be “indispensable” to Oscar Bronner’s daily newspaper business “with no actual or potential sub stitute”. The Court found that Oscar Bronner’s claim could not succeed given the fact that Oscar Bronner and oth ers were, in fact, presently competing on the daily news paper market despite their lack of access to Mediaprint’s network: “In the first place, it is undisputed that other methods of distributing daily newspapers. . even though they may be less advantageous for the distribution of certain news papers, exist and are used by the publishers of those daily newspapers.” Thus the effect ofthe refusal to supply did not eliminate or prevent competition entirely, and so for the same reason access to the facility could not be considered essential or indispensable. The Court’s treatment of Magill in the Oscar Bronner decision certainly seems to cast doubt on whether the Court is likely to accept an essential facilities argument as a basis for widening the scope of circumstances when compulsory licensing of copyrights is allowed on com petition law grounds. On the one hand, the court was reluctant to say that the same rules apply in Ii? and non IP contexts, hedging with its “even if” statement on applying Magill to Oscar Bronner’s claim. If so, and if the essential facilities argument becomes recognised as a valid argument with a somewhat lower standard in non-IP contexts, then it does not necessarily cross over into the distinct IP context. On the other hand, when the court proceeded on its “what if” basis, it seemed to indicate that Oscar Bronner’s claim failed under Magill’s exceptional circumstances test for much the same reason that it failed under the proposed essential facilities analysis—the plaintiff was able to gain at least some access to the downstream or related market despite the refusal to deal. Viewed in this light, the court could be understood as saying that it does not matter whether one applies Magiil’s “exceptional cir cumstances” holding or some version of the essential facilities doctrine: both mquiries set the hurdle at the same height, and the plaintiff clearly trips on it if the defendant’s conduct does not have the effect of elim inating competition in the relevant downstream mar- ket, Conclus!on If one reads the foregoing decisions ofthe Court of First Instance and the ECJ, and particularly Oscar Bronner, as the author does, then it is relatively easy to understand the author’s view that the treatment of the “essential facilities” doctrine by the European and US courts is converging in the direction of a requirement that the facility in question be virtually indispensable to com petition in the relevant downstream market, such that a refusal to deal would cut off any possibility of com petition. This narrow scope seems particularly appropriate when attempts are made to apply the doctrine to the exercise of intellectual property rights. The author tends to agree with the words of US commentators who have stated that the term “essential facility” is “just an epithet describing the monopolist’s situation: The monopolist possesses something the plaintiffwants. It is not an independent tool of analysis, but only a label”.8’ Just as the United States is left at the end of the second section above considering the relative merits ofthe posi tions put forward in Xerox and Kodak, so the EU is better off considering the proper scope of the “excep tional circumstan es” test set forth in Magill than seek irg broaden the rca h of the essential facil tics 2 0 R 168 0 1 SWEET & MAXW 2 UM)TED [ANT) ONTRIB TORI,]
  • 12. 480 MCCURDY: INTELLECTUAIPRCPBRTY AND COMPETITION: [2003] EJP.R. This position, the author weuLd submit, finds support in the recent decision by the Prsident of the Court of First Instance in IMS Health inc z BC Cornmission2 In staying the Commission’s ixiterini order requiring a copyright holder to license its proprietary data-report ing system to competitors in the market in which the defendant was alleged to be doixtinant (rather than in a related downstream market), the President issued a decision strongly suggesting that Magill’s “exceptional circumstances” inquiry provides the proper framework 82 Case T—184’OI [2001] 4 C]4LR. 2. for analysing competition law challenges to a righthold er’s refusal to license.83 Because the Commission subse quently withdrew its order in IMS Health, the question whether Magill’s “exceptional circumstances” test —rather than a new test based on some version of the essential facilities doctrine—provides the proper frame work for analysis in such cases will need to await further clarification by the courts. 83 See Areeda and Hovenkamp, n.5 above, at ¶j 94-106. A procedural challenge to the President of the Court of First Instance’s stay of the Commission’s interim order was in turn rejected by the President of the European Court of Justice See NDC Health Corp v IMS Health mc, Case C—481!01 [2002] 5 CMLR, 1. [253] ICIER ISSUE IC © SWEET & MAXWELL LIMiTED [AND CONTRIBUTORS]