SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 21
Download to read offline
Tension Minimizing Economies are Minimal Surface Economies August 2, 2017
Copyright © 2018, Richard Anthony Baum
Lecturer, Department of Economics, Retired
Allan Hancock College
One Hancock Drive
Lompoc, CA 93436
BaumRA@aol.com
Keywoods: Minimal Surfaces in Economics, Tension Minimizing Economies
Isothermal Minimal Surface Economies and Core Equivalence
ABSTRACT
Using differential geometry, a description of an economy that exhausts gains from trade
while preserving a vector divergence-free evolution of the Euclidean unit normal price vector is
given for the case of a public classical and a public signaling economy. The purpose is to to
minimize tension between resource owners and consumptive market participants. Though
limited to Euclidean 3-space, it easily generalizes to higher dimensions by a divergence-free
evolution of the Euclidean unit price vector. Assuming a point is not umbilic, a Gram-Schmidt
orthonormalization process may be numerically implemented once a principal direction has been
determined which is an eigenvector whose eigenvalue achieves a maximum or minimum at that
point. Solving analytically or by iteration, or by algorithm in a neighborhood of a point with
boundary, when the system always maintains zero tension, the surface representing it is a
minimal surface which minimizes area costly information must span. Exchange and production
is at every point a point of harmonicity in a minimal surface economy.
INTRODUCTION
Armen A. Alchian (see [1],[2],[7]) was the author’s graduate microeconomics instructor
at UCLA in 1974. Armen passed away February 19, 2013, of natural causes at age 98. May his
spirit rest in happy peace. Professor Alchian studied mathematics and economics at Stanford
University where he was granted a Doctor of Philosophy degree in 1942.
The first discussion in the literature of minimal surfaces in economics of which the author
is aware was in 1994 in an article by Donato [A]. The present paper is an extension of work
conceived February 20, 2015 by the author. On September 1, 2015, Aydin and Sepet [B]
submitted their paper on minimal production surfaces using Galilean Geometry. On March 1,
2016, Aydin and Ergut [C] posted to Math arXiv a discussion of production functions in
economics with a brief reference to when mean curvature 0H  , which would imply a minimal
surface.
Minimal surfaces have a long and rich history in mathematics, however are only
beginning to appear in economics. The author began his study of them in 1987 while a student
of differential geometer John Douglas Moore at the University of California Santa Barbara,
realizing the tangent wealth hyperplane to an indifference surface is a trivial minimal surface. It
was later found a pencil of hyperplanes is a minimal submanifold (a 4-dimensional extension
equivalent to fully opening a book along its spine where each page is a level set) or space itself
less the origin when every hyperplane passes at any angle through the origin.
Each hyperplane corresponds to a potential, the origin being excluded because it
corresponds to a point of infinite potential. The potential of each punctured hyperplane may be
thought of as its energy or the real wealth corresponding to that wealth hyperplane. Recall a
wealth hyperplane is analogous to a budget constraint in elementary microeconomic theory.
The topic of this tribute in honor of Armen A. Alchian is minimal surface economies and
core equivalence. Planar economies have been characterized in the literature as minimal
surfaces. The author believes part of Professor Alchian’s class discussion was on cores of planar
economies. The economic relevance of such a discussion is to minimize tension among market
participants after having exploited all gains from trade. The economic relevance of this paper is
to minimize tension among market participants in consumption space if we may first allow
mutually offsetting gains in production space. Such is the theory of perfect elasticity when a
metric in (u,v) space, where say u and v are labor and capital, is preserved in some target, say
consumption goods 1 2 3( , , )x x x , by a process of stretching or shrinking our source (u,v) of
resources to fit our target consumption sculpture so as to achieve a perfectly elastic equilibrium
in the rubber cap stretched over our consumption sculpture. Elastic equilibrium implies zero
tension at every point in our rubber cap (see Eells and Lemaire [11] page 1).
This paper is also a geometric treatment of parts of Balasko’s equilibrium manifold [4]
and Spence’s notion of signaling [19].
Except for planar surfaces, a lot of minimal surfaces form some sort of saddle. This is
consistent with having zero or negative Gaussian curvature. Minimal surfaces have zero mean
curvature. The amount of bending of the surface by some sort of shape operator averages out to
zero in the small and the large. Tangent to each point of a minimal surface is a plane.
Obviously, planes have zero net bending, or zero mean curvature. The set of all tangent planes
to a minimal surface is the tangent bundle of the minimal surface.
As the unit normal (see Appendix) to some sort of plane in economics seems important to
establish prices at which agents may move along the tangent plane and obtain their desired
bundle of goods, the tangent bundle becomes important when there are a multitude of equilibria
each existing at different price. This seems to violate the rule of one price, to which a placebo
has been offered in the form of a multitude of signaling equilibria, each position being offered to
some type of agent at some price, not all necessarily the same. An older way of violating the
rule of one price is with price discrimination, typically practiced by many doctors including
economists.
What is new in this paper is a proof classical competitive regular public economies, be
they one or many price economies with public factors of production, form minimal surfaces. A
corollary establishes that modern competitive signaling regular public economies with public
signals may also be minimal surfaces. Regular surfaces are smooth (no corners) whose normal at
every point is non-zero, consistent with the unit price vector not being the zero vector. Though
the difference between price and opportunity cost in a perfectly competitive private economy is
zero, economies with prices being the zero vector and the opportunity cost vector being the zero
vector are plain and not very interesting.
Also new is a type of core equivalence between parts of classical perfectly competitive
regular public economies and parts of modern perfectly competitive signaling regular public
economies. This is due to a correspondence between the tangent planes of the parts. Though
positions do not necessarily coincide, what is typically meant by a core is different positions
trace out a path, an area, a volume, or in this case a correspondence between an evolution of unit
normals to tangent planes of parts of each of the above two regular economies which are in fact
the unit price vectors in each economy. When the unit price vectors coincide, we have a form of
core equivalence for the two economies. This should not be taken to mean the tangent bundle of
both economies coincide.
What is not new is economies with a continua of traders and a continua of goods. Also
not new is dense economies. Since the economies under discussion are for the most part saddle
shaped, gross complementarity does not arise among isoquants with two public factors of
production.
Let ( , )u v be orthogonal coordinate axes representing the two public factors of
production. Then, for saddle surfaces, orthogonal cross-sections with respect to ( , )u v are
simultaneously partially convex and concave. A three good public economy may be
parameterized as 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx . Recall from the third paragraph, the
surface ( , )u vx may be planar or some type of saddle. I believe gross complementarity typically
arises with planar surfaces. With saddle surfaces it is not a problem as the orthogonal cross
sections of the isoquants imply some degree of simultaneous substitutability and
complementarity.
Recall we have a source space of public factors ( , )u v and a target space of ( , ).u vx
( , )u vx may be embedded in 3
. However, while the source space is not necessarily Euclidean,
a metric on our target space may be pulled back isometrically to yield an isometric minimal
(harmonic) immersion of our source into our target 2-surface. Indeed, much as the 3D ball may
be embedded in 3
its surface may be immersed as the two-sphere 2
.
The discussion is easy. The following requires some mathematical rigor.
ANALYTICS
Consumption space 1 2 3( , , )x x x denominated in the unit of account, say dollars, euros or
yen, where one is chosen as numéraire (the numéraire is the unit of account in terms of which all
other unit of accounts are relative or measured in terms of), is parameterized by ( , )u v .
Consider the surface 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , )).u v x u v x u v x u v x x Assume throughout ( , )u vx is a
regular parameterized surface.
DEFINITION 1: ( , )u vx x is isothermal if , ,u u v vx x x x and , 0u v x x , where
, denotes the standard inner product.
DEFINITION 2: ( , )u vx x is a minimal surface if its mean curvature is zero.
DEFINITION 3: ( , ) ( 1,2,3)ix u v i  is harmonic if 0ix  where  is the Laplace
operator defined by
2 2
2 2
.
u v
 
  
 
THEOREM 1: Assume x is isothermal. Then x is a minimal surface if and only if
 x 0 where 0 = (0,0,0).
PROOF: See Carmo [9], pp. 201-202.
THEOREM 2 (EXISTENCE): Consumption space in a classical, perfectly competitive full
information non-signaling, economy is an isothermal minimal surface.
PROOF: Let 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx be consumption space. Let x* be an
optimal production point which for convenience we suppose minimizes tension among
market participants and so is a point of harmonicity. Forming matrices of second partials,
it follows from the theory of elasticity that minimizing tension implies traction (off
diagonal terms) is zero and the trace of the matrices of second partials is zero. That is,
* * (0,0,0)uv vu  x x 0 and * * (0,0,0) .uu vv  x x 0 The implication is the rate of
change of the marginal value products of the two factors have equal magnitude but
opposite sign. Geometrically, this implies * and *uu vvx x are mutually offsetting vectors
or forces in the market. We would kind of expect that if an optimal point of production
were to minimize tension in the market among market participants. A simple way of
seeing this is to draw an Edgeworth box for production and observing when all gains
from trade have been exhausted, normals to tangent isoquants in the Edgeworth box point
in opposite directions. What remains to show is they have equal length. * and *u vx x
vectors of marginal value factor returns at optimas. Think: does theory say one ought to
exploit gains from trade until the length of the change in marginal value factor returns
come into equality, that is * *uu vv  x x , and is * *uu vv x x 0 kind of like some
type of second order optimizing condition for critical points of optimal levels of
production: it certainly is if one is trying to minimize tension between resource owners
and consumptive market participants. This is precisely the case when *x are points of
harmonicity given they are points on an isothermal production surface, which is to say
the optimal production surface given harmonicity is an isothermal minimal surface.
DIGRESSION BEFORE THE COUP DE GRACE:
Economic theory says to produce until the marginal revenue products of u and v come
into equality. Formally, we produce until * *u vx x . Scarcity of resources tends to
imply this is non-zero while our assumption of regularity assures this is not zero. Also,
we would like to show * *u vx x . The standard inner product is self adjoint and
normal (see Axler [3], pp. 99-100 and pp. 128-133) with respect some operators, for
example differentials and partial differentials (see Debnath and Mikusinski [10], pp. 247-
248). For example, from *, * *, * ,u u v v   x x x x some positive constant, it
follows:
*, * *, * 0 so * * *
*, * *, * 0 so * * * .
u u uu u uu u uu
v v vv v vv v vv
u
v

    


    

x x x x x x x 0
x x x x x x x 0
Further, Gray [14] shows any system of coordinates on a minimal surface can be made
isothermal. Assuming non-parallel vectors, another way of securing this result is with a
Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization process which, assuming we have identified a
principle direction, trivially yields the other principle direction such that
*, * *, * 1 and *, * 0u u v v u v  x x x x x x . We assume points of production
are regular so the first preceding equality implies the inner products are non-zero, while
the second equality implies * *u vx x . In summary, x* having been made isothermal
using a Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization process on the two vectors of first partials
immediately above produces an orthonormal vector basis for 3
, namely
 
* *
*, *, * where * .
* *
u v
u v
u v



x x
x x n n
x x
END OF DIGRESSION
Given this, ( , )u vx admits the parameterization ( , ) *u v u v   x x 2
(( , ) )u v R
where  and  are orthonormal vectors on ( , ).u vx That is, 1   and
, 0.   It follows * , * ,u u v v    x x x x and * *uu vv uu vv   x x x x 0 if
*x is a point of harmonicity. Hence,
(i) , ,u u v vx x x x and
(ii) , 0u v x x
so that consumption space is isothermal. Further,
(iii) ( , ) uu vvu v   x x x 0
so that consumption space is a minimal surface.
In this case, consumption space is simply a submanifold of wealth hyperplanes, one
wealth hyperplane passing through each of the various *x . If, in addition, points of optimal
production which minimize tension form a smooth regular surface, the surface x* above is a
minimal surface not necessarily planar, but rather saddle shaped with negative Gaussian
curvature. Classical candidates for a minimal production surface are the helicoid and the
catenoid, or perhaps even three Scherk’s first surfaces ( , , ( , )) 1,2,3iu v x u v i  .
Recent discussion (see Donato [A]) has focused on the Cobb-Douglas production
function and has characterized inputs ( . )u v as being perfectly non-substitutable, and thereby
having infinite elasticities of substitution. The classical case of this in economics is the Leontief
production function. In the plane, it forms a series of production functions forming right angles
parallel to the axes, the corner each of which just touches an infinite foliation of budget
constants, each corresponding to different expenditure but each having constant slope.
Apparently, for an infinitesimal change in u, the corresponding change in v is infinite, and for an
infinitesimal change in v, the change in u, is infinite, while maintaining the level set implied by
each of the right-angle Leontief production functions, each of which is projected onto the uv
plane as an isoquant.
Extending Colding and Minicozzi’s 2011 treatment where every embedded minimal
surface may be broken down into parts of plane or parts of a double sided spiral staircase (see
[D], pp. 289-94), it is seen the three dimensional analogue to such a production function is the
ruled surface called the helicoid. Using a Frenet Apparatus of a moving orthonormal frame, we
see the Leontief productions functions rotating upward along each step of the spiral staircase,
which in the limit as step size approaches zero is a very nice smooth approximation of what had
been discrete steps into a smooth ascending helicoid, which is a classical minimal surface.
To see this, perform a rigid motion of the double spiral staircase so as to achieve an
orientation consistent with the above description. Let the ambient space be xyz space with the
usual choice of axes according to the right hand rule. For each choice of u, a choice is made of a
v ruling parallel to the xy plane in xyz space. As u changes, this ruling rotates upward or
downward, this new ruling still parallel to the xy plane with axis of rotation being the z axis in
xyz space. The amount of movement of this spiraling surface along the z axis is given by the
choice of v. A ( , )u v parameterization of this surface embedded in xyz space is
( , ) ( cos , sin , ) ( , , ) where and .u v v u v u v x y z u v          x x
COROLLARY (EXISTENCE): Consumption space in a perfectly competitive signaling economy
in stable equilibrium is a minimal surface given a set of orthonormal signals.
PROOF: Signaling implies equilibrium depends on signaling types ( , ),  where ( , )  vary,
and may be exogenously given or endogenously determined by the system. Suppose
signaling types are exogenously determined by the system and have the feature they are
observable while productivity itself may or may not be directly observable, especially
when there are joint factors of production. Be that as it may, a parameterization of
consumption space in a perfectly competitive signaling economy in stable equilibrium for
various optimal production points *x (each of which minimizes tension among market
participants, that is a point of harmonicity) and exogenous directly observable types
( , )  is a submanifold of 3
given by ( , ) *u v u v   x x . The problem is to
prove ( , )u vx is a minimal submanifold. Given {( , )}  such that 1   and
, 0   , then as before we have *u u  x x , *v v  x x ,
* *uu vv uu vv   x x x x 0 and ( , ) uu vvu v   x x x 0 where x* are points of
harmonicity. However, we now assume that productivity is a constant scalar multiple 
of signals. That is, we assume observable signals can be realized such that
* and *u v  x x . Then for each orthonormal pair ( , )  there is a minimal
surface and a minimal submanifold results from {( , )}  . In summary, at any points
1 2 3( , ) and ( , , )x x x  , there are 3 3 6  signals (recall each and  are 3-tupples)
corresponding to each of the 3 2 6  ways of permuting
1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx at any point ( , )u vx in our target sculpture of
consumption space residing in 3
. This corresponds with the 1980’s notion there ought
to be one signal for each resource-consumption good combination.
Each tangent space of each of the above two types of economies is given by Span
( , )u vx x . Given regular parameterized surfaces, the unit normal price vector at any point on
either surface is ( , ) ( , ).u v
u v
u v
 
 
 
 
  
 
x x
n n
x x
Hence, the core equivalence of the two
economies given the set of all ( , )  common to both economies is the set of all unit price
vectors traced out by common ( , )  , namely { ( , )}u vn for some ( , )  .
DISCUSSION
Seemingly, the analysis has been static so far, or perhaps autonomous (time independent).
We may explore a global dynamical setting (see Smale [18] and Eells [12], [13]) by allowing
diffusion of a perturbation to the economy according to the diffusion or heat partial differential
system of equations, to wit:
t

 

x
x
where time t > 0 . This system of equations is realized by a squeezing of a reaction-diffusion
system of partial differential equations:
( )
t

  

x
x f x
where f(x), the reaction term, is characterized as excess demand. We assume opportunistic
behavior is led as though by an invisible hand to squeeze all super-profit or loss out of the system
so as to leave it in a state of equilibrium where excess demand is (0,0,0)0 . Let t = 0
correspond to an initial equilibria. Then let there be an exogenous or endogenous shock at some
0 < t < 1 . Assume it be closer to 0 than 1, perhaps infinitesimally close to 0 . The minimal
surface representing the initial equilibria is no longer minimal due to the act of being deformed
from its original shape. Perhaps economically and physically, the surface representing
consumption space is sent into wild vibrations. Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations observed
opportunistic behavior by individuals is led, as though by an invisible hand, to an outcome that
benefits all participants (see [18], p. 477). This opportunistic behavior continues until all the
gains from trade have been exhausted. By assuming certain regularity conditions, our slowly
diffusing consumption surface reacts so the free energy released by the shock is gradually
degraded by increasing entropy into unavailable energy, so our surface which initially reacted
now diffuses until it winds down into a new steady state equilibria at an arbitrary time 0 < s + t <
1 , s > 0 . The scaling of time is pretty arbitrary. The initial and new isothermal steady state
equilibria are minimal surfaces as:
 0,0,0
t

   

x
x 0 .
The only difference is the free energy which caused the shock to the initial minimal surface
imparts free energy to the system to do useful work, so the energy of our surface (where in the
case of a two-dimensional minimal surface, the energy is the area of the surface) degrades in the
process of adjusting into the unavailability of energy to do useful work, this type of degradation
of energy to do useful work leading to the ever increasing entropy postulated by
thermodynamics, statistical mechanics and fluid dynamics, to name a few other sciences. Thiel
[E] in his work on continuity and information theory in economics speaks of informational
entropy, following Shannon [F].
One may speculate should progress proceed at unit speed and opportunistic behavior is
efficient, a path from initial to new equilibria is a geodesic. This is perhaps true when movement
along the path on the surface is constrained to move in the tangent space by action of the unit
normal to the surface at each point p. This unit normal may be thought of as the unit price vector
at which trades may be made at that point p. Trade along the surface according to movement on
a path constrained by the unit normal to the surface form geodesics which in general minimize
arc length from one point to another on the surface (see Pressley [17], p. 171).
Progress at unit speed and efficient trade minimizing arc length between two positions on
our surface with the additional regularity assumption our surface does not blow up or collapse in
the process, perhaps due to surgery or the intervention of central banks or regulators when
things get too catastrophic, may insure our surface, though initially anchored by its initial value
boundary at worst suffers a lift (or fall) with a little stretch until re-anchored by the law of the
land and exhaustion of gains from trade until it reaches its new position of steady state equilibria.
What started as a minimal surface gets mapped by the near catastrophe into a new, somewhat
different, minimal surface. In the steady state, the preceding proofs still hold as the steady state
is characterized by ( , )u v x 0 where it is understood an equilibria is such that
t



x
0 in
equilibria.
Perhaps Professor Alchian would have understood. I am relatively certain Professor John
Forbes Nash, Jr. would have had no problem as an economist.
APPENDIX
Three normalizations of price frequently used in economics literature (See Balasko [5]
page 3) are:
(1) Choose a numéraire and set it equal to unity,
(2) The unit simplex method, and
(3) The unit euclidean norm method.
A most natural normalization that allows all currencies or goods to serve as numéraire is the unit
normal. Let 1 2 3x x x    be real wealth at 1 2 3( , , )x x x . Note these variables are not
necessarily independent of one another.
So what are we to do? Give up? No, life is not that simple. For the sake of sanity, let us
simply assume variables ( , )u v exist independently of the others in the static (here and now)
setting. Recall we have chosen to call u and v labor and capital. We will not pick the argument
that labor is independent of capital and vice versa, however rather rely on the mathematical logic
of the previous sentence and settle ourselves with the assumption that the two variables u and v
are independent without necessarily arguing capital and labor are independent. We have not
logically contradicted ourselves, however made life a little simpler. To clear things up, the
variables u and v are independent while the names and concepts capital and labor or labor and
capital are not necessarily independent. Indeed a now deceased Nobel Laureate in Economics
was brave enough to talk of human capital (see Becker [6]). So let us content ourselves with
talking about the two independent variables ( , )u v without worrying too much whether they are
presently alive.
When x is parameterized by (u,v), the unit normal price vector to the surface given in
terms of the factors of production is simply the unit normal u v
u v



x x
n
x x
which maps the
surface nicely onto the unit sphere under the Gauss map.
Another way of saying our economy’s submanifold is minimal or in equilibrium is when
the unit normal price vector n is divergence free. Recall the Gauss map for regular surfaces
resides on the surface of the unit sphere, where some points of the unit sphere are omitted
because they correspond to points where there is not a unit normal to the surface. Say
2 2
div (1 ) 2( ) (1 ) (0,0,0)v uu u v uv u vv       n n n n n n n n 0
(see Ito [15], p. 1031) where it is understood 1 2 3:( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vn and each
( , ) 1,2,3ix u v i  is a graph map with coordinates ( , , )iu v x . Let div n be defined for this
graph map as above. The payoff comes when, as Nash (see [16] p. 5) has suggested, we may
possibly have small remembrances of the past and possibly small inklings as to the future,
knowing the future is inherently uncertain. That is, our analysis takes place on the time interval
( , )  where 0  is a small number with mean zero.
VISIONS OF THE FUTURE
For those ready to tackle the problem, this may bring to mind our previous discussion of
mean curvature, where for a minimal surface the mean curvature or tension field identically
vanishes. That happens precisely when the divergence of the unit normal to our surface or what
is the same thing, the divergence of the unit price vector taken with respect to (u,v), is zero or
divergence free. In the case adjustment is instantaneous, the result is we have a family of
isothermal minimal surfaces when we constrain movement due to shocks to naturally minimize
tension in the price process so as to preserve (1) a divergence free unit normal price evolution,
(2) a zero mean curvature evolution of each family member surface representing an economy and
(3) a minimality of our model in the sense families of surfaces which arise from shocks exhaust
gains from trade due to shocks so as to preserve a divergence free Gauss map process of unit
normals to each family member surface or, what is the same, minimize tension among all market
participants be they resource owners or consumers in the course of exploiting gains from trade
due to shocks. In the case adjustment is instantaneous, we have an elliptic system as evidenced
by the spectrum of the Laplace operator. In the case adjustment takes time, our system is
parabolic and may be modeled by a system of reaction-diffusion equations eventually resulting
in zero excess demand (vanishing reaction terms) so as to achieve the heat or diffusion system in
the steady state and the Laplace system in the stationary or autonomous state when shocks cease
to be a disturbing factor.
REFERENCES
[A] DONATO, J., Minimal Surfaces in Economic Theory, in A. Prastaro and T. M. Rassias
(Eds.), Geometry in Partial Differential Equations, pp. 68-90, World Scientific,
1994.
[B] AYDIN, M. E. & M. ERGUT, Isotropic Geometry of Graph Surfaces Associated with
Product Production Functions in Economics, arXiv: 1603.00222v1,
[math.DG], 1 Mar 2016 (online mathematics repository).
[1] A. A. ALCHIAN & W. R. ALLEN, University Economics: Elements of Inquiry, Third
Edition, Wadsworth, Belmont, CA, 1972
[2] A. A. ALCHIAN & W. R. ALLEN, Exchange and Production: Competition, Coordination,
and Control, Second Edition, Wadsworth, Belmont, CA, 1977
[3] S. AXLER, Linear Algebra Done Right, Second Edition, Springer, New York, NY, 1997
[4] Y. BALASKO, The Equilibrium Manifold: Postmodern Developments in the Theory of
General Economic Equilibrium, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2009
[5] Y. BALASKO, General Equilibrium Theory of Value, PUP, Princeton, NJ, 2011
[6] G. S. BECKER, Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special
Reference to Education, Third Edition, University of Chicago Press, Chicago,
IL, 1993
[7] D. K. BENJAMIN, ED, The Collected Works of Armen A. Alchian, Volumes 1 and 2,
Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN, 2006
[8] E. CANNAN, ED., An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations
BY ADAM SMITH, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1976
[9] M. P. DO CARMO, Differential Geometry of Curves and Surfaces, Prentice-Hall,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1976
[10] L. DEBNATH & P. MIKUSINSKI, Introduction to Hilbert Spaces with Applications, Second
Edition, Academic Press, San Diego, CA, 1999
[11] J. EELLS & L. LEMAIRE, Two Reports on Harmonic Maps, World Scientific, Singapore,
1995
[12] J. EELLS & J. H. SAMPSON, Harmonic Mappings of Riemannian Manifolds, American
Journal of Mathematics, 86, 1964, pp. 109-160
[13] J. EELLS, A Setting for Global Analysis, Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society,
72, 1966, pp. 751-807
[14] A. GRAY, Modern Differential Geometry of Curves and Surfaces with Mathematica,
Second Edition, CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, 1998
[15] K. ITO, Encyclopedic Dictionary of Mathematics, Second Edition, Volumes 1-4. MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA 1987
[16] H. W. KUHN & S. NASAR, ED., The Essential John Nash, PUP, Princeton, NJ 2002
[17] A. PRESSLEY, Elementary Differential Geometry, Springer, London, 2002
[18] S. SMALE, The Mathematics of Time: Essays on Dynamical Systems, Economic
Processes, and Related Topics, Springer-Verlag, New York, NY, 1980
[19] A. MICHAEL SPENCE, Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related
Screening Processes, Harvard, Cambridge, MA 1974

More Related Content

Similar to 2018 tension minimizing economies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017

Economic theory of industrial location
Economic theory of industrial locationEconomic theory of industrial location
Economic theory of industrial locationParth Maru
 
Pre-newtonian calculus
Pre-newtonian calculusPre-newtonian calculus
Pre-newtonian calculusKeith Rodgers
 
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...Jack Sarkissian
 
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-mainjhetrocio
 
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam Lone
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam LoneINDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam Lone
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam LoneSAMEENALONE2
 
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand Models
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand ModelsApproaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand Models
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand ModelsAmy Isleb
 
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market Equlibra
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market EqulibraIntroduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market Equlibra
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market EqulibraAbner Chih Yi Huang
 
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysis
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysisIntroduction to financial forecasting in investment analysis
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysisSpringer
 
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial markets
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial marketsQuantum theory of securities price formation in financial markets
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial marketsJack Sarkissian
 
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...pace130557
 
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical accounting2010
 

Similar to 2018 tension minimizing economies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017 (20)

Dimension
Dimension Dimension
Dimension
 
Economic theory of industrial location
Economic theory of industrial locationEconomic theory of industrial location
Economic theory of industrial location
 
Pre-newtonian calculus
Pre-newtonian calculusPre-newtonian calculus
Pre-newtonian calculus
 
Beyond the Accelerating Inflation Controversy: The Jerk and Jounce Price Vari...
Beyond the Accelerating Inflation Controversy: The Jerk and Jounce Price Vari...Beyond the Accelerating Inflation Controversy: The Jerk and Jounce Price Vari...
Beyond the Accelerating Inflation Controversy: The Jerk and Jounce Price Vari...
 
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...
Option pricing under quantum theory of securities price formation - with copy...
 
HIGHER MATHEMATICS
HIGHER MATHEMATICSHIGHER MATHEMATICS
HIGHER MATHEMATICS
 
Essentials of physical economics
Essentials of physical economicsEssentials of physical economics
Essentials of physical economics
 
General equilibrium ppt
General equilibrium pptGeneral equilibrium ppt
General equilibrium ppt
 
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
1 s2.0-0022199679900175-main
 
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam Lone
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam LoneINDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam Lone
INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION AND ROY’S IDENTITIY by Maryam Lone
 
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand Models
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand ModelsApproaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand Models
Approaches To The Solution Of Intertemporal Consumer Demand Models
 
Micnotes
MicnotesMicnotes
Micnotes
 
IJMPC 2009
IJMPC 2009IJMPC 2009
IJMPC 2009
 
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market Equlibra
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market EqulibraIntroduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market Equlibra
Introduction to Algorithmic aspect of Market Equlibra
 
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysis
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysisIntroduction to financial forecasting in investment analysis
Introduction to financial forecasting in investment analysis
 
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial markets
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial marketsQuantum theory of securities price formation in financial markets
Quantum theory of securities price formation in financial markets
 
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!Optimal combinationofrealizedvolatilityestimators!!!!...
 
Krugman Chapter 1.pdf
Krugman Chapter 1.pdfKrugman Chapter 1.pdf
Krugman Chapter 1.pdf
 
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
Economics and accounting a comparison between philosophical
 
L5
L5L5
L5
 

More from Richard Anthony Baum

2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law
2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law
2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion lawRichard Anthony Baum
 
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for productionRichard Anthony Baum
 
2018 uc office of general counsel letter
2018 uc office of general counsel letter2018 uc office of general counsel letter
2018 uc office of general counsel letterRichard Anthony Baum
 
2017 uc office of general counsel letter
2017 uc office of general counsel letter2017 uc office of general counsel letter
2017 uc office of general counsel letterRichard Anthony Baum
 
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 20172018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017Richard Anthony Baum
 
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci Flow
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci FlowConvex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci Flow
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci FlowRichard Anthony Baum
 
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence Level
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence LevelThere is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence Level
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence LevelRichard Anthony Baum
 

More from Richard Anthony Baum (15)

2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law
2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law
2019 helicoid and factor exhaustion law
 
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production
2019 the helicoid is a minimal surface for production
 
2018 uc office of general counsel letter
2018 uc office of general counsel letter2018 uc office of general counsel letter
2018 uc office of general counsel letter
 
Ra baum 1972 ucsb citation
Ra baum 1972 ucsb citationRa baum 1972 ucsb citation
Ra baum 1972 ucsb citation
 
2017 uc office of general counsel letter
2017 uc office of general counsel letter2017 uc office of general counsel letter
2017 uc office of general counsel letter
 
2006 john nash letter
2006 john nash letter2006 john nash letter
2006 john nash letter
 
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 20172018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017
2018 tension minimizing econimies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017
 
Pres Robert Bacon Broadside
Pres Robert Bacon BroadsidePres Robert Bacon Broadside
Pres Robert Bacon Broadside
 
Pres to uc regents
Pres to uc regentsPres to uc regents
Pres to uc regents
 
(Pres) revised regents' attorney
(Pres) revised regents' attorney(Pres) revised regents' attorney
(Pres) revised regents' attorney
 
Armen a. alchian tribute
Armen a. alchian tributeArmen a. alchian tribute
Armen a. alchian tribute
 
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci Flow
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci FlowConvex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci Flow
Convex Preference, Divergence, Solitons and Ricci Flow
 
Oceanic Games of Terror
Oceanic Games of TerrorOceanic Games of Terror
Oceanic Games of Terror
 
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence Level
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence LevelThere is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence Level
There is No Such Thing as a Minimum Biological Subsistence Level
 
Family of Catenoids
Family of CatenoidsFamily of Catenoids
Family of Catenoids
 

Recently uploaded

The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdfGale Pooley
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxanshikagoel52
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfGale Pooley
 
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...Pooja Nehwal
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...ssifa0344
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdfAdnet Communications
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Bookingroncy bisnoi
 
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdfAdnet Communications
 
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...Pooja Nehwal
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryPooja Nehwal
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingMaristelaRamos12
 
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesMarketing847413
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfGale Pooley
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdfGale Pooley
 
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 

Recently uploaded (20)

The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 23.pdf
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 20.pdf
 
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...
Dharavi Russian callg Girls, { 09892124323 } || Call Girl In Mumbai ...
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...
Solution Manual for Financial Accounting, 11th Edition by Robert Libby, Patri...
 
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
20240417-Calibre-April-2024-Investor-Presentation.pdf
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
20240429 Calibre April 2024 Investor Presentation.pdf
 
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...
Independent Call Girl Number in Kurla Mumbai📲 Pooja Nehwal 9892124323 💞 Full ...
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
 
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 17.pdf
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 19.pdf
 
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(ANIKA) Budhwar Peth Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
 

2018 tension minimizing economies are minimal surface economies august 2, 2017

  • 1. Tension Minimizing Economies are Minimal Surface Economies August 2, 2017 Copyright © 2018, Richard Anthony Baum Lecturer, Department of Economics, Retired Allan Hancock College One Hancock Drive Lompoc, CA 93436 BaumRA@aol.com Keywoods: Minimal Surfaces in Economics, Tension Minimizing Economies Isothermal Minimal Surface Economies and Core Equivalence ABSTRACT Using differential geometry, a description of an economy that exhausts gains from trade while preserving a vector divergence-free evolution of the Euclidean unit normal price vector is given for the case of a public classical and a public signaling economy. The purpose is to to minimize tension between resource owners and consumptive market participants. Though limited to Euclidean 3-space, it easily generalizes to higher dimensions by a divergence-free evolution of the Euclidean unit price vector. Assuming a point is not umbilic, a Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization process may be numerically implemented once a principal direction has been determined which is an eigenvector whose eigenvalue achieves a maximum or minimum at that point. Solving analytically or by iteration, or by algorithm in a neighborhood of a point with boundary, when the system always maintains zero tension, the surface representing it is a
  • 2. minimal surface which minimizes area costly information must span. Exchange and production is at every point a point of harmonicity in a minimal surface economy. INTRODUCTION Armen A. Alchian (see [1],[2],[7]) was the author’s graduate microeconomics instructor at UCLA in 1974. Armen passed away February 19, 2013, of natural causes at age 98. May his spirit rest in happy peace. Professor Alchian studied mathematics and economics at Stanford University where he was granted a Doctor of Philosophy degree in 1942. The first discussion in the literature of minimal surfaces in economics of which the author is aware was in 1994 in an article by Donato [A]. The present paper is an extension of work conceived February 20, 2015 by the author. On September 1, 2015, Aydin and Sepet [B] submitted their paper on minimal production surfaces using Galilean Geometry. On March 1, 2016, Aydin and Ergut [C] posted to Math arXiv a discussion of production functions in economics with a brief reference to when mean curvature 0H  , which would imply a minimal surface. Minimal surfaces have a long and rich history in mathematics, however are only beginning to appear in economics. The author began his study of them in 1987 while a student
  • 3. of differential geometer John Douglas Moore at the University of California Santa Barbara, realizing the tangent wealth hyperplane to an indifference surface is a trivial minimal surface. It was later found a pencil of hyperplanes is a minimal submanifold (a 4-dimensional extension equivalent to fully opening a book along its spine where each page is a level set) or space itself less the origin when every hyperplane passes at any angle through the origin. Each hyperplane corresponds to a potential, the origin being excluded because it corresponds to a point of infinite potential. The potential of each punctured hyperplane may be thought of as its energy or the real wealth corresponding to that wealth hyperplane. Recall a wealth hyperplane is analogous to a budget constraint in elementary microeconomic theory. The topic of this tribute in honor of Armen A. Alchian is minimal surface economies and core equivalence. Planar economies have been characterized in the literature as minimal surfaces. The author believes part of Professor Alchian’s class discussion was on cores of planar economies. The economic relevance of such a discussion is to minimize tension among market participants after having exploited all gains from trade. The economic relevance of this paper is to minimize tension among market participants in consumption space if we may first allow mutually offsetting gains in production space. Such is the theory of perfect elasticity when a metric in (u,v) space, where say u and v are labor and capital, is preserved in some target, say consumption goods 1 2 3( , , )x x x , by a process of stretching or shrinking our source (u,v) of resources to fit our target consumption sculpture so as to achieve a perfectly elastic equilibrium
  • 4. in the rubber cap stretched over our consumption sculpture. Elastic equilibrium implies zero tension at every point in our rubber cap (see Eells and Lemaire [11] page 1). This paper is also a geometric treatment of parts of Balasko’s equilibrium manifold [4] and Spence’s notion of signaling [19]. Except for planar surfaces, a lot of minimal surfaces form some sort of saddle. This is consistent with having zero or negative Gaussian curvature. Minimal surfaces have zero mean curvature. The amount of bending of the surface by some sort of shape operator averages out to zero in the small and the large. Tangent to each point of a minimal surface is a plane. Obviously, planes have zero net bending, or zero mean curvature. The set of all tangent planes to a minimal surface is the tangent bundle of the minimal surface. As the unit normal (see Appendix) to some sort of plane in economics seems important to establish prices at which agents may move along the tangent plane and obtain their desired bundle of goods, the tangent bundle becomes important when there are a multitude of equilibria each existing at different price. This seems to violate the rule of one price, to which a placebo has been offered in the form of a multitude of signaling equilibria, each position being offered to some type of agent at some price, not all necessarily the same. An older way of violating the rule of one price is with price discrimination, typically practiced by many doctors including economists.
  • 5. What is new in this paper is a proof classical competitive regular public economies, be they one or many price economies with public factors of production, form minimal surfaces. A corollary establishes that modern competitive signaling regular public economies with public signals may also be minimal surfaces. Regular surfaces are smooth (no corners) whose normal at every point is non-zero, consistent with the unit price vector not being the zero vector. Though the difference between price and opportunity cost in a perfectly competitive private economy is zero, economies with prices being the zero vector and the opportunity cost vector being the zero vector are plain and not very interesting. Also new is a type of core equivalence between parts of classical perfectly competitive regular public economies and parts of modern perfectly competitive signaling regular public economies. This is due to a correspondence between the tangent planes of the parts. Though positions do not necessarily coincide, what is typically meant by a core is different positions trace out a path, an area, a volume, or in this case a correspondence between an evolution of unit normals to tangent planes of parts of each of the above two regular economies which are in fact the unit price vectors in each economy. When the unit price vectors coincide, we have a form of core equivalence for the two economies. This should not be taken to mean the tangent bundle of both economies coincide. What is not new is economies with a continua of traders and a continua of goods. Also not new is dense economies. Since the economies under discussion are for the most part saddle shaped, gross complementarity does not arise among isoquants with two public factors of production.
  • 6. Let ( , )u v be orthogonal coordinate axes representing the two public factors of production. Then, for saddle surfaces, orthogonal cross-sections with respect to ( , )u v are simultaneously partially convex and concave. A three good public economy may be parameterized as 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx . Recall from the third paragraph, the surface ( , )u vx may be planar or some type of saddle. I believe gross complementarity typically arises with planar surfaces. With saddle surfaces it is not a problem as the orthogonal cross sections of the isoquants imply some degree of simultaneous substitutability and complementarity. Recall we have a source space of public factors ( , )u v and a target space of ( , ).u vx ( , )u vx may be embedded in 3 . However, while the source space is not necessarily Euclidean, a metric on our target space may be pulled back isometrically to yield an isometric minimal (harmonic) immersion of our source into our target 2-surface. Indeed, much as the 3D ball may be embedded in 3 its surface may be immersed as the two-sphere 2 . The discussion is easy. The following requires some mathematical rigor. ANALYTICS
  • 7. Consumption space 1 2 3( , , )x x x denominated in the unit of account, say dollars, euros or yen, where one is chosen as numéraire (the numéraire is the unit of account in terms of which all other unit of accounts are relative or measured in terms of), is parameterized by ( , )u v . Consider the surface 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , )).u v x u v x u v x u v x x Assume throughout ( , )u vx is a regular parameterized surface. DEFINITION 1: ( , )u vx x is isothermal if , ,u u v vx x x x and , 0u v x x , where , denotes the standard inner product. DEFINITION 2: ( , )u vx x is a minimal surface if its mean curvature is zero. DEFINITION 3: ( , ) ( 1,2,3)ix u v i  is harmonic if 0ix  where  is the Laplace operator defined by 2 2 2 2 . u v        THEOREM 1: Assume x is isothermal. Then x is a minimal surface if and only if  x 0 where 0 = (0,0,0). PROOF: See Carmo [9], pp. 201-202. THEOREM 2 (EXISTENCE): Consumption space in a classical, perfectly competitive full information non-signaling, economy is an isothermal minimal surface. PROOF: Let 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx be consumption space. Let x* be an
  • 8. optimal production point which for convenience we suppose minimizes tension among market participants and so is a point of harmonicity. Forming matrices of second partials, it follows from the theory of elasticity that minimizing tension implies traction (off diagonal terms) is zero and the trace of the matrices of second partials is zero. That is, * * (0,0,0)uv vu  x x 0 and * * (0,0,0) .uu vv  x x 0 The implication is the rate of change of the marginal value products of the two factors have equal magnitude but opposite sign. Geometrically, this implies * and *uu vvx x are mutually offsetting vectors or forces in the market. We would kind of expect that if an optimal point of production were to minimize tension in the market among market participants. A simple way of seeing this is to draw an Edgeworth box for production and observing when all gains from trade have been exhausted, normals to tangent isoquants in the Edgeworth box point in opposite directions. What remains to show is they have equal length. * and *u vx x vectors of marginal value factor returns at optimas. Think: does theory say one ought to exploit gains from trade until the length of the change in marginal value factor returns come into equality, that is * *uu vv  x x , and is * *uu vv x x 0 kind of like some type of second order optimizing condition for critical points of optimal levels of production: it certainly is if one is trying to minimize tension between resource owners and consumptive market participants. This is precisely the case when *x are points of harmonicity given they are points on an isothermal production surface, which is to say the optimal production surface given harmonicity is an isothermal minimal surface. DIGRESSION BEFORE THE COUP DE GRACE:
  • 9. Economic theory says to produce until the marginal revenue products of u and v come into equality. Formally, we produce until * *u vx x . Scarcity of resources tends to imply this is non-zero while our assumption of regularity assures this is not zero. Also, we would like to show * *u vx x . The standard inner product is self adjoint and normal (see Axler [3], pp. 99-100 and pp. 128-133) with respect some operators, for example differentials and partial differentials (see Debnath and Mikusinski [10], pp. 247- 248). For example, from *, * *, * ,u u v v   x x x x some positive constant, it follows: *, * *, * 0 so * * * *, * *, * 0 so * * * . u u uu u uu u uu v v vv v vv v vv u v               x x x x x x x 0 x x x x x x x 0 Further, Gray [14] shows any system of coordinates on a minimal surface can be made isothermal. Assuming non-parallel vectors, another way of securing this result is with a Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization process which, assuming we have identified a principle direction, trivially yields the other principle direction such that *, * *, * 1 and *, * 0u u v v u v  x x x x x x . We assume points of production are regular so the first preceding equality implies the inner products are non-zero, while the second equality implies * *u vx x . In summary, x* having been made isothermal using a Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization process on the two vectors of first partials immediately above produces an orthonormal vector basis for 3 , namely   * * *, *, * where * . * * u v u v u v    x x x x n n x x
  • 10. END OF DIGRESSION Given this, ( , )u vx admits the parameterization ( , ) *u v u v   x x 2 (( , ) )u v R where  and  are orthonormal vectors on ( , ).u vx That is, 1   and , 0.   It follows * , * ,u u v v    x x x x and * *uu vv uu vv   x x x x 0 if *x is a point of harmonicity. Hence, (i) , ,u u v vx x x x and (ii) , 0u v x x so that consumption space is isothermal. Further, (iii) ( , ) uu vvu v   x x x 0 so that consumption space is a minimal surface. In this case, consumption space is simply a submanifold of wealth hyperplanes, one wealth hyperplane passing through each of the various *x . If, in addition, points of optimal production which minimize tension form a smooth regular surface, the surface x* above is a minimal surface not necessarily planar, but rather saddle shaped with negative Gaussian curvature. Classical candidates for a minimal production surface are the helicoid and the catenoid, or perhaps even three Scherk’s first surfaces ( , , ( , )) 1,2,3iu v x u v i  . Recent discussion (see Donato [A]) has focused on the Cobb-Douglas production function and has characterized inputs ( . )u v as being perfectly non-substitutable, and thereby having infinite elasticities of substitution. The classical case of this in economics is the Leontief
  • 11. production function. In the plane, it forms a series of production functions forming right angles parallel to the axes, the corner each of which just touches an infinite foliation of budget constants, each corresponding to different expenditure but each having constant slope. Apparently, for an infinitesimal change in u, the corresponding change in v is infinite, and for an infinitesimal change in v, the change in u, is infinite, while maintaining the level set implied by each of the right-angle Leontief production functions, each of which is projected onto the uv plane as an isoquant. Extending Colding and Minicozzi’s 2011 treatment where every embedded minimal surface may be broken down into parts of plane or parts of a double sided spiral staircase (see [D], pp. 289-94), it is seen the three dimensional analogue to such a production function is the ruled surface called the helicoid. Using a Frenet Apparatus of a moving orthonormal frame, we see the Leontief productions functions rotating upward along each step of the spiral staircase, which in the limit as step size approaches zero is a very nice smooth approximation of what had been discrete steps into a smooth ascending helicoid, which is a classical minimal surface. To see this, perform a rigid motion of the double spiral staircase so as to achieve an orientation consistent with the above description. Let the ambient space be xyz space with the usual choice of axes according to the right hand rule. For each choice of u, a choice is made of a v ruling parallel to the xy plane in xyz space. As u changes, this ruling rotates upward or downward, this new ruling still parallel to the xy plane with axis of rotation being the z axis in xyz space. The amount of movement of this spiraling surface along the z axis is given by the choice of v. A ( , )u v parameterization of this surface embedded in xyz space is
  • 12. ( , ) ( cos , sin , ) ( , , ) where and .u v v u v u v x y z u v          x x COROLLARY (EXISTENCE): Consumption space in a perfectly competitive signaling economy in stable equilibrium is a minimal surface given a set of orthonormal signals. PROOF: Signaling implies equilibrium depends on signaling types ( , ),  where ( , )  vary, and may be exogenously given or endogenously determined by the system. Suppose signaling types are exogenously determined by the system and have the feature they are observable while productivity itself may or may not be directly observable, especially when there are joint factors of production. Be that as it may, a parameterization of consumption space in a perfectly competitive signaling economy in stable equilibrium for various optimal production points *x (each of which minimizes tension among market participants, that is a point of harmonicity) and exogenous directly observable types ( , )  is a submanifold of 3 given by ( , ) *u v u v   x x . The problem is to prove ( , )u vx is a minimal submanifold. Given {( , )}  such that 1   and , 0   , then as before we have *u u  x x , *v v  x x , * *uu vv uu vv   x x x x 0 and ( , ) uu vvu v   x x x 0 where x* are points of harmonicity. However, we now assume that productivity is a constant scalar multiple  of signals. That is, we assume observable signals can be realized such that * and *u v  x x . Then for each orthonormal pair ( , )  there is a minimal surface and a minimal submanifold results from {( , )}  . In summary, at any points 1 2 3( , ) and ( , , )x x x  , there are 3 3 6  signals (recall each and  are 3-tupples)
  • 13. corresponding to each of the 3 2 6  ways of permuting 1 2 3( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vx at any point ( , )u vx in our target sculpture of consumption space residing in 3 . This corresponds with the 1980’s notion there ought to be one signal for each resource-consumption good combination. Each tangent space of each of the above two types of economies is given by Span ( , )u vx x . Given regular parameterized surfaces, the unit normal price vector at any point on either surface is ( , ) ( , ).u v u v u v              x x n n x x Hence, the core equivalence of the two economies given the set of all ( , )  common to both economies is the set of all unit price vectors traced out by common ( , )  , namely { ( , )}u vn for some ( , )  . DISCUSSION Seemingly, the analysis has been static so far, or perhaps autonomous (time independent). We may explore a global dynamical setting (see Smale [18] and Eells [12], [13]) by allowing diffusion of a perturbation to the economy according to the diffusion or heat partial differential system of equations, to wit: t     x x where time t > 0 . This system of equations is realized by a squeezing of a reaction-diffusion system of partial differential equations: ( ) t      x x f x
  • 14. where f(x), the reaction term, is characterized as excess demand. We assume opportunistic behavior is led as though by an invisible hand to squeeze all super-profit or loss out of the system so as to leave it in a state of equilibrium where excess demand is (0,0,0)0 . Let t = 0 correspond to an initial equilibria. Then let there be an exogenous or endogenous shock at some 0 < t < 1 . Assume it be closer to 0 than 1, perhaps infinitesimally close to 0 . The minimal surface representing the initial equilibria is no longer minimal due to the act of being deformed from its original shape. Perhaps economically and physically, the surface representing consumption space is sent into wild vibrations. Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations observed opportunistic behavior by individuals is led, as though by an invisible hand, to an outcome that benefits all participants (see [18], p. 477). This opportunistic behavior continues until all the gains from trade have been exhausted. By assuming certain regularity conditions, our slowly diffusing consumption surface reacts so the free energy released by the shock is gradually degraded by increasing entropy into unavailable energy, so our surface which initially reacted now diffuses until it winds down into a new steady state equilibria at an arbitrary time 0 < s + t < 1 , s > 0 . The scaling of time is pretty arbitrary. The initial and new isothermal steady state equilibria are minimal surfaces as:  0,0,0 t       x x 0 . The only difference is the free energy which caused the shock to the initial minimal surface imparts free energy to the system to do useful work, so the energy of our surface (where in the case of a two-dimensional minimal surface, the energy is the area of the surface) degrades in the process of adjusting into the unavailability of energy to do useful work, this type of degradation of energy to do useful work leading to the ever increasing entropy postulated by thermodynamics, statistical mechanics and fluid dynamics, to name a few other sciences. Thiel
  • 15. [E] in his work on continuity and information theory in economics speaks of informational entropy, following Shannon [F]. One may speculate should progress proceed at unit speed and opportunistic behavior is efficient, a path from initial to new equilibria is a geodesic. This is perhaps true when movement along the path on the surface is constrained to move in the tangent space by action of the unit normal to the surface at each point p. This unit normal may be thought of as the unit price vector at which trades may be made at that point p. Trade along the surface according to movement on a path constrained by the unit normal to the surface form geodesics which in general minimize arc length from one point to another on the surface (see Pressley [17], p. 171). Progress at unit speed and efficient trade minimizing arc length between two positions on our surface with the additional regularity assumption our surface does not blow up or collapse in the process, perhaps due to surgery or the intervention of central banks or regulators when things get too catastrophic, may insure our surface, though initially anchored by its initial value boundary at worst suffers a lift (or fall) with a little stretch until re-anchored by the law of the land and exhaustion of gains from trade until it reaches its new position of steady state equilibria. What started as a minimal surface gets mapped by the near catastrophe into a new, somewhat different, minimal surface. In the steady state, the preceding proofs still hold as the steady state is characterized by ( , )u v x 0 where it is understood an equilibria is such that t    x 0 in equilibria.
  • 16. Perhaps Professor Alchian would have understood. I am relatively certain Professor John Forbes Nash, Jr. would have had no problem as an economist. APPENDIX Three normalizations of price frequently used in economics literature (See Balasko [5] page 3) are: (1) Choose a numéraire and set it equal to unity, (2) The unit simplex method, and (3) The unit euclidean norm method. A most natural normalization that allows all currencies or goods to serve as numéraire is the unit normal. Let 1 2 3x x x    be real wealth at 1 2 3( , , )x x x . Note these variables are not necessarily independent of one another. So what are we to do? Give up? No, life is not that simple. For the sake of sanity, let us simply assume variables ( , )u v exist independently of the others in the static (here and now) setting. Recall we have chosen to call u and v labor and capital. We will not pick the argument that labor is independent of capital and vice versa, however rather rely on the mathematical logic
  • 17. of the previous sentence and settle ourselves with the assumption that the two variables u and v are independent without necessarily arguing capital and labor are independent. We have not logically contradicted ourselves, however made life a little simpler. To clear things up, the variables u and v are independent while the names and concepts capital and labor or labor and capital are not necessarily independent. Indeed a now deceased Nobel Laureate in Economics was brave enough to talk of human capital (see Becker [6]). So let us content ourselves with talking about the two independent variables ( , )u v without worrying too much whether they are presently alive. When x is parameterized by (u,v), the unit normal price vector to the surface given in terms of the factors of production is simply the unit normal u v u v    x x n x x which maps the surface nicely onto the unit sphere under the Gauss map. Another way of saying our economy’s submanifold is minimal or in equilibrium is when the unit normal price vector n is divergence free. Recall the Gauss map for regular surfaces resides on the surface of the unit sphere, where some points of the unit sphere are omitted because they correspond to points where there is not a unit normal to the surface. Say 2 2 div (1 ) 2( ) (1 ) (0,0,0)v uu u v uv u vv       n n n n n n n n 0 (see Ito [15], p. 1031) where it is understood 1 2 3:( , ) ( ( , ), ( , ), ( , ))u v x u v x u v x u vn and each ( , ) 1,2,3ix u v i  is a graph map with coordinates ( , , )iu v x . Let div n be defined for this
  • 18. graph map as above. The payoff comes when, as Nash (see [16] p. 5) has suggested, we may possibly have small remembrances of the past and possibly small inklings as to the future, knowing the future is inherently uncertain. That is, our analysis takes place on the time interval ( , )  where 0  is a small number with mean zero. VISIONS OF THE FUTURE For those ready to tackle the problem, this may bring to mind our previous discussion of mean curvature, where for a minimal surface the mean curvature or tension field identically vanishes. That happens precisely when the divergence of the unit normal to our surface or what is the same thing, the divergence of the unit price vector taken with respect to (u,v), is zero or divergence free. In the case adjustment is instantaneous, the result is we have a family of isothermal minimal surfaces when we constrain movement due to shocks to naturally minimize tension in the price process so as to preserve (1) a divergence free unit normal price evolution, (2) a zero mean curvature evolution of each family member surface representing an economy and (3) a minimality of our model in the sense families of surfaces which arise from shocks exhaust gains from trade due to shocks so as to preserve a divergence free Gauss map process of unit normals to each family member surface or, what is the same, minimize tension among all market participants be they resource owners or consumers in the course of exploiting gains from trade due to shocks. In the case adjustment is instantaneous, we have an elliptic system as evidenced
  • 19. by the spectrum of the Laplace operator. In the case adjustment takes time, our system is parabolic and may be modeled by a system of reaction-diffusion equations eventually resulting in zero excess demand (vanishing reaction terms) so as to achieve the heat or diffusion system in the steady state and the Laplace system in the stationary or autonomous state when shocks cease to be a disturbing factor. REFERENCES
  • 20. [A] DONATO, J., Minimal Surfaces in Economic Theory, in A. Prastaro and T. M. Rassias (Eds.), Geometry in Partial Differential Equations, pp. 68-90, World Scientific, 1994. [B] AYDIN, M. E. & M. ERGUT, Isotropic Geometry of Graph Surfaces Associated with Product Production Functions in Economics, arXiv: 1603.00222v1, [math.DG], 1 Mar 2016 (online mathematics repository). [1] A. A. ALCHIAN & W. R. ALLEN, University Economics: Elements of Inquiry, Third Edition, Wadsworth, Belmont, CA, 1972 [2] A. A. ALCHIAN & W. R. ALLEN, Exchange and Production: Competition, Coordination, and Control, Second Edition, Wadsworth, Belmont, CA, 1977 [3] S. AXLER, Linear Algebra Done Right, Second Edition, Springer, New York, NY, 1997 [4] Y. BALASKO, The Equilibrium Manifold: Postmodern Developments in the Theory of General Economic Equilibrium, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2009 [5] Y. BALASKO, General Equilibrium Theory of Value, PUP, Princeton, NJ, 2011 [6] G. S. BECKER, Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, Third Edition, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1993 [7] D. K. BENJAMIN, ED, The Collected Works of Armen A. Alchian, Volumes 1 and 2, Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN, 2006 [8] E. CANNAN, ED., An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations BY ADAM SMITH, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1976 [9] M. P. DO CARMO, Differential Geometry of Curves and Surfaces, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1976 [10] L. DEBNATH & P. MIKUSINSKI, Introduction to Hilbert Spaces with Applications, Second Edition, Academic Press, San Diego, CA, 1999 [11] J. EELLS & L. LEMAIRE, Two Reports on Harmonic Maps, World Scientific, Singapore, 1995 [12] J. EELLS & J. H. SAMPSON, Harmonic Mappings of Riemannian Manifolds, American Journal of Mathematics, 86, 1964, pp. 109-160 [13] J. EELLS, A Setting for Global Analysis, Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, 72, 1966, pp. 751-807
  • 21. [14] A. GRAY, Modern Differential Geometry of Curves and Surfaces with Mathematica, Second Edition, CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, 1998 [15] K. ITO, Encyclopedic Dictionary of Mathematics, Second Edition, Volumes 1-4. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA 1987 [16] H. W. KUHN & S. NASAR, ED., The Essential John Nash, PUP, Princeton, NJ 2002 [17] A. PRESSLEY, Elementary Differential Geometry, Springer, London, 2002 [18] S. SMALE, The Mathematics of Time: Essays on Dynamical Systems, Economic Processes, and Related Topics, Springer-Verlag, New York, NY, 1980 [19] A. MICHAEL SPENCE, Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening Processes, Harvard, Cambridge, MA 1974