SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 23
Download to read offline
40651 26/4/06 20:15                            FJDS_A_168181      (XML)




Journal of Development Studies,
Vol. 42, No. 4, 640–661, May 2006




The Political Determinants of Fiscal
Policies in the States of India:
An Empirical Investigation
KAUSIK CHAUDHURI* & SUGATO DASGUPTA**
*Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, India, **Jawaharlal Nehru University,
New Delhi, India


Final version accepted April 2005



ABSTRACT Using data from the 14 major states of India, we investigate whether state
governments’ fiscal policy choices are tempered by political considerations. Our principal findings
are twofold. First, we show that certain fiscal policies experience electoral cycles: state
governments raise less commodity tax revenue, spend less on the current account, and incur larger
capital account developmental expenditures in election years than in all other years. Second, we
show that coalition state governments raise less own non-tax revenues and spend less on the
current account than state governments that are more cohesive in composition. In sum, the
dispersion of political power affects government size.



I. Introduction
What determines the fiscal policies of a government? While the traditional public
finance literature answers this question from alternative perspectives, it is always
assumed that the government is a benevolent social planner, interested in maximising
the representative citizen’s welfare. In contrast, the recent literature on political
economy emphasises the institutional constraints under which policies are
formulated. It argues that policy-makers are typically political parties or politicians.
Naturally, the fiscal policies that are undertaken are tempered by political factors.
   This paper tests some of the political economy theories of government behaviour
in the context of a developing country. Specifically, we examine the 14 major states
of India over 21 financial years (1974–75 to 1994–95) and ask the following question:
Does the proximity of a state legislative assembly election or the extent of
government cohesion affect fiscal policies in the states of India?



Correspondence Address: Kausik Chaudhuri, IGIDR, Gen. Vaidya Marg, Goregaon (East), Mumbai
400 065, India, Email: kausik@igidr.ac.in
Sugato Dasgupta, Centre for Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi
110 067, India, Email: sugatodasgupta@rediffmail.com

ISSN 0022-0388 Print/1743-9140 Online/06/040640-22 ª 2006 Taylor & Francis
DOI: 10.1080/00220380600682116
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 641

   Our focus on India is interesting for two reasons. First, there is a vast literature
that uses data from developed countries to test for the presence of electoral and other
political considerations in government behaviour. This literature has scarcely been
extended to developing countries (Schuknecht (2000), Block (2002), Shi and
Svensson (2002a, b), and Khemani (2004) are recent and notable exceptions). There
is an obvious reason for the lacuna – democratic institutions have only very recently
taken root in developing countries. India, on the other hand, has been a democracy
since its independence in 1947, and periodic elections to the national and state
legislative assemblies have taken place since 1952. Therefore, the Indian experience
sheds light on political economy models in the context of a developing country with
long-standing democratic traditions.1 Second, it is commonly maintained that voters
in India do not condition their votes on economic variables; rather, voting behaviour
is exclusively based on caste allegiances. If this is true, political economy models,
which invariably hinge on economic factors, are doomed to fail in the Indian
context. Evidence to the contrary will indicate that voters in India, at least at the
margin, are not blind devotees of primordial caste ties.
   Our use of state level data yields tangible benefits as well. Most studies that seek to
establish electoral cycles in fiscal policies proceed one country at a time. Even when a
relatively long country-specific history is observed, the number of election years
remains small.2 We, on the other hand, obtain information on an aggregate of 68
state legislative assembly elections, thereby circumventing the degrees-of-freedom
problem.3 In addition, the cross-section units in our data set (that is, the states of
India) are not too disparate entities. Similar arguments also apply when the
relationship between government cohesion and fiscal policies is examined.
   We now briefly outline the models that provide the theoretical rationale for our
empirical investigation. Beginning with Nordhaus (1975), several theoretical papers
have explored the interactions between election timing and governments’ fiscal policy
choices. We test the predictions of two influential models in this genre. In Rogoff and
Sibert (1988), an opportunistic incumbent government seeks to remain in power. In
an election year, it lowers tax revenues and raises public expenditures to signal its
competency to the electorate.4 In an interesting variant, Rogoff (1990) allows the
government to incur expenditures of two sorts: public consumption and public
investment. Since the effects of public investment are imperfectly observed by voters,
election-year signalling shifts expenditures in favour of consumption and against
investment.5
   A separate theoretical strand of the political economy literature emphasises the
connection between the dispersion of political power and budget deficits. Alesina and
Tabellini (1990) consider a polity with two political parties that differ in their pre-
ferences over the composition of public spending. The party in power, fearing an
electoral defeat, issues public debt to constrain the spending capacity of its successor.
Hence, the intertemporal sharing of political authority generates budget deficits.6
Alesina and Drazen (1993) explore the case of a coalition government that must raise
taxes to balance its budget. Each coalition partner wishes to avoid its share of the tax
burden; the ensuing war of attrition generates rising public debt. Hence, the contem-
poraneous sharing of political authority facilitates the creation of budget deficits.7,8
   Instead of focusing on the government budget deficit, we consider its two main
components: expenditures incurred by the government and tax revenues collected.
642 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

At least two plausible theories have been proposed linking government characteristic
(coalition or single-party) to expenditure and tax policies. First, in a coalition
government, each coalition partner normally caters to a narrow constituency of core
supporters. A coalition partner therefore has an incentive to demand targeted
programmes that are inefficiently large relative to financing costs, which are
customarily borne by the citizens in aggregate.9 In sum, coalition governments spend
more than single-party governments. If government spending is roughly matched
by tax revenue, coalition governments also raise more taxes than single-party
governments. An alternative, albeit informal, argument (see, for example, Dutta
(1996a) and Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001)) runs as follows: Coalition governments
are frequently unstable; hence, the future consequences of current actions are
severely discounted. This general neglect of the future coupled with a desire to buy
more time in office from supporters leads to lower taxes and higher expenditures. We
shall argue (see Section II for the theoretical framework) that the instability
associated with coalition governments may actually dampen public spending! When
indivisibilities force the benefits of public spending in a given year to be conferred on
a subset of the coalition partners, the excluded parties in the government will be
willing to pay up their share of the financing costs only if there are compensating
future gains to be had. The possibility of a government breakdown reduces the
expected value of future benefits and therefore leads to a bargaining impasse.10
   Our study contributes to the small but growing literature that uses data from
India to test political economy models of government behaviour. A branch of this
literature explores the links between the timing of elections to the national legislative
assembly and central governments’ economic policies in India. Chibber (1995) shows
that central governments’ food subsidies are higher in election years than in non-
election years. Karnik (1990) demonstrates that central government expenditure,
aggregated over current and capital accounts, increases when an election is
impending. Sen and Vaidya (1996) fail to uncover electoral cycles in central
governments’ current account expenditure, capital account expenditure and current
account receipt; however, deficit in the current account is shown to be higher in
election years than in non-election years. In a slightly different vein, Chowdhury
(1993) detects political surfing by central governments – that is, central governments
strategically call for national elections when the economy’s output growth turns out
to be high. Besley and Burgess (2000, 2002), on the other hand, focus on the behaviour
of state governments in India. Besley and Burgess (2000) demonstrate that party
ideology affects public policy. Specifically, the cumulative land reforms passed in a
given state-year depends on the four-year lagged state legislative assembly seat shares
of different political groups. Besley and Burgess (2002) show that state governments
are more responsive to falls in food production and crop damage through floods where
newspaper circulation is higher and electoral accountability is greater.
   Our work is directly linked to two papers that we discuss below. Dutta (1996a)
analyses state level data from India to determine whether the tax and expenditure
policies of coalition governments are markedly different from those of single-party
governments. Coalition governments are shown to have higher levels of current
account expenditure and lower levels of non-tax revenue; on the other hand, the
levels of tax revenue and surplus (deficit) in the current account budget are
unaffected by government fragmentation. Khemani (2004) examines the impact of
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 643

state legislative assembly elections on the fiscal policies of state governments in India.
Her findings are in striking contrast to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988)
and Rogoff (1990). During election years, Khemani concludes that state govern-
ments do not provide tax rate cuts on products that are widely consumed; rather, tax
breaks are given to small groups of producers. Furthermore, the proximity of state
elections leaves state governments’ total expenditure unaffected. Instead, the
composition of spending changes during election years, away from public
consumption and in favour of investment spending. All of this is viewed as evidence
of election-year manipulation of fiscal policies to favour a narrow constituency of
pivotal voters. Our study differs from these two papers in three ways. First, we
examine a substantially larger set of policy variables; the ensuing analysis is therefore
more detailed. Second, we provide a framework in which the policy effects of
government characteristic and election timing are jointly studied. It turns out that
both of the political variables impact on state governments’ fiscal policies. Third, the
econometric model that we specify differs somewhat from that of Dutta (1996a) and
Khemani (2004).11 Empirical findings that survive these differences can therefore be
deemed to be reasonably robust.
   The principal findings of this paper are threefold. (1) State governments collect less
commodity tax revenue in election years than in non-election years. (2) Spending on
the current account, which has a substantial government consumption component, is
lower in election years than in non-election years. In contrast, developmental
spending on the capital account, which has a large physical investment component,
experiences an election-year spurt. Results (1) and (2) are broadly consistent with the
findings of Khemani (2004). (3) Coalition governments raise less own non-tax
revenues and spend less on the current account than governments that are more
cohesive in composition. In other words, the dispersion of political power affects
governments’ fiscal policy choices.
   The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section II presents a
theoretical framework to demonstrate that the political instability associated with
coalition governments can actually dampen public spending. Section III provides a
description of the data set used in our analysis. Section IV presents both the
econometric procedures that we employed and the empirical results obtained. Section
V briefly considers the robustness of the empirical results. Section VI concludes.

II. A Theoretical Framework
In this section, we present a simple model to show that the political instability of
coalition governments may actually dampen government spending. Consider, to this
end, a two-period discrete-time model in which a government forms in the first
period (that is, period 1). The government consists of two political parties, A and B,
each political party representing exactly one quarter of the population of a nation.
   In period 1, the government has the option to undertake a new project with the
following features: (1) the total financing cost of the project is c (each political party
                          c
in power has to pay up 4), and (2) aggregate benefits from the project are V, which
are evenly distributed over both the time periods. In contrast to Baron (1991, 1998),
project benefits within a given period are however not divisible. Specifically, should
the project be undertaken, the period-1 benefit from the project is V to one of the two
                                                                      2
644 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

political parties in power. Without loss of generality, let party A be this period-1
beneficiary.
   Once period 1 concludes, two possibilities arise. First, for exogenous reasons the
government terminates with probability p; post-collapse, the project is scrapped and
the continuation payoffs of the two erstwhile coalition members are normalised to 0.
Second, if government collapse is averted, the project remains in place and party B
receives period-2 benefits of V. 2
   Suppose sanctioning of the project requires consent by both parties A and B. Then,
for a fixed V, when is the project undertaken? Notice that if party B agrees to finance
the project, its expected benefit, assuming no discounting, is V Â ð1 À pÞ while its cost
                                                                 2
   c
is 4. Hence, the project goes through only if c is weakly less than the threshold value of
2V 6 (1 7 p). As government instability (that is, p) increases, the threshold value
decreases. In other words, the overspending associated with pork barrel politics is
muted when government instability is enhanced. The intuition behind the result is
transparent: party B agrees to finance the project in period 1 only because current
period cooperation leads to gains in the future. When government breakdown is
imminent, the future is heavily discounted and cooperation becomes difficult to
sustain.12
   We close the discussion of our model with a final remark. Our model is written in
terms of public investment. A slight reinterpretation of the model allows us to
consider public consumption as well. Here, we can think of the political parties as
representing distinct geographical regions, the government potentially engaged in
hiring a fixed number of workers at an above-market wage, and certain
indivisibilities in the hiring process.



III. The Data
The data set for our study consists of annual observations. It spans 21 financial years
(1974–75 to 1994–95) and covers the 14 major states of India. India comprises 25
states and seven union territories. In the financial year 1994–95, the aforementioned
14 states accounted for 83.1 per cent of India’s land area, 93.2 per cent of her
population, and 92.6 per cent of the net domestic product.
   The variables that we consider partition into three distinct categories: (1) Data on
the fiscal (revenue and expenditure) policies of state governments were assembled
from various volumes of the Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, published by the central
bank of India. (2) State economic and demographic characteristics, which served as
control variables in the empirical analysis, were compiled as follows. The National
Accounts Statistics (published by the Central Statistical Organisation) provided
information on state domestic product and the proportion of state domestic product
derived from the primary sector; state literacy rate data were obtained from the
Census of India and the National Sample Survey rounds (both published by the
Government of India); while Press in India (published by the Ministry of
Information and Broadcasting) recorded the per capita newspaper circulation data
for each state-year.13 (3) The political variables were gleaned from two sources. First,
the dates of all state legislative assembly elections were taken from the book India
Decides. Thereafter, for each state-year, the ‘nature’ of the state government (details
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 645

given below) was determined. This information was extracted from the publication
Encyclopaedia of India and Her States.
  How do we measure the ‘nature’ of state governments? The theory sketched in
Section II maintains that fiscal policy choices are systematically influenced by the extent
of government cohesion. At first blush, this suggests a distinction between single-party
and coalition governments. Such a distinction misses an important point: coalition
governments per se do not affect fiscal policy choices; rather, what matters is the
bargaining between strategically important coalition partners with disparate interests.
Following Dutta (1996a, b), we posit that a coalition partner is strategically important
only if it is a pivotal member of the coalition; that is, if its withdrawal from the
government transforms a hitherto winning coalition (with majority support) into a
nonviable one. A coalition government, in turn, is presumed to distort fiscal policy
choices should it contain two or more pivotal parties. Henceforth, we shall refer to such
a government as a fragmented coalition.14
  For each of the 14 major states of India, column 1 of Table 1 shows the incidence
of fragmented coalition governments. The construction of column 1 proceeds as
follows. First, from the 21-year-long electoral history of each state (financial year
1974–75 to 1994–95), we calculated the number of months during which the
government had multiple pivotal parties. Second, the aggregate months were
converted into equivalent years. For example, the state of Bihar witnessed
governments of the aforementioned type for a sum total of 22 months. This is the
equivalent of 1.83 years. Column 1 reveals an interesting finding: most of the 14
chosen states have had some exposure to fragmented coalition governments.
  Table 2 shows the summary statistics of state governments’ fiscal policy variables
analysed in this study. Notice that these variables are of three kinds: revenue


Table 1. Incidence of fragmented coalition governments and left-wing governments in the
                                     states of India

States                 Fragmented coalition govt. (in years)        Left-wing govt. (in years)

Andhra Pradesh                           0.00                                  0.00
Bihar                                    1.83                                  0.00
Gujarat                                  5.08                                  0.00
Haryana                                  5.08                                  0.00
Karnataka                                1.92                                  0.00
Kerala                                  16.25                                  5.83
Madhya Pradesh                           0.00                                  0.00
Maharashtra                              2.08                                  0.00
Orissa                                   0.17                                  0.00
Punjab                                   2.75                                  0.00
Rajasthan                                0.67                                  0.00
Tamil Nadu                               0.00                                  0.00
Uttar Pradesh                            1.83                                  0.00
West Bengal                              0.00                                 17.83

Note: The sample period covered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. ‘Fragmented coalition
govt. (in years)’ shows the total number of years during which the government of the state was
a fragmented coalition. ‘Left-wing govt. (in years)’ shows the total number of years during
which a communist party headed the government of the state.
646 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

 Table 2. Summary statistics of fiscal policy variables: (constant 1960–61 rupees per capita)

Variables                                    # Obs.              Mean               Std. dev.

Revenue
Own tax revenue                                21                35.94               18.50
Commodity tax revenue                          21                32.15               16.85
Own non-tax revenue                            21                13.26                8.29
Current account expenditure
Total current acct. expenditure                21                74.89               30.58
Non-developmental expenditure                  21                23.14               11.36
Developmental expenditure                      21                50.89               20.41
Grants to local bodies                         21                 0.85                0.80
Economic services expenditure                  21                22.03               11.53
Social services expenditure                    21                28.99               10.77
Capital account expenditure
Developmental expenditure                      21                10.83                 5.26
Economic services expenditure                  21                 9.51                 5.11
Social services expenditure                    21                 1.38                 1.00
Education expenditure                          21                 0.19                 0.20

Note: The sample period considered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. All of the variables
are measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. ‘# Obs.’ is the number of state-specific
observations for the variable. ‘Mean’ (‘Std. dev.’) computes the average (standard deviation)
of the variable over the sample state-years.

variables, and variables related to expenditure on the current and capital accounts.
Below, we provide a brief overview of the fiscal structure of state governments.
   The total revenue of a state government has two components: total tax revenue
and total non-tax revenue. Averaged over the sample state-years, total tax revenue
accounts for 67.8 per cent of total revenue. A state government’s total tax revenue is,
in turn, decomposed into two parts: its share in the tax revenue of the central
government (31.5 per cent), and revenue raised through state taxes (68.5 per cent).
State governments levy taxes on agricultural income, property, and commodities.
Commodity taxes yield 88.9 per cent of states’ own tax revenue. A state
government’s non-tax revenue derives from two sources: grants from the central
government and own non-tax revenue (the three most important subcategories being
interest receipts from loans issued by the state government, dividends and profits
from public sector undertakings owned by the state government, and revenues from
state lotteries). Our study pays special attention to the own tax revenue and own
non-tax revenue components of total revenue.
   Expenditures incurred by state governments are on either the current account (71.1
per cent) or the capital account (28.9 per cent). Current account expenditure is of three
types: developmental spending (68.3 per cent), non-developmental spending (30.6 per
cent), and grants to local bodies and Panchayati Raj institutions (1.2 per cent).
Developmental expenditure, which is largely devoted to the maintenance of existing
assets, involves spending on social services (56.7 per cent) and economic services (43.3
per cent). Non-developmental expenditure principally comprises interest payments on
accumulated debt and outlays on fiscal and administrative services.
   State governments’ capital account expenditure mainly entails the discharge of
internal debt, the repayment of loans to the central government, and the provision of
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 647

loans for assorted purposes. However, 39.8 per cent of capital account expenditure is
devoted to the creation of physical assets. This developmental component, in
turn, involves spending on social services (12.2 per cent) and economic services
(87.8 per cent). Our study focusses on capital account developmental expenditure.

IV. Empirical Results
Do political considerations (namely, the proximity of a state election and the extent
of government cohesion) affect the fiscal policy choices of state governments? To
answer this question, we consider estimating a fixed-effects error-components model
of the form:


   Pst ¼ as þ dt þ bxst þ gFragmentst þ oElecst þ est ðs ¼ 1; . . . ; S; t ¼ 1; . . . ; TÞ   ð1Þ

where Pst denotes a particular fiscal policy variable (for example, the log of per
capita own tax revenue) in state s during financial year t, as is a state fixed effect, dt is
a year effect, xst is a (k61) vector of explanatory variables that capture economic
and demographic characteristics of state s in financial year t, Fragmentst measures
the proportion of financial year t during which the government of state s had more
than one pivotal party, Elecst (henceforth, referred to as the election year dummy) is a
zero-one variable that equals one if financial year t is an election year in state s, and
est is the error term, presumed to be orthogonal to all of the regressors. The political
theories that we test deal exclusively with the significance, sign and magnitude of the
estimates of g and o.
   The treatment of elections in equation 1 merits scrutiny. First, some rule must
specify when financial year t is deemed to be an election year in state s. Following
Alesina et al. (1993) and Reid (1998), financial year t is called an election year in
state s if a state legislative assembly election is held in the second half of financial
year t or in the first half of the next financial year.
   A more serious problem pertains to the potential endogeneity of elections.15 The
constitution of India mandates that a state legislative assembly have a normal term
of five years from the date appointed for its first sitting. Accordingly, we classify a
state legislative assembly election as scheduled if it is held when the current assembly
is at least four years of age. In our data set, the 14 states have experienced an
aggregate of 68 state legislative assembly elections; 47 of these elections are classified
as scheduled. What accounts for the remaining 21 mid-term elections?
   Three circumstances lead to mid-term elections. First, a state government may lose
the confidence of a majority in the state legislature. The governor of the state, upon
verifying that no claimant can form an alternative government commanding majority
support, conventionally calls for fresh elections. Second, the president of India, upon
receipt of a report by the governor of a state or otherwise, may be satisfied that
constitutional breakdown has occurred at the state level. This leads to the temporary
imposition of President’s Rule and, eventually, fresh elections. Third, a state government
may voluntarily petition the governor of the state to hold mid-term elections.
   The third reason for mid-term elections is especially problematic. If the incumbent
state government strategically holds elections for electoral gains, then election timing
648 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

         Table 3. Time duration between successive state legislative assembly elections

                         # elects.;     # elects.;     # elects.;     # elects.;      # elects.;
States                    0–1 yr.       1–2 yrs.       2–3 yrs.       3–4 yrs.         !4 yrs.

Andhra Pradesh               0              0              1              0                4
Bihar                        0              0              1              0                4
Gujarat                      0              0              0              1                4
Haryana                      0              0              0              1                3
Karnataka                    0              0              1              0                4
Kerala                       0              0              2              0                3
Madhya Pradesh               0              0              2              0                3
Maharashtra                  0              0              1              0                4
Orissa                       0              0              1              1                3
Punjab                       0              0              1              0                3
Rajasthan                    0              0              2              0                3
Tamil Nadu                   0              0              2              0                3
Uttar Pradesh                0              1              2              1                2
West Bengal                  0              0              0              0                4
Column Totals                0              1             16              4               47

Note: The sample period considered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. For each of the 14
states, the variable ‘# elects.; 0–1 yr.’ computes the number of state legislative assembly
elections for which the elapsed time since the immediately preceding state legislative assembly
election is weakly less than 12 months. The other variables are constructed analogously.



may be correlated with shocks to fiscal policies. Table 3 reports on the time duration
between successive state legislative assembly elections. Table 3 is constructed as
follows. We proceeded one state at a time. For each state legislative assembly
election held between financial years 1974–75 and 1994–95, we calculated the number
of months that had elapsed between the election under scrutiny and the one directly
preceding it. Thereafter, we computed the total number of elections for which the
elapsed time is less than 12 months, between 12 months and 24 months, and so on.
Table 3 reveals two patterns of interest: (1) In aggregate, there are 47 scheduled
elections and 21 mid-term elections in our sample. (2) Out of the 21 mid-term
elections, 17 experienced an elapsed time less than 36 months. Yet, even this
clustering of mid-term elections near the beginning of a government’s term does not
necessarily preclude a strategic accounting of such elections.16
   Following Khemani (2004) and Shi and Svensson (2002a, b), we therefore estimate
equation 1 with Elecst equal to 1 only if a scheduled election takes place in state-year
(s, t). In other words, our empirical work differentiates scheduled election years from
all other years.17 This estimation strategy does not guarantee that o measures the
causal effect of scheduled elections on public policy. If governments that last for the
full term of five years are distinct from governments that dissolve rapidly, then o
could simply be reflecting policy differences between the different government
types.18 Such concerns about survivorship bias are partially allayed since we include
Fragment (a government characteristic variable) as a regressor in equation 1. In
addition, we add an extra regressor, called Match Dummy, to account for the extent
of political affiliation between governments at the centre and the state. Specifically,
Match Dummyst is a dummy variable that assumes the value 1(0) if the government
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 649

in state s is politically affiliated with the central government for more (less) than six
months during financial year t.
   We conclude this section with an important caveat. In equation 1, the following
four variables are included in the vector xst: the log of per capita domestic
product in state-year (s, t), the proportion of the domestic product in state-year
(s, t) that is derived from the primary sector, the literacy rate in state-year (s, t),
and the per capita newspaper circulation in state-year (s, t). These variables are
intended to control for state specific factors that affect both state governments’
fiscal policy choices and government characteristics. Yet, concerns about the
interpretation of g remain warranted. Specifically, g measures the causal effect of
government fragmentation only if there is no omitted and time-varying state
specific variable that drives both government fragmentation and public policy.
Since the above requirement is not guaranteed, our results should be viewed with
caution.19

Empirical Results for State Governments’ Revenues
In this subsection, we analyse the political determinants of state governments’ own
revenue. Recall that state governments’ own revenue is the sum of own tax revenue
and own non-tax revenue. Columns 1 and 3 of Table 4 present the regression results
for, respectively, state governments’ per capita own tax revenue and own non-tax
revenue.20 Note that in neither case is the coefficient of the election year dummy
statistically significant at conventional levels. Averaged over the state-years in our
sample, 88.9 per cent of state governments’ own tax revenue is obtained from taxes
levied on commodities. Given this, we next investigate whether political considera-
tions influence state governments’ commodity tax revenue. Column 2 of Table 4
presents the regression results. Here, the dummy variable for election year is


                       Table 4. Impact of political factors on revenue

                                                    Dependent variables
                                      (1)                  (2)                    (3)
                                    Own tax           Commodity tax           Own non-tax
                                    revenue              revenue                revenue

Share primary sector             70.32 (71.16)        70.37 (71.56)          70.72 (70.86)
State domestic product            0.54 (5.32)          0.56 (6.65)            1.23 (3.28)
Literacy rate                     0.01 (0.82)          0.00 (0.22)           70.04 (71.01)
Newspaper circulation            70.12 (70.20)         0.51 (0.90)            0.30 (0.22)
Match dummy                      70.01 (70.35)        70.00 (70.18)          70.09 (72.05)
Election year dummy              70.01 (70.68)        70.02b (71.78)         70.04 (71.44)
Government fragmentation         70.01 (70.29)        70.00 (70.35)          70.11b (71.84)
R-squared                            0.98                 0.99                   0.84
Number of observations               294                  294                    294

Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the
regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies. The t-ratios, which are
heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in
parentheses; b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test).
650 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

correctly signed and statistically significant at the 0.10 level; per capita commodity
tax revenue collected by state governments is approximately 2 per cent lower in
scheduled election years than in all other years.21 The electoral cycle in commodity
tax revenue is a robust feature of the Indian experience; Khemani (2004) detects
this cycle as well despite differences in model specification and a somewhat different
data set.
   How does one interpret the electoral cycle in commodity tax revenue? State
governments’ commodity tax revenue derives from three sources: state excise duties
on the production of alcoholic liquor, a producer tax on inter-state trade of goods,
and state sales tax. Khemani (2004: 139–40) finds that scheduled elections lower state
governments’ revenues from state excise tax and trade tax, but leave revenues from
the regressive sales tax unaffected. Since the first two tax categories have a narrow
base, the evidence is viewed as inconsistent with the broad-based tax reductions
predicted by Rogoff and Sibert (1988); instead, the targeted tax relief for a small set
of individuals is regarded as pointing towards ‘a story of political purchase of
campaign support’. Our evidence is more ambiguous. We ran separate regressions
for state governments’ per capita sales tax revenue and the sum of state governments’
per capita excise and trade tax revenue. In both regressions, the coefficient of the
election year dummy is negatively signed but not significant at conventional levels
(the t-statistics are 71.34 and 71.28, respectively).
   The government fragmentation variable in Table 4 merits scrutiny as well. In each
of the three regressions reported, the coefficient of Fragment is negative; statistical
significance at the 0.10 level obtains for state governments’ own non-tax revenue.
How large in magnitude is this effect? Contrast state-years of two sorts: one type
witnesses 12 months of fragmented coalition government, the other type experiences
12 months of single-party rule. Per capita own non-tax revenue is 11 per cent lower
in a state-year of the first kind than in a state-year of the second kind. Taken in total,
our evidence suggests that fragmented coalition governments raise less revenue than
single-party governments.
   In summary, political factors influence the revenue collected by state governments.
The commodity tax revenue is reduced when state legislative assembly elections are
impending. Furthermore, own non-tax revenue declines when the state government
is a fragmented coalition rather than a single party.

Empirical Results for State Governments’ Current Account Expenditures
This subsection explores the political determinants of state governments’ expenditure
on the current account. To this end, column 1 of Table 5 reports the regression
results for state governments’ per capita total current account expenditure. Contrary
to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988), there is no election year increase in
public spending. Indeed, the coefficient of the election year dummy is negative and
statistically significant at the 0.10 level; per capita total current account expenditure
by state governments is approximately 4 per cent lower in scheduled election years
than in all other years.
   How does one interpret the above result? Khemani (2004) also finds that
scheduled election years are associated with a decrease in state governments’ total
current account expenditure. This, she argues, represents an election-year shift in
Table 5. Impact of political factors on current account expenditure

                                                                                  Dependent variables
                                      (1)                   (2)                     (3)                 (4)                 (5)                (6)
                                    Current          Non-developmental          Grants to         Developmental           Social           Economic
                                  account exp.             exp.                local bodies            exp.            services exp.      services exp.

Share primary sector              0.17 (0.32)            0.92 (1.95)           1.92 (0.98)       70.08 (70.13)        70.59 (72.06)      70.29 (70.36)
State domestic product            0.33 (1.91)          70.00 (70.07)           1.74 (1.30)         0.35 (1.84)         0.62 (5.22)        0.37 (1.32)
Literacy rate                   70.01 (70.47)            0.01 (0.64)           0.17 (3.97)       70.02 (71.79)        70.01 (70.47)      70.02 (71.30)
Newspaper circulation             1.08 (1.08)            2.66 (1.62)           4.58 (1.04)         0.14 (0.88)        70.83 (71.56)      71.59 (71.65)
Match dummy                     70.02 (70.84)          70.03 (71.05)           0.11 (0.66)       70.02 (70.49)        70.07 (72.79)       0.00 (0.09)
Election year dummy             70.04b (71.66)         70.05b (71.72)        70.16a (72.37)      70.03 (71.26)        70.01 (70.27)      70.01 (70.39)
Government fragmentation        70.04b (71.84)           0.01 (0.16)         70.21 (70.63)       70.06b (71.88)       70.02 (71.00)      70.10 (71.53)
R-squared                            0.94                   0.93                  0.75                0.93                0.96               0.91
Number of observations               294                    294                   294                 294                 294                294

Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies.
The t-ratios, which are heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in parentheses; a ¼ significance at the
0.05 level (two-tailed test), and b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test).
                                                                                                                                                            Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 651
652 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

the composition of spending, away from public consumption and towards
physical investments. However, what drives the electoral cycle in total current
account expenditure? Columns 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6 of Table 5 report the regression
results for, respectively, state governments’ per capita non-developmental
expenditure on the current account, per capita grants to local bodies and
Panchayati Raj institutions, per capita developmental expenditure on the current
account, and the two components of developmental expenditure (that is, per
capita expenditure on social services and economic services). Our results show
that the electoral cycle in total current account expenditure is based on the
electoral cycles in non-developmental current account expenditure and grants to
local bodies. In other words, during a scheduled election year, the incumbent
government does not tinker with subsidies or wages to public sector employees
(these are items in the developmental expenditure category); rather, current
account expenditure is pruned at the expense of local bodies and by organising
the functioning of government at a lower cost.22
   The government fragmentation variable in Table 5 elicits two observations. First,
the coefficient of Fragment is negative and statistically significant at the 0.10 level for
per capita total current account expenditure. The magnitude of the coefficient
indicates that a state-year with 12 months of fragmented coalition government
experiences 4 per cent lower spending on the current account than a state-year with
12 months of single-party rule. Second, the effect of government fragmentation on
total current account expenditure works through the developmental component.
Column 4 shows that per capita developmental expenditure on the current account is
6 per cent lower in a state-year with 12 months of fragmented coalition government
than in a state-year with 12 months of single-party government.
   In summary, the current account expenditure of state governments is influenced by
political factors. In striking contrast to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988),
current account spending by state governments is lower in scheduled election years
than in all other years. There is also some evidence that government fragmentation
reduces total current account expenditure and developmental expenditure on the
current account.


Empirical Results for State Governments’ Capital Account Expenditures
As mentioned in Section III, state governments’ per capita total capital account
expenditure consists of several items (for example, the discharge of internal debt, the
repayment of loans to the central government, and the provision of loans for assorted
purposes) that are not readily manipulable. Accordingly, we emphasise here the
manipulable component of per capita total capital account expenditure – namely, per
capita capital account developmental expenditure. Column 1 of Table 6 reports the
regression results for state governments’ per capita capital account developmental
expenditure. Notice that in sharp contrast to the predictions of Rogoff (1990), the
coefficient of the election year dummy is positively signed and statistically significant at
the 0.10 level; per capita capital account developmental expenditure by state governments
is approximately 6 per cent higher in scheduled election years than in all other years.
   The above finding elicits two observations. First, Khemani (2004) detects an
electoral cycle in state governments’ per capita total capital account expenditure and
Table 6. Impact of political factors on capital account expenditure

                                                                                     Dependent variables
                                              (1)                              (2)                           (3)                             (4)
                                       Developmental exp.             Social services exp.           Economic services exp.             Education exp.

Share primary sector                      70.13 (70.12)                   0.64 (0.47)                     70.31 (1.20)                    0.64 (0.36)
State domestic product                      0.60 (1.21)                   0.66 (1.21)                      0.63 (0.60)                    2.23 (4.41)
Literacy rate                             70.02 (70.41)                  70.09 (71.68)                    70.01 (70.16)                 70.12 (72.35)
Newspaper circulation                       0.10 (0.08)                   1.72 (1.32)                     70.17 (70.11)                   7.77 (1.64)
Match dummy                                 0.11 (1.49)                  70.03 (70.41)                     0.12 (0.08)                  70.11 (70.72)
Election year dummy                        0.06b (1.69)                  70.02 (70.33)                     0.07 (1.61)                   0.15a (2.09)
Government fragmentation                  70.09 (70.81)                   0.01 (0.09)                     70.11 (70.73)                 70.27a (71.97)
R-squared                                      0.75                          0.73                             0.72                           0.74
Number of observations                         292                           293                              292                            292

Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies.
The t-ratios, which are heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in parentheses; a ¼ significance at the
0.05 level (two-tailed test), and b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test).
                                                                                                                                                            Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 653
654 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

argues that the flexibility of public investment spending allows the incumbent party
to provide election-year targeted benefits to a select group of pivotal voters. If this
conjecture is accurate, then an electoral cycle should perforce crop up in the
developmental component of total capital account expenditure. We have shown that
this is indeed the case. Second, in a panel study of 24 developing countries for the
1973–92 period, Schuknecht (2000) finds prominent electoral cycles in public
investment. Our study extends this finding to a different setting.
   Capital account developmental expenditure has two components: spending on
social services and spending on economic services. Accordingly, we ran separate
regressions with state governments’ per capita social services expenditure and
economic services expenditure as regressands. For economic services expenditure,
the coefficient of the election year dummy is positive with a p-value of 0.108. In
contrast, for social services expenditure, the coefficient of the election year dummy is
negative and far from achieving statistical significance. This suggests that the
electoral cycle in capital account developmental expenditure stems from the
behaviour of economic services expenditure.
   We also estimated separate regressions for three expenditure subcategories of
social services (education, medical and public health, and water supply and
sanitation) and two expenditure subcategories of economic services (agriculture and
allied activities, and industry and minerals). An electoral cycle crops up only in the
case of education expenditure (column 4 of Table 6). The size of the electoral cycle in
education expenditure is large: per capita capital account education expenditure by
state governments is approximately 15 per cent higher in scheduled election years
than in all other years.
   Does government cohesion affect spending on the capital account? Table 6 shows
that the coefficient of Fragment is negative and statistically significant for state
governments’ education expenditure. This effect is substantial in size. Contrast state-
years of two sorts: one type witnesses 12 months of fragmented coalition
government, the other type experiences 12 months of single-party rule. Per capita
capital account education expenditure is 27 per cent lower in a state-year of the first
kind than in a state-year of the latter variety.
   We summarise the findings of Table 6 as follows. First, in contrast to the
predictions of Rogoff (1990), there is no election-year decline in capital account
expenditure. Indeed, we observe election-year spurts in capital account develop-
mental expenditure and capital account education expenditure. Second, fragmented
coalitions spend less on education than single-party governments.

V. Robustness of the Results
In a seminal paper, Hibbs (1977) modelled political parties as partisan rather than
opportunistic. In other words, political parties were assumed to have intrinsic
preferences defined on a policy space. Once in office, these political parties simply
implemented their favoured policies.23 We, on the other hand, have allowed no role
for government ideology as a determinant of fiscal outcomes (see equation 1). This is
because most political parties in India are organised around linguistic, regional,
religious and caste affiliations (Weiner, 1989); they simply do not have natural
locations on a conventional left–right scale.24
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 655

   The above difficulties notwithstanding, we did experiment briefly with government
ideology. Specifically, we distinguished between a left-wing government (that is, a
government headed by a communist party) and all other government types.
Column 2 of Table 1 details the incidence of left-wing governments in the 14 major
states of India. Column 2 is constructed as follows. From the electoral history of
each state, we first computed the number of months during which a left-wing
government was in place. Subsequently, the aggregate months were converted into
equivalent years. Column 2 indicates that only two of the 14 states, Kerala and West
Bengal, have witnessed left-wing state governments.
   To study the impact of government ideology on fiscal policies, we constructed a
variable, LeftWingst, that measures the proportion of financial year t during which
the government of state s was a left-wing government. Inclusion of this variable as a
regressor yielded two conclusions. First, out of the 13 policy variables in Tables 4
through 6, LeftWingst is statistically significant at conventional levels in three
cases. Specifically, the coefficient of LeftWingst is 70.09 (t-statistic equals 71.95),
70.52 (t-statistic equals 72.58) and 70.80 (t-statistic equals 74.25) for,
respectively, non-developmental expenditure on the current account, social services
expenditure on the capital account, and education expenditure on the capital
account. Second, while the above findings are perhaps contrary to expectation, it
turns out that the results for Elecst and Fragmentst are entirely insensitive to the
inclusion of the ideology variable.
   In Section IV, the electoral cycle in expenditure variables was estimated by
considering scheduled election years only. The logical justification for this
approach has previously been given. What happens, however, when the regressions
are re-run without differentiating between scheduled and mid-term elections?25
Three observations are relevant here. First, the effects of government fragmenta-
tion are robust and do not depend on how the election year dummy is coded.
Second, for the current account expenditure categories, there is no hint of an
electoral cycle: the t-statistic corresponding to the election year dummy ranges
from a high of 0.99 (developmental expenditure) to a low of 0.01 (social services
expenditure). In other words, as in Section IV, our findings continue to violate the
predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988). Third, in Section IV, we had noted
election-year spurts in capital account developmental expenditure and education
expenditure, thereby contradicting the predictions of Rogoff (1990). Now, the
electoral cycle in capital account developmental expenditure disappears. Summing
up, insofar as expenditure variables are concerned, our evidence lends scant
support to Rogoff and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990) regardless of how the
election year dummy is coded.
   Finally, to allay concerns regarding the potential endogeneity of the (scheduled)
election year dummy, we estimated panel regressions instrumenting Elecst in
equation 1. Our instrument takes the value of 1 in the fifth year after every state
legislative assembly election (mid-term or scheduled), and is 0 otherwise.26,27 Our
findings can be summarised as follows. First, the effects of government fragmenta-
tion do not change when Elecst is instrumented. Second, consider the revenue results
in Table 4. The dummy for election year remains negatively signed for own tax
revenue and commodity tax revenue. However, statistical significance is no longer
obtained for commodity tax revenue. Third, consider the current account
656 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

expenditure results in Table 5. The election year dummy remains negatively signed
for all of the expenditure categories; statistical significance at the 0.05 level obtains
for total current account expenditure and current account non-developmental
expenditure. Fourth, consider the capital account expenditure results in Table 6.
Here, the election year dummy turns up positively signed for developmental
expenditure and education expenditure; however, in neither case is statistical
significance obtained. While our results undoubtedly deteriorate when Elecst is
instrumented, note that we continue to find no support for the predictions of Rogoff
and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990).

VI. Conclusion
Using state level data from India, we have studied whether the fiscal policies of state
governments are systematically affected by the proximity of scheduled state elections
and the extent of government cohesion. Our findings are twofold. First, state
governments raise less commodity tax revenue, spend less on the current account,
and incur larger capital account developmental expenditures in scheduled election
years than in all other years. Consistent with Khemani (2004), we detect no election-
year splurges in current account expenditure (as predicted by Rogoff and Sibert
(1988)) and no election-year contractions in capital account spending (as predicted
by Rogoff (1990)). Second, our evidence suggests that fragmented coalition
governments are smaller than their single-party counterparts. Relative to single-
party governments, fragmented coalitions have lower levels of own non-tax revenue
and current account expenditure.
   We note that many empirical questions remain to be explored. In this study,
government expenditure was analysed. Variations in expenditure do not necessarily
translate into corresponding movements in the provision of public goods. Hence,
there is a need to estimate the impact of political factors on the supply of various
public goods.
   Frey and Schneider (1978a, b) and Schultz (1995) have independently suggested an
amendment to the politico–economic models of government policy. Since policy
manipulation is presumed to be costly (for example, there may be a loss in
reputational capital), the extent of government manoeuvring depends on the value of
the marginal vote. Thus, safe elections should not witness policy distortions. Indian
state level data provide an ideal testing ground for this intriguing observation (see
notes for details).28
   Finally, we have presented but one half of the complete story. Specifically, while
governments’ fiscal policy choices were analysed, voter behaviour was unmodelled.
Does the electorate condition its vote on fiscal variables? Some evidence, employing
US and OECD data, already exists. Peltzman (1992) and Lowry et al. (1998) find
clear fiscal policy effects in the vote data for US presidential, senatorial and
gubernatorial elections. Besley and Case (1995b) show that US governors whose tax
hikes are less than in adjacent states have a higher probability of re-election. Alesina
et al. (1998) use OECD data to demonstrate that government fiscal restraint is not
systematically followed by a popularity decline. Comparable work with Indian data
is non-existent. In sum, the analysis of voter behaviour in India remains a fruitful
and unexplored research topic.
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 657

Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank seminar participants at Indira Gandhi Institute of
Development Research, Indian Statistical Institute (Delhi Centre), and University of
Sydney for helpful comments. Thanks are especially due to Lekha Chakraborty,
Pinaki Chakraborty, Saumen Chattopadhyay, Bhaskar Dutta, Shubhashis
Gangopadhyay, Jyotsna Jalan, Kirit Parikh and Arijit Sen for numerous helpful
discussions. Two anonymous referees suggested changes that greatly improved the
quality of the paper. Of course, the usual disclaimer applies. S. Dasgupta’s research
was supported by a grant from PPRU.

Notes
1. Khemani (2004) makes this point as well.
2. For example, Alesina and Sachs (1988) study ten US presidential elections; Andrikopoulos et al.
   (1998) study ten national elections in Greece; Chowdhury (1993) studies seven national elections in
   India; Heckelman and Berument (1998) study ten national elections in Japan; while Schultz (1995) and
   Serletis and Afxentiou (1998) study, respectively, nine and twenty national elections in Great Britain and
   Canada.
3. To alleviate the degrees-of-freedom problem, recent studies have examined cross-country evidence.
   Thus, Alesina and Roubini (1992), Alesina et al. (1993), De Haan and Sturm (1997), De Haan et al.
   (1999), Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001), and Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) consider panels of OECD
   countries.
4. Since this article repeatedly refers to Rogoff and Sibert (1988), it may be worthwhile to provide a brief
   sketch of the mechanism at work in that paper. The set-up of the Rogoff-Sibert model is as follows. An
   incumbent government, which may be intrinsically competent or incompetent, provides certain fixed
   services to citizens. To pay for these services, revenues must be raised through any combination of
   non-distortionary taxes (that voters observe immediately) and distortionary taxes (that voters observe
   with a lag). To provide the given services, competent governments naturally require less aggregate tax
   revenue than incompetent governments.
      Suppose the incumbent government is competent. In an election year, it convinces the electorate of
   its competency by lowering the level of visible non-distortionary tax revenues. Why does an
   incompetent government not mimic the behaviour of a competent government, thereby enhancing its
   electoral prospects as well? This is because mimicking forces the incompetent government to raise very
   large revenues through distortionary taxes; the consequent damage to voter welfare serves as an
   effective deterrent. The argument for electoral cycles in expenditures, omitted for brevity, is identical
   in spirit to that for the tax revenues case.
5. Several studies furnish empirical support for the signalling models. Besley and Case (1995a), for
   example, examine the behaviour of governors in the US; state taxes are shown to be lower when the
   incumbent governor stands for re-election.
6. De Haan and Sturm (1994) provide corroborating evidence: for member countries of the European
   Community, the growth of government debt is positively related to the frequency of government
   changes.
7. Empirical evidence for this theory is mixed. Alt and Lowry (1994) and Poterba (1994, 1996) examine
   state governments in the United States; adjustments to fiscal shocks are demonstrated to be slower
   when a state government is ‘divided’ (that is, the executive and legislative branches are controlled by
   different political parties). Roubini and Sachs (1989a, b) study the fiscal histories of several OECD
   countries; budget deficits are shown to be correlated with the extent of government fragmentation.
   However, De Haan and Sturm (1994, 1997), De Haan et al. (1999), Volkerink and De Haan (2001),
   and Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) argue persuasively that the Roubini-Sachs conclusions are
   fragile.
8. While Alesina and Tabellini (1990) and Alesina and Drazen (1993) explore the link between budget
   deficits and the fragmentation of political power, we alert the reader to a complementary strand of
   work (see, for example, Alesina et al. (1999), Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001), Perotti and Kontopoulos
658 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

      (2002)) that uses cross-country panels to show that budget institutions (for example, ex ante spending
      limits or borrowing constraints) robustly predict budget deficits and government spending.
 9.   Weingast et al. (1981) were the first to argue that in a system wherein geography forms the basis for
      political representation, there is an inherent tendency for programmes to exceed efficient scale. We
      adapt their insights to the problem at hand. To make matters concrete, consider a single-party
      government that represents exactly one half of the population of a nation. This government will
      implement a targeted programme should its benefit–cost ratio exceed 0.5. Consider a two-party
      government in which each coalition partner represents one quarter of the population of a nation. A
      coalition partner will now seek to implement a targeted programme should its benefit–cost ratio
      exceed 0.25. Hence, the fragmentation of a government leads to increased public spending (see also
      Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) for an extended discussion).
10.   Boix (1997) analyses the privatisation experiences of various countries and hints at a similar treatment
      of coalition governments. In contrast to single-party governments, coalition governments are posited
      to generate gridlock effects: ‘parties within the coalition are prone to veto each other’s projects
      whenever the resulting policies are believed to result in significant costs for their corresponding
      constituencies’.
11.   Dutta (1996a), for example, does not include state fixed effects in his model and uses state specific time
      trends instead of year dummies. The set of controls in Khemani (2004) (state net domestic product,
      share of agriculture in state net domestic product, and proportion of state population that is rural) is
      different from ours, the set of states considered differs as well (she includes Assam in her list of 14
      states while we include Haryana instead), and so on.
12.   Our model imposes period-by-period budget balance. Since unstable coalition governments spend less
      than stable governments, they raise less revenues as well. This revenue result will persist in a less
      restrictive model so long as expenditures and revenues move together (that is, are positively
      correlated). In our data set, the correlation coefficient between state governments’ own tax revenue
      and current account developmental expenditure is 0.86, while that between state governments’ own tax
      revenue and capital account developmental expenditure is 0.27.
13.   For certain years, state literacy rate data were not available from either the Census of India or the
      National Sample Survey rounds. For these years, we have interpolated the data using a simple growth
      rate formula.
14.   In the Indian context, it is not uncommon to find coalition governments with one pivotal party. For
      instance, the state of West Bengal has been ruled by a coalition called the Left Front since 1977. The
      Communist Party of India (Marxist), which is a member of this coalition, has won an absolute
      majority of legislative assembly seats in each of the state elections since 1977.
15.   The possibility of election endogeneity in a parliamentary system has been recognised by several
      researchers: Cargill and Hutchison (1991) explore this issue in the case of Japan, Chowdhury (1993)
      and Khemani (2004) focus on India, Heckelman and Berument (1998) study both Japan and the
      United Kingdom, while Reid (1998) looks at the Canadian situation.
16.   The authors thank an anonymous referee for emphasising this point.
17.   Section V discusses the sensitivity of the regression results to an alternative coding of Elecst.
18.   Khemani (2004) makes this point as well.
19.   The authors thank an anonymous referee for emphasising this point.
20.   The regressands are, in fact, the log of state governments’ per capita own tax revenue and per
      capita own non-tax revenue. For expositional ease, we henceforth suppress the qualifier ‘log of.’
21.   States’ own tax revenue consists of commodity tax revenue and revenue from taxes levied on
      agricultural income and property. There is an electoral cycle for commodity tax revenue. Why does
      this cycle disappear for the broader category of own tax revenue (compare columns 1 and 2 of Table
      4)? For many states, the direct tax component of own tax revenue has been left untouched for years.
      Thus, the Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission (p. 28) observes: ‘There are a few other taxes
      which the states can levy, but remain unexploited or under-exploited. Taxation of agricultural incomes
      is one of them and profession tax is another. The land revenue which has traditionally been the
      principal mode of taxing agriculture in the country has fallen into disuse’. At any rate, since one
      component of own tax revenue does not respond at all to electoral considerations, precise estimation
      of the electoral cycle for own tax revenue becomes difficult. Economists at the National Institute of
      Public Finance and Policy (a government-funded institute dealing with public finance issues) provided
      two reasons for why state governments show little interest in manipulating the direct tax component of
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 659

      own tax revenue: (1) the cost of administering such taxes is exceptionally high; and (2) states perceive
      their share of centrally-levied direct taxes to be the principal source of direct tax revenue.
22.   Non-developmental current account expenditure consists mainly of interest payments on accumulated
      debt and outlays on fiscal and administrative services. It is surprising that an electoral cycle crops up
      for non-developmental current account expenditure since its components appear a priori to be difficult
      to manipulate. To explore this issues further, we ran a regression where the regressand was the sum of
      per capita expenditure on fiscal services and per capita expenditure on administrative services. The
      coefficient of the election year dummy was negative (70.09) and statistically significant (t-statistic
      equal to 72.24).
23.   Alesina (1987) demonstrates that the partisan assumption does not rule out election-year effects on
      macroeconomic variables. Hibbs (1992) provides an in-depth review of the political economy literature
      with partisan political parties.
24.   The difficulty in assigning ideological locations to political parties is a common feature of developing
      country experiences. We are unaware of a single paper that uses data from developing countries and
      considers fiscal policy as partially determined by government ideology (see, for example, Schuknecht
      (2000), Block (2002), Shi and Svensson (2002a, b), and Khemani (2004)).
25.   Now, Elecst equals 1 if an election (scheduled or mid-term) takes place in state s during the second half
      of financial year t or during the first half of the next financial year.
26.   Khemani (2004) briefly experiments with this instrument as well.
27.   Following Davidson and MacKinnon (1993: 241–42), we also conducted a test to determine whether
      the (scheduled) election year dummy, Elecst, is endogenous in India. The exogeneity of Elecst could not
      be rejected.
28.   The electoral history of India divides into two distinct phases: a pre-1967 period during which state
      legislative assembly elections were dominated by the Congress party, and a post-1967 era that beheld
      lively inter-party competition for assembly seats. Electoral cycles in fiscal variables – shown, in this
      study, to be sometimes present in the post-1967 data – should disappear completely during the years of
      Congress party hegemony. More generally, a contrast of the two electoral phases can shed light on the
      benefits and costs of political competition.



References
Alesina, A. (1987) Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game, Quarterly Journal of
    Economics, 102, pp. 651–78.
Alesina, A., Cohen, G. and Roubini, N. (1993) Electoral business cycles in industrial democracies,
    European Journal of Political Economy, 9, pp. 1–23.
Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1993) Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review, 82,
    pp. 1170–88.
Alesina, A., Hausman, R., Hommes, R. and Stein, E. (1999) Budget institutions and fiscal performance in
    Latin America, Journal of Development Economics, 59, pp. 253–73.
Alesina, A., Perotti, R. and Tavares, J. (1998) The political economy of fiscal adjustments, Brookings
    Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 197–266.
Alesina, A. and Roubini, N. (1992) Political cycles in OECD economies, Review of Economic Studies, 59,
    pp. 663–88.
Alesina, A. and Sachs, J. (1988) Political parties and the business cycle in the United States, 1948–1984,
    Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20, pp. 63–82.
Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1990) A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt, Review of
    Economic Studies, 57, pp. 403–14.
Alt, J. and Lowry, R. (1994) Divided government and budget deficits: evidence from the states, American
    Political Science Review, 88, pp. 811–28.
Andrikopoulos, A., Prodromidis, K. and Serletis, A. (1998) Electoral and partisan cycle regularities: a
    cointegration test, Journal of Policy Modeling, 20, pp. 119–40.
Baron, D. (1991) Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control, American
    Journal of Political Science, 35, pp. 57–90.
Baron, D. (1998) Comparative dynamics of parliamentary governments, American Political Science
    Review, 92, pp. 593–609.
660 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta

Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2000) Land reform, poverty reduction, and growth: evidence from India,
    Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1l5, pp. 389–430.
Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2002) The political economy of government responsiveness: theory and
    evidence from India, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, pp. 1415–51.
Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995a) Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence
    from gubernatorial term limits, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, pp. 769–98.
Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995b) Incumbent behavior: vote-seeking, tax-setting, and yardstick competition,
    American Economic Review, 85, pp. 25–45.
Block, S. (2002) Political business cycles, democratization, and economic reform: the case of Africa,
    Journal of Development Economics, 67, pp. 205–28.
Boix, C. (1997) Privatizing the public business sector in the eighties: economic performance, partisan
    responses and divided governments, British Journal of Political Science, 27, pp. 473–96.
Butler, D., Lahiri, A. and Roy, P. (1996) India Decides, Elections 1952–1995 (New Delhi: Living Media
    India Limited).
Cargill, T. and Hutchison, M. (1991) Political business cycles with endogenous election timing: evidence
    from Japan, Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, pp. 733–39.
Chibber, P. (1995) Political parties, electoral competition, government expenditures and economic reform
    in India, Journal of Development Studies, 32, pp. 74–96.
Chowdhury, A. (1993) Political surfing over economic waves: parliamentary election timing in India,
    American Journal of Political Science, 37, pp. 1100–18.
Davidson, R. and MacKinnon, J. (1993) Estimation and Inference in Econometrics (New York: Oxford
    University Press).
De Haan, J. and Sturm, J.-E. (1994) Political and institutional determinants of fiscal policies in the
    European Community, Public Choice, 80, pp. 157–72.
De Haan, J. and Sturm, J.-E. (1997) Political and economic determinants of OECD budget deficits
    and government expenditures: a reinvestigation, European Journal of Political Economy, 13,
    pp. 739–50.
De Haan, J., Sturm, J.-E. and Beckhuis, G. (1999) The weak government thesis: some new evidence, Public
    Choice, 101, pp. 163–76.
Dutta, B. (1996a) Coalitional governments and policy distortions: the Indian experience (mimeo), Indian
    Statistical Institute, New Delhi.
Dutta, B. (1996b) Fragmented legislatures and electoral systems: the Indian experience (mimeo), Indian
    Statistical Institute, New Delhi.
Frey, B. and Schneider, F. (1978a) An empirical study of politico–economic interactions in the United
    States, Review of Economics and Statistics, 60, pp. 174–83.
Frey, B. and Schneider, F. (1978b) A politico-economic model of the United Kingdom, The Economic
    Journal, 88, pp. 243–53.
Government of India (2000) Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission (For 2000–2005) (New Delhi:
    Government of India Press).
Government of India, Ministry of Planning, Department of Statistics, various issues, National Accounts
    Statistics (New Delhi: Central Statistical Organisation).
Government of India, Ministry of Information and Broadcasting, various issues, Press in India, Annual
    Report of the Registrar of Newspapers for India (New Delhi: Government of India Press).
Grover, V. and Arora, R. (1998) Encyclopaedia of India and Her States (New Delhi: Deep and Deep
    Publications).
Harrinvirta, M. and Mattila, M. (2001) The hard business of balancing budgets: a study of public finances
    in seventeen OECD countries, British Journal of Political Science, 31, pp. 497–521.
Heckelman, J. and Berument, H. (1998) Political business cycles and endogenous elections, Southern
    Economic Journal, 64, pp. 987–1000.
Hibbs, D. (1977) Political parties and macroeconomic policy, American Political Science Review, 71,
    pp. 1467–87.
Hibbs, D. (1992) Partisan theory after fifteen years, European Journal of Political Economy, 8, pp. 361–73.
Karnik, A. (1990) Elections and government expenditures: the Indian evidence, Journal of Quantitative
    Economics, 6, pp. 203–12.
Khemani, S. (2004) Political cycles in a developing economy: effect of elections in the Indian states, Journal
    of Development Economics, 73, pp. 125–54.
Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 661

Lowry, R., Alt, J. and Ferree, K. (1998) Fiscal policy outcomes and electoral accountability in American
    states, American Political Science Review, 92, pp. 759–74.
Nordhaus, W. (1975) The political business cycle, Review of Economic Studies, 42, pp. 169–90.
Peltzman, S. (1992) Voters as fiscal conservatives, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, pp. 327–61.
Perotti, R. and Kontopoulos, Y. (2002) Fragmented fiscal policy, Journal of Public Economics, 86,
    pp. 191–222.
Poterba, J. (1994) State responses to fiscal crises: the effects of budgetary institutions and politics, Journal
    of Political Economy, 102, pp. 799–822.
Poterba, J. (1996) Budget institutions and fiscal policy in the US states, American Economic Review, 86,
    pp. 395–400.
Reid, B. (1998) Endogenous elections, electoral budget cycles and Canadian provincial governments,
    Public Choice, 97, pp. 35–48.
Reserve Bank of India, various issues, Reserve Bank of India Bulletin (Mumbai: Reserve Bank of India).
Rogoff, K. (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles, American Economic Review, 80, pp. 21–35.
Rogoff, K. and Sibert, A. (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles, Review of Economic Studies,
    55, pp. 1–16.
Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989a) Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in the industrial
    democracies, European Economic Review, 33, pp. 903–38.
Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989b) Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial democracies,
    Economic Policy, 8, pp. 100–32.
Schuknecht, L. (2000) Fiscal policy cycles and public expenditure in developing countries, Public Choice,
    102, pp. 115–30.
Schultz, K. (1995) The politics of the political business cycle, British Journal of Political Science, 25,
    pp. 79–99.
Sen, K. and Vaidya, R. (1996) Political budget cycles in India, Economic and Political Weekly, 30,
    pp. 2023–27.
Serletis, A. and Afxentiou, P. (1998) Electoral and partisan cycle regularities in Canada, Canadian Journal
    of Economics, 31, pp. 28–46.
Shi, M. and Svensson, J. (2002a) Political budget cycles in developed and developing countries (mimeo),
    Development Research Group, World Bank.
Shi, M. and Svensson, J. (2002b) Conditional political budget cycles (mimeo), Development Research
    Group, World Bank.
Volkerink, B. and De Haan, J. (2001) Fragmented government effects on fiscal policy: new evidence,
    Public Choice, 109, pp. 221–42.
Weiner, M. (1989) The Indian Paradox: Essays in Indian Politics (New Delhi: Sage Publications).
Weingast, B., Shepsle, K. and Johnson, C. (1981) The political economy of benefits and costs: a
    neoclassical approach to distributive politics, Journal of Political Economy, 89, pp. 642–64.
20855407

More Related Content

What's hot

Prelude to union budget fy19
Prelude to union budget fy19Prelude to union budget fy19
Prelude to union budget fy19Inves Trekk
 
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...Ministry of Finance (Singapore)
 
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide Worksheet
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide WorksheetBrazil-International Country Risk Guide Worksheet
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide WorksheetMichael Yatskievych
 
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paper
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paperPAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paper
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paperPhillip Mitchell
 
New microsoft office word document
New microsoft office word documentNew microsoft office word document
New microsoft office word documentDevi Behera
 
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?Shujaat Ahmed
 
How elections affect an economy.
How elections affect an economy.How elections affect an economy.
How elections affect an economy.Vikas Kumar
 
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...inventionjournals
 
Presentation irspm april 2010
Presentation irspm april 2010Presentation irspm april 2010
Presentation irspm april 2010Robert Smith
 
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman India
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman IndiaIndia Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman India
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman IndiaAklanta Kalita
 
To rational voters of brazil analysis of the economic proposals of the major...
To rational voters of brazil  analysis of the economic proposals of the major...To rational voters of brazil  analysis of the economic proposals of the major...
To rational voters of brazil analysis of the economic proposals of the major...Fernando Alcoforado
 
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)Alexander Decker
 
India Union budget challenges-f18
India Union budget  challenges-f18India Union budget  challenges-f18
India Union budget challenges-f18Kannan R
 
2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis
2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis
2011 Look before you LEP - PugalisLee Pugalis
 
The Relationship between Gender and Tax Payments
The Relationship between Gender and Tax PaymentsThe Relationship between Gender and Tax Payments
The Relationship between Gender and Tax PaymentsHendra Gunawan
 

What's hot (20)

Prelude to union budget fy19
Prelude to union budget fy19Prelude to union budget fy19
Prelude to union budget fy19
 
Yoyo
YoyoYoyo
Yoyo
 
ch4
ch4ch4
ch4
 
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...
Income Growth, Distribution and Mobility Trends in Singapore (Ministry of Fin...
 
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide Worksheet
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide WorksheetBrazil-International Country Risk Guide Worksheet
Brazil-International Country Risk Guide Worksheet
 
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paper
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paperPAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paper
PAD 632 Foundations of Public Policy Final paper
 
New microsoft office word document
New microsoft office word documentNew microsoft office word document
New microsoft office word document
 
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?
Will Budget 2017-18 promote local and foreign investment ?
 
How elections affect an economy.
How elections affect an economy.How elections affect an economy.
How elections affect an economy.
 
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...
Do Regional Finance Accountability And Budgetary Composition Enhance Regional...
 
The Role of Government Treasurer in State Universities in Tax Compliance
The Role of Government Treasurer in State Universities in Tax ComplianceThe Role of Government Treasurer in State Universities in Tax Compliance
The Role of Government Treasurer in State Universities in Tax Compliance
 
Presentation irspm april 2010
Presentation irspm april 2010Presentation irspm april 2010
Presentation irspm april 2010
 
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman India
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman IndiaIndia Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman India
India Economic Survey 2017 by Edelman India
 
To rational voters of brazil analysis of the economic proposals of the major...
To rational voters of brazil  analysis of the economic proposals of the major...To rational voters of brazil  analysis of the economic proposals of the major...
To rational voters of brazil analysis of the economic proposals of the major...
 
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)
Composition of ethiopian domestic revenues and tax buoyancies (1975 2013)
 
India Union budget challenges-f18
India Union budget  challenges-f18India Union budget  challenges-f18
India Union budget challenges-f18
 
Dr. omer farooq zain 6
Dr. omer farooq zain 6Dr. omer farooq zain 6
Dr. omer farooq zain 6
 
text-1
text-1text-1
text-1
 
2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis
2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis
2011 Look before you LEP - Pugalis
 
The Relationship between Gender and Tax Payments
The Relationship between Gender and Tax PaymentsThe Relationship between Gender and Tax Payments
The Relationship between Gender and Tax Payments
 

Similar to 20855407

Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docx
Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docxEconomics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docx
Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docxtidwellveronique
 
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdf
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdfCPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdf
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdfMianTahirWaseem
 
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...Triple A Research Journal
 
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docx
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docxwww.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docx
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docxericbrooks84875
 
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing CountriesThe Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing CountriesStockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...AJHSSR Journal
 
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
Good Governance
Good GovernanceGood Governance
Good Governanceijcnes
 
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....petrwawrosz1
 
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdfWajidKhanMP
 
Business Research Method (project of 30 article)
Business Research Method (project of 30 article) Business Research Method (project of 30 article)
Business Research Method (project of 30 article) Umair Ahmed
 
Keller Kelly accepted article
Keller Kelly accepted articleKeller Kelly accepted article
Keller Kelly accepted articleedejkeller
 
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...Alexander Decker
 

Similar to 20855407 (20)

Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docx
Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docxEconomics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docx
Economics ResourcesTaxes on Savings - GRUBER File.pdf.docx
 
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdf
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdfCPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdf
CPPB1 - Chiminya Adonia.pdf
 
ch2
ch2ch2
ch2
 
Corruption and fdi: a theorical analysis
Corruption and fdi: a theorical analysisCorruption and fdi: a theorical analysis
Corruption and fdi: a theorical analysis
 
Blessing corruption: institutional reforms
Blessing corruption: institutional reformsBlessing corruption: institutional reforms
Blessing corruption: institutional reforms
 
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...
Dimensions of Accountability and Transparency at Local Level Finance Manageme...
 
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docx
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docxwww.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docx
www.freetheworld.com • www.fraserinstitute.org • Fraser Instit.docx
 
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing CountriesThe Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries
The Costs of Political In‡fluence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries
 
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...
Budget Behavior and Corruption: An Manifestation of Political Economy in Indo...
 
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx
[Public choice] analyzes the mo-tives and activities of poli.docx
 
Essay On Politics And Controversy
Essay On Politics And ControversyEssay On Politics And Controversy
Essay On Politics And Controversy
 
Good Governance
Good GovernanceGood Governance
Good Governance
 
Political Influence in Transition Economies: Firm Level Evidence
Political Influence in Transition Economies: Firm Level EvidencePolitical Influence in Transition Economies: Firm Level Evidence
Political Influence in Transition Economies: Firm Level Evidence
 
ch3
ch3ch3
ch3
 
one nation one election.docx
one nation one election.docxone nation one election.docx
one nation one election.docx
 
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
Presentation - The rleationships between Public finance and Fiscal Policy 24....
 
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf
5 Insights on Future Challenges Facing Governments.pdf
 
Business Research Method (project of 30 article)
Business Research Method (project of 30 article) Business Research Method (project of 30 article)
Business Research Method (project of 30 article)
 
Keller Kelly accepted article
Keller Kelly accepted articleKeller Kelly accepted article
Keller Kelly accepted article
 
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
 

20855407

  • 1. 40651 26/4/06 20:15 FJDS_A_168181 (XML) Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 42, No. 4, 640–661, May 2006 The Political Determinants of Fiscal Policies in the States of India: An Empirical Investigation KAUSIK CHAUDHURI* & SUGATO DASGUPTA** *Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, India, **Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi, India Final version accepted April 2005 ABSTRACT Using data from the 14 major states of India, we investigate whether state governments’ fiscal policy choices are tempered by political considerations. Our principal findings are twofold. First, we show that certain fiscal policies experience electoral cycles: state governments raise less commodity tax revenue, spend less on the current account, and incur larger capital account developmental expenditures in election years than in all other years. Second, we show that coalition state governments raise less own non-tax revenues and spend less on the current account than state governments that are more cohesive in composition. In sum, the dispersion of political power affects government size. I. Introduction What determines the fiscal policies of a government? While the traditional public finance literature answers this question from alternative perspectives, it is always assumed that the government is a benevolent social planner, interested in maximising the representative citizen’s welfare. In contrast, the recent literature on political economy emphasises the institutional constraints under which policies are formulated. It argues that policy-makers are typically political parties or politicians. Naturally, the fiscal policies that are undertaken are tempered by political factors. This paper tests some of the political economy theories of government behaviour in the context of a developing country. Specifically, we examine the 14 major states of India over 21 financial years (1974–75 to 1994–95) and ask the following question: Does the proximity of a state legislative assembly election or the extent of government cohesion affect fiscal policies in the states of India? Correspondence Address: Kausik Chaudhuri, IGIDR, Gen. Vaidya Marg, Goregaon (East), Mumbai 400 065, India, Email: kausik@igidr.ac.in Sugato Dasgupta, Centre for Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi 110 067, India, Email: sugatodasgupta@rediffmail.com ISSN 0022-0388 Print/1743-9140 Online/06/040640-22 ª 2006 Taylor & Francis DOI: 10.1080/00220380600682116
  • 2. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 641 Our focus on India is interesting for two reasons. First, there is a vast literature that uses data from developed countries to test for the presence of electoral and other political considerations in government behaviour. This literature has scarcely been extended to developing countries (Schuknecht (2000), Block (2002), Shi and Svensson (2002a, b), and Khemani (2004) are recent and notable exceptions). There is an obvious reason for the lacuna – democratic institutions have only very recently taken root in developing countries. India, on the other hand, has been a democracy since its independence in 1947, and periodic elections to the national and state legislative assemblies have taken place since 1952. Therefore, the Indian experience sheds light on political economy models in the context of a developing country with long-standing democratic traditions.1 Second, it is commonly maintained that voters in India do not condition their votes on economic variables; rather, voting behaviour is exclusively based on caste allegiances. If this is true, political economy models, which invariably hinge on economic factors, are doomed to fail in the Indian context. Evidence to the contrary will indicate that voters in India, at least at the margin, are not blind devotees of primordial caste ties. Our use of state level data yields tangible benefits as well. Most studies that seek to establish electoral cycles in fiscal policies proceed one country at a time. Even when a relatively long country-specific history is observed, the number of election years remains small.2 We, on the other hand, obtain information on an aggregate of 68 state legislative assembly elections, thereby circumventing the degrees-of-freedom problem.3 In addition, the cross-section units in our data set (that is, the states of India) are not too disparate entities. Similar arguments also apply when the relationship between government cohesion and fiscal policies is examined. We now briefly outline the models that provide the theoretical rationale for our empirical investigation. Beginning with Nordhaus (1975), several theoretical papers have explored the interactions between election timing and governments’ fiscal policy choices. We test the predictions of two influential models in this genre. In Rogoff and Sibert (1988), an opportunistic incumbent government seeks to remain in power. In an election year, it lowers tax revenues and raises public expenditures to signal its competency to the electorate.4 In an interesting variant, Rogoff (1990) allows the government to incur expenditures of two sorts: public consumption and public investment. Since the effects of public investment are imperfectly observed by voters, election-year signalling shifts expenditures in favour of consumption and against investment.5 A separate theoretical strand of the political economy literature emphasises the connection between the dispersion of political power and budget deficits. Alesina and Tabellini (1990) consider a polity with two political parties that differ in their pre- ferences over the composition of public spending. The party in power, fearing an electoral defeat, issues public debt to constrain the spending capacity of its successor. Hence, the intertemporal sharing of political authority generates budget deficits.6 Alesina and Drazen (1993) explore the case of a coalition government that must raise taxes to balance its budget. Each coalition partner wishes to avoid its share of the tax burden; the ensuing war of attrition generates rising public debt. Hence, the contem- poraneous sharing of political authority facilitates the creation of budget deficits.7,8 Instead of focusing on the government budget deficit, we consider its two main components: expenditures incurred by the government and tax revenues collected.
  • 3. 642 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta At least two plausible theories have been proposed linking government characteristic (coalition or single-party) to expenditure and tax policies. First, in a coalition government, each coalition partner normally caters to a narrow constituency of core supporters. A coalition partner therefore has an incentive to demand targeted programmes that are inefficiently large relative to financing costs, which are customarily borne by the citizens in aggregate.9 In sum, coalition governments spend more than single-party governments. If government spending is roughly matched by tax revenue, coalition governments also raise more taxes than single-party governments. An alternative, albeit informal, argument (see, for example, Dutta (1996a) and Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001)) runs as follows: Coalition governments are frequently unstable; hence, the future consequences of current actions are severely discounted. This general neglect of the future coupled with a desire to buy more time in office from supporters leads to lower taxes and higher expenditures. We shall argue (see Section II for the theoretical framework) that the instability associated with coalition governments may actually dampen public spending! When indivisibilities force the benefits of public spending in a given year to be conferred on a subset of the coalition partners, the excluded parties in the government will be willing to pay up their share of the financing costs only if there are compensating future gains to be had. The possibility of a government breakdown reduces the expected value of future benefits and therefore leads to a bargaining impasse.10 Our study contributes to the small but growing literature that uses data from India to test political economy models of government behaviour. A branch of this literature explores the links between the timing of elections to the national legislative assembly and central governments’ economic policies in India. Chibber (1995) shows that central governments’ food subsidies are higher in election years than in non- election years. Karnik (1990) demonstrates that central government expenditure, aggregated over current and capital accounts, increases when an election is impending. Sen and Vaidya (1996) fail to uncover electoral cycles in central governments’ current account expenditure, capital account expenditure and current account receipt; however, deficit in the current account is shown to be higher in election years than in non-election years. In a slightly different vein, Chowdhury (1993) detects political surfing by central governments – that is, central governments strategically call for national elections when the economy’s output growth turns out to be high. Besley and Burgess (2000, 2002), on the other hand, focus on the behaviour of state governments in India. Besley and Burgess (2000) demonstrate that party ideology affects public policy. Specifically, the cumulative land reforms passed in a given state-year depends on the four-year lagged state legislative assembly seat shares of different political groups. Besley and Burgess (2002) show that state governments are more responsive to falls in food production and crop damage through floods where newspaper circulation is higher and electoral accountability is greater. Our work is directly linked to two papers that we discuss below. Dutta (1996a) analyses state level data from India to determine whether the tax and expenditure policies of coalition governments are markedly different from those of single-party governments. Coalition governments are shown to have higher levels of current account expenditure and lower levels of non-tax revenue; on the other hand, the levels of tax revenue and surplus (deficit) in the current account budget are unaffected by government fragmentation. Khemani (2004) examines the impact of
  • 4. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 643 state legislative assembly elections on the fiscal policies of state governments in India. Her findings are in striking contrast to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990). During election years, Khemani concludes that state govern- ments do not provide tax rate cuts on products that are widely consumed; rather, tax breaks are given to small groups of producers. Furthermore, the proximity of state elections leaves state governments’ total expenditure unaffected. Instead, the composition of spending changes during election years, away from public consumption and in favour of investment spending. All of this is viewed as evidence of election-year manipulation of fiscal policies to favour a narrow constituency of pivotal voters. Our study differs from these two papers in three ways. First, we examine a substantially larger set of policy variables; the ensuing analysis is therefore more detailed. Second, we provide a framework in which the policy effects of government characteristic and election timing are jointly studied. It turns out that both of the political variables impact on state governments’ fiscal policies. Third, the econometric model that we specify differs somewhat from that of Dutta (1996a) and Khemani (2004).11 Empirical findings that survive these differences can therefore be deemed to be reasonably robust. The principal findings of this paper are threefold. (1) State governments collect less commodity tax revenue in election years than in non-election years. (2) Spending on the current account, which has a substantial government consumption component, is lower in election years than in non-election years. In contrast, developmental spending on the capital account, which has a large physical investment component, experiences an election-year spurt. Results (1) and (2) are broadly consistent with the findings of Khemani (2004). (3) Coalition governments raise less own non-tax revenues and spend less on the current account than governments that are more cohesive in composition. In other words, the dispersion of political power affects governments’ fiscal policy choices. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section II presents a theoretical framework to demonstrate that the political instability associated with coalition governments can actually dampen public spending. Section III provides a description of the data set used in our analysis. Section IV presents both the econometric procedures that we employed and the empirical results obtained. Section V briefly considers the robustness of the empirical results. Section VI concludes. II. A Theoretical Framework In this section, we present a simple model to show that the political instability of coalition governments may actually dampen government spending. Consider, to this end, a two-period discrete-time model in which a government forms in the first period (that is, period 1). The government consists of two political parties, A and B, each political party representing exactly one quarter of the population of a nation. In period 1, the government has the option to undertake a new project with the following features: (1) the total financing cost of the project is c (each political party c in power has to pay up 4), and (2) aggregate benefits from the project are V, which are evenly distributed over both the time periods. In contrast to Baron (1991, 1998), project benefits within a given period are however not divisible. Specifically, should the project be undertaken, the period-1 benefit from the project is V to one of the two 2
  • 5. 644 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta political parties in power. Without loss of generality, let party A be this period-1 beneficiary. Once period 1 concludes, two possibilities arise. First, for exogenous reasons the government terminates with probability p; post-collapse, the project is scrapped and the continuation payoffs of the two erstwhile coalition members are normalised to 0. Second, if government collapse is averted, the project remains in place and party B receives period-2 benefits of V. 2 Suppose sanctioning of the project requires consent by both parties A and B. Then, for a fixed V, when is the project undertaken? Notice that if party B agrees to finance the project, its expected benefit, assuming no discounting, is V Â ð1 À pÞ while its cost 2 c is 4. Hence, the project goes through only if c is weakly less than the threshold value of 2V 6 (1 7 p). As government instability (that is, p) increases, the threshold value decreases. In other words, the overspending associated with pork barrel politics is muted when government instability is enhanced. The intuition behind the result is transparent: party B agrees to finance the project in period 1 only because current period cooperation leads to gains in the future. When government breakdown is imminent, the future is heavily discounted and cooperation becomes difficult to sustain.12 We close the discussion of our model with a final remark. Our model is written in terms of public investment. A slight reinterpretation of the model allows us to consider public consumption as well. Here, we can think of the political parties as representing distinct geographical regions, the government potentially engaged in hiring a fixed number of workers at an above-market wage, and certain indivisibilities in the hiring process. III. The Data The data set for our study consists of annual observations. It spans 21 financial years (1974–75 to 1994–95) and covers the 14 major states of India. India comprises 25 states and seven union territories. In the financial year 1994–95, the aforementioned 14 states accounted for 83.1 per cent of India’s land area, 93.2 per cent of her population, and 92.6 per cent of the net domestic product. The variables that we consider partition into three distinct categories: (1) Data on the fiscal (revenue and expenditure) policies of state governments were assembled from various volumes of the Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, published by the central bank of India. (2) State economic and demographic characteristics, which served as control variables in the empirical analysis, were compiled as follows. The National Accounts Statistics (published by the Central Statistical Organisation) provided information on state domestic product and the proportion of state domestic product derived from the primary sector; state literacy rate data were obtained from the Census of India and the National Sample Survey rounds (both published by the Government of India); while Press in India (published by the Ministry of Information and Broadcasting) recorded the per capita newspaper circulation data for each state-year.13 (3) The political variables were gleaned from two sources. First, the dates of all state legislative assembly elections were taken from the book India Decides. Thereafter, for each state-year, the ‘nature’ of the state government (details
  • 6. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 645 given below) was determined. This information was extracted from the publication Encyclopaedia of India and Her States. How do we measure the ‘nature’ of state governments? The theory sketched in Section II maintains that fiscal policy choices are systematically influenced by the extent of government cohesion. At first blush, this suggests a distinction between single-party and coalition governments. Such a distinction misses an important point: coalition governments per se do not affect fiscal policy choices; rather, what matters is the bargaining between strategically important coalition partners with disparate interests. Following Dutta (1996a, b), we posit that a coalition partner is strategically important only if it is a pivotal member of the coalition; that is, if its withdrawal from the government transforms a hitherto winning coalition (with majority support) into a nonviable one. A coalition government, in turn, is presumed to distort fiscal policy choices should it contain two or more pivotal parties. Henceforth, we shall refer to such a government as a fragmented coalition.14 For each of the 14 major states of India, column 1 of Table 1 shows the incidence of fragmented coalition governments. The construction of column 1 proceeds as follows. First, from the 21-year-long electoral history of each state (financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95), we calculated the number of months during which the government had multiple pivotal parties. Second, the aggregate months were converted into equivalent years. For example, the state of Bihar witnessed governments of the aforementioned type for a sum total of 22 months. This is the equivalent of 1.83 years. Column 1 reveals an interesting finding: most of the 14 chosen states have had some exposure to fragmented coalition governments. Table 2 shows the summary statistics of state governments’ fiscal policy variables analysed in this study. Notice that these variables are of three kinds: revenue Table 1. Incidence of fragmented coalition governments and left-wing governments in the states of India States Fragmented coalition govt. (in years) Left-wing govt. (in years) Andhra Pradesh 0.00 0.00 Bihar 1.83 0.00 Gujarat 5.08 0.00 Haryana 5.08 0.00 Karnataka 1.92 0.00 Kerala 16.25 5.83 Madhya Pradesh 0.00 0.00 Maharashtra 2.08 0.00 Orissa 0.17 0.00 Punjab 2.75 0.00 Rajasthan 0.67 0.00 Tamil Nadu 0.00 0.00 Uttar Pradesh 1.83 0.00 West Bengal 0.00 17.83 Note: The sample period covered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. ‘Fragmented coalition govt. (in years)’ shows the total number of years during which the government of the state was a fragmented coalition. ‘Left-wing govt. (in years)’ shows the total number of years during which a communist party headed the government of the state.
  • 7. 646 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta Table 2. Summary statistics of fiscal policy variables: (constant 1960–61 rupees per capita) Variables # Obs. Mean Std. dev. Revenue Own tax revenue 21 35.94 18.50 Commodity tax revenue 21 32.15 16.85 Own non-tax revenue 21 13.26 8.29 Current account expenditure Total current acct. expenditure 21 74.89 30.58 Non-developmental expenditure 21 23.14 11.36 Developmental expenditure 21 50.89 20.41 Grants to local bodies 21 0.85 0.80 Economic services expenditure 21 22.03 11.53 Social services expenditure 21 28.99 10.77 Capital account expenditure Developmental expenditure 21 10.83 5.26 Economic services expenditure 21 9.51 5.11 Social services expenditure 21 1.38 1.00 Education expenditure 21 0.19 0.20 Note: The sample period considered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. All of the variables are measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. ‘# Obs.’ is the number of state-specific observations for the variable. ‘Mean’ (‘Std. dev.’) computes the average (standard deviation) of the variable over the sample state-years. variables, and variables related to expenditure on the current and capital accounts. Below, we provide a brief overview of the fiscal structure of state governments. The total revenue of a state government has two components: total tax revenue and total non-tax revenue. Averaged over the sample state-years, total tax revenue accounts for 67.8 per cent of total revenue. A state government’s total tax revenue is, in turn, decomposed into two parts: its share in the tax revenue of the central government (31.5 per cent), and revenue raised through state taxes (68.5 per cent). State governments levy taxes on agricultural income, property, and commodities. Commodity taxes yield 88.9 per cent of states’ own tax revenue. A state government’s non-tax revenue derives from two sources: grants from the central government and own non-tax revenue (the three most important subcategories being interest receipts from loans issued by the state government, dividends and profits from public sector undertakings owned by the state government, and revenues from state lotteries). Our study pays special attention to the own tax revenue and own non-tax revenue components of total revenue. Expenditures incurred by state governments are on either the current account (71.1 per cent) or the capital account (28.9 per cent). Current account expenditure is of three types: developmental spending (68.3 per cent), non-developmental spending (30.6 per cent), and grants to local bodies and Panchayati Raj institutions (1.2 per cent). Developmental expenditure, which is largely devoted to the maintenance of existing assets, involves spending on social services (56.7 per cent) and economic services (43.3 per cent). Non-developmental expenditure principally comprises interest payments on accumulated debt and outlays on fiscal and administrative services. State governments’ capital account expenditure mainly entails the discharge of internal debt, the repayment of loans to the central government, and the provision of
  • 8. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 647 loans for assorted purposes. However, 39.8 per cent of capital account expenditure is devoted to the creation of physical assets. This developmental component, in turn, involves spending on social services (12.2 per cent) and economic services (87.8 per cent). Our study focusses on capital account developmental expenditure. IV. Empirical Results Do political considerations (namely, the proximity of a state election and the extent of government cohesion) affect the fiscal policy choices of state governments? To answer this question, we consider estimating a fixed-effects error-components model of the form: Pst ¼ as þ dt þ bxst þ gFragmentst þ oElecst þ est ðs ¼ 1; . . . ; S; t ¼ 1; . . . ; TÞ ð1Þ where Pst denotes a particular fiscal policy variable (for example, the log of per capita own tax revenue) in state s during financial year t, as is a state fixed effect, dt is a year effect, xst is a (k61) vector of explanatory variables that capture economic and demographic characteristics of state s in financial year t, Fragmentst measures the proportion of financial year t during which the government of state s had more than one pivotal party, Elecst (henceforth, referred to as the election year dummy) is a zero-one variable that equals one if financial year t is an election year in state s, and est is the error term, presumed to be orthogonal to all of the regressors. The political theories that we test deal exclusively with the significance, sign and magnitude of the estimates of g and o. The treatment of elections in equation 1 merits scrutiny. First, some rule must specify when financial year t is deemed to be an election year in state s. Following Alesina et al. (1993) and Reid (1998), financial year t is called an election year in state s if a state legislative assembly election is held in the second half of financial year t or in the first half of the next financial year. A more serious problem pertains to the potential endogeneity of elections.15 The constitution of India mandates that a state legislative assembly have a normal term of five years from the date appointed for its first sitting. Accordingly, we classify a state legislative assembly election as scheduled if it is held when the current assembly is at least four years of age. In our data set, the 14 states have experienced an aggregate of 68 state legislative assembly elections; 47 of these elections are classified as scheduled. What accounts for the remaining 21 mid-term elections? Three circumstances lead to mid-term elections. First, a state government may lose the confidence of a majority in the state legislature. The governor of the state, upon verifying that no claimant can form an alternative government commanding majority support, conventionally calls for fresh elections. Second, the president of India, upon receipt of a report by the governor of a state or otherwise, may be satisfied that constitutional breakdown has occurred at the state level. This leads to the temporary imposition of President’s Rule and, eventually, fresh elections. Third, a state government may voluntarily petition the governor of the state to hold mid-term elections. The third reason for mid-term elections is especially problematic. If the incumbent state government strategically holds elections for electoral gains, then election timing
  • 9. 648 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta Table 3. Time duration between successive state legislative assembly elections # elects.; # elects.; # elects.; # elects.; # elects.; States 0–1 yr. 1–2 yrs. 2–3 yrs. 3–4 yrs. !4 yrs. Andhra Pradesh 0 0 1 0 4 Bihar 0 0 1 0 4 Gujarat 0 0 0 1 4 Haryana 0 0 0 1 3 Karnataka 0 0 1 0 4 Kerala 0 0 2 0 3 Madhya Pradesh 0 0 2 0 3 Maharashtra 0 0 1 0 4 Orissa 0 0 1 1 3 Punjab 0 0 1 0 3 Rajasthan 0 0 2 0 3 Tamil Nadu 0 0 2 0 3 Uttar Pradesh 0 1 2 1 2 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 4 Column Totals 0 1 16 4 47 Note: The sample period considered is financial year 1974–75 to 1994–95. For each of the 14 states, the variable ‘# elects.; 0–1 yr.’ computes the number of state legislative assembly elections for which the elapsed time since the immediately preceding state legislative assembly election is weakly less than 12 months. The other variables are constructed analogously. may be correlated with shocks to fiscal policies. Table 3 reports on the time duration between successive state legislative assembly elections. Table 3 is constructed as follows. We proceeded one state at a time. For each state legislative assembly election held between financial years 1974–75 and 1994–95, we calculated the number of months that had elapsed between the election under scrutiny and the one directly preceding it. Thereafter, we computed the total number of elections for which the elapsed time is less than 12 months, between 12 months and 24 months, and so on. Table 3 reveals two patterns of interest: (1) In aggregate, there are 47 scheduled elections and 21 mid-term elections in our sample. (2) Out of the 21 mid-term elections, 17 experienced an elapsed time less than 36 months. Yet, even this clustering of mid-term elections near the beginning of a government’s term does not necessarily preclude a strategic accounting of such elections.16 Following Khemani (2004) and Shi and Svensson (2002a, b), we therefore estimate equation 1 with Elecst equal to 1 only if a scheduled election takes place in state-year (s, t). In other words, our empirical work differentiates scheduled election years from all other years.17 This estimation strategy does not guarantee that o measures the causal effect of scheduled elections on public policy. If governments that last for the full term of five years are distinct from governments that dissolve rapidly, then o could simply be reflecting policy differences between the different government types.18 Such concerns about survivorship bias are partially allayed since we include Fragment (a government characteristic variable) as a regressor in equation 1. In addition, we add an extra regressor, called Match Dummy, to account for the extent of political affiliation between governments at the centre and the state. Specifically, Match Dummyst is a dummy variable that assumes the value 1(0) if the government
  • 10. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 649 in state s is politically affiliated with the central government for more (less) than six months during financial year t. We conclude this section with an important caveat. In equation 1, the following four variables are included in the vector xst: the log of per capita domestic product in state-year (s, t), the proportion of the domestic product in state-year (s, t) that is derived from the primary sector, the literacy rate in state-year (s, t), and the per capita newspaper circulation in state-year (s, t). These variables are intended to control for state specific factors that affect both state governments’ fiscal policy choices and government characteristics. Yet, concerns about the interpretation of g remain warranted. Specifically, g measures the causal effect of government fragmentation only if there is no omitted and time-varying state specific variable that drives both government fragmentation and public policy. Since the above requirement is not guaranteed, our results should be viewed with caution.19 Empirical Results for State Governments’ Revenues In this subsection, we analyse the political determinants of state governments’ own revenue. Recall that state governments’ own revenue is the sum of own tax revenue and own non-tax revenue. Columns 1 and 3 of Table 4 present the regression results for, respectively, state governments’ per capita own tax revenue and own non-tax revenue.20 Note that in neither case is the coefficient of the election year dummy statistically significant at conventional levels. Averaged over the state-years in our sample, 88.9 per cent of state governments’ own tax revenue is obtained from taxes levied on commodities. Given this, we next investigate whether political considera- tions influence state governments’ commodity tax revenue. Column 2 of Table 4 presents the regression results. Here, the dummy variable for election year is Table 4. Impact of political factors on revenue Dependent variables (1) (2) (3) Own tax Commodity tax Own non-tax revenue revenue revenue Share primary sector 70.32 (71.16) 70.37 (71.56) 70.72 (70.86) State domestic product 0.54 (5.32) 0.56 (6.65) 1.23 (3.28) Literacy rate 0.01 (0.82) 0.00 (0.22) 70.04 (71.01) Newspaper circulation 70.12 (70.20) 0.51 (0.90) 0.30 (0.22) Match dummy 70.01 (70.35) 70.00 (70.18) 70.09 (72.05) Election year dummy 70.01 (70.68) 70.02b (71.78) 70.04 (71.44) Government fragmentation 70.01 (70.29) 70.00 (70.35) 70.11b (71.84) R-squared 0.98 0.99 0.84 Number of observations 294 294 294 Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies. The t-ratios, which are heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in parentheses; b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test).
  • 11. 650 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta correctly signed and statistically significant at the 0.10 level; per capita commodity tax revenue collected by state governments is approximately 2 per cent lower in scheduled election years than in all other years.21 The electoral cycle in commodity tax revenue is a robust feature of the Indian experience; Khemani (2004) detects this cycle as well despite differences in model specification and a somewhat different data set. How does one interpret the electoral cycle in commodity tax revenue? State governments’ commodity tax revenue derives from three sources: state excise duties on the production of alcoholic liquor, a producer tax on inter-state trade of goods, and state sales tax. Khemani (2004: 139–40) finds that scheduled elections lower state governments’ revenues from state excise tax and trade tax, but leave revenues from the regressive sales tax unaffected. Since the first two tax categories have a narrow base, the evidence is viewed as inconsistent with the broad-based tax reductions predicted by Rogoff and Sibert (1988); instead, the targeted tax relief for a small set of individuals is regarded as pointing towards ‘a story of political purchase of campaign support’. Our evidence is more ambiguous. We ran separate regressions for state governments’ per capita sales tax revenue and the sum of state governments’ per capita excise and trade tax revenue. In both regressions, the coefficient of the election year dummy is negatively signed but not significant at conventional levels (the t-statistics are 71.34 and 71.28, respectively). The government fragmentation variable in Table 4 merits scrutiny as well. In each of the three regressions reported, the coefficient of Fragment is negative; statistical significance at the 0.10 level obtains for state governments’ own non-tax revenue. How large in magnitude is this effect? Contrast state-years of two sorts: one type witnesses 12 months of fragmented coalition government, the other type experiences 12 months of single-party rule. Per capita own non-tax revenue is 11 per cent lower in a state-year of the first kind than in a state-year of the second kind. Taken in total, our evidence suggests that fragmented coalition governments raise less revenue than single-party governments. In summary, political factors influence the revenue collected by state governments. The commodity tax revenue is reduced when state legislative assembly elections are impending. Furthermore, own non-tax revenue declines when the state government is a fragmented coalition rather than a single party. Empirical Results for State Governments’ Current Account Expenditures This subsection explores the political determinants of state governments’ expenditure on the current account. To this end, column 1 of Table 5 reports the regression results for state governments’ per capita total current account expenditure. Contrary to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988), there is no election year increase in public spending. Indeed, the coefficient of the election year dummy is negative and statistically significant at the 0.10 level; per capita total current account expenditure by state governments is approximately 4 per cent lower in scheduled election years than in all other years. How does one interpret the above result? Khemani (2004) also finds that scheduled election years are associated with a decrease in state governments’ total current account expenditure. This, she argues, represents an election-year shift in
  • 12. Table 5. Impact of political factors on current account expenditure Dependent variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Current Non-developmental Grants to Developmental Social Economic account exp. exp. local bodies exp. services exp. services exp. Share primary sector 0.17 (0.32) 0.92 (1.95) 1.92 (0.98) 70.08 (70.13) 70.59 (72.06) 70.29 (70.36) State domestic product 0.33 (1.91) 70.00 (70.07) 1.74 (1.30) 0.35 (1.84) 0.62 (5.22) 0.37 (1.32) Literacy rate 70.01 (70.47) 0.01 (0.64) 0.17 (3.97) 70.02 (71.79) 70.01 (70.47) 70.02 (71.30) Newspaper circulation 1.08 (1.08) 2.66 (1.62) 4.58 (1.04) 0.14 (0.88) 70.83 (71.56) 71.59 (71.65) Match dummy 70.02 (70.84) 70.03 (71.05) 0.11 (0.66) 70.02 (70.49) 70.07 (72.79) 0.00 (0.09) Election year dummy 70.04b (71.66) 70.05b (71.72) 70.16a (72.37) 70.03 (71.26) 70.01 (70.27) 70.01 (70.39) Government fragmentation 70.04b (71.84) 0.01 (0.16) 70.21 (70.63) 70.06b (71.88) 70.02 (71.00) 70.10 (71.53) R-squared 0.94 0.93 0.75 0.93 0.96 0.91 Number of observations 294 294 294 294 294 294 Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies. The t-ratios, which are heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in parentheses; a ¼ significance at the 0.05 level (two-tailed test), and b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test). Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 651
  • 13. 652 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta the composition of spending, away from public consumption and towards physical investments. However, what drives the electoral cycle in total current account expenditure? Columns 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6 of Table 5 report the regression results for, respectively, state governments’ per capita non-developmental expenditure on the current account, per capita grants to local bodies and Panchayati Raj institutions, per capita developmental expenditure on the current account, and the two components of developmental expenditure (that is, per capita expenditure on social services and economic services). Our results show that the electoral cycle in total current account expenditure is based on the electoral cycles in non-developmental current account expenditure and grants to local bodies. In other words, during a scheduled election year, the incumbent government does not tinker with subsidies or wages to public sector employees (these are items in the developmental expenditure category); rather, current account expenditure is pruned at the expense of local bodies and by organising the functioning of government at a lower cost.22 The government fragmentation variable in Table 5 elicits two observations. First, the coefficient of Fragment is negative and statistically significant at the 0.10 level for per capita total current account expenditure. The magnitude of the coefficient indicates that a state-year with 12 months of fragmented coalition government experiences 4 per cent lower spending on the current account than a state-year with 12 months of single-party rule. Second, the effect of government fragmentation on total current account expenditure works through the developmental component. Column 4 shows that per capita developmental expenditure on the current account is 6 per cent lower in a state-year with 12 months of fragmented coalition government than in a state-year with 12 months of single-party government. In summary, the current account expenditure of state governments is influenced by political factors. In striking contrast to the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988), current account spending by state governments is lower in scheduled election years than in all other years. There is also some evidence that government fragmentation reduces total current account expenditure and developmental expenditure on the current account. Empirical Results for State Governments’ Capital Account Expenditures As mentioned in Section III, state governments’ per capita total capital account expenditure consists of several items (for example, the discharge of internal debt, the repayment of loans to the central government, and the provision of loans for assorted purposes) that are not readily manipulable. Accordingly, we emphasise here the manipulable component of per capita total capital account expenditure – namely, per capita capital account developmental expenditure. Column 1 of Table 6 reports the regression results for state governments’ per capita capital account developmental expenditure. Notice that in sharp contrast to the predictions of Rogoff (1990), the coefficient of the election year dummy is positively signed and statistically significant at the 0.10 level; per capita capital account developmental expenditure by state governments is approximately 6 per cent higher in scheduled election years than in all other years. The above finding elicits two observations. First, Khemani (2004) detects an electoral cycle in state governments’ per capita total capital account expenditure and
  • 14. Table 6. Impact of political factors on capital account expenditure Dependent variables (1) (2) (3) (4) Developmental exp. Social services exp. Economic services exp. Education exp. Share primary sector 70.13 (70.12) 0.64 (0.47) 70.31 (1.20) 0.64 (0.36) State domestic product 0.60 (1.21) 0.66 (1.21) 0.63 (0.60) 2.23 (4.41) Literacy rate 70.02 (70.41) 70.09 (71.68) 70.01 (70.16) 70.12 (72.35) Newspaper circulation 0.10 (0.08) 1.72 (1.32) 70.17 (70.11) 7.77 (1.64) Match dummy 0.11 (1.49) 70.03 (70.41) 0.12 (0.08) 70.11 (70.72) Election year dummy 0.06b (1.69) 70.02 (70.33) 0.07 (1.61) 0.15a (2.09) Government fragmentation 70.09 (70.81) 0.01 (0.09) 70.11 (70.73) 70.27a (71.97) R-squared 0.75 0.73 0.72 0.74 Number of observations 292 293 292 292 Note: Each of the dependent variables is measured per capita in 1960–61 rupees. All of the regressions include state fixed effects and year dummies. The t-ratios, which are heteroskedasticity-robust and corrected for within-state clustering of the error term, are in parentheses; a ¼ significance at the 0.05 level (two-tailed test), and b ¼ significance at the 0.10 level (two-tailed test). Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 653
  • 15. 654 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta argues that the flexibility of public investment spending allows the incumbent party to provide election-year targeted benefits to a select group of pivotal voters. If this conjecture is accurate, then an electoral cycle should perforce crop up in the developmental component of total capital account expenditure. We have shown that this is indeed the case. Second, in a panel study of 24 developing countries for the 1973–92 period, Schuknecht (2000) finds prominent electoral cycles in public investment. Our study extends this finding to a different setting. Capital account developmental expenditure has two components: spending on social services and spending on economic services. Accordingly, we ran separate regressions with state governments’ per capita social services expenditure and economic services expenditure as regressands. For economic services expenditure, the coefficient of the election year dummy is positive with a p-value of 0.108. In contrast, for social services expenditure, the coefficient of the election year dummy is negative and far from achieving statistical significance. This suggests that the electoral cycle in capital account developmental expenditure stems from the behaviour of economic services expenditure. We also estimated separate regressions for three expenditure subcategories of social services (education, medical and public health, and water supply and sanitation) and two expenditure subcategories of economic services (agriculture and allied activities, and industry and minerals). An electoral cycle crops up only in the case of education expenditure (column 4 of Table 6). The size of the electoral cycle in education expenditure is large: per capita capital account education expenditure by state governments is approximately 15 per cent higher in scheduled election years than in all other years. Does government cohesion affect spending on the capital account? Table 6 shows that the coefficient of Fragment is negative and statistically significant for state governments’ education expenditure. This effect is substantial in size. Contrast state- years of two sorts: one type witnesses 12 months of fragmented coalition government, the other type experiences 12 months of single-party rule. Per capita capital account education expenditure is 27 per cent lower in a state-year of the first kind than in a state-year of the latter variety. We summarise the findings of Table 6 as follows. First, in contrast to the predictions of Rogoff (1990), there is no election-year decline in capital account expenditure. Indeed, we observe election-year spurts in capital account develop- mental expenditure and capital account education expenditure. Second, fragmented coalitions spend less on education than single-party governments. V. Robustness of the Results In a seminal paper, Hibbs (1977) modelled political parties as partisan rather than opportunistic. In other words, political parties were assumed to have intrinsic preferences defined on a policy space. Once in office, these political parties simply implemented their favoured policies.23 We, on the other hand, have allowed no role for government ideology as a determinant of fiscal outcomes (see equation 1). This is because most political parties in India are organised around linguistic, regional, religious and caste affiliations (Weiner, 1989); they simply do not have natural locations on a conventional left–right scale.24
  • 16. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 655 The above difficulties notwithstanding, we did experiment briefly with government ideology. Specifically, we distinguished between a left-wing government (that is, a government headed by a communist party) and all other government types. Column 2 of Table 1 details the incidence of left-wing governments in the 14 major states of India. Column 2 is constructed as follows. From the electoral history of each state, we first computed the number of months during which a left-wing government was in place. Subsequently, the aggregate months were converted into equivalent years. Column 2 indicates that only two of the 14 states, Kerala and West Bengal, have witnessed left-wing state governments. To study the impact of government ideology on fiscal policies, we constructed a variable, LeftWingst, that measures the proportion of financial year t during which the government of state s was a left-wing government. Inclusion of this variable as a regressor yielded two conclusions. First, out of the 13 policy variables in Tables 4 through 6, LeftWingst is statistically significant at conventional levels in three cases. Specifically, the coefficient of LeftWingst is 70.09 (t-statistic equals 71.95), 70.52 (t-statistic equals 72.58) and 70.80 (t-statistic equals 74.25) for, respectively, non-developmental expenditure on the current account, social services expenditure on the capital account, and education expenditure on the capital account. Second, while the above findings are perhaps contrary to expectation, it turns out that the results for Elecst and Fragmentst are entirely insensitive to the inclusion of the ideology variable. In Section IV, the electoral cycle in expenditure variables was estimated by considering scheduled election years only. The logical justification for this approach has previously been given. What happens, however, when the regressions are re-run without differentiating between scheduled and mid-term elections?25 Three observations are relevant here. First, the effects of government fragmenta- tion are robust and do not depend on how the election year dummy is coded. Second, for the current account expenditure categories, there is no hint of an electoral cycle: the t-statistic corresponding to the election year dummy ranges from a high of 0.99 (developmental expenditure) to a low of 0.01 (social services expenditure). In other words, as in Section IV, our findings continue to violate the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988). Third, in Section IV, we had noted election-year spurts in capital account developmental expenditure and education expenditure, thereby contradicting the predictions of Rogoff (1990). Now, the electoral cycle in capital account developmental expenditure disappears. Summing up, insofar as expenditure variables are concerned, our evidence lends scant support to Rogoff and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990) regardless of how the election year dummy is coded. Finally, to allay concerns regarding the potential endogeneity of the (scheduled) election year dummy, we estimated panel regressions instrumenting Elecst in equation 1. Our instrument takes the value of 1 in the fifth year after every state legislative assembly election (mid-term or scheduled), and is 0 otherwise.26,27 Our findings can be summarised as follows. First, the effects of government fragmenta- tion do not change when Elecst is instrumented. Second, consider the revenue results in Table 4. The dummy for election year remains negatively signed for own tax revenue and commodity tax revenue. However, statistical significance is no longer obtained for commodity tax revenue. Third, consider the current account
  • 17. 656 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta expenditure results in Table 5. The election year dummy remains negatively signed for all of the expenditure categories; statistical significance at the 0.05 level obtains for total current account expenditure and current account non-developmental expenditure. Fourth, consider the capital account expenditure results in Table 6. Here, the election year dummy turns up positively signed for developmental expenditure and education expenditure; however, in neither case is statistical significance obtained. While our results undoubtedly deteriorate when Elecst is instrumented, note that we continue to find no support for the predictions of Rogoff and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990). VI. Conclusion Using state level data from India, we have studied whether the fiscal policies of state governments are systematically affected by the proximity of scheduled state elections and the extent of government cohesion. Our findings are twofold. First, state governments raise less commodity tax revenue, spend less on the current account, and incur larger capital account developmental expenditures in scheduled election years than in all other years. Consistent with Khemani (2004), we detect no election- year splurges in current account expenditure (as predicted by Rogoff and Sibert (1988)) and no election-year contractions in capital account spending (as predicted by Rogoff (1990)). Second, our evidence suggests that fragmented coalition governments are smaller than their single-party counterparts. Relative to single- party governments, fragmented coalitions have lower levels of own non-tax revenue and current account expenditure. We note that many empirical questions remain to be explored. In this study, government expenditure was analysed. Variations in expenditure do not necessarily translate into corresponding movements in the provision of public goods. Hence, there is a need to estimate the impact of political factors on the supply of various public goods. Frey and Schneider (1978a, b) and Schultz (1995) have independently suggested an amendment to the politico–economic models of government policy. Since policy manipulation is presumed to be costly (for example, there may be a loss in reputational capital), the extent of government manoeuvring depends on the value of the marginal vote. Thus, safe elections should not witness policy distortions. Indian state level data provide an ideal testing ground for this intriguing observation (see notes for details).28 Finally, we have presented but one half of the complete story. Specifically, while governments’ fiscal policy choices were analysed, voter behaviour was unmodelled. Does the electorate condition its vote on fiscal variables? Some evidence, employing US and OECD data, already exists. Peltzman (1992) and Lowry et al. (1998) find clear fiscal policy effects in the vote data for US presidential, senatorial and gubernatorial elections. Besley and Case (1995b) show that US governors whose tax hikes are less than in adjacent states have a higher probability of re-election. Alesina et al. (1998) use OECD data to demonstrate that government fiscal restraint is not systematically followed by a popularity decline. Comparable work with Indian data is non-existent. In sum, the analysis of voter behaviour in India remains a fruitful and unexplored research topic.
  • 18. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 657 Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank seminar participants at Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Indian Statistical Institute (Delhi Centre), and University of Sydney for helpful comments. Thanks are especially due to Lekha Chakraborty, Pinaki Chakraborty, Saumen Chattopadhyay, Bhaskar Dutta, Shubhashis Gangopadhyay, Jyotsna Jalan, Kirit Parikh and Arijit Sen for numerous helpful discussions. Two anonymous referees suggested changes that greatly improved the quality of the paper. Of course, the usual disclaimer applies. S. Dasgupta’s research was supported by a grant from PPRU. Notes 1. Khemani (2004) makes this point as well. 2. For example, Alesina and Sachs (1988) study ten US presidential elections; Andrikopoulos et al. (1998) study ten national elections in Greece; Chowdhury (1993) studies seven national elections in India; Heckelman and Berument (1998) study ten national elections in Japan; while Schultz (1995) and Serletis and Afxentiou (1998) study, respectively, nine and twenty national elections in Great Britain and Canada. 3. To alleviate the degrees-of-freedom problem, recent studies have examined cross-country evidence. Thus, Alesina and Roubini (1992), Alesina et al. (1993), De Haan and Sturm (1997), De Haan et al. (1999), Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001), and Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) consider panels of OECD countries. 4. Since this article repeatedly refers to Rogoff and Sibert (1988), it may be worthwhile to provide a brief sketch of the mechanism at work in that paper. The set-up of the Rogoff-Sibert model is as follows. An incumbent government, which may be intrinsically competent or incompetent, provides certain fixed services to citizens. To pay for these services, revenues must be raised through any combination of non-distortionary taxes (that voters observe immediately) and distortionary taxes (that voters observe with a lag). To provide the given services, competent governments naturally require less aggregate tax revenue than incompetent governments. Suppose the incumbent government is competent. In an election year, it convinces the electorate of its competency by lowering the level of visible non-distortionary tax revenues. Why does an incompetent government not mimic the behaviour of a competent government, thereby enhancing its electoral prospects as well? This is because mimicking forces the incompetent government to raise very large revenues through distortionary taxes; the consequent damage to voter welfare serves as an effective deterrent. The argument for electoral cycles in expenditures, omitted for brevity, is identical in spirit to that for the tax revenues case. 5. Several studies furnish empirical support for the signalling models. Besley and Case (1995a), for example, examine the behaviour of governors in the US; state taxes are shown to be lower when the incumbent governor stands for re-election. 6. De Haan and Sturm (1994) provide corroborating evidence: for member countries of the European Community, the growth of government debt is positively related to the frequency of government changes. 7. Empirical evidence for this theory is mixed. Alt and Lowry (1994) and Poterba (1994, 1996) examine state governments in the United States; adjustments to fiscal shocks are demonstrated to be slower when a state government is ‘divided’ (that is, the executive and legislative branches are controlled by different political parties). Roubini and Sachs (1989a, b) study the fiscal histories of several OECD countries; budget deficits are shown to be correlated with the extent of government fragmentation. However, De Haan and Sturm (1994, 1997), De Haan et al. (1999), Volkerink and De Haan (2001), and Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) argue persuasively that the Roubini-Sachs conclusions are fragile. 8. While Alesina and Tabellini (1990) and Alesina and Drazen (1993) explore the link between budget deficits and the fragmentation of political power, we alert the reader to a complementary strand of work (see, for example, Alesina et al. (1999), Harrinvirta and Mattila (2001), Perotti and Kontopoulos
  • 19. 658 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta (2002)) that uses cross-country panels to show that budget institutions (for example, ex ante spending limits or borrowing constraints) robustly predict budget deficits and government spending. 9. Weingast et al. (1981) were the first to argue that in a system wherein geography forms the basis for political representation, there is an inherent tendency for programmes to exceed efficient scale. We adapt their insights to the problem at hand. To make matters concrete, consider a single-party government that represents exactly one half of the population of a nation. This government will implement a targeted programme should its benefit–cost ratio exceed 0.5. Consider a two-party government in which each coalition partner represents one quarter of the population of a nation. A coalition partner will now seek to implement a targeted programme should its benefit–cost ratio exceed 0.25. Hence, the fragmentation of a government leads to increased public spending (see also Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) for an extended discussion). 10. Boix (1997) analyses the privatisation experiences of various countries and hints at a similar treatment of coalition governments. In contrast to single-party governments, coalition governments are posited to generate gridlock effects: ‘parties within the coalition are prone to veto each other’s projects whenever the resulting policies are believed to result in significant costs for their corresponding constituencies’. 11. Dutta (1996a), for example, does not include state fixed effects in his model and uses state specific time trends instead of year dummies. The set of controls in Khemani (2004) (state net domestic product, share of agriculture in state net domestic product, and proportion of state population that is rural) is different from ours, the set of states considered differs as well (she includes Assam in her list of 14 states while we include Haryana instead), and so on. 12. Our model imposes period-by-period budget balance. Since unstable coalition governments spend less than stable governments, they raise less revenues as well. This revenue result will persist in a less restrictive model so long as expenditures and revenues move together (that is, are positively correlated). In our data set, the correlation coefficient between state governments’ own tax revenue and current account developmental expenditure is 0.86, while that between state governments’ own tax revenue and capital account developmental expenditure is 0.27. 13. For certain years, state literacy rate data were not available from either the Census of India or the National Sample Survey rounds. For these years, we have interpolated the data using a simple growth rate formula. 14. In the Indian context, it is not uncommon to find coalition governments with one pivotal party. For instance, the state of West Bengal has been ruled by a coalition called the Left Front since 1977. The Communist Party of India (Marxist), which is a member of this coalition, has won an absolute majority of legislative assembly seats in each of the state elections since 1977. 15. The possibility of election endogeneity in a parliamentary system has been recognised by several researchers: Cargill and Hutchison (1991) explore this issue in the case of Japan, Chowdhury (1993) and Khemani (2004) focus on India, Heckelman and Berument (1998) study both Japan and the United Kingdom, while Reid (1998) looks at the Canadian situation. 16. The authors thank an anonymous referee for emphasising this point. 17. Section V discusses the sensitivity of the regression results to an alternative coding of Elecst. 18. Khemani (2004) makes this point as well. 19. The authors thank an anonymous referee for emphasising this point. 20. The regressands are, in fact, the log of state governments’ per capita own tax revenue and per capita own non-tax revenue. For expositional ease, we henceforth suppress the qualifier ‘log of.’ 21. States’ own tax revenue consists of commodity tax revenue and revenue from taxes levied on agricultural income and property. There is an electoral cycle for commodity tax revenue. Why does this cycle disappear for the broader category of own tax revenue (compare columns 1 and 2 of Table 4)? For many states, the direct tax component of own tax revenue has been left untouched for years. Thus, the Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission (p. 28) observes: ‘There are a few other taxes which the states can levy, but remain unexploited or under-exploited. Taxation of agricultural incomes is one of them and profession tax is another. The land revenue which has traditionally been the principal mode of taxing agriculture in the country has fallen into disuse’. At any rate, since one component of own tax revenue does not respond at all to electoral considerations, precise estimation of the electoral cycle for own tax revenue becomes difficult. Economists at the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy (a government-funded institute dealing with public finance issues) provided two reasons for why state governments show little interest in manipulating the direct tax component of
  • 20. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 659 own tax revenue: (1) the cost of administering such taxes is exceptionally high; and (2) states perceive their share of centrally-levied direct taxes to be the principal source of direct tax revenue. 22. Non-developmental current account expenditure consists mainly of interest payments on accumulated debt and outlays on fiscal and administrative services. It is surprising that an electoral cycle crops up for non-developmental current account expenditure since its components appear a priori to be difficult to manipulate. To explore this issues further, we ran a regression where the regressand was the sum of per capita expenditure on fiscal services and per capita expenditure on administrative services. The coefficient of the election year dummy was negative (70.09) and statistically significant (t-statistic equal to 72.24). 23. Alesina (1987) demonstrates that the partisan assumption does not rule out election-year effects on macroeconomic variables. Hibbs (1992) provides an in-depth review of the political economy literature with partisan political parties. 24. The difficulty in assigning ideological locations to political parties is a common feature of developing country experiences. We are unaware of a single paper that uses data from developing countries and considers fiscal policy as partially determined by government ideology (see, for example, Schuknecht (2000), Block (2002), Shi and Svensson (2002a, b), and Khemani (2004)). 25. Now, Elecst equals 1 if an election (scheduled or mid-term) takes place in state s during the second half of financial year t or during the first half of the next financial year. 26. Khemani (2004) briefly experiments with this instrument as well. 27. Following Davidson and MacKinnon (1993: 241–42), we also conducted a test to determine whether the (scheduled) election year dummy, Elecst, is endogenous in India. The exogeneity of Elecst could not be rejected. 28. The electoral history of India divides into two distinct phases: a pre-1967 period during which state legislative assembly elections were dominated by the Congress party, and a post-1967 era that beheld lively inter-party competition for assembly seats. Electoral cycles in fiscal variables – shown, in this study, to be sometimes present in the post-1967 data – should disappear completely during the years of Congress party hegemony. More generally, a contrast of the two electoral phases can shed light on the benefits and costs of political competition. References Alesina, A. (1987) Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, pp. 651–78. Alesina, A., Cohen, G. and Roubini, N. (1993) Electoral business cycles in industrial democracies, European Journal of Political Economy, 9, pp. 1–23. Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1993) Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review, 82, pp. 1170–88. Alesina, A., Hausman, R., Hommes, R. and Stein, E. (1999) Budget institutions and fiscal performance in Latin America, Journal of Development Economics, 59, pp. 253–73. Alesina, A., Perotti, R. and Tavares, J. (1998) The political economy of fiscal adjustments, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 197–266. Alesina, A. and Roubini, N. (1992) Political cycles in OECD economies, Review of Economic Studies, 59, pp. 663–88. Alesina, A. and Sachs, J. (1988) Political parties and the business cycle in the United States, 1948–1984, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20, pp. 63–82. Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1990) A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt, Review of Economic Studies, 57, pp. 403–14. Alt, J. and Lowry, R. (1994) Divided government and budget deficits: evidence from the states, American Political Science Review, 88, pp. 811–28. Andrikopoulos, A., Prodromidis, K. and Serletis, A. (1998) Electoral and partisan cycle regularities: a cointegration test, Journal of Policy Modeling, 20, pp. 119–40. Baron, D. (1991) Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control, American Journal of Political Science, 35, pp. 57–90. Baron, D. (1998) Comparative dynamics of parliamentary governments, American Political Science Review, 92, pp. 593–609.
  • 21. 660 K. Chaudhuri & S. Dasgupta Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2000) Land reform, poverty reduction, and growth: evidence from India, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1l5, pp. 389–430. Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2002) The political economy of government responsiveness: theory and evidence from India, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, pp. 1415–51. Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995a) Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence from gubernatorial term limits, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, pp. 769–98. Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995b) Incumbent behavior: vote-seeking, tax-setting, and yardstick competition, American Economic Review, 85, pp. 25–45. Block, S. (2002) Political business cycles, democratization, and economic reform: the case of Africa, Journal of Development Economics, 67, pp. 205–28. Boix, C. (1997) Privatizing the public business sector in the eighties: economic performance, partisan responses and divided governments, British Journal of Political Science, 27, pp. 473–96. Butler, D., Lahiri, A. and Roy, P. (1996) India Decides, Elections 1952–1995 (New Delhi: Living Media India Limited). Cargill, T. and Hutchison, M. (1991) Political business cycles with endogenous election timing: evidence from Japan, Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, pp. 733–39. Chibber, P. (1995) Political parties, electoral competition, government expenditures and economic reform in India, Journal of Development Studies, 32, pp. 74–96. Chowdhury, A. (1993) Political surfing over economic waves: parliamentary election timing in India, American Journal of Political Science, 37, pp. 1100–18. Davidson, R. and MacKinnon, J. (1993) Estimation and Inference in Econometrics (New York: Oxford University Press). De Haan, J. and Sturm, J.-E. (1994) Political and institutional determinants of fiscal policies in the European Community, Public Choice, 80, pp. 157–72. De Haan, J. and Sturm, J.-E. (1997) Political and economic determinants of OECD budget deficits and government expenditures: a reinvestigation, European Journal of Political Economy, 13, pp. 739–50. De Haan, J., Sturm, J.-E. and Beckhuis, G. (1999) The weak government thesis: some new evidence, Public Choice, 101, pp. 163–76. Dutta, B. (1996a) Coalitional governments and policy distortions: the Indian experience (mimeo), Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. Dutta, B. (1996b) Fragmented legislatures and electoral systems: the Indian experience (mimeo), Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. Frey, B. and Schneider, F. (1978a) An empirical study of politico–economic interactions in the United States, Review of Economics and Statistics, 60, pp. 174–83. Frey, B. and Schneider, F. (1978b) A politico-economic model of the United Kingdom, The Economic Journal, 88, pp. 243–53. Government of India (2000) Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission (For 2000–2005) (New Delhi: Government of India Press). Government of India, Ministry of Planning, Department of Statistics, various issues, National Accounts Statistics (New Delhi: Central Statistical Organisation). Government of India, Ministry of Information and Broadcasting, various issues, Press in India, Annual Report of the Registrar of Newspapers for India (New Delhi: Government of India Press). Grover, V. and Arora, R. (1998) Encyclopaedia of India and Her States (New Delhi: Deep and Deep Publications). Harrinvirta, M. and Mattila, M. (2001) The hard business of balancing budgets: a study of public finances in seventeen OECD countries, British Journal of Political Science, 31, pp. 497–521. Heckelman, J. and Berument, H. (1998) Political business cycles and endogenous elections, Southern Economic Journal, 64, pp. 987–1000. Hibbs, D. (1977) Political parties and macroeconomic policy, American Political Science Review, 71, pp. 1467–87. Hibbs, D. (1992) Partisan theory after fifteen years, European Journal of Political Economy, 8, pp. 361–73. Karnik, A. (1990) Elections and government expenditures: the Indian evidence, Journal of Quantitative Economics, 6, pp. 203–12. Khemani, S. (2004) Political cycles in a developing economy: effect of elections in the Indian states, Journal of Development Economics, 73, pp. 125–54.
  • 22. Political Factors and Fiscal Policies in Indian States 661 Lowry, R., Alt, J. and Ferree, K. (1998) Fiscal policy outcomes and electoral accountability in American states, American Political Science Review, 92, pp. 759–74. Nordhaus, W. (1975) The political business cycle, Review of Economic Studies, 42, pp. 169–90. Peltzman, S. (1992) Voters as fiscal conservatives, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, pp. 327–61. Perotti, R. and Kontopoulos, Y. (2002) Fragmented fiscal policy, Journal of Public Economics, 86, pp. 191–222. Poterba, J. (1994) State responses to fiscal crises: the effects of budgetary institutions and politics, Journal of Political Economy, 102, pp. 799–822. Poterba, J. (1996) Budget institutions and fiscal policy in the US states, American Economic Review, 86, pp. 395–400. Reid, B. (1998) Endogenous elections, electoral budget cycles and Canadian provincial governments, Public Choice, 97, pp. 35–48. Reserve Bank of India, various issues, Reserve Bank of India Bulletin (Mumbai: Reserve Bank of India). Rogoff, K. (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles, American Economic Review, 80, pp. 21–35. Rogoff, K. and Sibert, A. (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles, Review of Economic Studies, 55, pp. 1–16. Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989a) Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in the industrial democracies, European Economic Review, 33, pp. 903–38. Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989b) Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial democracies, Economic Policy, 8, pp. 100–32. Schuknecht, L. (2000) Fiscal policy cycles and public expenditure in developing countries, Public Choice, 102, pp. 115–30. Schultz, K. (1995) The politics of the political business cycle, British Journal of Political Science, 25, pp. 79–99. Sen, K. and Vaidya, R. (1996) Political budget cycles in India, Economic and Political Weekly, 30, pp. 2023–27. Serletis, A. and Afxentiou, P. (1998) Electoral and partisan cycle regularities in Canada, Canadian Journal of Economics, 31, pp. 28–46. Shi, M. and Svensson, J. (2002a) Political budget cycles in developed and developing countries (mimeo), Development Research Group, World Bank. Shi, M. and Svensson, J. (2002b) Conditional political budget cycles (mimeo), Development Research Group, World Bank. Volkerink, B. and De Haan, J. (2001) Fragmented government effects on fiscal policy: new evidence, Public Choice, 109, pp. 221–42. Weiner, M. (1989) The Indian Paradox: Essays in Indian Politics (New Delhi: Sage Publications). Weingast, B., Shepsle, K. and Johnson, C. (1981) The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics, Journal of Political Economy, 89, pp. 642–64.