SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 36
Download to read offline
2 2 4 
Marcin Sasin 
Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate 
Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in 
Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions 
W a r s a w , 2 0 0 1
Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further 
publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect Author’s point of view and 
not necessarily those of CASE. 
This paper was prepared for the research project No. 0144/H02/99/17 entitled "Analiza 
przyczyn i przebiegu kryzysów walutowych w krajach Azji, Ameryki £aciñskiej i Europy 
OErodkowo - Wschodniej: wnioski dla Polski i innych krajów transformuj¹cych siê" (Analysis of 
the Causes and Progress of Currency Crises in Asian, Latin American and CEE Countries: 
Conclusions for Poland and Other Transition Countries" financed by the State Committee 
for Scientific Research (KBN) in the years 1999 - 2001. 
The publication was financed by Rabobank Polska SA. 
© CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2001 
Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury 
DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. 
ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN 83-7178-246-2 
Publisher: 
CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 
ul. Sienkiewicza 12, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland 
tel.: (4822) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax (4822) 828 60 69 
e-mail: case@case.com.pl 
www.case.com.pl
Contents 
Abstract 5 
Introduction 6 
1. Predicting Currency Crises 7 
1.1. Model Specification 7 
1.2. Data, Methodology and the Results 18 
2. The Universality of the Results 23 
2.1. Crisis Definition 23 
2.2. The Significance of Fundamentals 26 
3. Conclusions 27 
References 32
Marcin Sasin 
Marcin Sasin (born 1974) joined CASE Foundation in 2000. He is an economist 
specializing in international financial economics and monetary policy issues. He obtained 
Master of Science in Economics at the Catholic University of Leuven, Belgium in 2000 and he 
also holds MA in Oriental Studies from the Warsaw University. 
4 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
Abstract 
Informative content of macroeconomic fundamentals with respect to currency crisis 
prediction is reassessed for the period of 1990s on the panel of 46 developed and 
emerging economies. 
In the first part the paper develops a model for currency crisis prediction. The 
distinction is made between variables emphasized by 'first generation' and 'second 
generation' models. Special attention is directed towards multiple equilibria and 
contagion phenomena. Considerable amount of predictability is found, particularly on 
behalf of standard leading crisis indicators, such as overvaluation of the real exchange rate 
and the level of foreign exchange reserves. Multiple equilibria don't get much support 
from the data while contagion effect is obviously working – apparently through various 
channels. 
In the second part the relationship between model specification and the significance 
of coefficients is investigated in the attempt to ultimately evaluate what can be expected 
from empirical implementation of crisis prediction. An average predictive power of such 
models and employed variables is assessed. 
5 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
Introduction 
This paper reassesses the informative content of macroeconomic fundamentals 
with respect to currency crisis prediction for the period of 1990s on the panel of 46 
developed and emerging economies. The distinction is made between variables 
emphasized by "first generation" and "second generation" models. Special attention is 
directed towards multiple equilibria and contagion phenomena. 
In the second part of the paper the relationship between model specification and 
the significance of coefficients is investigated. This is done in an attempt to ultimately 
evaluate what can be expected from empirical implementation of crisis prediction. 
From theoretical point of view the idea that currency crises need not necessarily be 
irrational and unpredictable events, as they might have been regarded, emerged around 
Krugman (1979). The so-called "first generation" models have been developed – in 
which unsustainable policies of the authorities led to a currency crisis. The theory 
emphasized a set of variables that were responsible for crisis eruption – they are called 
"hard fundamentals" and include domestic credit (expansion), foreign exchange 
reserves, budget balance (deficits) etc. Starting in mid-1980s but especially after 
unexpected ERM crisis in 1992–93 economists switched attention to so-called "second 
generation" models, which introduced an optimizing government and an "escape 
clause" in its policy. Second generation models identified a new set of variables that 
could be responsible for crises – actually any variable that enters government decision 
whether to defend the exchange rate or not, especially domestic economic and political 
situation (inflation, unemployment) should be monitored. New and interesting 
phenomena these models could account for include multiple equilibria and contagion. 
They have been particularly popular in explaining recent crisis and obtain special 
attention in this paper. Finally, after Asian, Russian and Brazilian crisis some economist 
claim that a new brand of crises emerged – "third generation" – one of their 
characteristics is an important role played by microeconomic factors. For more 
extensive treatment of the theoretical background of currency crises see Antczak 
(2000). 
Empirical literature concerning systematical prediction and explanation of currency 
crises has flourished recently but is rather limited in success. Tomczyñska (2000) as well 
as Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1998) provide a good survey. 
6 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
1. Predicting Currency Crises 
1.1. Model Specification 
In this chapter the model for crisis prediction and explanation is built. 
Theory provides the list of fundamentals that can be endowed with an informative 
content. As both the two main approaches to currency crises presented by the "first" 
and the "second" generation models are encompassed – the model includes the 
standard "hard" and measurable fundamentals (the usual macroeconomic variables) as 
well as some approximation of multiple equilibria and contagion. 
In the analysis following instruments are employed: 
– Real exchange rate, measured as a deviation from purchasing power parity; 
– Foreign exchange reserves level, measured in years of import that can be 
purchased by it; 
– Trade balance, expressed as a dummy variable of one if the deficit exceeds 5%, a 
number roughly regarded as a frontier of safe sustainability; 
– Government surplus, as a surplus to GDP ratio; 
– Domestic credit, described relatively to GDP; 
– Inflation; 
– Unemployment; 
– Output level, in a form of a squared output gap (deviation of the GDP from a 
linear trend in % squared). The basis for such specification is a priori presumption 
that both economic depression and a state of excessive economic boom can be 
potentially unattractive and supposedly dangerous for the investor in a given 
currency; 
– Short term foreign liabilities expressed as a ratio of foreign private bank claims due 
within a year to foreign exchange reserves. The unbalanced maturity of foreign 
obligations became the most direct cause of the Mexican crisis in 1994–95; 
– The level of non-bank financial institution activity measured as a percentage of 
total country's deposits in hands of those institutions. The moral hazard exercised 
by such financial intermediaries in the absence of sufficient banking control is 
frequently blamed for the severity of the Southeast Asian collapse in 1997–98; 
– The level of international interest rate as the average of the US and German 
treasury bill rate. This variable can supposedly account for contemporaneous 
breakdown of many exchange rates, what can seemingly look like a contagion, and 
what actually is not a contagion; 
7 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
– Exchange rate regime type in a form of a set of two dummy variables – one for 
managed float and one for currency peg leaving purely flexible exchange rate as a 
reference category [1]; 
– Multiple equilibria as dummy variable of one if there exist a possibility of self-fulfilling 
currency crash; 
– Sensitivity to contagion due to trade link measured as the impairment 
of competitiveness caused by the crisis elsewhere; 
– Sensitivity to contagion due to informational spillovers and herding behavior. 
The last three instruments require further explanation. 
1.1.1. Multiple Equilibria 
This variable is obtained from the extension of Jeanne (1997) model to all countries 
included in this study. There is barely any fundamental so hard to measure as the 
possibility of multiple equilibria. However Jeanne argues that specific behavior of the 
short-term interest rate, regarded as the reflection of the devaluation expectations can 
be interpreted as the manifestation of multiple equilibria. In what follows I track 
Jeanne's model as well as Lyrio and Dewachter's (1999) application. 
In many second generation models with optimizing government the net benefit of 
maintaining fixed exchange rate at period t can be expressed as 
(1) 
B b e τ = τ −απ τ −1 
where bτ is the gross benefit of the fixed peg depending solely on underlying 
macroeconomic fundamentals, and πe 
τ−1 is the probability that the government decides 
to abandon exchange rate evaluated by the private sector in the preceding period. This 
is only the simplest formulation of the fact that net benefit of the peg depends also on 
how credible is the peg itself. To illustrate that point suppose that unemployment (the 
fundamental) enters (negatively) into government objective function. Unemployment 
itself is determined (at least partly) by the nominal arrangements made within private 
sector (let's say workers and employers). These arrangements are conditioned on the 
expectations concerning government action (to devalue or not). So the only way to 
increase employment above natural level is to surprise private sector with unexpected 
devaluation. Facing high devaluation expectation and not devaluing is equivalent to 
unexpected revaluation, which in turn drastically raises unemployment. Such 
8 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[1] Currency board dummy doesn't exhibit enough variation to be included.
interaction of expectations is a common way of obtaining multiple equilibria. 
We assume that the net benefit of the peg (the state of fundamental) obeys the 
following simple stochastic process. 
(2) 
where the innovation ετ is independently and identically distributed and characterized 
by typical, well behaved, bell shaped density function and associated cumulative 
distribution function F. 
It is common knowledge that government devalues if and only if net benefit is 
negative and at the same time the government has such a political will. This will is 
observable and happens with a probability μ. If the government doesn't exhibit such a will 
it defends the exchange rate at every cost. 
Therefore we can express the probability at time τ of a currency crisis in the next 
period as: 
(3) 
but from (1) and (2) Bτ+1< 0 is equivalent to 
(4) 
hence 
(5) 
In the rational expectations we have to assume that πe 
τ=πτ . Private sector's 
expectations must be validated in equilibrium, otherwise they would be altered. 
Denoting φτ = Eτbτ+1 which represents the overall (expected next period) state of the 
economy – "the" fundamental – equation (5) becomes 
(6) 
We introduce two simplifying assumptions: 
1 
2 
− 
s 
2 2 
φ 
e σ s 
– F ≡ Fσ(φ)= , i.e. the innovation to fundamental has normal 
distribution with mean zero and standard deviation σ. 
9 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
bτ = Eτ −1bτ + ετ 
π τ = μ Prτ (Bτ +1 < 0) 
ετ +1 <απ τ − Eτ bτ +1 e 
πτ = μ Prτ (ετ +1 <απ τe − Eτ bτ +1 ) 
π τ = μFσ (απ τ −φτ ) 
2πσ 
∫ ∂ 
−∞
– α=1. Because φ is a compounded fundamental it is always possible to scale down α 
to unity by scaling at the same time the composition weights as well. It is not only a 
simplification – the necessary condition for parameter identification requires an 
additional constraint on one of the parameters in the argument of F. 
Nonlinear equation (6) can have one, two (not generic, so we ignore this), or three 
solutions. This idea can be summarized in the following way: 
1. If the slope of a distribution function at inflection point does not exceed unity [2] 
the number of solutions to this equation is always one for the whole range of 
fundamentals. No multiple equilibria exist. 
2. If the slope (at inflection point) exceeds unity three cases are possible: 
– for the fundamental lower (worse) than some critical value φl 
only one equilibrium 
l 
π exist φ– it is high (bad) equilibrium when the probability of devaluation is high, 
– for the fundamental higher (better) than some critical value φh only one equilibrium 
π exist – it is low (good) equilibrium when the probability of devaluation is low, 
– for fundamentals between and φh that is in the certain and well specified range 
there are three solution corresponding to three equilibria {π1,π2,π3} high, medium 
and low [3]. 
Figure 1 presents the reasoning more clearly. On the left panel straight 45o line and 
a curve of the normal cumulative distribution represent respectively left and right hand 
side of equation (6) and must equal at solution. Right panel is the same analysis 
transferred into φ − π space. The curve consists of all pairs (φ, {π1,π2,π3}) or (φ, π) that 
solve (6). 
For every country in my sample I estimate the following model: 
(7) 
(8) 
(9) 
π τ =πˆτ +ητ 
πˆτ = μFσ (πˆτ −φτ ) 
φτ =γ ′ ⋅ xτ 
where the vector xτ contain relevant components of macroeconomic fundamental, such 
as real exchange rate, trade balance to GDP ratio, the level of foreign exchange reserves 
measured in billions of dollars and a constant, γ is a vector of parameters, parameter μ 
is the probability of the occurrence of a political will to devalue, σ is a parameter for the 
standard deviation of the cumulative distribution function. ητ is a prediction error which 
is assumed to be independently, identically, normally distributed with mean zero and a 
standard deviation of ση. 
10 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[2] The slope is maximal at the inflection point, so in this case the slope never exceeds unity. 
[3] The medium equilibrium π2 has an undesirable property of positive correlation between the 
fundamental and the devaluation probability. It is also dynamically unstable and mainly for that reason it will be 
ignored in the rest of the analysis.
There is a need for a time series of devaluation probabilities (π 's) to exercise the 
estimation. These probabilities are assumed to be roughly equal to the interest rate 
differential on short maturities (money market rate) [4]. 
It is also essential to make assumption about the magnitude of devaluation expected 
by private sector to happen at the crisis. It was set to unconditional mean real 
overvaluation of the currency [5]. 
The estimation was carried over by means of the maximum likelihood method by 
maximizing: 
(10) 
11 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Figure 1. Solutions to πτ = μμFσ(απτ−φτ) 
Source: 
 
     
 
 
     
μ σ γ σ η π 
 
 
2 
− T  
− u d 
e T 
  
−   
  
  
2 
Σ 
=   
 
  
1 
min ˆ 2 2 
 
1 
, ˆ 
1 
( 2 ) 
max 
, , 
ση 
τ 
πτ πτ πτ πτ 
[4]To get "pure" devaluation probabilities interest rate differentials have to be adjusted by expected change 
in the (explicit or implicit) trend – this is particularly important in the case of a crawling peg or a managed float. 
Where the trend (rate of currency depreciation) is not explicitly stated by the monetary authorities the implicit 
trend has been first estimated. It would be also reasonable to adjust interest rates for the expected rate change 
relative to the trend. Although the exact theoretical behavior of the exchange rate within bands (at least in 
target zone models) is highly nonlinear, Bertola and Svensson (1993) argue that this behavior is characterized 
by strong mean (trend) reversion and can be well approximated by the first order autoregressive process. To 
correct for this they propose so-called "drift adjustment" method. This method is not, however, used in this 
paper as it produces implausible values for devaluation probabilites. 
[5] If that turned out to be negative – to the average realized devaluation provided it exceeded two 
standard deviations of the usual rate change. The minimum and maximum expected devaluations have been 
constrained to 5 % (10% for currency boards) and 25% respectively.
uτ 
πˆ d 
where T equals number of observations and , πˆτ 
are two extreme π 's solving (8) 
at τ given γ, μ and σ. If necessary (if only one equilibrium exists) . 
u d 
πˆτ = πˆτ 
After the coefficients have been obtained the critical range and fitted values of the 
l 
fundamental were φcomputed. The dummy variable capturing multiple equilibria 
possibility was set to one if and only if inferred compounded fundamental for a given 
country in a given period was between critical values and φh. 
The analysis has, of course, many drawbacks. First, it assumes that changes in 
interest rate differentials without respective changes in the fundamental are necessarily 
reflections of the multiple equilibria phenomenon but it does not have to be the case 
[6]. Second, it assumes a specific, namely normal, distribution function for innovation 
to the fundamental – this assumption is rather crucial for obtaining multiple equilibria. 
Finally in some cases, judging from log-likelihood comparison, just the linear model of 
devaluation probability performed apparently better. 
Some sample results from estimating the model are presented in Figure 2 on the 
following page. Vertical axis indicates devaluation probabilities, horizontal axis 
represents the value of compounded fundamental [7]. Curves represent inferred 
relationship between devaluation probability and fundamentals, dots – observations. 
1.1.2. Contagion 
This paper distinguishes between two sources of contagion, namely trade-link 
contagion and informational spillovers. 
The idea that trade links play important role in the spread of currency crises is well 
justified theoretically [e.g. Gerlach and Smets, 1994; Masson, 1999] and empirically 
[Glick and Rose, 1999] as well. There are several types of links that can be identified. 
For our analysis let's denote by X the country in question and by N the set of all other 
countries engaged in the foreign trade, ΨXY the trade (export) volume that goes from 
X to Y, ΔY devaluation of country Y (measured in relation to X). 
Ψ 
= 
XY 
XY ω 
Let's also denote – the importance of country Y for country X 
Σ∈Ψ 
J N 
XJ 
measured as Y's weight in X's export basket. 
12 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[6] For example in credible currency boards changes in the interest rate may reflect fluctuations in liquidity, 
as the authorities do not engage in interest rate smoothing – see the case of Estonia in Figure 2. 
[7] The axis is scaled by the maximization procedure to fit the shape of the curve, so absolute values of the 
fundamental are country-specific and have no meaning for comparison between countries.
13 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Figure 2. Sample results from multiple equilibria estimation. (Dots represent 
observations, curves represent inferred relationship between the fundamental and 
devaluation probability. If slope at inflection>1 there is a possibility of multiple 
equilibria)
The simplest channel of contagion is the direct loss of competitiveness in bilateral 
trade. It can be expressed as: 
(11) 
TcX ω XY Y 1 
This simple formula says that country X's loss of direct bilateral competitiveness is 
equal to the amount X's partner has devalued times the importance of that partner in 
X's export basket and this summed over all X's trade (export) partners. Other, more 
comprehensive measure of trade links is the index of a competitiveness loss on export 
markets. It is expressed as 
(12) 
ΣΨ Δ 
Country K is X's export partner. The right fraction represents the (minus) average 
price of K's import. It is equal to total K's import volume weighted by its (minus) prices, 
(i.e. exchange rates of countries exporting to K) divided by total K's import volume. 
When countries that export to K devalue, and X does not – X's competitiveness 
become severely impaired. This is again multiplied by the importance of K in X's export 
basket and summed over all X's trade partners. 
This index can be refined to control for the extent to which countries compete on 
export markets: 
14 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
Figure 2. Sample results from multiple equilibria estimation. (Dots represent 
observations, curves represent inferred relationship between the fundamental and 
devaluation probability. If slope at inflection>1 there is a possibility of multiple 
equilibria) – continued 
= Σ Δ 
Y∈N 
Σ 
ΣΨ 
= 
∈ 
∈ 
∈ 
K N 
Y N 
YK 
Y N 
YK Y 
TcX ω XK 2
(13) 
 
 
 
 
Ψ −Ψ 
Σ Σ 
∈ ∈ −   
 
  
XK YK 
3 ω 1 
X Y XK Tc 
= Δ − 
Y N K N Y XK YK 
 
  
  
Ψ + Ψ 
{ } 
It exploits the fact that not all X's competitors are of equal importance. Countries 
of a very different size seldom fiercely compete (on average) in the world trade. X 
would be mostly concerned about competitors that are of similar size, from similar 
region, producing similar goods for similar markets. Y is X's competitor. The term inside 
brackets expresses the degree of similarity of X's and Y's export volume to country K. 
It is presupposed that similar export volume to K can approximate similar export 
patterns of X and Y and therefore the degree of their competition on K's market. For 
given Y, it is weight-summed over all markets K that X and Y compete on, and then 
multiplied by Y's devaluation (X's loss of competition) and again summed over all X 
competitors. 
Further possibilities to refine the index of competitiveness loss, e.g. by splitting 
total trade into sectors, introducing export elasticities into the analysis, etc., are, of 
course, unlimited. 
I employ the last formulation as the approximation of exposure to trade-link-caused 
contagion. It seems the most sophisticated and appealing out of the mentioned three. 
For example trade links between Southeast Asian region are by no means that 
developed, as the links of individual SE Asian countries with the rest of the world [8]. 
Additional (but not very significant) three modifications are made: 
– instead of devaluation itself, I'm using my 0–1 crisis index (as explained below) to 
make it compatible with the rest of the analysis; 
– as I'm not interested in competitiveness loss contemporaneous to the crisis (that 
would severely bias the analysis towards finding trade link contagion) I proceed as 
follow: X's competitor devaluation (crisis) is set to one if and only if that country has 
had a crisis during past three periods; 
– one has also to notice that different countries react differently to equal devaluation 
by the whole set of countries (this happens for example because not all 200 or so 
world countries are included in the analysis). To correct for that I divide by 
(14) 
15 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
 
 
Ψ − Ψ 
XK YK 
Σ Σ   
  
3 ω 1 
ScaleX XK 
= − 
Y∈N K∈N − { X , Y } 
Ψ XK + Ψ 
YK 
[8] For example, Thai export to its biggest trade partner in the region and a neighbor – Malaysia (excluding 
Singapore and Hong-Kong for a moment) – was in 1997 equal roughly 12% of a combined export to the US 
and Japan – the biggest importers from Southeast Asia.
16 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
Another source of contagion can be so-called informational spillovers. That factor 
arises due to following reasons: 
– it is costly to monitor possibly infinite set of relevant macroeconomic fundamentals. 
Instead investor can rely on the behavior of other presumably better informed market 
participants. Calvo and Mendoza (1996) notice that the more diversified the investor is 
the less become the marginal gain from gathering information about portfolio 
components. That makes investors very sensible to small amount of information and can 
result in "herding behavior" or "information cascades"; 
– the rules of the game in financial market, or the state of common knowledge, the 
level of expectations, or the government response function, or other important piece of 
information can be unclear or missing. Krugman (1996) shows that if the authorities 
preferences are not publicly observed investors might test it by a speculative attack - then 
observe which attack has been successful and which has failed, and learn on that basis. In 
Shiller (1995) investors differently interpret information and are unsure about other 
investors interpretation. Therefore market reaction to a piece of news provides 
information about the way how other information should be interpreted and can possibly 
lead to drastic changes in expectations and to overreaction. 
I know of no empirical paper testing such a contagion channel. This is an ad-hoc 
attempt to fill the gap. 
I base my informational-spillover-caused-contagion-possibility index on the 
assumption that a crisis in country X reveals information that crises in general are more 
likely in countries characterized by similar fundamentals as X. Countries that are similar 
to a crisis country X are immediately attacked by investors trying to profit (or escape 
capital losses) from possible crisis - before others turn against that country as well. It is 
computed as: 
(15) 
( ) 
Δ 
f f f f 
min , 
X Y Y X Y 
( ) 
Σ 
Σ 
Y N 
Σ Σ 
f ∈ 
F 
∈ 
min , 
I ∈ N ∪ X J ∈ N − I ∪ 
X 
1 
+ 
= 
f f f f 
I J J I 
X 
N 
Inf spill 
{ } { } { } 
1 
. 
where ƒx is a value of fundamental ƒ in country X, ΔY (as in trade contagion case) 
equals one if Y has had a crisis during past three periods, and zero otherwise. Before I 
sum over all fundamentals ƒ ∈ F (the set of fundamentals) I scale it to achieve 
comparability between fundamentals. 
1.1.3. The Dependent Variable – Crisis Index 
The problem with a choice of crisis period is obvious and not trivial. The key 
decision is either crisis periods should be hand-picked by experienced researcher
17 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
basing on his knowledge, financial press and common beliefs, or should they be an 
outcome of a rigorous procedure in which only objective and measurable characteristic 
enter the choice function. Both methods have advantages and disadvantages, and the 
conflict between them if far from being resolved. This paper takes the latter approach. 
This decision is, of course not, the end of a difficult and controversial selection 
process. There is a need to find a method to transform macroeconomic fundamentals 
into crisis indicator. 
As Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz (1996) correctly note "currency crises cannot 
be identified [only] with actual devaluations (…) for two reasons: First, not all 
speculative attacks are successful. The currency may be supported through the 
expenditure of reserves (…). Alternatively the authorities may repel attacks by rising 
interest rates. (…) Ideally, an index of speculative pressure would be obtained by 
employing a structural model of exchange rate determination, from which one would 
derive the excess demand for foreign exchange." 
So the speculative attack can manifest itself via three not mutually exclusive 
channels: currency devaluation, foreign exchange reserves losses and sharp increases in 
(short term) interest rates. It became somehow common in the literature to use so- 
-called exchange market pressure index [after Girton and Roper, 1977]. It is an average 
of the changes in the above mentioned three components weighted by respective 
standard deviations (so their contribution become comparable). Crisis is said to happen 
if that index exceeds certain threshold – usually its mean plus some number times its 
standard deviation. It is not very surprising that different authors use different version. 
Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz use the mean plus 1.5 times the standard deviation; 
Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1998) require the index to be 3 standard deviations 
above its mean. Some authors regress the index itself. 
In defining crisis I proceed as follows: 
– I construct exchange market pressure index as the standard-deviation-weighted 
average of changes in (log) exchange rate, (log) reserves (with a minus sign), and short 
term interest rate. At period τ change is measured not from period τ−1, but from the 
average of periods τ−3, τ−2 and τ−1. That is because in times of turmoil these variables 
get unusually volatile – it smoothes the behavior of the index and make it consistent 
with itself. For currency boards exchange rate change doesn't enter the index. 
– crisis dummy variable is set to one if and only if exchange market pressure index 
exceeds 2.25 its standard deviation above its mean (2.25 is halfway in-between 1.5 
and 3) and at least one of the components has an absolute change of at least 1.5% 
(that excludes small changes in very stable countries, e.g. Netherlands, from being 
interpreted as crises).
18 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
1.2. Data, Methodology and the Results 
I'm working on an unbalanced panel of 46 developed and emerging economies [9] 
observed monthly from January of 1990 until March 1999. 
Most of the data comes from International Monetary Fund's International Financial 
Statistics CD-ROM. Another large part is taken from OECD's Main Economic Indicators. Data 
on short-term debt comes from BIS/IMF/OECD/WB project. Some of the data are taken 
from financial informational services like Reuters or Bloomberg. IMF's reports Exchange 
Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions have been studied to extract information about 
exchange rate arrangement for regime dummy variables. Data on foreign trade comes from 
IMF Directions of Trade Statistics. A lot of missing observation has been completed thanks to 
Internet sites of National Central Banks and National Statistical Offices. 
Still, the data is severely constrained by missing observation, and the requirement 
that all variables' time series must be of the same length within the country – all the 
incomplete observations has been discarded. 
The data has been then visually inspected for notorious mistakes, which has been 
corrected. There were some problems with data frequency – mainly with GDP, which 
usually is not collected monthly. It has been overcome by approximating GDP with 
industrial production. 
This basis has been further contracted by the requirement of comparability. Particularly: 
– data on emerging countries from Central and Eastern Europe has been restricted 
not to begin before January 1994, 
– data on some Western European countries that entered the EMS or started a peg 
(reasonably short period) after January 1990 has been cut to start at their accession 
(beginning of the peg), 
– data on emerging countries from Latin America start right after they have 
suppressed the hyperinflation and implemented stabilization plans, 
– for some countries data has been set to begin at the time that a country in 
question abandoned dual exchange rate system, and unified both rates, 
– for countries that presently form the EMU time series end on December 1998, 
– some data has been additionally dropped in the estimation procedure due to 
insufficient variation. 
[9] Argentina, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Colombia, Croatia, Czech 
Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Hong-Kong (SAR), Hungary, Iceland, India, Indonesia, 
Ireland, Israel, Italy, Korea, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan, Peru, 
Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, 
Thailand, Turkey, United Kingdom.
The statistical method of the analysis has naturally far reaching consequences for 
the results. Apart from the graphical analysis, "visual" or "narrative" approaches, or 
univariate maximizations there are two main and popular methods for estimating 
currency crisis prediction models, namely: simple linear regression and probit models. 
In this study I employ panel data fixed effects linear specification. The motivation is 
as follows: 
– such model allows the appreciation of differences between countries and 
sufficiently exploits within as well as between dimension of the data, 
– it is of no importance that this model allows the inferred crisis index to exceed 
one, or to be negative, as long as one doesn't interpret crisis index as the 
probability of a crisis, 
– linear and probit/logit based binary choice models usually give similar qualitative 
results unless the variable in question is of low or no significance, 
– probit/logit models put rather tight distributional assumptions on the error term 
structure. 
Nevertheless, as a benchmark, I also employ also a probit model. 
Summing up I estimate the following models: 
(16) 
where xi,τ denotes the vector of regressors (macroeconomic fundamentals, constant 
excluded), β denotes the vector of coefficients, αi denotes country specific intercept 
term, κ is a constant, ηi,τ is an error term – distributed independently and identically 
over time and over countries, with mean zero and a standard deviation of ση.The 
model is estimated by means of the OLS. 
as well as 
(17) 
(18) 
(19) 
∗ 
C 
↔ > 
1 0 
Crisisi τ 
= ∗ 
C ∗ 
=κ + xi′,τ β + ε i.τ (probit model) with C* as a latent state variable, and εi,τ distributed standard normally, 
independently and identically over time and over countries. The model is estimated 
with the maximum likelihood. 
I also estimate the model for each of the two subsamples i.e. emerging and 
developed economies for better inference and interpretation. 
19 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Crisisi,τ = κ + α i + xi′,τ β + η i.τ 
Crisisi,τ = Pr (Crisisi,τ =1) +ηi.τ 
 
  
↔ < 
0 0 
, 
C
The results are summarized in Table 1. 
In interpretation that follows I will base myself mainly on the coefficients obtained 
from linear regression. 
First of all, it is clearly visible that real exchange rate and the level of foreign 
exchange reserves – standard and well identified variables of the "first generation" 
models as well as any empirical model employed to predict crises – has allover the 
predicted sign and unquestionable significance. This finding is in line with almost all 
empirical testing of crisis determinants. It is also important to recognize the differences 
in magnitude and significance of those two variables between subsamples. The RER 
overvaluation impact and importance is much lower for the emerging markets 
comparing to those developed. The explanation that comes to mind is the well known 
Balassa-Samuelson effect [10]. The opposite (but not as clear) story is with the reserves 
– sudden drop in reserves is more likely to harm developing economies – they ability 
to acquire emergency liquidity injection is limited. 
Trade balance in probit specification has both the predicted sign and sufficient 
significance. We should however admit that different countries have different levels of 
current account sustainability [11]. Consequently if we allow for country-specific level 
of sustainability the implications of trade balance for currency crisis prediction shrink 
to nil. 
Two measures of government policy stance – government budget surplus and domestic 
credit creation – are clearly proven to have its significant impact on the exposure to the 
currency crisis. Expansionary fiscal policy reflected in budget deficits, and its financing by 
domestic credit expansion is – as "first generation" models predict – a shortcut to foreign 
exchange market crash. This is especially evident in the case of emerging markets that 
usually don't have sufficient capacity to absorb additional domestic credit. 
I find only weak backing for the thesis that variables entering (according to early 
"second generation" models) the government's utility function (inflation and 
unemployment) play certain role in attracting crises – they are usually only properly signed. 
The data doesn't support the view that the output gap (in absolute values) plays any 
important role. That might be due to somehow unusual specification. 
Short-term debt level and the degree of non-bank financial institution activity 
coefficients are accurately signed and have some significance for the whole sample and 
for emerging markets. 
20 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[10] Emerging markets use to have (seemingly) overvalued real exchange rates due to faster economic 
growth and divergence in tradable and non-tradable goods sectors' productivity. 
[11] For example CEE economies like Estonia or Poland use to run enormous trade deficit, not having 
suffered up to the present any severe currency crisis – the deficit is financed by the inflow of FDI.
21 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Table 1 : Fixed effects linear regression and probit results 
Whole sample Emerging markets Developed economies 
Regressors linear probit linear probit linear probit 
RER • 0.4254 ! • 0.1684 ! • 0.2240 ** • 0.1169 ! • 0.5420 ! • 0.2077 ! 
Fx Reserves •-0.1599 ! •-0.0197*** •-0.2322 ! •-0.0190*** •-0.1499 ! •-0.0431 ! 
☯ Trade balance • 0.0122 • 0.0417 ! -0.0228 • 0.0229 ! -0.0064 • 0.1233 ! 
Govnmt surplus •-0.8346 ! 0.0679 •-2.0577 ! 0.0218 •-0.3796 * 0.2348 * 
Domestic credit • 0.1259 ! • 0.0432 ! • 0.1931 ! • 0.0367 ! • 0.0402 -0.0241 * 
Inflation • 0.4160 ! • 0.0157 • 0.0576 • 0.0322 * • 0.5948 • 0.2397 
Unemployment • 0.0007 • 0.0001 • 0.0009 • 0.0016 * • 0.0001 -0.0007 
Output gap • 0.2452 • 1.4927*** -0.6657 • 0.8050*** -1.0013 • 0.0682 
Short term debt • 0.032 *** • 0.0045 * • 0.0097 • 0.0004 dropped dropped 
Non-bank instit. • 0.3575 -0.0185 • 0.3464 • 0.0599 ** -0.3971 -0.2361 ! 
Int’l interest rate -0.3145 -0.7063 ** • 3.1090 ! • 1.7532 ! -3.6530 ! -2.3639 ! 
☯ Managed float -0.0412 -0.0105 -0.0162 -0.0157 ** -0.0099 -0.0112 
☯ Peg • 0.0021 -0.0096 -0.0141 -0.0135 ** • 0.0281 -0.0067 
☯Multp equilibria -0.0108 • 0.0042 -0.0194 -0.0008 -0.0003 • 0.0109 
Trade contagion • 0.1591 ! • 0.0668*** • 0.4004 ! • 0.1247 ! • 0.0746 * • 0.0204 
Inform. spillover • 0.0085 ! • 0.0093 ! • 0.0096 ! • 0.0035 ! -0.0019 • 0.0056 * 
No of observ. 2355 2355 999 999 1356 1356 
within/pseudo R2 0.0978 0.1229 0.2022 0.2710 0.0720 0.1513 
Probit estimated with maximum likelihood. Probit coefficients expressed as derivatives of the probability to change in underlying fundamental 
evaluated at mean (∂F/∂xx=x-bar). For discrete variables (marked with ☯) derivative is to discrete change in the variable. Country specific 
intercepts of fixed effects estimation not reported. • - coefficient signed as predicted. Significance level : * 25% , ** 10%, *** 5%, 
! 1% and higher, based on t-statistics (z-statistics) for hypothesis of no effect. Slopes correctly signed and significantly different from zero at 
the 0.05 are shaded.
The coefficient accompanying the international interest rate poses some puzzle. Its 
importance is undoubtfully clear only in the case of emerging markets. The result for 
developed countries is a kind of anomaly. 
I presupposed the exchange rate regime dummy variables to have positive 
coefficients, i.e. any attempt of the authorities to control the exchange rate exposes a 
country to increased market pressure ("currency peg is the accident waiting to 
happen"). The data doesn't provide much support for that. 
Also multiple equilibria dummy has apparently no significance in the model. It 
seems that Jeanne's (1997) idea of practical application of the notion of self-fulfilling 
crisis has mainly theoretical appeal; its potential empirical reflection must be 
overridden by other factors. 
Last but not least come two contagion indexes. The results on trade contagion 
reinforce the view that trade links have indeed crucial meaning in the spread of 
currency crises (compare Glick and Rose (1999), who find parallel relationship). This 
effect is much stronger in the case of emerging markets. 
The category contagion due to informational spillovers is also proven to be 
important – a crisis in a similar country raises the probability of a crisis in a given 
country. The contagion effect works through (at least) two distinct channels [12]. 
In general a currency crisis spreads much more easily among emerging markets. 
Rather clear picture arises from the analysis. There is a set of variables – that is to say 
real exchange rate overvaluation, foreign exchange reserves deficit, domestic credit 
expansion, government budget deficit, trade links or similarities with countries suffering 
crises, and others – that have indeed apparent predictive potential with respect to currency 
crisis. The overall fit of the employed models is not very impressive but reasonable – it ranges 
from 7 to 27%. There is much more predictability in the emerging markets – perhaps the 
sophistication of the policy instruments available to them to counteract mounting problems 
– and wipe out this way some of the predictability – is limited. Some results of a predicting 
performance of the model are presented in Figure 3. It includes the predictions from the 
linear fixed effect regression. The horizontal axis indicates time, the vertical axis – inferred 
severity of the crisis index. Crisis periods are indicated with a circle [13]. 
22 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[12] The two indexes exhibit analogous qualitative patterns. It may suggest that both reflect just the basic 
relationship that crisis elsewhere has an impact on probability of a crisis in home country. However the correlation 
between these two variables is only 0.09 and a quantitative comparison of relative magnitudes of their coefficients 
gives much room for the hypothesis that contagion effect works indeed through distinct channels. 
[13] Because the model is linear and because each country has it specific constant (fixed effects) the 
inferred "probabilities" are not necessarily between 0 and 1. Instead they should rather be treated as a 
"vulnerability to crises" index – comparable between countries. Within countries only relative changes matter 
(absolute values should be compared with an average for a given country).
2. The Universality of the Results 
One is right to retain some degree of reservation with respect to such analyses. 
Although there are some common findings in the empirical literature, there are also 
many differences. In recent years various researchers have claimed success in 
systematically predicting currency crises with different methods and approaches, and 
to have discovered different variables responsible for foreign exchange market events. 
They usually back their claims with regressions having significant coefficients on 
variables in question. 
There is a point in assessing the reliability of such findings – to what extent are they 
"true", common, similar and to what extent fall they prey to data mining biases (data-set 
overusing), departures from actual a priori null-hypothesis specification, etc. 
In other words – what can expect the researcher setting off in pursuit for crisis 
predictability assessment. 
2.1. Crisis Definition 
When a researcher has made a decision that the data, not he himself, would decide 
what qualifies as a crisis and what doesn't, he faces a choice of a selection algorithm. 
The trade-off in such mechanism is obvious: the more "true" crises it captures the more 
"tranquil" period it marks as crises. 
I proceed as follows: basing on the financial press, journal articles, common 
knowledge, my experience and on the visual analysis of the data I manually select 
months that can be called crisis periods. Then I construct market pressure index (as 
described above) using the following parameters: 
– number of index components (three or two – without interest rate), 
– length of moving average from which the change in fundamental is assessed (from 
one-just first difference, to twelve), 
– weights for underlying index component, 
When the index has been constructed I define crises to exist when it satisfies certain 
conditions with parameters as follows: 
– threshold it has to exceed to be qualified as a crisis (from 1,25 to 2.5 its standard 
deviation above its mean), 
– number of periods between and after a crisis to be set to crisis or to missing 
(from 0 to 6), 
23 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
24 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
Figure 3. Successes and failures in predicting crises. Predictions from the linear fixed 
effect regression. On the horizontal axis – time, on the vertical axis – inferred severity 
of the crisis index ("probability" of a crisis). Crisis periods are indicated with a circle.
– threshold that at least one of underlying fundamentals must exceed (jump of 
minimum zero to 5%). 
The combination of these criteria gives at least several dozen thousand of 
algorithms – I compare them on the basis on how precisely they have identified crises 
periods relative to my hand-picked specimen. 
The outcome is presented in the Figure 4. On the horizontal axis I mark how many 
percent of the total sample has been covered with bad predictions (indicating crisis in 
a tranquil period). On the vertical axis – how many percent of total crisis periods have 
been called (good predictions). Each dot represents one algorithm. 
The figure portrays a typical trade-off problem. It has a "Pareto optimal" frontier. 
The implication is the fact that there are better and worse ways of selecting crises 
periods from the sample. The best algorithms minimize the number of bad predictions 
for a given accuracy (percent of crisis periods correctly called). The researcher has to 
decide what is his trade-off between good and bad predictions (his "indifference curve") 
and choose the appropriate algorithm (on the "Pareto" frontier). 
The straight line represents my "indifference curve". Judging from visual inspection 
of its prediction this paper's crisis index does a good job in calling all major and medium 
crises and at the same time it has a low dispersion. Of course the above analysis is very 
subjective – economists differ in what events they call crisis [14]. 
25 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Figure 3. Successes and failures in predicting crises. Predictions from the linear fixed 
effect regression. On the horizontal axis – time, on the vertical axis – inferred severity 
of the crisis index ("probability" of a crisis). Crisis periods are indicated with a circle – 
continued 
[14]This issue is somehow analogous to the interdependence between type-I and type-II errors in 
econometric hypothesis testing – their probability cannot be simultaneously minimized.
2.2. The Significance of Fundamentals 
Afterward I estimate my two models with regressors modified in various ways and 
in different configurations. 
Modifications include: 
– various computations of real exchange rates: CPI based, relative normalized unit 
labor cost based, real export value based etc., 
– foreign reserves represented as a ratio to GDP or to import, 
– trade balance as it is, squared (sign corrected), as a dummy (sign corrected) equal 
to one when exceeding five different thresholds, 
– government surplus treated similarly, 
– domestic credit and short term debt represented as a ratio to GDP or to reserves, 
– different computations of the output gap, 
– different composition of international interest rate, 
26 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
Figure 4. The behavior of crisis selection mechanisms (good predictions against bad 
predictions, in %)
– "drift adjustment" (in a sense of Bertola and Svensson), no adjustment, different 
trend specifications in the multiple equilibria dummy, 
– different versions of trade link contagion index with different lags, 
and it is combined with 
– different crises selection algorithms, 
Around 5000 regressions are exercised in total. Since the coefficients are not 
directly comparable [15] I present only sample distributions of t-statistics (for null 
hypothesis of no effect) obtained from those regressions. I also report a sample 
distribution of the R2 's. Densities for subsamples have been scaled down by the factor 
of two, not to obscure figures. Averages are indicated with a dashed line. The results 
are presented in Figure 5 [16]. 
Given the large amount of the literature on currency crises prediction and various 
results obtained by the authors this exercise was meant to reconcile these differences 
by assessing what is an "average" prediction, regardless of variables used, regressors' 
specification, methods employed and other variations and definitions [17]. 
3. Conclusions 
The study found quite considerable amount of predictability, particularly on behalf of 
standard leading crisis indicators, such as overvaluation of the real exchange rate and the 
level of foreign exchange reserves. Multiple equilibria don't get much support from the 
data while contagion effect is obviously working – apparently through various channels. 
The predictability is especially evident in the case of emerging economies. 
What is the explanation for that relatively large predictable component in currency 
crises probability assessment – and, more generally, what is, if any, the role for currency 
crises prediction? 
After deeper inquiry one may well be tempted to conclude that if currency crises 
increase (as they most probably do) social loss function, and the authorities have any 
27 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
[15] Common interpretation of the slope coefficients is ∂E(y)/∂x=βx . However the magnitude of E(Δx) 
can vary substantially from model to model obscuring comparison between them. 
[16] For example a typical study should, on average, find that, say, trade balance deficit (current account) 
has a positive influence on the probability of the crisis but it is usually not very significant (average 
t-statistic=0.5). It should have no significance for emerging economies (t-statistic=0, i.e. current account 
doesn't matter) and be highly significant for developed countries (t-statistic around 2). 
[17] There is, however, the possibility for further extensions: the sample composition, time period, etc. 
can also be altered to check for the sensitivity and the significance of the results.
power to influence the state of the economy – so there should be no room for 
currency crises prediction from the point of view of the policymaker. Any information 
contained by any variable should be immediately and continuously incorporated into 
government's (or market's) reaction function in the attempt to avoid currency crash 
(capital losses) and to return on the "balanced path". 
But such a conclusion would be, naturally, premature. When we allow for self-fulfilling 
crises and for problems with expectations coordination then there is nothing wrong with 
a situation that everybody knows the probability of a crash is significant and yet nobody 
withdraws. It is a Perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium based on a balance of beliefs. No one 
wants to be the first to leave profitable market, especially when the timing of a crisis is 
indefinite (compare with an interesting model of Caplin and Leahy (1994)). 
On the side of the policymaker – at any moment the decision to devalue is the 
outcome of his maximization problem [18]. The probability of a crisis usually enters a 
trade-off with the state of the economy the policymaker desires. As a consequence he 
does not want this probability to be zero in general. Instead, he weights costs (sacrifice 
ratios) of adjusting the economy against benefits of the present state, net of the 
expected costs of a crisis. 
This is why we can have significant variables in predicting crisis. This is also 
precisely the role of currency crisis prediction – i.e. to discover the dynamics (statistical 
properties) of such interplay of expectations and its expected outcome (the probability 
and expected magnitude of a crash) conditional on the state of fundamentals. 
The scale of surprise with which the Mexican and especially the Asian crises has 
been welcomed indicates that the job is far from being completed. But on the other 
hand there is not enough data (in quantity and quality), so to speak, not enough well 
described crises episodes so far, to draw precise inferences. 
28 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
[18] In words of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) "most central banks have access to enough foreign exchange 
resources to beat down a speculative attack of any magnitude, provided they are willing to subordinate all the 
other goals of monetary policy." (italics on behalf of OR).
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
29 
Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises 
prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different 
specification of dependent and explaining variables)
30 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 
Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises 
prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different 
specification of dependent and explaining variables) - continued
31 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 
Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises 
prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different 
specification of dependent and explaining variables) - continued
References 
Antczak R. (2000). "Theoretical Aspects of Currency Crises". CASE S&A No. 211. 
Baig T., I. Goldfajn (1999). "Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis". IMF Staff 
papers 46/2. 
Banerjee A. (1992). "A Simple Model of Herd Behaviour". The Quarterly Journal of 
Economics 107, p. 797-817. 
Berg A., C. Patillo (1999). "Predicting Currency Crises, the Indicators Approach and 
an Alternative". Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 561-586. 
Bertola G., L.E.O. Svensson (1993). "Stochastic Devaluation Risk and the Empirical fit 
of Target-zone Models". Review of Economic Studies 60, p. 689-712. 
Bikchandani S., D. Hirshleifer, I. Welsh (1992). "A Theory of Fads, Fashions, Custom and 
Cultural Change as Information Cascades". Journal of Political Economy 100, p. 992-102. 
Blackburn, K., M. Sola, (1993). "Speculative Currency Attacks and Balance-of-payment 
Crises". Journal of Economic Surveys 7, p. 119-44. 
Blanco H., P.M. Garber (1986). "Recurrent Devaluation and Speculative Attacks on 
the Mexican Peso". Journal of Political Economy 94, p. 148-166. 
Calvo G.A., E.G. Mendoza (1996). "Mexico's Balance of Payment Crisis: a Chronicle 
of a Death Foretold". Journal of International Economics 41, p. 235-264. 
Caplin A., J. Leahy (1994). "Business as Usual, Market Crashes, and Wisdom after the 
Fact". American Economic Review 84, p. 549-65. 
Cheung Y., M. Chinn, I.W. Marsh (2000). "How do UK based Foreign Exchange 
Dealers Think their Market Operates?". NBER WP 7524. 
Cooper, R., A. John (1988). "Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynsian Models". 
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103, p. 347-358. 
Cumby R.E., S. van Wijbergen (1989). "Financial Policy and Speculative Runs with a 
Crawling Peg: Argentina 1979-1981". Journal of International Economics 27, p. 111-27. 
Eichengreen B., A. Rose, Ch. Wyplosz (1995). "Exchange Market Mayhem: the 
Antecedants and Aftermath of Speculative Attacks". Economic Policy 21, p. 251-312. 
Eichengreen B., A. Rose, Ch. Wyplosz (1996). "Contagious Currency Crises: First 
Test". Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98, p. 463-484. 
Frankel J.A., A.K. Rose (1996). "Currency Crashes in Emerging Markets; An Empirical 
Treatment". Journal of International Economics 41, p. 351-366. 
Gerlach S., F. Smets (1994). "Contagious Speculative Attacks". CEPR 1055. 
Girton L., D. Roper (1977). "A monetary Model of Exchange Market Pressure Applied 
to Postwar Canadian Experience". American Economic Review 67, p. 537-48. 
32 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
Glick R., A. Rose (1999). "Contagion and Trade: Why are Currency Crises Regional?". 
Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 603-17. 
Goldfajn I., R.O. Valdes (1997). "Are Currency Crises Predictable?". IMF WP 97/159. 
Jeanne O. (1997). "Are Currency Crises Self-fulfilling? A Test". Journal of International 
Economics 43, p. 263-286. 
Jeanne O. (1999). "Currency Crises, a Perspective on Recent Theoretical 
Development". CEPR 2170. 
Krugman P. (1979). "A Model of Balance-of-payment Crises". Journal of Money Credit 
and Banking 11, 3, p. 311-325. 
Krugman, P. (1996). "Are Currency Crises Self-fulfilling?". NBER Macroeconomic 
Annual, Cambridge, MIT Press. 
Kaminsky G., C. Reinhard (1996). "The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and 
Balance of Payment Problems". Board of Governors FRS, IFDP 544. 
Kaminsky G., Lizondo, C. Reinhart (1998). "Leading Indicators of Currency Crises". 
IMF. 
Lyrio M., H. Dewachter (1999). "Multiple Equilibria and the Credibility of the Brazilian 
Crawling Peg". 1995-1998, CES-KUL. 
Masson, P. (1998). "Contagion, Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, ans Jumps between 
Multiple Equilibria". IMF WP 98/142. 
Masson, P. (1999). "Contagion: Macroeconomic Model with Multiple Equilibria". 
Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 587-602. 
Obstfeld, M. (1986). "Rational and Self-fulfilling Balance-of-payment Crises". 
American Economic Review 76, p. 72-81. 
Obstfeld, M. (1994). "The Logic of Currency Crises". Cahiers économiques et 
monétaires 43, p. 189-213. 
Obstfeld, M. (1996). "Models of Currency Crises with Self-fulfilling Features". 
European Economic Review 40, p. 1037-47. 
Obstfeld M., K. Rogoff (1995). "The Mirage of Fixed Exchange Rates". Journal of 
Economic Perspectives 9, p. 73-96. 
Salant S.W., D.W. Henderson (1978). "Market Anticipation of Government Policies 
and the Price of Gold". Journal of Political Economy 86, p. 627-648. 
Tomczyñska M. (2000). "Early Indicators of Currency Crises". Review of some 
literature, CASE S&A No. 208. 
33 
Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
34 
170 Gerhard Fink, Peter R. Haiss, Lucjan T. Or³owski, Privilege Interim/Bank 
Relationship in Central Europe: Trigger or Tap for Corporate Governance 
171 Ma³gorzata Markiewicz, Urban Górski, Marta Dekhtiarchuk, Monetary Policy in 
Ukraine in 1996-1999 
172  ,
,
1994-1998   . 
173 Magdalena Tomczyñska, European Union Financial Transfers to Applicant 
Countries 
174 # $%

More Related Content

What's hot

The capitalist world system performance in recent period
The capitalist world system performance in recent periodThe capitalist world system performance in recent period
The capitalist world system performance in recent periodFernando Alcoforado
 
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...AI Publications
 
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...pkconference
 
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...iosrjce
 
Journal paper 1
Journal paper 1Journal paper 1
Journal paper 1crmbasel
 
EconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftEconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftJames Supeene
 
Zimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policyZimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policySABC News
 
Imf working paper
Imf working paperImf working paper
Imf working paperslimpick333
 
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economies
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African EconomiesThe Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economies
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economiespaperpublications3
 
Note classical
Note classicalNote classical
Note classicalranil2010
 
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014Viara G. Bojkova
 
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...Associate Professor in VSB Coimbatore
 
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...Joannes Mongardini
 
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...Palkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 

What's hot (20)

The capitalist world system performance in recent period
The capitalist world system performance in recent periodThe capitalist world system performance in recent period
The capitalist world system performance in recent period
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 209 - What Factors led to the Asian Financi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 209 - What Factors led to the Asian Financi...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 209 - What Factors led to the Asian Financi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 209 - What Factors led to the Asian Financi...
 
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...
Non-monetary effects Employee performance during Financial Crises in the Kurd...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 411 - The Global Financial Crisis and its I...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 411 - The Global Financial Crisis and its I...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 411 - The Global Financial Crisis and its I...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 411 - The Global Financial Crisis and its I...
 
Financial structure, financial develop and banking fragility, international e...
Financial structure, financial develop and banking fragility, international e...Financial structure, financial develop and banking fragility, international e...
Financial structure, financial develop and banking fragility, international e...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
 
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...
Crisis Perception in Financial Media Discourse : A concrete application throu...
 
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...
Foundations of Financial Sector Mechanisms and Economic Growth in Emerging Ec...
 
Journal paper 1
Journal paper 1Journal paper 1
Journal paper 1
 
EconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftEconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraft
 
Zimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policyZimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policy
 
Imf working paper
Imf working paperImf working paper
Imf working paper
 
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economies
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African EconomiesThe Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economies
The Role of Banks in the Propagation of External Shocks to African Economies
 
Note classical
Note classicalNote classical
Note classical
 
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014
Japanese Short Term Interest Rates-2014
 
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...
Different Level of Financial Development and Individual’s Decision Regarding ...
 
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...
Mitigating the Deadly Embrace in Financial Cycles: Countercyclical Buffers an...
 
1579-3152-2-PB
1579-3152-2-PB1579-3152-2-PB
1579-3152-2-PB
 
ECON 4AA3 Bubble Research
ECON 4AA3 Bubble ResearchECON 4AA3 Bubble Research
ECON 4AA3 Bubble Research
 
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...
The Boom and the Depression: An Analysis within the Aggregate-Demand - Aggreg...
 

Viewers also liked

Putting Out an Electrical Fire
Putting Out an Electrical Fire Putting Out an Electrical Fire
Putting Out an Electrical Fire auswebsolutionss
 
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data Policy
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data PolicyJohn Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data Policy
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data PolicyWiley
 
Proposed NJ Recycling Museum
Proposed NJ Recycling MuseumProposed NJ Recycling Museum
Proposed NJ Recycling Museumcrimeinparis
 
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong Learning
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong LearningDeep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong Learning
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong LearningDana Longley
 
CNP Company overview
CNP Company overviewCNP Company overview
CNP Company overviewbwainscott
 
wedding photography and videography
wedding photography and videographywedding photography and videography
wedding photography and videographydavidericjerry
 
I have a dream to tell
I have a dream to tellI have a dream to tell
I have a dream to tellElkass Sannoh
 

Viewers also liked (9)

Putting Out an Electrical Fire
Putting Out an Electrical Fire Putting Out an Electrical Fire
Putting Out an Electrical Fire
 
JRres3nophone
JRres3nophoneJRres3nophone
JRres3nophone
 
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data Policy
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data PolicyJohn Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data Policy
John Rolfe - Editor Case Study: Implementing a Journal Data Policy
 
Proposed NJ Recycling Museum
Proposed NJ Recycling MuseumProposed NJ Recycling Museum
Proposed NJ Recycling Museum
 
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong Learning
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong LearningDeep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong Learning
Deep Diving into the Heart of Lifelong Learning
 
Thomas_Sarkis_Resume
Thomas_Sarkis_ResumeThomas_Sarkis_Resume
Thomas_Sarkis_Resume
 
CNP Company overview
CNP Company overviewCNP Company overview
CNP Company overview
 
wedding photography and videography
wedding photography and videographywedding photography and videography
wedding photography and videography
 
I have a dream to tell
I have a dream to tellI have a dream to tell
I have a dream to tell
 

Similar to CASE Network Studies and Analyses 224 - Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions

LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusLA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusDavid J Dingus
 
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...Economist
 
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Grupo de Economia Política IE-UFRJ
 
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Grupo de Economia Política IE-UFRJ
 
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dino
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dinoCashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dino
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dinoDino, llc
 
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1Cashflow fluiddynamics 1
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1Dino, llc
 
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...AI Publications
 
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To Asia
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To AsiaAsia Paul Krugman What Happened To Asia
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To AsiaFaizul Hyun Jea
 
Liquidity and liquidity risks
Liquidity and liquidity risksLiquidity and liquidity risks
Liquidity and liquidity risksStudsPlanet.com
 
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunch
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunchFinancial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunch
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunchFINALIANCE
 
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeria
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeriaImpact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeria
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeriaAlexander Decker
 
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista, 2011 Global Financial Crisis
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista,  2011 Global Financial CrisisProfessor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista,  2011 Global Financial Crisis
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista, 2011 Global Financial CrisisEconomist
 
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?Dr. Ivo Pezzuto
 
E275060
E275060E275060
E275060aijbm
 

Similar to CASE Network Studies and Analyses 224 - Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions (20)

Crisis prevention and management: What worked in the 2008/09 crisis?
Crisis prevention and management: What worked in the 2008/09 crisis?Crisis prevention and management: What worked in the 2008/09 crisis?
Crisis prevention and management: What worked in the 2008/09 crisis?
 
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusLA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 429 - The International Crisis and Latin Am...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 429 - The International Crisis and Latin Am...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 429 - The International Crisis and Latin Am...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 429 - The International Crisis and Latin Am...
 
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista Effects of the Economic Crisis in Latin Ame...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 204 - The Banking and Currency Crises in Bu...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 204 - The Banking and Currency Crises in Bu...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 204 - The Banking and Currency Crises in Bu...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 204 - The Banking and Currency Crises in Bu...
 
bankruptcy testing analysis
bankruptcy testing analysisbankruptcy testing analysis
bankruptcy testing analysis
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 241 - Inflation and Monetary Policy in Russ...
 
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
 
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
Country-Risk Premium in the Periphery and the International Financial Cycle 1...
 
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dino
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dinoCashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dino
CashflowFluiDynamics.icv_dino
 
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1Cashflow fluiddynamics 1
Cashflow fluiddynamics 1
 
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...
Financial crisis: Non-monetary factors influencing Employee performance at ba...
 
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To Asia
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To AsiaAsia Paul Krugman What Happened To Asia
Asia Paul Krugman What Happened To Asia
 
Liquidity and liquidity risks
Liquidity and liquidity risksLiquidity and liquidity risks
Liquidity and liquidity risks
 
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunch
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunchFinancial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunch
Financial crisis, bank behaviour and credit crunch
 
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeria
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeriaImpact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeria
Impact of injection and withdrawal of money stock on economic growth in nigeria
 
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista, 2011 Global Financial Crisis
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista,  2011 Global Financial CrisisProfessor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista,  2011 Global Financial Crisis
Professor Alejandro Diaz-Bautista, 2011 Global Financial Crisis
 
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?
Ivo Pezzuto - Predictable and Avoidable: What's Next?
 
E275060
E275060E275060
E275060
 
Post Standart
Post StandartPost Standart
Post Standart
 

More from CASE Center for Social and Economic Research

More from CASE Center for Social and Economic Research (20)

In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
 
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencjePraca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
 
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economyThe retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
 
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economyProblems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
 
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
 
Informal employment and wages in Poland
Informal employment and wages in PolandInformal employment and wages in Poland
Informal employment and wages in Poland
 
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
 
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final ReportStudy and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
 
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to GoIncreasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
 
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
 
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
 
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii EuropejskiejNasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
 
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European UnionOur Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
 
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
 
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
 
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
 
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
 
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for PolandEstonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
 
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
 
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final ReportStudy and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
 

Recently uploaded

VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...
VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...
VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...Suhani Kapoor
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxanshikagoel52
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfAdnet Communications
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Commonwealth
 
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Serviceranjana rawat
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130 Available With Roomdivyansh0kumar0
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...Suhani Kapoor
 
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779Delhi Call girls
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School DesignsInstant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designsegoetzinger
 
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignHenry Tapper
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikCall Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesMarketing847413
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...makika9823
 
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service AizawlVip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawlmakika9823
 
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewNew dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewAntonis Zairis
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingMaristelaRamos12
 

Recently uploaded (20)

VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...
VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...
VIP Call Girls in Saharanpur Aarohi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Sah...
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
 
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(TANVI) Call Girls Nanded City ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
 
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Jodhpur Park 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
 
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 18 Call Me: 8448380779
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School DesignsInstant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
 
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaignLog your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
Log your LOA pain with Pension Lab's brilliant campaign
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
Independent Lucknow Call Girls 8923113531WhatsApp Lucknow Call Girls make you...
 
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service AizawlVip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
Vip B Aizawl Call Girls #9907093804 Contact Number Escorts Service Aizawl
 
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business ReviewNew dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
New dynamic economic model with a digital footprint | European Business Review
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
 
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of MarketingQuarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
Quarter 4- Module 3 Principles of Marketing
 

CASE Network Studies and Analyses 224 - Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions

  • 1. 2 2 4 Marcin Sasin Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions W a r s a w , 2 0 0 1
  • 2. Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect Author’s point of view and not necessarily those of CASE. This paper was prepared for the research project No. 0144/H02/99/17 entitled "Analiza przyczyn i przebiegu kryzysów walutowych w krajach Azji, Ameryki £aciñskiej i Europy OErodkowo - Wschodniej: wnioski dla Polski i innych krajów transformuj¹cych siê" (Analysis of the Causes and Progress of Currency Crises in Asian, Latin American and CEE Countries: Conclusions for Poland and Other Transition Countries" financed by the State Committee for Scientific Research (KBN) in the years 1999 - 2001. The publication was financed by Rabobank Polska SA. © CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2001 Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN 83-7178-246-2 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research ul. Sienkiewicza 12, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland tel.: (4822) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax (4822) 828 60 69 e-mail: case@case.com.pl www.case.com.pl
  • 3. Contents Abstract 5 Introduction 6 1. Predicting Currency Crises 7 1.1. Model Specification 7 1.2. Data, Methodology and the Results 18 2. The Universality of the Results 23 2.1. Crisis Definition 23 2.2. The Significance of Fundamentals 26 3. Conclusions 27 References 32
  • 4. Marcin Sasin Marcin Sasin (born 1974) joined CASE Foundation in 2000. He is an economist specializing in international financial economics and monetary policy issues. He obtained Master of Science in Economics at the Catholic University of Leuven, Belgium in 2000 and he also holds MA in Oriental Studies from the Warsaw University. 4 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
  • 5. Abstract Informative content of macroeconomic fundamentals with respect to currency crisis prediction is reassessed for the period of 1990s on the panel of 46 developed and emerging economies. In the first part the paper develops a model for currency crisis prediction. The distinction is made between variables emphasized by 'first generation' and 'second generation' models. Special attention is directed towards multiple equilibria and contagion phenomena. Considerable amount of predictability is found, particularly on behalf of standard leading crisis indicators, such as overvaluation of the real exchange rate and the level of foreign exchange reserves. Multiple equilibria don't get much support from the data while contagion effect is obviously working – apparently through various channels. In the second part the relationship between model specification and the significance of coefficients is investigated in the attempt to ultimately evaluate what can be expected from empirical implementation of crisis prediction. An average predictive power of such models and employed variables is assessed. 5 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
  • 6. Introduction This paper reassesses the informative content of macroeconomic fundamentals with respect to currency crisis prediction for the period of 1990s on the panel of 46 developed and emerging economies. The distinction is made between variables emphasized by "first generation" and "second generation" models. Special attention is directed towards multiple equilibria and contagion phenomena. In the second part of the paper the relationship between model specification and the significance of coefficients is investigated. This is done in an attempt to ultimately evaluate what can be expected from empirical implementation of crisis prediction. From theoretical point of view the idea that currency crises need not necessarily be irrational and unpredictable events, as they might have been regarded, emerged around Krugman (1979). The so-called "first generation" models have been developed – in which unsustainable policies of the authorities led to a currency crisis. The theory emphasized a set of variables that were responsible for crisis eruption – they are called "hard fundamentals" and include domestic credit (expansion), foreign exchange reserves, budget balance (deficits) etc. Starting in mid-1980s but especially after unexpected ERM crisis in 1992–93 economists switched attention to so-called "second generation" models, which introduced an optimizing government and an "escape clause" in its policy. Second generation models identified a new set of variables that could be responsible for crises – actually any variable that enters government decision whether to defend the exchange rate or not, especially domestic economic and political situation (inflation, unemployment) should be monitored. New and interesting phenomena these models could account for include multiple equilibria and contagion. They have been particularly popular in explaining recent crisis and obtain special attention in this paper. Finally, after Asian, Russian and Brazilian crisis some economist claim that a new brand of crises emerged – "third generation" – one of their characteristics is an important role played by microeconomic factors. For more extensive treatment of the theoretical background of currency crises see Antczak (2000). Empirical literature concerning systematical prediction and explanation of currency crises has flourished recently but is rather limited in success. Tomczyñska (2000) as well as Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1998) provide a good survey. 6 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
  • 7. 1. Predicting Currency Crises 1.1. Model Specification In this chapter the model for crisis prediction and explanation is built. Theory provides the list of fundamentals that can be endowed with an informative content. As both the two main approaches to currency crises presented by the "first" and the "second" generation models are encompassed – the model includes the standard "hard" and measurable fundamentals (the usual macroeconomic variables) as well as some approximation of multiple equilibria and contagion. In the analysis following instruments are employed: – Real exchange rate, measured as a deviation from purchasing power parity; – Foreign exchange reserves level, measured in years of import that can be purchased by it; – Trade balance, expressed as a dummy variable of one if the deficit exceeds 5%, a number roughly regarded as a frontier of safe sustainability; – Government surplus, as a surplus to GDP ratio; – Domestic credit, described relatively to GDP; – Inflation; – Unemployment; – Output level, in a form of a squared output gap (deviation of the GDP from a linear trend in % squared). The basis for such specification is a priori presumption that both economic depression and a state of excessive economic boom can be potentially unattractive and supposedly dangerous for the investor in a given currency; – Short term foreign liabilities expressed as a ratio of foreign private bank claims due within a year to foreign exchange reserves. The unbalanced maturity of foreign obligations became the most direct cause of the Mexican crisis in 1994–95; – The level of non-bank financial institution activity measured as a percentage of total country's deposits in hands of those institutions. The moral hazard exercised by such financial intermediaries in the absence of sufficient banking control is frequently blamed for the severity of the Southeast Asian collapse in 1997–98; – The level of international interest rate as the average of the US and German treasury bill rate. This variable can supposedly account for contemporaneous breakdown of many exchange rates, what can seemingly look like a contagion, and what actually is not a contagion; 7 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
  • 8. – Exchange rate regime type in a form of a set of two dummy variables – one for managed float and one for currency peg leaving purely flexible exchange rate as a reference category [1]; – Multiple equilibria as dummy variable of one if there exist a possibility of self-fulfilling currency crash; – Sensitivity to contagion due to trade link measured as the impairment of competitiveness caused by the crisis elsewhere; – Sensitivity to contagion due to informational spillovers and herding behavior. The last three instruments require further explanation. 1.1.1. Multiple Equilibria This variable is obtained from the extension of Jeanne (1997) model to all countries included in this study. There is barely any fundamental so hard to measure as the possibility of multiple equilibria. However Jeanne argues that specific behavior of the short-term interest rate, regarded as the reflection of the devaluation expectations can be interpreted as the manifestation of multiple equilibria. In what follows I track Jeanne's model as well as Lyrio and Dewachter's (1999) application. In many second generation models with optimizing government the net benefit of maintaining fixed exchange rate at period t can be expressed as (1) B b e τ = τ −απ τ −1 where bτ is the gross benefit of the fixed peg depending solely on underlying macroeconomic fundamentals, and πe τ−1 is the probability that the government decides to abandon exchange rate evaluated by the private sector in the preceding period. This is only the simplest formulation of the fact that net benefit of the peg depends also on how credible is the peg itself. To illustrate that point suppose that unemployment (the fundamental) enters (negatively) into government objective function. Unemployment itself is determined (at least partly) by the nominal arrangements made within private sector (let's say workers and employers). These arrangements are conditioned on the expectations concerning government action (to devalue or not). So the only way to increase employment above natural level is to surprise private sector with unexpected devaluation. Facing high devaluation expectation and not devaluing is equivalent to unexpected revaluation, which in turn drastically raises unemployment. Such 8 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [1] Currency board dummy doesn't exhibit enough variation to be included.
  • 9. interaction of expectations is a common way of obtaining multiple equilibria. We assume that the net benefit of the peg (the state of fundamental) obeys the following simple stochastic process. (2) where the innovation ετ is independently and identically distributed and characterized by typical, well behaved, bell shaped density function and associated cumulative distribution function F. It is common knowledge that government devalues if and only if net benefit is negative and at the same time the government has such a political will. This will is observable and happens with a probability μ. If the government doesn't exhibit such a will it defends the exchange rate at every cost. Therefore we can express the probability at time τ of a currency crisis in the next period as: (3) but from (1) and (2) Bτ+1< 0 is equivalent to (4) hence (5) In the rational expectations we have to assume that πe τ=πτ . Private sector's expectations must be validated in equilibrium, otherwise they would be altered. Denoting φτ = Eτbτ+1 which represents the overall (expected next period) state of the economy – "the" fundamental – equation (5) becomes (6) We introduce two simplifying assumptions: 1 2 − s 2 2 φ e σ s – F ≡ Fσ(φ)= , i.e. the innovation to fundamental has normal distribution with mean zero and standard deviation σ. 9 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... bτ = Eτ −1bτ + ετ π τ = μ Prτ (Bτ +1 < 0) ετ +1 <απ τ − Eτ bτ +1 e πτ = μ Prτ (ετ +1 <απ τe − Eτ bτ +1 ) π τ = μFσ (απ τ −φτ ) 2πσ ∫ ∂ −∞
  • 10. – α=1. Because φ is a compounded fundamental it is always possible to scale down α to unity by scaling at the same time the composition weights as well. It is not only a simplification – the necessary condition for parameter identification requires an additional constraint on one of the parameters in the argument of F. Nonlinear equation (6) can have one, two (not generic, so we ignore this), or three solutions. This idea can be summarized in the following way: 1. If the slope of a distribution function at inflection point does not exceed unity [2] the number of solutions to this equation is always one for the whole range of fundamentals. No multiple equilibria exist. 2. If the slope (at inflection point) exceeds unity three cases are possible: – for the fundamental lower (worse) than some critical value φl only one equilibrium l π exist φ– it is high (bad) equilibrium when the probability of devaluation is high, – for the fundamental higher (better) than some critical value φh only one equilibrium π exist – it is low (good) equilibrium when the probability of devaluation is low, – for fundamentals between and φh that is in the certain and well specified range there are three solution corresponding to three equilibria {π1,π2,π3} high, medium and low [3]. Figure 1 presents the reasoning more clearly. On the left panel straight 45o line and a curve of the normal cumulative distribution represent respectively left and right hand side of equation (6) and must equal at solution. Right panel is the same analysis transferred into φ − π space. The curve consists of all pairs (φ, {π1,π2,π3}) or (φ, π) that solve (6). For every country in my sample I estimate the following model: (7) (8) (9) π τ =πˆτ +ητ πˆτ = μFσ (πˆτ −φτ ) φτ =γ ′ ⋅ xτ where the vector xτ contain relevant components of macroeconomic fundamental, such as real exchange rate, trade balance to GDP ratio, the level of foreign exchange reserves measured in billions of dollars and a constant, γ is a vector of parameters, parameter μ is the probability of the occurrence of a political will to devalue, σ is a parameter for the standard deviation of the cumulative distribution function. ητ is a prediction error which is assumed to be independently, identically, normally distributed with mean zero and a standard deviation of ση. 10 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [2] The slope is maximal at the inflection point, so in this case the slope never exceeds unity. [3] The medium equilibrium π2 has an undesirable property of positive correlation between the fundamental and the devaluation probability. It is also dynamically unstable and mainly for that reason it will be ignored in the rest of the analysis.
  • 11. There is a need for a time series of devaluation probabilities (π 's) to exercise the estimation. These probabilities are assumed to be roughly equal to the interest rate differential on short maturities (money market rate) [4]. It is also essential to make assumption about the magnitude of devaluation expected by private sector to happen at the crisis. It was set to unconditional mean real overvaluation of the currency [5]. The estimation was carried over by means of the maximum likelihood method by maximizing: (10) 11 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Figure 1. Solutions to πτ = μμFσ(απτ−φτ) Source:              μ σ γ σ η π   2 − T  − u d e T   −       2 Σ =      1 min ˆ 2 2  1 , ˆ 1 ( 2 ) max , , ση τ πτ πτ πτ πτ [4]To get "pure" devaluation probabilities interest rate differentials have to be adjusted by expected change in the (explicit or implicit) trend – this is particularly important in the case of a crawling peg or a managed float. Where the trend (rate of currency depreciation) is not explicitly stated by the monetary authorities the implicit trend has been first estimated. It would be also reasonable to adjust interest rates for the expected rate change relative to the trend. Although the exact theoretical behavior of the exchange rate within bands (at least in target zone models) is highly nonlinear, Bertola and Svensson (1993) argue that this behavior is characterized by strong mean (trend) reversion and can be well approximated by the first order autoregressive process. To correct for this they propose so-called "drift adjustment" method. This method is not, however, used in this paper as it produces implausible values for devaluation probabilites. [5] If that turned out to be negative – to the average realized devaluation provided it exceeded two standard deviations of the usual rate change. The minimum and maximum expected devaluations have been constrained to 5 % (10% for currency boards) and 25% respectively.
  • 12. uτ πˆ d where T equals number of observations and , πˆτ are two extreme π 's solving (8) at τ given γ, μ and σ. If necessary (if only one equilibrium exists) . u d πˆτ = πˆτ After the coefficients have been obtained the critical range and fitted values of the l fundamental were φcomputed. The dummy variable capturing multiple equilibria possibility was set to one if and only if inferred compounded fundamental for a given country in a given period was between critical values and φh. The analysis has, of course, many drawbacks. First, it assumes that changes in interest rate differentials without respective changes in the fundamental are necessarily reflections of the multiple equilibria phenomenon but it does not have to be the case [6]. Second, it assumes a specific, namely normal, distribution function for innovation to the fundamental – this assumption is rather crucial for obtaining multiple equilibria. Finally in some cases, judging from log-likelihood comparison, just the linear model of devaluation probability performed apparently better. Some sample results from estimating the model are presented in Figure 2 on the following page. Vertical axis indicates devaluation probabilities, horizontal axis represents the value of compounded fundamental [7]. Curves represent inferred relationship between devaluation probability and fundamentals, dots – observations. 1.1.2. Contagion This paper distinguishes between two sources of contagion, namely trade-link contagion and informational spillovers. The idea that trade links play important role in the spread of currency crises is well justified theoretically [e.g. Gerlach and Smets, 1994; Masson, 1999] and empirically [Glick and Rose, 1999] as well. There are several types of links that can be identified. For our analysis let's denote by X the country in question and by N the set of all other countries engaged in the foreign trade, ΨXY the trade (export) volume that goes from X to Y, ΔY devaluation of country Y (measured in relation to X). Ψ = XY XY ω Let's also denote – the importance of country Y for country X Σ∈Ψ J N XJ measured as Y's weight in X's export basket. 12 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [6] For example in credible currency boards changes in the interest rate may reflect fluctuations in liquidity, as the authorities do not engage in interest rate smoothing – see the case of Estonia in Figure 2. [7] The axis is scaled by the maximization procedure to fit the shape of the curve, so absolute values of the fundamental are country-specific and have no meaning for comparison between countries.
  • 13. 13 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Figure 2. Sample results from multiple equilibria estimation. (Dots represent observations, curves represent inferred relationship between the fundamental and devaluation probability. If slope at inflection>1 there is a possibility of multiple equilibria)
  • 14. The simplest channel of contagion is the direct loss of competitiveness in bilateral trade. It can be expressed as: (11) TcX ω XY Y 1 This simple formula says that country X's loss of direct bilateral competitiveness is equal to the amount X's partner has devalued times the importance of that partner in X's export basket and this summed over all X's trade (export) partners. Other, more comprehensive measure of trade links is the index of a competitiveness loss on export markets. It is expressed as (12) ΣΨ Δ Country K is X's export partner. The right fraction represents the (minus) average price of K's import. It is equal to total K's import volume weighted by its (minus) prices, (i.e. exchange rates of countries exporting to K) divided by total K's import volume. When countries that export to K devalue, and X does not – X's competitiveness become severely impaired. This is again multiplied by the importance of K in X's export basket and summed over all X's trade partners. This index can be refined to control for the extent to which countries compete on export markets: 14 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin Figure 2. Sample results from multiple equilibria estimation. (Dots represent observations, curves represent inferred relationship between the fundamental and devaluation probability. If slope at inflection>1 there is a possibility of multiple equilibria) – continued = Σ Δ Y∈N Σ ΣΨ = ∈ ∈ ∈ K N Y N YK Y N YK Y TcX ω XK 2
  • 15. (13)     Ψ −Ψ Σ Σ ∈ ∈ −      XK YK 3 ω 1 X Y XK Tc = Δ − Y N K N Y XK YK      Ψ + Ψ { } It exploits the fact that not all X's competitors are of equal importance. Countries of a very different size seldom fiercely compete (on average) in the world trade. X would be mostly concerned about competitors that are of similar size, from similar region, producing similar goods for similar markets. Y is X's competitor. The term inside brackets expresses the degree of similarity of X's and Y's export volume to country K. It is presupposed that similar export volume to K can approximate similar export patterns of X and Y and therefore the degree of their competition on K's market. For given Y, it is weight-summed over all markets K that X and Y compete on, and then multiplied by Y's devaluation (X's loss of competition) and again summed over all X competitors. Further possibilities to refine the index of competitiveness loss, e.g. by splitting total trade into sectors, introducing export elasticities into the analysis, etc., are, of course, unlimited. I employ the last formulation as the approximation of exposure to trade-link-caused contagion. It seems the most sophisticated and appealing out of the mentioned three. For example trade links between Southeast Asian region are by no means that developed, as the links of individual SE Asian countries with the rest of the world [8]. Additional (but not very significant) three modifications are made: – instead of devaluation itself, I'm using my 0–1 crisis index (as explained below) to make it compatible with the rest of the analysis; – as I'm not interested in competitiveness loss contemporaneous to the crisis (that would severely bias the analysis towards finding trade link contagion) I proceed as follow: X's competitor devaluation (crisis) is set to one if and only if that country has had a crisis during past three periods; – one has also to notice that different countries react differently to equal devaluation by the whole set of countries (this happens for example because not all 200 or so world countries are included in the analysis). To correct for that I divide by (14) 15 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...   Ψ − Ψ XK YK Σ Σ     3 ω 1 ScaleX XK = − Y∈N K∈N − { X , Y } Ψ XK + Ψ YK [8] For example, Thai export to its biggest trade partner in the region and a neighbor – Malaysia (excluding Singapore and Hong-Kong for a moment) – was in 1997 equal roughly 12% of a combined export to the US and Japan – the biggest importers from Southeast Asia.
  • 16. 16 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin Another source of contagion can be so-called informational spillovers. That factor arises due to following reasons: – it is costly to monitor possibly infinite set of relevant macroeconomic fundamentals. Instead investor can rely on the behavior of other presumably better informed market participants. Calvo and Mendoza (1996) notice that the more diversified the investor is the less become the marginal gain from gathering information about portfolio components. That makes investors very sensible to small amount of information and can result in "herding behavior" or "information cascades"; – the rules of the game in financial market, or the state of common knowledge, the level of expectations, or the government response function, or other important piece of information can be unclear or missing. Krugman (1996) shows that if the authorities preferences are not publicly observed investors might test it by a speculative attack - then observe which attack has been successful and which has failed, and learn on that basis. In Shiller (1995) investors differently interpret information and are unsure about other investors interpretation. Therefore market reaction to a piece of news provides information about the way how other information should be interpreted and can possibly lead to drastic changes in expectations and to overreaction. I know of no empirical paper testing such a contagion channel. This is an ad-hoc attempt to fill the gap. I base my informational-spillover-caused-contagion-possibility index on the assumption that a crisis in country X reveals information that crises in general are more likely in countries characterized by similar fundamentals as X. Countries that are similar to a crisis country X are immediately attacked by investors trying to profit (or escape capital losses) from possible crisis - before others turn against that country as well. It is computed as: (15) ( ) Δ f f f f min , X Y Y X Y ( ) Σ Σ Y N Σ Σ f ∈ F ∈ min , I ∈ N ∪ X J ∈ N − I ∪ X 1 + = f f f f I J J I X N Inf spill { } { } { } 1 . where ƒx is a value of fundamental ƒ in country X, ΔY (as in trade contagion case) equals one if Y has had a crisis during past three periods, and zero otherwise. Before I sum over all fundamentals ƒ ∈ F (the set of fundamentals) I scale it to achieve comparability between fundamentals. 1.1.3. The Dependent Variable – Crisis Index The problem with a choice of crisis period is obvious and not trivial. The key decision is either crisis periods should be hand-picked by experienced researcher
  • 17. 17 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... basing on his knowledge, financial press and common beliefs, or should they be an outcome of a rigorous procedure in which only objective and measurable characteristic enter the choice function. Both methods have advantages and disadvantages, and the conflict between them if far from being resolved. This paper takes the latter approach. This decision is, of course not, the end of a difficult and controversial selection process. There is a need to find a method to transform macroeconomic fundamentals into crisis indicator. As Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz (1996) correctly note "currency crises cannot be identified [only] with actual devaluations (…) for two reasons: First, not all speculative attacks are successful. The currency may be supported through the expenditure of reserves (…). Alternatively the authorities may repel attacks by rising interest rates. (…) Ideally, an index of speculative pressure would be obtained by employing a structural model of exchange rate determination, from which one would derive the excess demand for foreign exchange." So the speculative attack can manifest itself via three not mutually exclusive channels: currency devaluation, foreign exchange reserves losses and sharp increases in (short term) interest rates. It became somehow common in the literature to use so- -called exchange market pressure index [after Girton and Roper, 1977]. It is an average of the changes in the above mentioned three components weighted by respective standard deviations (so their contribution become comparable). Crisis is said to happen if that index exceeds certain threshold – usually its mean plus some number times its standard deviation. It is not very surprising that different authors use different version. Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz use the mean plus 1.5 times the standard deviation; Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1998) require the index to be 3 standard deviations above its mean. Some authors regress the index itself. In defining crisis I proceed as follows: – I construct exchange market pressure index as the standard-deviation-weighted average of changes in (log) exchange rate, (log) reserves (with a minus sign), and short term interest rate. At period τ change is measured not from period τ−1, but from the average of periods τ−3, τ−2 and τ−1. That is because in times of turmoil these variables get unusually volatile – it smoothes the behavior of the index and make it consistent with itself. For currency boards exchange rate change doesn't enter the index. – crisis dummy variable is set to one if and only if exchange market pressure index exceeds 2.25 its standard deviation above its mean (2.25 is halfway in-between 1.5 and 3) and at least one of the components has an absolute change of at least 1.5% (that excludes small changes in very stable countries, e.g. Netherlands, from being interpreted as crises).
  • 18. 18 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin 1.2. Data, Methodology and the Results I'm working on an unbalanced panel of 46 developed and emerging economies [9] observed monthly from January of 1990 until March 1999. Most of the data comes from International Monetary Fund's International Financial Statistics CD-ROM. Another large part is taken from OECD's Main Economic Indicators. Data on short-term debt comes from BIS/IMF/OECD/WB project. Some of the data are taken from financial informational services like Reuters or Bloomberg. IMF's reports Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions have been studied to extract information about exchange rate arrangement for regime dummy variables. Data on foreign trade comes from IMF Directions of Trade Statistics. A lot of missing observation has been completed thanks to Internet sites of National Central Banks and National Statistical Offices. Still, the data is severely constrained by missing observation, and the requirement that all variables' time series must be of the same length within the country – all the incomplete observations has been discarded. The data has been then visually inspected for notorious mistakes, which has been corrected. There were some problems with data frequency – mainly with GDP, which usually is not collected monthly. It has been overcome by approximating GDP with industrial production. This basis has been further contracted by the requirement of comparability. Particularly: – data on emerging countries from Central and Eastern Europe has been restricted not to begin before January 1994, – data on some Western European countries that entered the EMS or started a peg (reasonably short period) after January 1990 has been cut to start at their accession (beginning of the peg), – data on emerging countries from Latin America start right after they have suppressed the hyperinflation and implemented stabilization plans, – for some countries data has been set to begin at the time that a country in question abandoned dual exchange rate system, and unified both rates, – for countries that presently form the EMU time series end on December 1998, – some data has been additionally dropped in the estimation procedure due to insufficient variation. [9] Argentina, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Colombia, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Hong-Kong (SAR), Hungary, Iceland, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Korea, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Thailand, Turkey, United Kingdom.
  • 19. The statistical method of the analysis has naturally far reaching consequences for the results. Apart from the graphical analysis, "visual" or "narrative" approaches, or univariate maximizations there are two main and popular methods for estimating currency crisis prediction models, namely: simple linear regression and probit models. In this study I employ panel data fixed effects linear specification. The motivation is as follows: – such model allows the appreciation of differences between countries and sufficiently exploits within as well as between dimension of the data, – it is of no importance that this model allows the inferred crisis index to exceed one, or to be negative, as long as one doesn't interpret crisis index as the probability of a crisis, – linear and probit/logit based binary choice models usually give similar qualitative results unless the variable in question is of low or no significance, – probit/logit models put rather tight distributional assumptions on the error term structure. Nevertheless, as a benchmark, I also employ also a probit model. Summing up I estimate the following models: (16) where xi,τ denotes the vector of regressors (macroeconomic fundamentals, constant excluded), β denotes the vector of coefficients, αi denotes country specific intercept term, κ is a constant, ηi,τ is an error term – distributed independently and identically over time and over countries, with mean zero and a standard deviation of ση.The model is estimated by means of the OLS. as well as (17) (18) (19) ∗ C ↔ > 1 0 Crisisi τ = ∗ C ∗ =κ + xi′,τ β + ε i.τ (probit model) with C* as a latent state variable, and εi,τ distributed standard normally, independently and identically over time and over countries. The model is estimated with the maximum likelihood. I also estimate the model for each of the two subsamples i.e. emerging and developed economies for better inference and interpretation. 19 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Crisisi,τ = κ + α i + xi′,τ β + η i.τ Crisisi,τ = Pr (Crisisi,τ =1) +ηi.τ    ↔ < 0 0 , C
  • 20. The results are summarized in Table 1. In interpretation that follows I will base myself mainly on the coefficients obtained from linear regression. First of all, it is clearly visible that real exchange rate and the level of foreign exchange reserves – standard and well identified variables of the "first generation" models as well as any empirical model employed to predict crises – has allover the predicted sign and unquestionable significance. This finding is in line with almost all empirical testing of crisis determinants. It is also important to recognize the differences in magnitude and significance of those two variables between subsamples. The RER overvaluation impact and importance is much lower for the emerging markets comparing to those developed. The explanation that comes to mind is the well known Balassa-Samuelson effect [10]. The opposite (but not as clear) story is with the reserves – sudden drop in reserves is more likely to harm developing economies – they ability to acquire emergency liquidity injection is limited. Trade balance in probit specification has both the predicted sign and sufficient significance. We should however admit that different countries have different levels of current account sustainability [11]. Consequently if we allow for country-specific level of sustainability the implications of trade balance for currency crisis prediction shrink to nil. Two measures of government policy stance – government budget surplus and domestic credit creation – are clearly proven to have its significant impact on the exposure to the currency crisis. Expansionary fiscal policy reflected in budget deficits, and its financing by domestic credit expansion is – as "first generation" models predict – a shortcut to foreign exchange market crash. This is especially evident in the case of emerging markets that usually don't have sufficient capacity to absorb additional domestic credit. I find only weak backing for the thesis that variables entering (according to early "second generation" models) the government's utility function (inflation and unemployment) play certain role in attracting crises – they are usually only properly signed. The data doesn't support the view that the output gap (in absolute values) plays any important role. That might be due to somehow unusual specification. Short-term debt level and the degree of non-bank financial institution activity coefficients are accurately signed and have some significance for the whole sample and for emerging markets. 20 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [10] Emerging markets use to have (seemingly) overvalued real exchange rates due to faster economic growth and divergence in tradable and non-tradable goods sectors' productivity. [11] For example CEE economies like Estonia or Poland use to run enormous trade deficit, not having suffered up to the present any severe currency crisis – the deficit is financed by the inflow of FDI.
  • 21. 21 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Table 1 : Fixed effects linear regression and probit results Whole sample Emerging markets Developed economies Regressors linear probit linear probit linear probit RER • 0.4254 ! • 0.1684 ! • 0.2240 ** • 0.1169 ! • 0.5420 ! • 0.2077 ! Fx Reserves •-0.1599 ! •-0.0197*** •-0.2322 ! •-0.0190*** •-0.1499 ! •-0.0431 ! ☯ Trade balance • 0.0122 • 0.0417 ! -0.0228 • 0.0229 ! -0.0064 • 0.1233 ! Govnmt surplus •-0.8346 ! 0.0679 •-2.0577 ! 0.0218 •-0.3796 * 0.2348 * Domestic credit • 0.1259 ! • 0.0432 ! • 0.1931 ! • 0.0367 ! • 0.0402 -0.0241 * Inflation • 0.4160 ! • 0.0157 • 0.0576 • 0.0322 * • 0.5948 • 0.2397 Unemployment • 0.0007 • 0.0001 • 0.0009 • 0.0016 * • 0.0001 -0.0007 Output gap • 0.2452 • 1.4927*** -0.6657 • 0.8050*** -1.0013 • 0.0682 Short term debt • 0.032 *** • 0.0045 * • 0.0097 • 0.0004 dropped dropped Non-bank instit. • 0.3575 -0.0185 • 0.3464 • 0.0599 ** -0.3971 -0.2361 ! Int’l interest rate -0.3145 -0.7063 ** • 3.1090 ! • 1.7532 ! -3.6530 ! -2.3639 ! ☯ Managed float -0.0412 -0.0105 -0.0162 -0.0157 ** -0.0099 -0.0112 ☯ Peg • 0.0021 -0.0096 -0.0141 -0.0135 ** • 0.0281 -0.0067 ☯Multp equilibria -0.0108 • 0.0042 -0.0194 -0.0008 -0.0003 • 0.0109 Trade contagion • 0.1591 ! • 0.0668*** • 0.4004 ! • 0.1247 ! • 0.0746 * • 0.0204 Inform. spillover • 0.0085 ! • 0.0093 ! • 0.0096 ! • 0.0035 ! -0.0019 • 0.0056 * No of observ. 2355 2355 999 999 1356 1356 within/pseudo R2 0.0978 0.1229 0.2022 0.2710 0.0720 0.1513 Probit estimated with maximum likelihood. Probit coefficients expressed as derivatives of the probability to change in underlying fundamental evaluated at mean (∂F/∂xx=x-bar). For discrete variables (marked with ☯) derivative is to discrete change in the variable. Country specific intercepts of fixed effects estimation not reported. • - coefficient signed as predicted. Significance level : * 25% , ** 10%, *** 5%, ! 1% and higher, based on t-statistics (z-statistics) for hypothesis of no effect. Slopes correctly signed and significantly different from zero at the 0.05 are shaded.
  • 22. The coefficient accompanying the international interest rate poses some puzzle. Its importance is undoubtfully clear only in the case of emerging markets. The result for developed countries is a kind of anomaly. I presupposed the exchange rate regime dummy variables to have positive coefficients, i.e. any attempt of the authorities to control the exchange rate exposes a country to increased market pressure ("currency peg is the accident waiting to happen"). The data doesn't provide much support for that. Also multiple equilibria dummy has apparently no significance in the model. It seems that Jeanne's (1997) idea of practical application of the notion of self-fulfilling crisis has mainly theoretical appeal; its potential empirical reflection must be overridden by other factors. Last but not least come two contagion indexes. The results on trade contagion reinforce the view that trade links have indeed crucial meaning in the spread of currency crises (compare Glick and Rose (1999), who find parallel relationship). This effect is much stronger in the case of emerging markets. The category contagion due to informational spillovers is also proven to be important – a crisis in a similar country raises the probability of a crisis in a given country. The contagion effect works through (at least) two distinct channels [12]. In general a currency crisis spreads much more easily among emerging markets. Rather clear picture arises from the analysis. There is a set of variables – that is to say real exchange rate overvaluation, foreign exchange reserves deficit, domestic credit expansion, government budget deficit, trade links or similarities with countries suffering crises, and others – that have indeed apparent predictive potential with respect to currency crisis. The overall fit of the employed models is not very impressive but reasonable – it ranges from 7 to 27%. There is much more predictability in the emerging markets – perhaps the sophistication of the policy instruments available to them to counteract mounting problems – and wipe out this way some of the predictability – is limited. Some results of a predicting performance of the model are presented in Figure 3. It includes the predictions from the linear fixed effect regression. The horizontal axis indicates time, the vertical axis – inferred severity of the crisis index. Crisis periods are indicated with a circle [13]. 22 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [12] The two indexes exhibit analogous qualitative patterns. It may suggest that both reflect just the basic relationship that crisis elsewhere has an impact on probability of a crisis in home country. However the correlation between these two variables is only 0.09 and a quantitative comparison of relative magnitudes of their coefficients gives much room for the hypothesis that contagion effect works indeed through distinct channels. [13] Because the model is linear and because each country has it specific constant (fixed effects) the inferred "probabilities" are not necessarily between 0 and 1. Instead they should rather be treated as a "vulnerability to crises" index – comparable between countries. Within countries only relative changes matter (absolute values should be compared with an average for a given country).
  • 23. 2. The Universality of the Results One is right to retain some degree of reservation with respect to such analyses. Although there are some common findings in the empirical literature, there are also many differences. In recent years various researchers have claimed success in systematically predicting currency crises with different methods and approaches, and to have discovered different variables responsible for foreign exchange market events. They usually back their claims with regressions having significant coefficients on variables in question. There is a point in assessing the reliability of such findings – to what extent are they "true", common, similar and to what extent fall they prey to data mining biases (data-set overusing), departures from actual a priori null-hypothesis specification, etc. In other words – what can expect the researcher setting off in pursuit for crisis predictability assessment. 2.1. Crisis Definition When a researcher has made a decision that the data, not he himself, would decide what qualifies as a crisis and what doesn't, he faces a choice of a selection algorithm. The trade-off in such mechanism is obvious: the more "true" crises it captures the more "tranquil" period it marks as crises. I proceed as follows: basing on the financial press, journal articles, common knowledge, my experience and on the visual analysis of the data I manually select months that can be called crisis periods. Then I construct market pressure index (as described above) using the following parameters: – number of index components (three or two – without interest rate), – length of moving average from which the change in fundamental is assessed (from one-just first difference, to twelve), – weights for underlying index component, When the index has been constructed I define crises to exist when it satisfies certain conditions with parameters as follows: – threshold it has to exceed to be qualified as a crisis (from 1,25 to 2.5 its standard deviation above its mean), – number of periods between and after a crisis to be set to crisis or to missing (from 0 to 6), 23 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
  • 24. 24 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin Figure 3. Successes and failures in predicting crises. Predictions from the linear fixed effect regression. On the horizontal axis – time, on the vertical axis – inferred severity of the crisis index ("probability" of a crisis). Crisis periods are indicated with a circle.
  • 25. – threshold that at least one of underlying fundamentals must exceed (jump of minimum zero to 5%). The combination of these criteria gives at least several dozen thousand of algorithms – I compare them on the basis on how precisely they have identified crises periods relative to my hand-picked specimen. The outcome is presented in the Figure 4. On the horizontal axis I mark how many percent of the total sample has been covered with bad predictions (indicating crisis in a tranquil period). On the vertical axis – how many percent of total crisis periods have been called (good predictions). Each dot represents one algorithm. The figure portrays a typical trade-off problem. It has a "Pareto optimal" frontier. The implication is the fact that there are better and worse ways of selecting crises periods from the sample. The best algorithms minimize the number of bad predictions for a given accuracy (percent of crisis periods correctly called). The researcher has to decide what is his trade-off between good and bad predictions (his "indifference curve") and choose the appropriate algorithm (on the "Pareto" frontier). The straight line represents my "indifference curve". Judging from visual inspection of its prediction this paper's crisis index does a good job in calling all major and medium crises and at the same time it has a low dispersion. Of course the above analysis is very subjective – economists differ in what events they call crisis [14]. 25 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Figure 3. Successes and failures in predicting crises. Predictions from the linear fixed effect regression. On the horizontal axis – time, on the vertical axis – inferred severity of the crisis index ("probability" of a crisis). Crisis periods are indicated with a circle – continued [14]This issue is somehow analogous to the interdependence between type-I and type-II errors in econometric hypothesis testing – their probability cannot be simultaneously minimized.
  • 26. 2.2. The Significance of Fundamentals Afterward I estimate my two models with regressors modified in various ways and in different configurations. Modifications include: – various computations of real exchange rates: CPI based, relative normalized unit labor cost based, real export value based etc., – foreign reserves represented as a ratio to GDP or to import, – trade balance as it is, squared (sign corrected), as a dummy (sign corrected) equal to one when exceeding five different thresholds, – government surplus treated similarly, – domestic credit and short term debt represented as a ratio to GDP or to reserves, – different computations of the output gap, – different composition of international interest rate, 26 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin Figure 4. The behavior of crisis selection mechanisms (good predictions against bad predictions, in %)
  • 27. – "drift adjustment" (in a sense of Bertola and Svensson), no adjustment, different trend specifications in the multiple equilibria dummy, – different versions of trade link contagion index with different lags, and it is combined with – different crises selection algorithms, Around 5000 regressions are exercised in total. Since the coefficients are not directly comparable [15] I present only sample distributions of t-statistics (for null hypothesis of no effect) obtained from those regressions. I also report a sample distribution of the R2 's. Densities for subsamples have been scaled down by the factor of two, not to obscure figures. Averages are indicated with a dashed line. The results are presented in Figure 5 [16]. Given the large amount of the literature on currency crises prediction and various results obtained by the authors this exercise was meant to reconcile these differences by assessing what is an "average" prediction, regardless of variables used, regressors' specification, methods employed and other variations and definitions [17]. 3. Conclusions The study found quite considerable amount of predictability, particularly on behalf of standard leading crisis indicators, such as overvaluation of the real exchange rate and the level of foreign exchange reserves. Multiple equilibria don't get much support from the data while contagion effect is obviously working – apparently through various channels. The predictability is especially evident in the case of emerging economies. What is the explanation for that relatively large predictable component in currency crises probability assessment – and, more generally, what is, if any, the role for currency crises prediction? After deeper inquiry one may well be tempted to conclude that if currency crises increase (as they most probably do) social loss function, and the authorities have any 27 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... [15] Common interpretation of the slope coefficients is ∂E(y)/∂x=βx . However the magnitude of E(Δx) can vary substantially from model to model obscuring comparison between them. [16] For example a typical study should, on average, find that, say, trade balance deficit (current account) has a positive influence on the probability of the crisis but it is usually not very significant (average t-statistic=0.5). It should have no significance for emerging economies (t-statistic=0, i.e. current account doesn't matter) and be highly significant for developed countries (t-statistic around 2). [17] There is, however, the possibility for further extensions: the sample composition, time period, etc. can also be altered to check for the sensitivity and the significance of the results.
  • 28. power to influence the state of the economy – so there should be no room for currency crises prediction from the point of view of the policymaker. Any information contained by any variable should be immediately and continuously incorporated into government's (or market's) reaction function in the attempt to avoid currency crash (capital losses) and to return on the "balanced path". But such a conclusion would be, naturally, premature. When we allow for self-fulfilling crises and for problems with expectations coordination then there is nothing wrong with a situation that everybody knows the probability of a crash is significant and yet nobody withdraws. It is a Perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium based on a balance of beliefs. No one wants to be the first to leave profitable market, especially when the timing of a crisis is indefinite (compare with an interesting model of Caplin and Leahy (1994)). On the side of the policymaker – at any moment the decision to devalue is the outcome of his maximization problem [18]. The probability of a crisis usually enters a trade-off with the state of the economy the policymaker desires. As a consequence he does not want this probability to be zero in general. Instead, he weights costs (sacrifice ratios) of adjusting the economy against benefits of the present state, net of the expected costs of a crisis. This is why we can have significant variables in predicting crisis. This is also precisely the role of currency crisis prediction – i.e. to discover the dynamics (statistical properties) of such interplay of expectations and its expected outcome (the probability and expected magnitude of a crash) conditional on the state of fundamentals. The scale of surprise with which the Mexican and especially the Asian crises has been welcomed indicates that the job is far from being completed. But on the other hand there is not enough data (in quantity and quality), so to speak, not enough well described crises episodes so far, to draw precise inferences. 28 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin [18] In words of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) "most central banks have access to enough foreign exchange resources to beat down a speculative attack of any magnitude, provided they are willing to subordinate all the other goals of monetary policy." (italics on behalf of OR).
  • 29. Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... 29 Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different specification of dependent and explaining variables)
  • 30. 30 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different specification of dependent and explaining variables) - continued
  • 31. 31 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ... Figure 5. The ultimate significance of macroeconomic fundamentals in currency crises prediction. (Sample distribution of t-statistics obtained from regressions with different specification of dependent and explaining variables) - continued
  • 32. References Antczak R. (2000). "Theoretical Aspects of Currency Crises". CASE S&A No. 211. Baig T., I. Goldfajn (1999). "Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis". IMF Staff papers 46/2. Banerjee A. (1992). "A Simple Model of Herd Behaviour". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, p. 797-817. Berg A., C. Patillo (1999). "Predicting Currency Crises, the Indicators Approach and an Alternative". Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 561-586. Bertola G., L.E.O. Svensson (1993). "Stochastic Devaluation Risk and the Empirical fit of Target-zone Models". Review of Economic Studies 60, p. 689-712. Bikchandani S., D. Hirshleifer, I. Welsh (1992). "A Theory of Fads, Fashions, Custom and Cultural Change as Information Cascades". Journal of Political Economy 100, p. 992-102. Blackburn, K., M. Sola, (1993). "Speculative Currency Attacks and Balance-of-payment Crises". Journal of Economic Surveys 7, p. 119-44. Blanco H., P.M. Garber (1986). "Recurrent Devaluation and Speculative Attacks on the Mexican Peso". Journal of Political Economy 94, p. 148-166. Calvo G.A., E.G. Mendoza (1996). "Mexico's Balance of Payment Crisis: a Chronicle of a Death Foretold". Journal of International Economics 41, p. 235-264. Caplin A., J. Leahy (1994). "Business as Usual, Market Crashes, and Wisdom after the Fact". American Economic Review 84, p. 549-65. Cheung Y., M. Chinn, I.W. Marsh (2000). "How do UK based Foreign Exchange Dealers Think their Market Operates?". NBER WP 7524. Cooper, R., A. John (1988). "Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynsian Models". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103, p. 347-358. Cumby R.E., S. van Wijbergen (1989). "Financial Policy and Speculative Runs with a Crawling Peg: Argentina 1979-1981". Journal of International Economics 27, p. 111-27. Eichengreen B., A. Rose, Ch. Wyplosz (1995). "Exchange Market Mayhem: the Antecedants and Aftermath of Speculative Attacks". Economic Policy 21, p. 251-312. Eichengreen B., A. Rose, Ch. Wyplosz (1996). "Contagious Currency Crises: First Test". Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98, p. 463-484. Frankel J.A., A.K. Rose (1996). "Currency Crashes in Emerging Markets; An Empirical Treatment". Journal of International Economics 41, p. 351-366. Gerlach S., F. Smets (1994). "Contagious Speculative Attacks". CEPR 1055. Girton L., D. Roper (1977). "A monetary Model of Exchange Market Pressure Applied to Postwar Canadian Experience". American Economic Review 67, p. 537-48. 32 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – M. Sasin
  • 33. Glick R., A. Rose (1999). "Contagion and Trade: Why are Currency Crises Regional?". Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 603-17. Goldfajn I., R.O. Valdes (1997). "Are Currency Crises Predictable?". IMF WP 97/159. Jeanne O. (1997). "Are Currency Crises Self-fulfilling? A Test". Journal of International Economics 43, p. 263-286. Jeanne O. (1999). "Currency Crises, a Perspective on Recent Theoretical Development". CEPR 2170. Krugman P. (1979). "A Model of Balance-of-payment Crises". Journal of Money Credit and Banking 11, 3, p. 311-325. Krugman, P. (1996). "Are Currency Crises Self-fulfilling?". NBER Macroeconomic Annual, Cambridge, MIT Press. Kaminsky G., C. Reinhard (1996). "The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and Balance of Payment Problems". Board of Governors FRS, IFDP 544. Kaminsky G., Lizondo, C. Reinhart (1998). "Leading Indicators of Currency Crises". IMF. Lyrio M., H. Dewachter (1999). "Multiple Equilibria and the Credibility of the Brazilian Crawling Peg". 1995-1998, CES-KUL. Masson, P. (1998). "Contagion, Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, ans Jumps between Multiple Equilibria". IMF WP 98/142. Masson, P. (1999). "Contagion: Macroeconomic Model with Multiple Equilibria". Journal of International Money and Finance 18, p. 587-602. Obstfeld, M. (1986). "Rational and Self-fulfilling Balance-of-payment Crises". American Economic Review 76, p. 72-81. Obstfeld, M. (1994). "The Logic of Currency Crises". Cahiers économiques et monétaires 43, p. 189-213. Obstfeld, M. (1996). "Models of Currency Crises with Self-fulfilling Features". European Economic Review 40, p. 1037-47. Obstfeld M., K. Rogoff (1995). "The Mirage of Fixed Exchange Rates". Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, p. 73-96. Salant S.W., D.W. Henderson (1978). "Market Anticipation of Government Policies and the Price of Gold". Journal of Political Economy 86, p. 627-648. Tomczyñska M. (2000). "Early Indicators of Currency Crises". Review of some literature, CASE S&A No. 208. 33 Studies & Analyses CASE No. 224 – Predicting Currency Crises ...
  • 34. 34 170 Gerhard Fink, Peter R. Haiss, Lucjan T. Or³owski, Privilege Interim/Bank Relationship in Central Europe: Trigger or Tap for Corporate Governance 171 Ma³gorzata Markiewicz, Urban Górski, Marta Dekhtiarchuk, Monetary Policy in Ukraine in 1996-1999 172 ,
  • 35. ,
  • 36. 1994-1998 . 173 Magdalena Tomczyñska, European Union Financial Transfers to Applicant Countries 174 # $%
  • 38. , ) '
  • 39. , *)+
  • 40. 1998 . + % , 175 Mateusz Walewski, A Short Play on the Idea of the Laffer Curve in Transition Economies 176 ' -%, ', %
  • 41. , .
  • 42. , )
  • 43. ) /: 1$
  • 44. #2 177 Georges de Menil, Stephane Hamayon, Mihai Seitan, Romania’s Pension System: The Weight of the Past 178 Katarzyna Zawaliñska, Agriculture of the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland in Perspective of Joining Common Agricultural Policy – with Some Fiscal Remarks 179 )3 4, $
  • 45. ) ,
  • 46. -% 199151998 ,. 6
  • 47. % 180 Pavel Stepanek, Ondrej Schneider - Present and Future Fiscal Policy Problems in the Czech Republic 181 Krzysztof Po³omski, Tax System in Selected Transition Economies. An overview 182 Stanis³aw Gomu³ka, Comparative Notes on Pension Developments and Reforms in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Romania 183 Eugeniusz Kwiatkowski, Pawe³ Kubiak, Tomasz Tokarski, Procesy dostosowawcze na rynku pracy jako czynnik konsolidacji reform rynkowych w Polsce
  • 48. 35 184 Mateusz Walewski, Restrukturyzacja tradycyjnych bran¿ przemys³owych w krajach Europy Zachodniej – wybrane przyk³ady 185 Katarzyna Zawaliñska, The Institutional Approach to Assets/Liability Management by Commercial Banks in Poland: A Special Focus on Risc Management186 Ma³gorzata Jakubiak, Tomasz Tokarski, Pawe³ Kaczorowski, Joanna Siwiñska, Private, Public and Foreign Savings 187 Barbara Liberda, Household Saving in Poland 188 Wojciech Maliszewski, VAR-ing Monetary Policy 189 Urszula Sztanderska, Jacek Liwiñski, Koszty pracy a tworzenie miejsc pracy 190 Miros³aw Gronicki, Katarzyna Piêtka, Macroeconomic Model for Ukraine 191 # $%
  • 49. , 4, -
  • 50. %
  • 51. )3
  • 52. #
  • 53. %37 1999-2000 , 192 Artur Radziwi³³, Octavian Scerbatchi, Constantin Zaman, Financial Crisis in Moldowa – Causes and Consequences 193 Tytus Kamiñski, Zachowania przedsiêbiorstw sprywatyzowanych 194 Marek Jarociñski, Strategie rynku pracy w wybranych krajach 195 Wies³aw Karsz, Pomoc publiczna ukierunkowana na zatrudnienie. Próba identyfikacji i szacunki 196 Alina Kudina, An Approach to Forecasting Ukrainian GDP from the Supply Side 197 Artur Radziwi³³, Perspektywy zró¿nicowania regionalnego bezrobocia w Polsce 198 ' ()#
  • 54. ,
  • 55. 7
  • 56.
  • 57. 7
  • 58. ,
  • 59. 200 Lubomira Anastassova, Institutional Arrangements of Currency Boards – Comparative Macroeconomic Analysis 201 Stanis³awa Golinowska, Ochrona socjalna bezrobotnych w Polsce oraz w innych krajach
  • 60. 36 203 Ma³gorzata Jakubiak, Design and Operation of Existing Currency Board Arrangements 204 Preslava Kovatchevska, The Banking and Currency Crises in Bulgaria: 1996–1997 205 Marek Jarociñski, Moldova in 1995–1999: Macroeconomic and Monetary Consequences of Fiscal Imbalances 206 Rafa³ Antczak, Stanislav Bogdankiewich, Pavel Daneiko, Krzysztof Po³omski, Vladymir Usowski: Impact of the Russian Crisis on the Belarussian Economy 207 Yurij Kuz'myn, Ukraine's Foreign Trade Developments and Forecasts 208 Magdalena Tomczyñska, Early Indicators of Currency Crises. Review of some Literature 209 Monika B³aszkiewicz, What Factors Led to the Asian Financial Crisis: Where or Where Not Asian Economic Sound? 210 Elena Jarociñska, Labour Developments in Moldova 211 Rafa³ Antczak, Theoretical aspects of currency crises 212 Artur Radziwi³³, Poland's Accession to the EMU 214 : ;%
  • 61. , $%/), =3
  • 62. %7 #?3 @ #
  • 63. %# 215 Jacek Cukrowski, Financing the Defict of the State Budget by National Bank of Georgia (1996–1999) 218 Ma³gorzata Jakubiak, Indicators of Currency Crisis: Empirical Analysis of Some Emerging and Transition Economies 219 Joanna Siwiñska Currency Crises and Fiscal Imbalances – the Transition Countries Perspective 220 Larisa Lubarova, Oleg Petrushin, Artur Radziwi³³, Is Moldova Ready to Grow? Assessment of post-crisis policies 1999–2000 224 Marcin Sasin, Predicting Currency Crises, the Ultimate Significance of Macroeconomic Fundamentals in Linear Specifications with Nonlinear Extensions