SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 204
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458
LIHEAP reconsidered
Mark J. Kaiser*, Allan G. Pulsipher
Center for Energy Studies, Louisiana State University, One East
Fraternity Circle, Baton Rouge, LA 70803-0301, USA
Abstract
The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP)
is a federal block grant program established in 1981 to help
low-
income households meet a portion of their home energy costs.
The manner in which LIHEAP funds are allocated to states,
however,
has been a contentious issue since the inception of the program.
In 1984, the Health and Human Services developed a new
formula
to increase equity among the states by incorporating state
cooling requirements in an equal weighting scheme with state
heating
requirements. In addition to the new distribution formula,
various provisions were also included in the LIHEAP re-
authorization
amendment that specified when and how the 1984 formula could
be employed. These provisions have turned out to be so
constraining, however, that they have effectively disabled the
1984 formula. The purpose of this paper is to introduce realistic
policy
alternatives to the current LIHEAP allocation mechanism and to
examine the impact of each alternative. Three options are
discussed ranging from the complete elimination of the hold-
harmless (HH) provisions to a proposal that maintains the
primary HH
provision but reduces the trigger level when it is enabled. A
simple allotment block distribution based on mixing the two
competing
funding formulas is also considered. The models presented in
this paper represent the first time that policy alternatives to the
LIHEAP allocation mechanism has been examined within an
analytic framework.
r 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Program
(LIHEAP) was authorized by Congress through Title
XXVI of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of
1981, and currently authorized through the end of FY
2004 by the Coats Human Services Re-authorization
Act of 1998, P.L.105-285, enacted on October 27, 1998,
www.acf.dhhs.gov.
The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Act of
1981 established the Low-Income Home Energy Assis-
tance block grant program to help eligible households
meet home energy costs. States can provide assistance to
low-income households through various program com-
ponents, including home heating and cooling assistance,
energy crisis assistance, and home weatherization
(General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1986):
* Home energy assistance consists of helping low-
income households pay heating and cooling costs.
Grantees provide assistance in the form of cash,
vouchers, coupons, and two-party checks to eligible
households, and may make payments to landlords or
home energy suppliers on behalf of eligible house-
holds.
* Energy crisis assistance includes funding for weather-
related, supply shortages, and other household
energy-related emergencies. States provide cash,
shelter, emergency supplies, or supplemental heating
sources to households without heat or in imminent
danger of having their fuel supplies terminated.
* Weatherization assistance includes funding for low -
cost residential weatherization or other energy-
related home repair.
LIHEAP is limited to households that include recipients
of aid to families with dependent children, supplemen-
tary security income, food stamps, or certain veteran’s
benefits. Households with incomes less than 150% of the
poverty level, or less than 60% of the state’s median
income, whichever is greater, also qualify under the
statute.
The LIHEAP is a block grant program, meaning that
the state can—within the statutory requirements—
choose their method of administration, eligibility
criteria, benefit levels, and funding levels for program
activities. A number of legislative amendments over the
years have placed some restrictions on state program
discretion; for example, no more than 25% of LIHEAP
ARTICLE IN PRESS
*Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-225-578-4554; fax: +1-225-
578-
4541.
E-mail address: [email protected] (M.J. Kaiser).
0301-4215/03/$ - see front matter r 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd.
All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 3 0 1 - 4 2 1 5 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 2 0 0 - 8
funds can be used for weatherization and no more than
10% can be spent on state administration costs. States
can transfer a maximum of 10% of their funds to other
block grants and cannot carry more than 15% of their
allotment to the succeeding fiscal year.
The General Accounting Office by legislative mandate
is required to evaluate LIHEAP, and as requested by
various government units, have produced a number of
reports on the program, e.g., General Accounting
Office, US Congress (1986, 1987, 1990). A handful of
academic papers on federal energy assistance programs
are scattered throughout the literature (Colton, 1990;
Higgins and Lutzenhiser, 1995; Kennedy, 1987; Kings-
ley, 1992; Landsberg and Dukert, 1981), including a few
Congressional Research Service reports (Abbey, 2001;
Gish, 2000; Stoltzfus, 2002) and numerous LIHEAP
reports to Congress (Low Income Home Energy
Assistance Programs, 1983, 1985, 1994, 2000).
The federal government distributes funds to states for
LIHEAP using a legislated formula. The LIHEAP
formula was originally legislated in 1981 and then
revised in 1984 in large measure due to political pressure
from many warm-weather states that maintained that
the 1981 formula over-allocated funds to cold-weather
states. Pursuant to the re-authorization amendment for
LIHEAP in 1984, the Health and Human Services
developed a new formula to increase the overall equity
among the states. The LIHEAP formula was revised to
incorporate state cooling requirements in an equal
weighting scheme with state heating requirements, but
various additional conditions were also included in the
amendment that specified when and how the 1984
formula could be employed. To ‘‘turn-on’’ the 1984
formula for instance, LIHEAP’s regular appropriation
is required to exceed a minimum threshold level of
$1.975 billion, but because program commitment to
LIHEAP has fallen over the years, the revised allocation
mechanism has only rarely been applied—specifically,
twice over the past 17 years, and last during FY 1986.
The primary intent of the 1984 legislation to increase
the overall equity of the distribution of LIHEAP funds
has thus failed miserably, and so there is a need to
examine alternative allotment methods to bring the 1984
formula ‘‘back into’’ the allocation mechanism as
intended by the legislation. The primary purpose of this
paper is to suggest viable policy alternatives to the
current legislative framework and to develop an analytic
model to quantify the impact of each alternative. The
present work represents the first time that alternative
allocation mechanisms to LIHEAP have been modeled
and presented publicly. This model not only provides
legislators insight on competing policy proposals, but
also hopefully, provides a forum and stimulus for future
debate.
The outline of the paper is as follows. The current
LIHEAP statute is discussed in Section 2, followed by a
summary of LIHEAP funding levels in Section 3 and a
general description in Section 4 of three realistic policy
alternatives. In Sections 5–7 the policy alternatives are
examined. In Section 5, a comparison of the 1981 and
1984 formula allocation formulas are discussed by state
and region, and in Section 6, the effect of a trigger-level
reduction on state allotments and system measures are
outlined. In Section 7 a block allotment procedure is
described which combines the 1981 and 1984 formula.
In Section 8 conclusions complete the paper. To
maintain focus on the policy proposals, the theoretical
foundation of the allocation mechanisms are maintained
in separate appendices.
2. The LIHEAP statute
The LIHEAP statute currently assigns each state and
the District of Columbia an allotment percentage based
on the value of the regular appropriation $D for the
fiscal year. One of three cases can occur depending on
the value of D:
Case I : Dp$1:975B
Case II : $1:975BoDo$2:25B
Case III : DX$2:25B
Case I: Dp$1:975B: When the regular appropriation
in a fiscal year is less than or equal to $1.975B, the 1981
formula is employed to determine state allocation
percentages. In other words, the 1981 formula repre-
sents a default condition if regular appropriation does
not exceed the trigger F ¼ $1:975B: The 1981 allocation
percentages shown in Table 1 are now over 20-years old
and the arbitrary basis of their ‘‘derivation’’ forgotten
by the legislative community. Further, and more
importantly, since regular appropriations have fallen
below the trigger level every year for the past 15 years
(and counting), the high frequency of usage of the 1981
formula has helped to create a sense of ‘‘acceptance’’
and ‘‘validity’’ for its application, which is anything but
satisfactory.
Three main ‘‘problems’’ exist with the 1981 formula:
(1) The 1981 formula represented the outcome of a
political process as opposed to being based on good
science.
(2) The 1981 formula was poorly designed, extremely
complex, and arbitrarily ‘‘derived’’ in a manner that
strongly favored cold-weather climates.
(3) The 1981 formula is a ‘‘static’’ formula that fixed
the allocation percentages of states based on pre-
1980 data for state climate, fuel price, demographic,
and expenditure patterns.
The 1981 formula is unusually easy to criticize and
very difficult to defend. It is important to recognize
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581442
that the 1981 formula was designed in response
to conditions specific to the times that emphasized
the rapidly increasing fuel oil prices in the Northeast
during the late 1970s. The formula allocation caused
great consternation on the part of many warm-weather
states
1
and the continued application of the 1981
formula remains one of the better-kept ‘‘secrets’’ in
Washington.
The primary shortcomings of the 1981 formula are
easy to recognize: The 1981 formula does not nor cannot
reflect the current low-income demographic, consump-
tion, and fuel price mix in the country (since the data on
which the formula is based is over 20-years old), and
further, the formula itself cannot be ‘‘updated’’ to reflect
more recent data (since the allocation mechanism is a
static design). The most egregious aspect of the 1981
formula is that the allocation mechanism does not
distribute funds based on the need for home energy
assistance. Instead, the 1981 formula defines need in a
mysterious and complicated fashion primarily in terms
of the home heating needs of cold-climate states.
A complex and convoluted formula is not necessarily
a ‘‘bad’’ formula, but unfortunately—and more to the
point—it is not clear what the 1981 state allocation
percentages mean or if they identify the need for home
energy assistance. Four separate formulas are entangled
with the 1981 formula allotment—two House of
Representatives formula alternatives, the FY 1980 state
allotment, and the Windfall Profit Tax Act formula—
commingled with pro-rata reductions, weak hold-harm-
less (HH) provisions, and arbitrary formula compar-
isons. And as each one of the four formulas is biased
toward cold-climate states, no matter what procedural
elements are invoked, a biased
2
cold-climate formula
remains a biased cold-climate formula.
Pursuant to the re-authorization amendment for
LIHEAP in 1984, the 1981 formula was completely
revised in the ‘‘1984 formula’’, but for the 1984 formula
to be ‘‘turned-on’’ the regular appropriation must
exceed $1.975B.
Case II: $1:975BoDo$2:25B: When the regular
appropriation exceeds $1.975B in a fiscal year, then an
allocation mechanism based on the 1984 formula
coupled with two HH provisions is adopted. The first
HH condition, or primary HH provision, is enabled
when D > $1:975B: When DX$2:25B a second HH
provision kicks in.
The 1984 formula, or ‘‘new formula’’, was established
to provide a mechanism to distribute LIHEAP funds
based solely on the home energy needs of low-income
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Table 1
LIHEAP allocation percentages according to the 1981 and 1984
formula
State 1981 Formula
(%)
1984 Formula
(%)
Statutory
floor ($M)
Alabama 0.86 1.68 16.99
Alaska 0.55 0.36 10.84
Arizona 0.42 1.25 8.21
Arkansas 0.66 1.21 12.96
California 4.61 6.00 91.12
Colorado 1.61 1.15 31.77
Connecticut 2.10 1.40 41.45
Delaware 0.28 0.37 5.50
D.C. 0.33 0.27 6.44
Florida 1.36 4.16 26.88
Georgia 1.08 2.68 21.25
Hawaii 0.11 0.12 2.14
Idaho 0.63 0.28 12.39
Illinois 5.81 5.30 114.72
Indiana 2.63 2.21 51.94
Iowa 1.86 1.22 36.81
Kansas 0.86 1.07 16.91
Kentucky 1.37 1.73 27.03
Louisiana 0.88 1.79 17.37
Maine 1.36 0.55 26.85
Maryland 1.61 2.26 31.74
Massachusetts 4.20 2.91 82.91
Michigan 5.51 4.82 108.92
Minnesota 3.97 1.68 78.47
Mississippi 0.74 1.87 14.56
Missouri 2.32 2.41 45.82
Montana 0.74 0.35 14.54
Nebraska 0.92 0.55 18.21
Nevada 0.20 0.51 3.86
New Hampshire 0.79 0.45 15.69
New Jersey 3.90 3.28 76.97
New Mexico 0.52 0.54 10.28
New York 12.72 8.68 251.34
North Carolina 1.90 3.14 37.45
North Dakota 0.80 0.21 15.79
Ohio 5.14 4.86 101.49
Oklahoma 0.79 1.31 15.61
Oregon 1.25 0.95 24.62
Pennsylvania 6.84 5.15 134.99
Rhode Island 0.69 0.47 13.65
South Carolina 0.68 1.44 13.49
South Dakota 0.65 0.29 12.83
Tennessee 1.39 2.08 27.38
Texas 2.26 6.60 44.71
Utah 0.75 0.54 14.76
Vermont 0.60 0.23 11.76
Virginia 1.96 3.05 38.66
Washington 2.05 1.50 40.50
West Virginia 0.91 0.96 17.89
Wisconsin 3.58 1.93 70.63
Wyoming 0.30 0.18 5.91
1
‘‘It has only been through the making of legislative history with
regard to this and previous appropriations bills for this program
that
the prejudice favoring cold-weather energy bill assistance and
opposing
hot-weather energy bill assistance has developedy it is counter
to the
American tradition of fair play. I would urge the Congress to re-
examine its conscience and design a fairer solution’’.
Additional view
of Bill Alexander, Low Income Energy Assistance, House of
Representatives Report No. 96-1244, August 21, 1980.
2
Granted, the home heating needs of cold-climate states were
particularly severe in the early 1980s but the incorporation of
these
same factors today is not defendable.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1443
households—where ‘‘home energy’’ was interpreted to
mean the heating and cooling requirements of house-
holds. According to Section 2604(a)(2) of P.L. 97-35 as
amended by P.L.98-558,
‘‘y For fiscal year 1985 and thereafter, a state’s
allotment percentage is the percentage which expen-
ditures for home energy by low-income households in
that state bears to such expenditures in all statesy’’
The 1984 formula was a significant improvement over
the 1981 formula in terms of its transparency and equity
and in many regards can be considered the ‘‘ideal’’
mechanism to distribute LIHEAP funds:
(1) The 1984 formula determines state allocation
percentages according to a simple, easy-to-under-
stand, and science-based mechanism using estimates
of state expenditures for the Btu requirements of
low-income households for each fuel source con-
tributing to home heating and cooling needs.
(2) The 1984 formula is extremely well designed and
easy-to-defend and is based on the ‘‘best-available’’
statistical data.
(3) The 1984 formula is a dynamic allocation that is
updated annually to normalize for changes in
weather patterns (heating and cooling degree-days)
and fuel prices (coal, electricity, fuel oil, liquid
petroleum gases, and natural gas) at the state level.
The 1984 formula allocations are shown in Table 1
alongside the 1981 allotments, but unlike the 1981
percentage allocation values, the 1984 formula values do
not represent the final state allotment percentages. The
final allotment percentages can only be calculated after
the regular appropriation D is known for the fiscal year
and the impact of the HH and give-back (GB)
provisions are incorporated within the allocation
mechanism.
The HH condition establishes a statutory floor for
each state determined by the 1981 formula allocation
and the appropriation level F ¼ $1:975B as shown in
Table 1. If a state does not achieve its statutory floor
under the appropriation D and 1984 formula allotment,
then it is held ‘‘harmless’’ at its floor. The funds
necessary to maintain states at their floor is mandated
by a GB provision which specifies that all states above
their floor will have their allotments reduced propor-
tionally until the funds required to make-up the deficit is
achieved. Since the funds necessary to make-up the
deficit come from states that benefit under the new
allocation mechanism, these states effective allotment
percentages are reduced from their 1984 allotment.
Case III: DX$2:25B: When the regular appropriation
for a given fiscal year is equal to or exceeds $2.25B, then
another HH and GB condition is triggered, referred to
as the secondary HH-GB provision or the LTOP (less
than 1%) provision. The LTOP provision stipulates that
any state that receives less than 1% of the total
allotment funding at the appropriation level D cannot
have a smaller allotment percentage than its allotment
percentage at $2.14B. The impact of the secondary HH-
GB provision acts to maintai n a set of states at their
allotment percentage achieved at $2.14B. Since a set of
states are maintained at an allotment percentage that is
higher than dictated by the primary HH-GB provision,
the complementary set of states which are not affected
by the LTOP provision provide the funds required to
satisfy this condition.
The inclusion of the secondary HH-GB provision is
interesting because it indicates the ‘‘mind-set’’ of the
legislators at the time the LIHEAP statute was revised.
It was expected, or at least anticipated, that regular
appropriations for LIHEAP would increase in the years
ahead and might conceivably even exceed $2.25B! As it
turns out, however, due to factors such as the oil price
crash of 1986 and the Emergency Deficit Control Act,
funding levels for LIHEAP in the years following the
1984 re-authorization plummeted.
3. LIHEAP funding levels
The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of
program funds: regular block grant and emergency.
Regular funds are authorized under Section 2602(b) of
the LIHEAP statute and are currently allocated
according to the mechanism described in Section 2.
Emergency funds are authorized under 2602(e) of the
LIHEAP statute and are authorized and distributed at
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Table 2
LIHEAP funding history, 1981–2002
FY Regular appropriation ($B) Emergency ($M)
1981 1.850
1982 1.875
1983 1.975
1984 2.075
1985 2.100
1986 2.010
1987 1.825
1988 1.532
1989 1.383
1990 1.393 50
1991 1.415 195
1992 1.500
1993 1.346
1994 1.439 298
1995 1.319 100
1996 0.900 180
1997 1.000 215
1998 1.000 160
1999 1.100 180
2000 1.100 744
2001 1.400 456
2002 1.700
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581444
the discretion of the President and Secretary of the
Health and Human Services at any point in time in the
fiscal year. The funding history of LIHEAP is shown in
Table 2. The average value of LIHEAP regular
appropriation from 1981–2002 is EðDÞ ¼ $1:51B with
a standard deviation of sðDÞ ¼ $0:37B: Observe that
since the LIHEAP program was reauthorized in 1984,
funding levels have exceeded the trigger level $1.975B
only during FY 1985 and FY 1986.
4. Policy proposals
The principal condition that has prevented the
application of the 1984 formula is immediately clear.
The level of the regular funding appropriated for
LIHEAP over the years has not achieved the legislated
trigger, and so by default, the 1981 formula—despite its
obvious shortcomings—has become the effective alloca-
tion mechanism for federal funding.
To address the failure of the 1984 legislation, three
suggestions follow:
* Eliminate the trigger level,
* Reduce the trigger level or
* Devise an alternative allocation mechanism.
These suggestions are formalized as the following
options:
Option A: Eliminate the HH-GB provisions and apply
the 1984 formula allocation at a zero trigger level.
Option B: Reduce the trigger level of the HH-GB
provision and eliminate the LTOP provision.
Option C: Apply an allocation mechanism based on a
linear combination of the 1981 and 1984 formula values.
A brief description of each option is now provided
followed in Sections 5–7 by models that explore the
impact of each alternative.
Option A: This is the most dramatic approach, the
simplest, and arguably the most equitable. Unfortu-
nately, Option A is also unlikely to garner the political
support necessary to achieve passage.
The purpose of LIHEAP is to assist low-income
households meet the costs of home energy. This purpose
is clear and unambiguous and a very good allocation
mechanism already exists in the 1984 formula to satisfy
this objective—and in fact it is doubtful that a ‘‘better’’
formula can be developed unless the legislative mandate
of LIHEAP radically changes—but for the past 15 years
the 1984 formula could not be employed since the
trigger level to turn it ‘‘on’’ has never been attained.
Hence, by eliminating the HH provisions and setting the
trigger point to zero, the 1984 formula will serve as the
new default formula.
The basic premise of Option A is that any use of the
1981 formula perpetrates a distribution of funds that is
inequitable since the allocation is not based on the home
energy needs of low-income households. The manner in
which LIHEAP funds should be distributed to states
should mimic the state’s home energy expenditures
3
paid
by low-income households. Interestingly, this also
appears to be the Bush Administration position.
4
Although Option A is believed to be the fairest,
simplest and best way to revise LIHEAP, it may not be
politically viable or develop a strong enough coalition of
support, especially in the Senate since a majority of
states realize a smaller allotment percentage under the
1984 formula. The fight in Congress over Option A will
be especially difficult since Senators are not likely to
vote their state a lower allotment percentage to ‘‘right
the wrongs’’ of an archaic and cryptic formula. Be that
as it may, if legislators can be convinced to move on
LIHEAP—perhaps for the sake of good government,
good conscience, or daresay, a good formula—viability
may hinge on maintaining some form of the HH
condition as opposed to the complete elimination of
the statutory floor. One simple means to accomplish this
task is to simply re-set the trigger level of F downward
as proposed in Option B.
Option B: Any revision to LIHEAP should be realistic
and based on a politically viable strategy.
The value of the trigger point F currently represents a
level that has not, nor likely will, be surpassed in the
future, and hence its adjustment downward is necessary
to ensure that a more equitable allocation mechanism be
applied to future LIHEAP funding. The value of the
trigger point was set by legislative mandate and over
time has lost its relation to D: At one time (15-years ago)
the values of D and F were roughly comparable, while
today F appears as an upper bound that is unlikely to be
exceeded.
There is also some precedence for trigger re-adjust-
ment. When the HH-GB provision was initially devised
in 1984, F was set at the FY 1984 appropriation level of
$2.075B. In 1986, when the regular appropriation fell
below the required trigger, the value of F was reduced to
the FY 1983 level of $1.975 to bring the 1984 formula
back ‘‘in’’ the allocation mechanism.
5
Unfortunately,
FY 1986 represented the last year in which program
appropriations exceeded $1.975B, and subsequent to
this time no further action has been taken to address this
issue and/or re-adjust F:
ARTICLE IN PRESS
3
Home energy expenditures paid by low-income households is
also
relatively easy to estimate, and so there is no technical
difficulties
associated with the computation.
4
‘‘y The legislatively established formula currently used to
distribute LIHEAP block grant funds to states is based on 20-
year
old population and winter heating cost data. The Administration
is
interested in options that would make block grant allocations
more
equitable by basing the formula on current home energy
expenditures
paid by low-income households’’. Bush Administration LIHEAP
Budget for Fiscal Year 2003.
5
Apparently LIHEAP re-authorization legislation was still fresh
in
legislators minds.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1445
The ideal equitable allocation mechanism would be
based on the 1984 formula with no provisions attached
(Option A), but because of the historical precedence to
couple the 1984 formula with HH and GB provisions,
and the need to satisfy a majority of votes in the Senate,
Option B is likely to be viewed as compromise
legislation.
Option C: An alternative approach to maintain the
application of the 1981 formula that does not rely
explicitly on re-adjusting the trigger level F is to
set-aside a certain percentage ðrÞ of the regular appro-
priation to be used with the 1981 formula, rD; and then
to apply the 1984 formula to the remaining funds,
ð1 � rÞD: This has an advantage over Option B since
regardless of the appropriation level the 1984 formula
would always be applied to the same portion of the
regular appropriation.
6
Option C ensures application of
the 1984 formula with no ‘‘downside risk’’ as in Option
B, but it also foregoes the ‘‘upside potential’’ when D >
F: On methodological grounds a formula mix is not
especially appealing, but as will be demonstrated in
Section 7, a linear combination of the 1981 and 1984
formula is equivalent to Option B under a suitable
correspondence.
A summary of the three options is depicted in Table 3
along with a brief description of their advantages and
disadvantages.
5. A comparison of the 1981 and 1984 formula allotments
The 1981 formula is for all practical purposes a
‘‘perpetual’’ formula since the funding levels required
to ‘‘turn-on’’ the new allocation mechanism has only
rarely been achieved in the past and is unlikely to be
attained in the future. The HH and GB provisions
associated with the allocation mechanism are therefore
relaxed and the trigger level required to turn-on the 1984
formula is set equal to zero. A direct comparison is
performed between the old and new formula allotment
percentages by state and region.
5.1. Comparison by state
If the vectors f and g denote the 1981 and 1984 state
allotment percentages:
f ¼ ðf1; y; f51Þ; 0ofio1;
X
fi ¼ 1;
g ¼ ðg1; y; g51Þ; 0ogio1;
X
gi ¼ 1;
then the set of states that would benefit from a formula
change is denoted
fBg ¼ fi j fiogig;
while the set of states that would be harmed is denoted
fCg ¼ fi j fi > gig:
The sets fBg and fCg partition the 50 states and District
of Columbia (D.C.) according to states that ‘‘benefit’’
and are ‘‘harmed’’ by the formula change. If a state’s
1984 formula allotment percentage is greater than its
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Table 3
A comparison of three policy options
Policy Description Advantages Disadvantages
Option A Eliminate the primary and Simple Senate fight
secondary HH-GB provisions Fair Large percentage change in
state allotment
and nullify the trigger level Rational
mechanism
Satisfies original intent of LIHEAP
Bush Administration position
House passage likely
Option B Maintain the primary HH-GB Maintains form of
Maintains convoluted formula
provision but reduce the statute Not a rational mechanism for
distribution
trigger level when it is enabled Enables 1984 Level of fairness
not guaranteed
formula
Compromise formula
Senate support more likely
Option C Apply an allotment based Simple Formula mix
on a linear combination Easy to understand Not a rational
mechanism for distribution
of the 1981 and 1984 No downside risk Foregoes upside
potential
formula values Correspondence with
Option B
6
Under Option B, if F is re-set at a value that is ‘‘too high’’ (say
$1.5B) and D again drifts downward away from F; then the
same
inequity will return to the distribution.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581446
1981 allotment percentage, fiogi; then state i is said to
benefit from the new policy.
In Table 4, 23 states are shown to benefit under
Option A while 28 states would be harmed. States that
benefit realize a percentage change in their allotment
ranging from 4% (New Mexico, Missouri) to 200%
(Arizona, Florida) while states that are harmed range
from �6% (Ohio) to �74% (North Dakota). A graphical
representation of allotment percentage changes is
depicted in Fig. 1. The average percentage change for
states in fBg and fCg is 81% and �35%; respectively.
Eight states in fBg realize an allocation percentage
change greater than 100% (FL, AZ, TX, NV, MS, GA,
SC, LA), while seven states in fCg realize a change in
allocation percentage greater than 50% (ND, VT, MN,
ID, SD, ME, MT).
Under the 1984 formula allotment, the set of states
that benefit from the new policy would realize a 20.4%
increase in total allotment, which would be transferred
from the states in fCg:7 The total amount of money
transferred depends on the value of D; e.g., if D ¼ $1B;
then $204M would be transferred under Option A from
fCg to fBg:
All states are impacted by the new policy. The
expected annual difference in state allocations is com-
puted in Table 4 based on the 1981–2002 average annual
regular appropriations for LIHEAP, EðDÞ ¼ $1:51B;
multiplied by the difference in allotment percentages,
gi � fi: The ‘‘big winners’’ under Option A include Texas
($65M), Florida ($42M), Georgia ($24M), California
($20M), and North Carolina ($18M), while states that
lose money include New York ð�$61MÞ; Minnesota
ð�$35MÞ; Pennsylvania ð�$25MÞ; Wisconsin ð�$25MÞ;
and Massachusetts ð�$19MÞ: See Fig. 2 for a graph of
the expected annual difference in funding under Option
A. The average annual difference in funding levels in
fBg and fCg is $13.4M and �$11:0M; respectively. The
top five states in fCg represent nearly 60% of the total
funds that would be reallocated under Option A to the
top five states in fBg: The remaining funds are
transferred among the 41 other states in fBg and fCg:
To provide a rough measure of the degree of inequity
that has been promulgated over the past decade through
the continued use of the 1981 formula, refer to the last
column in Table 4. The values depicted are based on the
ARTICLE IN PRESS
-100 -50 0 50 100 150 200 250
S
ta
te
s
Percentage Change (%)
{C} {B}
Fig. 1. State LIHEAP allotment percentage change: 1981 vs.
1984
formula.
Table 4
The impact of using the 1984 formula allocation
State Percentage
change (%)
Expected
annual
difference
($M)
10-year
cumulative
impact ($M)
Alabama 95.02 12.34 112.80
Alaska �34.34 �2.85 �26.02
Arizona 200.42 12.59 115.07
Arkansas 84.80 8.40 76.82
California 29.93 20.85 190.62
Colorado �28.38 �6.89 �63.03
Connecticut �33.41 �10.59 �96.79
Delaware 33.73 1.42 12.97
D.C. �17.24 �0.85 �7.76
Florida 205.14 42.15 385.35
Georgia 148.79 24.17 221.00
Hawaii 7.21 0.12 1.08
Idaho �55.66 �5.27 �48.22
Illinois �8.77 �7.70 �70.35
Indiana �15.88 �6.31 �57.65
Iowa �34.33 �9.66 �88.34
Kansas 24.40 3.15 28.84
Kentucky 26.51 5.48 50.08
Louisiana 103.62 13.76 125.77
Maine �54.82 �11.26 �102.89
Maryland 40.82 9.91 90.55
Massachusetts �30.64 �19.42 �177.56
Michigan �12.63 �10.52 �96.20
Minnesota �57.74 �34.64 �316.65
Mississippi 153.94 17.14 156.69
Missouri 3.98 1.40 12.76
Montana �52.58 �5.84 �53.43
Nebraska �40.55 �5.64 �51.60
Nevada 159.36 4.70 42.97
New Hampshire �42.59 �5.15 �47.11
New Jersey �15.97 �9.40 �85.89
New Mexico 3.62 0.28 2.60
New York �31.87 �61.23 �559.73
North Carolina 65.31 18.70 170.97
North Dakota �73.56 �8.88 �81.18
Ohio �5.56 �4.31 �39.42
Oklahoma 65.51 7.82 71.50
Oregon �23.96 �4.51 �41.23
Pennsylvania �24.64 �25.43 �232.51
Rhode Island �32.56 �3.40 �31.06
South Carolina 110.44 11.39 104.13
South Dakota �55.35 �5.43 �49.62
Tennessee 49.99 10.47 95.68
Texas 191.33 65.41 597.96
Utah �27.92 �3.15 �28.81
Vermont �62.14 �5.59 �51.09
Virginia 55.88 16.52 151.00
Washington �27.08 �8.38 �76.65
West Virginia 5.56 0.76 6.95
Wisconsin �45.98 �24.83 �226.98
Wyoming �39.63 �1.79 �16.37
7
Capital redistribution is a zero-sum game.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1447
LIHEAP cumulative allotments from 1992–2002,
$13.80B, multiplied by the allocation differential, gi �
fi: The values shown give an indication of what states
can expect to gain and/or lose over the next decade
should Option A be implemented.
5.2. Comparison by region
Regional comparisons are especially insightful since
they indicate the inequity that the 1984 legislation was
originally intended to address. Assign each state to one
of four census regions: Northeast, North Central, South,
and West, as shown in Table 5. The percentage of the
total appropriation by region according to the 1981 and
1984 formula allocation is shown in Table 6.
States that benefit from Option A are drawn
predominately from the South and to a lesser extent
the West and North Central regions. No state in the
Northeast benefits from a formula change, and hence it
is not surprising that the Northeast forms a strong and
vocal coalition against any changes to LIHEAP’s status
quo (Pataki, 2001). Relative to the 1984 formula, the
Northeast and North Central states receive a 17.6%
over-allotment of funds, which are effectively being
withdrawn from the South. The Southern states mean-
while have expressed dissatisfaction with the mechanism
that promotes this distribution although their criticism
remains rather soft (Patton and Hodges, 2001) con-
sidering the duration and extent of the inequity—
although political considerations may also be at work
here. The Western region as a class does not realize a
noticeable difference in allotment percentages under the
two formulas, although individual states may realize
significant variation, e.g., Arizona (200%), California
(30%), Nevada (159%), Idaho ð�56%Þ; Oregon ð�24%Þ
and Washington ð�27%Þ:
5.3. The cumulative allocation
A description of the cumulative percentage allotment
provides further insight into the allocation mechanism.
Under the 1981 formula, nine states receive 53% of
LIHEAP funds (NY, PA, IL, MI, OH, CA, MA, MN,
NJ); 19 states receive 75% of total funds (WI, IN, MO,
TX, CT, WA, VA, NC, IA, CO), and 33 states receive
90% of funds. Under the 1984 formula, 10 states receive
52% of LIHEAP funds (NY, TX, CA, IL, PA, OH, MI,
FL, NJ, NC); 20 states receive 75% of the funds (VA,
MS, GA, MO, MD, IN, TN, WI, MI, LA); and 30 states
receive 90% of the funds. The placement of states under
the two formulas shift slightly, and from a global
perspective the allotments are quite similar. Under the
1981 formula allocation, 25 states receive less than 1%
of the total funding, while with the 1984 formula, 19
states receive less than a 1% allocation. A cumulative
representation of the two allocations can be compared
by first ordering the elements in descending rank and
then perform a cumulative summation. The result in
Fig. 3 shows the curves to be nearly identical. The 1984
cumulative curve falls ever so below the 1981 curve
indicating an allocation that distributes funds in
aggregate slightly more evenly across states.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
-80 -60 -40 -20 0 20 40 60 80
S
ta
te
s
Expected Annual Difference ($M)
{C} {B}
Fig. 2. Expected difference in annual LIHEAP allotments: 1981
vs.
1984 formula.
Table 6
Percentage of the total appropriation by census region
Region 1981
Allotment
(%)
1984
Allotment
(%)
Difference
(%)
Northeast 33.2 23.2 �10.0
North
Central
34.1 26.5 �7.5
South 19.0 36.6 17.6
West 13.7 13.7 —
Table 5
State assignment via census region
Northeast North Central South West
Connecticut Illinois Alabama
a
Alaska
Maine Indiana Arkansas
a
Arizona
a
Massachusetts Iowa Delaware
a
California
a
New Hampshire Kansas
a
D.C. Colorado
New Jersey Michigan Florida
a
Hawaii
a
New York Minnesota Georgia
a
Idaho
Pennsylvania Missouri
a
Kentucky
a
Montana
Rhode Island Nebraska Louisiana
a
Nevada
a
Vermont North Dakota Maryland
a
New Mexico
a
Ohio Mississippi
a
Oregon
South Dakota North Carolina
a
Utah
Wisconsin Oklahoma
a
Washington
South Carolina
a
Wyoming
Tennessee
a
Texas
a
Virginia
a
West Virginia
a
a
Indicate states that benefit from the application of the 1984
formula allotment.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581448
6. The effect of a trigger-level reduction
Application of the 1981 formula to distribute funds is
considered fundamentally unfair since it does not satisfy
the intent of LIHEAP nor does it allocate federal dollars
in a rational manner. Application of the 1984 formula
was originally tied to a HH provision to protect states
from receiving less money under the new formula.
Unfortunately, regular appropriations for LIHEAP fell
after the 1984 legislation was passed and has come in
under the threshold 15 of the last 17 years, and so by
default, the problematic 1981 formula continues to be
used to distribute federal dollars.
The primary problem with the LIHEAP allocation
mechanism is due to the fact that the trigger level F was
set nearly two decades ago at a value commensurate to
mid-1980 appropriation levels, while actual (real)
appropriations began to slide shortly after the 1984
legislation was passed. Today, the trigger level F ¼
$1:975B is not representative of current LIHEAP
appropriation levels and future appropriation is not
expected to reach F ¼ $1:975B—let alone surpass F to
‘‘turn-on’’ the 1984 formula. To increase the chance of
allocating some funds with the 1984 formula, it is
necessary to lower the value of the trigger. Ultimately,
the value of F will need to be negotiated, and so it is
useful to understand how the selection of F impacts
global measures and individual state allotments. The
basic idea of Option B is to set F at a level below the
expected value of D:
6.1. Theoretical structure
The LIHEAP allocation mechanism described in
Section 2 is first simplified by eliminating the secondary
HH provision, and for analytical purposes, the value of
F is considered variable. The LIHEAP allocation
mechanism is constructed according to Theorem 1 and
its limiting relations are proved in Theorem 2.
Theorem 1. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under
the primary HH-GB provision yields state allotments
according to the following recipe:
AiðF; DÞ ¼
Dfi; iAfSg; DpF;
Ffi; iAfHg; D > F;
Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg; D > F;
8><
>:
where fSg ¼ fHg,fNg; fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g;
fNg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgip1g; Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ; g ¼ X =Q;
X ¼ D � F; and Q ¼
P
iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ:
Proof. See Appendix A.
Theorem 2. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under
the primary HH-GB yields the following limiting rela-
tions:
lim
D=F-1
aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi;
lim
D=F-N
aiðF; DÞ ¼ gi:
Proof. See Appendix A.
The LIHEAP allocation mechanism described in
Theorem 1 and system measures derived from the
mechanism can be expressed as a function of the ratio
D=F as shown in Theorems 3 and 4.
Theorem 3. For D > F; the LIHEAP allocation mechan-
ism under the primary HH-GB provision yields state
allotment percentages
aiðF; DÞ ¼
F
D
fi; iAfHg;
F
D
fi þ
Ei
D
; iAfNg
(
that are functions of the ratio F=D:
Proof. See Appendix B.
Theorem 4. The LIHEAP system measures
sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms
of the ratio D=F as sðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; and rðD=FÞ:
ARTICLE IN PRESS
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
1 4 7
1
0
1
3
1
6
1
9
2
2
2
5
2
8
3
1
3
4
3
7
4
0
4
3
4
6
4
9
Number of States
C
u
m
u
la
ti
v
e
P
e
rc
e
n
ta
g
e
1981 allotment 1984 allotment
Fig. 3. The 1981 and 1984 cumulative percentage LIHEAP
allotment.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1449
Proof. See Appendix B.
6.2. Universal tableaux
Application of the theoretical structure is now
presented. Theorem 1 describes how to construct
state allotments and Theorem 2 presents the limiting
cases when D ¼ F and DbF: The result of Theorems 3
and 4 demonstrate that the LIHEAP allocation percen-
tages, aiðF; DÞ; and aggregate measures sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ;
and rðF; DÞ—which are a function of F and D—can
be expressed in terms of one variable, the ratio D=F:
This is not only a very convenient result but
also quite useful since rather than enumerate all
the various combinations of F and D sepa-
rately, e.g., F ¼ 1; D ¼ ð1; 1:25; 1:5; 1:75; 2:0; yÞ; F ¼
1:5; D ¼ ð1:5; 1:75; 2:0; 2:25; 2:5; 2:75; 3:0; yÞ; etc. one
‘‘universal tableaux’’ suffices to present all relevant
allocation percentages and aggregate measures.
The aggregate measures employed are empirically
derived and are defined formally as follows:
H ¼
P
iAH Ffi Amount of money allocated to
H under the imposition of the
HH provision ($)
G ¼
P
iAH Dgi Amount of money allocated to
H if the HH provision was
eliminated ($)
N ¼
P
iAN Ffi þ X Amount of money allocated to
N under the imposition of the
HH provision ($)
X ¼ D � F Money available for distribu-
tion after all state statutory
floors are maintained ($)
M ¼
P
iAN Dgi Amount of money allocated to
N if the HH provision was
eliminated ($)
sðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=D Percentage of money trans-
ferred from N to H relative to
the total appropriation
D; 0psðD=FÞp1
rðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=M Percentage reduction in the
funding allocation to N due to
the imposition of the HH-GB
provision, 0prðD=FÞp1
iðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=G Percentage increase in the fund-
ing allocation to H due to the
imposition of the HH-GB pro-
vision, 0piðD=FÞp1
pðD=FÞ ¼ H=D Percentage of the total funds D
allocated to H Due to the
imposition of the HH-GB pro-
vision, 0ppðD=FÞp1
qðD=FÞ ¼ G=D Percentage of the total funds D
allocated to H if the HH-GB
provision was eliminated,
0pqðD=FÞp1
H The number of states in H
N The number of states in N
Application of the tableaux follows three steps:
Step 1: Assume D:
Step 2: Select F:
Step 3: Compute D=F:
* If D=Fp1; then read the row of Table 7 (or column
of Table 8) for D=F ¼ 1:
* If 1oD=Fp3; then select the row (or column) for
D=F closest to the ratio value.
* If D=F > 3; then read the row (or column) for
D=F ¼ 3:
The tableaux is easy to use and the results are bound
through the limiting relations described in Theorem 2. A
few examples illustrate the application of the tableaux.
Example. (a) If D ¼ $1:3B and F ¼ $0:5B; then D=F ¼
2:6 and the row for D=F ¼ 2:5 should be used in
Table 7 and the column for D=F ¼ 2:5 should be used
in Table 8.
(b) If D ¼ $1:5B and F ¼ $1B; then use the row and
column in Tables 7 and 8 corresponding to D=F ¼ 1:5:
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Table 7
The impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP
parameters
as a function of D=F for the appropriation level D ($B) and
trigger
level F ($B)
D=F sðD=FÞ rðD=FÞ iðD=FÞ pðD=FÞ qðD=FÞ #fHg #fNg
1.00 20.5 42.4 39.5 72.3 51.8 28 23
1.05 17.0 35.3 32.9 68.8 51.8 28 23
1.10 14.1 24.1 33.8 55.7 41.7 28 23
1.15 11.7 18.5 31.7 48.5 36.8 25 26
1.20 9.7 14.2 31.0 41.1 31.3 23 28
1.25 8.1 11.7 26.0 39.2 31.1 22 29
1.30 6.6 9.5 21.2 37.7 31.1 22 29
1.35 5.3 7.1 21.2 30.3 25.0 20 31
1.40 4.3 5.4 19.5 26.0 21.8 17 34
1.45 3.4 4.2 17.8 22.2 18.9 16 35
1.50 2.8 3.1 28.9 12.6 9.7 13 38
1.55 2.5 2.7 36.8 9.2 6.8 11 40
1.60 2.2 2.4 32.5 9.0 6.8 11 40
1.65 1.9 2.1 28.5 8.7 6.8 11 40
1.70 1.7 1.8 27.8 7.7 6.0 9 42
1.75 1.5 1.6 24.2 7.5 6.0 9 42
1.80 1.3 1.3 22.6 6.8 5.6 8 43
1.85 1.1 1.1 19.3 6.7 5.6 8 43
1.90 1.0 1.0 26.1 4.6 3.6 7 44
1.95 0.8 0.9 22.9 4.5 3.6 7 44
2.00 0.7 0.8 19.8 4.4 3.6 7 44
2.25 0.3 0.3 11.3 2.7 2.4 4 47
2.50 0.1 0.1 27.7 0.5 0.4 2 49
2.75 0.1 0.1 37.5 0.3 0.2 1 50
3.00 0.1 0.1 26.0 0.3 0.2 1 50
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581450
(c) If D ¼ $0:8B and F ¼ $0:75B; then D=F ¼ 1:067
and the row for D=F ¼ 1:05 should be used in Table 7
and the column entry for D=F ¼ 1:1 used in Table 8.
The impact of the primary HH-GB provision on
LIHEAP parameters sðD=FÞ; rðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ;
qðD=FÞ; #fHg and #fNg presented in Table 7 are
graphed in Figs. 4–6. In Table 8 the final LIHEAP
allocation percentages under the primary HH-GB
provision as a function of D=F is depicted. To determine
state allotment dollars for a given value of D and F;
compute D=F; retrieve the appropriate final allotment
ARTICLE IN PRESS
Table 8
Final LIHEAP allocation percentages under the primary HH-GB
provision as a function of D=F
State 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.0 2.5 3.0
Alabama 0.86 1.13 1.32 1.45 1.54 1.59 1.61 1.63 1.64 1.65 1.66
1.67 1.68
Alaska 0.55 0.50
a
0.46
a
0.42
a
0.39
a
0.37
a
0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36
Arizona 0.42 0.72 0.92 1.04 1.13 1.17 1.19 1.21 1.22 1.23 1.23
1.25 1.25
Arkansas 0.66 0.84 0.97 1.06 1.12 1.15 1.17 1.18 1.19 1.20 1.21
1.21 1.21
California 4.61 4.90 5.20 5.45 5.65 5.77 5.82 5.87 5.90 5.92
5.94 5.99 5.99
Colorado 1.61 1.46
a
1.34
a
1.24
a
1.15 1.15 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.15
Connecticut 2.10 1.91
a
1.75
a
1.61
a
1.50
a
1.40 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.40 1.40
Delaware 0.28 0.30 0.32 0.34 0.35 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.37 0.37 0.37
0.37 0.37
D.C. 0.33 0.30
a
0.27
a
0.27 0.26 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27
Florida 1.36 2.38 3.04 3.46 3.74 3.90 3.97 4.02 4.06 4.08 4.10
4.15 4.15
Georgia 1.08 1.64 2.02 2.27 2.43 2.52 2.57 2.60 2.62 2.64 2.65
2.68 2.68
Hawaii 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.12
0.12 0.12
Idaho 0.63 0.57
a
0.52
a
0.48
a
0.45
a
0.42
a
0.39
a
0.37
a
0.35
a
0.33
a
0.31
a
0.28 0.28
Illinois 5.81 5.29
a
5.13 5.11 5.15 5.19 5.21 5.23 5.24 5.25 5.26 5.29 5.30
Indiana 2.63 2.39
a
2.20 2.17 2.17 2.18 2.18 2.19 2.19 2.20 2.20 2.21 2.21
Iowa 1.86 1.69
a
1.55
a
1.43
a
1.33
a
1.24
a
1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22
Kansas 0.86 0.89 0.94 0.97 1.01 1.03 1.04 1.04 1.05 1.05 1.06
1.06 1.06
Kentucky 1.37 1.44 1.51 1.58 1.63 1.67 1.68 1.70 1.70 1.71
1.77 1.73 1.73
Louisiana 0.88 1.19 1.40 1.54 1.64 1.70 1.72 1.74 1.75 1.76
1.77 1.79 1.79
Maine 1.36 1.24
a
1.13
a
1.05
a
0.97
a
0.91
a
0.85
a
0.80
a
0.76
a
0.72
a
0.68
a
0.61 0.61
Maryland 1.61 1.78 1.92 2.04 2.12 2.17 2.19 2.21 2.22 2.23
2.24 2.26 2.26
Massachusetts 4.20 3.82
a
3.50
a
3.23
a
3.00
a
2.90 2.90 2.89 2.90 2.90 2.90 2.91 2.91
Michigan 5.51 5.01
a
4.74 4.69 4.70 4.73 4.74 4.76 4.77 4.78 4.79 4.81 4.82
Minnesota 3.97 3.61
a
3.31
a
3.06
a
2.84
a
2.65
a
2.48
a
2.34
a
2.21
a
2.09
a
1.99
a
1.68 1.68
Mississippi 0.74 1.14 1.41 1.58 1.70 1.76 1.79 1.82 1.83 1.84
1.85 1.87 1.87
Missouri 2.32 2.23 2.24 2.27 2.31 2.35 2.36 2.37 2.38 2.39 2.39
2.41 2.41
Montana 0.74 0.67
a
0.61
a
0.57
a
0.53
a
0.49
a
0.46
a
0.43
a
0.41
a
0.39
a
0.37
a
0.35 0.35
Nebraska 0.92 0.84
a
0.77
a
0.71
a
0.66
a
0.61
a
0.58
a
0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55
Nevada 0.20 0.31 0.38 0.43 0.46 0.48 0.49 0.49 0.50 0.50 0.50
0.51 0.51
New Hampshire 0.79 0.72
a
0.66
a
0.61
a
0.57
a
0.53
a
0.50
a
0.47
a
0.45 0.45 0.45 0.45 0.45
New Jersey 3.90 3.54
a
3.26 3.21 3.21 3.22 3.23 3.24 3.24 3.25 3.26 3.27 3.27
New Mexico 0.52 0.50 0.50 0.51 0.52 0.52 0.53 0.53 0.53 0.53
0.54 0.54 0.54
New York 12.72 11.57
a
10.60
a
9.79
a
9.09
a
8.66 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.66 8.67
North Carolina 1.90 2.28 2.56 2.76 2.90 2.99 3.03 3.06 3.08
3.09 3.10 3.13 3.13
North Dakota 0.80 0.73
a
0.67
a
0.62
a
0.57
a
0.53
a
0.50
a
0.47
a
0.44
a
0.42
a
0.40
a
0.32
a
0.27
a
Ohio 5.14 4.74
a
4.64 4.65 4.70 4.74 4.76 4.78 4.80 4.81 4.82 4.85 4.85
Oklahoma 0.79 0.95 1.07 1.15 1.21 1.25 1.26 1.28 1.28 1.29
1.30 1.31 1.31
Oregon 1.25 1.13
a
1.04
a
0.96
a
0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.95 0.95
Pennsylvania 6.84 6.21
a
5.70
a
5.26
a
5.12 5.10 5.10 5.11 5.11 5.12 5.13 5.15 5.15
Rhode Island 0.69 0.63
a
0.58
a
0.53
a
0.49
a
0.47 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.47 0.47
South Carolina 0.68 0.94 1.12 1.24 1.31 1.36 1.38 1.40 1.41
1.42 1.42 1.44 1.44
South Dakota 0.65 0.59
a
0.54
a
0.50
a
0.46
a
0.43
a
0.41
a
0.38
a
0.36
a
0.34
a
0.32
a
0.29 0.29
Tennessee 1.39 1.58 1.74 1.85 1.94 1.99 2.01 2.03 2.04 2.05
2.06 2.08 2.08
Texas 2.26 3.84 4.86 5.52 5.95 6.20 6.31 6.39 6.45 6.49 6.52
6.58 6.59
Utah 0.75 0.68
a
0.62
a
0.58
a
0.54 0.54 0.53 0.53 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54
Vermont 0.60 0.54
a
0.50
a
0.46
a
0.43
a
0.40
a
0.37
a
0.35
a
0.33
a
0.31
a
0.30
a
0.24
a
0.23
a
Virginia 1.96 2.28 2.53 2.71 2.84 2.92 2.95 2.98 3.00 3.01 3.02
3.05 3.05
Washington 2.05 1.86
a
1.71
a
1.58
a
1.49 1.49 1.48 1.48 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
West Virginia 0.91 0.88 0.88 0.90 0.92 0.93 0.93 0.94 0.95 0.95
0.95 0.95 0.96
Wisconsin 3.58 3.25
a
2.98
a
2.75
a
2.55
a
2.38
a
2.24
a
2.10
a
1.99
a
1.93 1.93 1.93 1.93
Wyoming 0.30 0.27
a
0.25
a
0.23
a
0.21
a
0.20
a
0.19
a
0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18
a
Designates membership in H:
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1451
percentage depicted in Table 8, and then multiply by the
value of D:
AiðD=FÞ ¼ DaiðD=FÞ:
The functionals sðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ; and qðD=FÞ are
defined in terms of the regular appropriation D; while
rðD=FÞ is defined in terms of the money allocated to the
states that fall within the set fNg: When D=F ¼ 1 þ E;
the 28 states in fHg control 72% of the total funds
allocated to the program, and as D increases, pðF; DÞ ¼
H=D declines since the number of states within fHg will
decrease and with it the amount of money that fHg
controls. This is shown in Fig. 4. At D=F ¼ 1:15;
roughly half of the states control half of the total
appropriation. The value of qðF; DÞ ¼ G=D represents
the proportion of funds that the states fHg would
control without the HH-GB provision. The difference
between pðF; DÞ and qðF; DÞ—equivalent to sðF; DÞ—
represents the distortion of the 1984 formula in
percentage terms relative to the total appropriation.
In Fig. 5 the impact of the primary HH-GB provision on
the functional rðD=FÞ represents the percentage reduc-
tion in the funding allocation to fNg due to the HH-GB
provision. The counting functions #fHg and #fNg
count the number of elements of fHg and fNg and is
depicted in Fig. 6. The counting functionals are mirror
images of one another since #fHg þ #fNg ¼ 51; and as
D=F increases, #fHg-0 and fNg-fSg:
6.3. Regional distribution
The state allocation percentages depicted in Table 8
are aggregated according to region and presented
ARTICLE IN PRESS
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1
1.
1
1.
2
1.
3
1.
4
1.
5
1.
6
1.
7
1.
8
1.
9 2
D/F
P
e
rc
e
n
ta
g
e
o
f
D
(
%
)
s (D/F) p (D/F) q (D/F)
Fig. 4. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP
functionals sðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ; and qðD=FÞ:
0
10
20
30
40
50
1
1.
1
1.
2
1.
3
1.
4
1.
5
1.
6
1.
7
1.
8
1.
9 2
D/F
P
e
rc
e
n
ta
g
e
(
%
)
r (D/F)
Fig. 5. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP
functional rðD=FÞ:
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
1
1
.1
5
1
.3
1
.4
5
1
.6
1
.7
5
1
.9
2
.0
5
2
.2
2
.3
5
2
.5
2
.6
5
2
.8
2
.9
5
D/F
N
u
m
b
e
r
o
f
S
ta
te
s
#{H} #{N}
Fig. 6. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on the LIHEAP
counting functionals #fHg and #fNg:
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581452
graphically in Fig. 7 as a function of D=F: The limits of
the distribution for the 1981 formula allotment
ðD=Fp1Þ and the 1984 allotment ðD=FX1:5Þ represent
the endpoints of the graph and were described
previously in Table 6. As the ratio D=F increases federal
allocation percentage in the Northeast and North
Central regions are reallocated to the South, while the
Western region maintains an essentially constant allot-
ment percentage over the entire range of D=F: As D=F
exceeds 1.5 the allotment percentages stabilize as the
impact of the HH-GB provision significantly declines.
Recall from Table 7 that when D=F ¼ 1:5 less than 3%
of the regular appropriation is required to satisfy the
HH provision.
7. Allotment block procedure
An alternative approach to distribute funds that does
not depend on selecting a specific value of F is to ‘‘set-
aside’’ a given percentage of the regular appropriation
to be used with the 1981 formula and then to apply the
1984 formula to the remaining funds. This mechanism
does not hold states harmless in the sense described by
the LIHEAP statute or in the trigger-level re-adjust-
ment, but can be correlated with these allotment
procedures using an approximating algebraic correspon-
dence.
If the percentage of funds allocated through the 1981
formula is denoted by r; then a state’s allotment dollars
for a given fiscal year is given by
AiðrÞ ¼ rDfi þ ð1 � rÞDgi
and its allotment percentage is ai ¼ Ai=D or
aiðrÞ ¼ rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi; 0oro1:
The allotment percentage is a linear combination of fi
and gi and so aðrÞ ¼ ða1; y; a51Þ is an allotment
percentage sinceX
aiðrÞ ¼
X
ðrfi þ ð1 � rÞgiÞ
¼ r
X
fi þ ð1 � rÞ
X
gi ¼ 1:
The value of aðrÞ as a function of r is shown in Table 9.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
1
1.
05 1.
1
1.
15 1.
2
1.
25 1.
3
1.
35 1.
4
1.
45 1.
5
D/F
P
e
rc
e
n
ta
g
e
(
%
)
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Fig. 7. Regional distributional of funds.
Table 9
Weighted linear combination of the 1981 and 1984 formula,
aiðrÞ ¼
rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi
State r
0.2 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.8
Alabama 1.51 1.35 1.27 1.19 1.02
Alaska 0.40 0.44 0.45 0.47 0.51
Arizona 1.08 0.92 0.83 0.75 0.58
Arkansas 1.11 0.99 0.93 0.88 0.77
California 5.72 5.44 5.30 5.17 4.89
Colorado 1.24 1.33 1.38 1.43 1.52
Connecticut 1.54 1.68 1.75 1.82 1.96
Delaware 0.35 0.33 0.33 0.32 0.30
D.C. 0.28 0.29 0.30 0.30 0.31
Florida 3.59 3.04 2.76 2.48 1.92
Georgia 2.36 2.04 1.88 1.72 1.40
Hawaii 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11
Idaho 0.35 0.42 0.45 0.49 0.56
Illinois 5.40 5.50 5.55 5.60 5.71
Indiana 2.30 2.38 2.42 2.46 2.55
Iowa 1.35 1.48 1.54 1.61 1.74
Kansas 1.02 0.98 0.96 0.94 0.90
Kentucky 1.66 1.59 1.55 1.51 1.44
Louisiana 1.61 1.43 1.33 1.24 1.06
Maine 0.76 0.91 0.99 1.06 1.21
Maryland 2.13 2.00 1.93 1.87 1.74
Massachusetts 3.17 3.43 3.55 3.68 3.94
Michigan 4.96 5.10 5.17 5.24 5.38
Minnesota 2.14 2.60 2.83 3.06 3.51
Mississippi 1.65 1.42 1.30 1.19 0.96
Missouri 2.39 2.38 2.37 2.36 2.34
Montana 0.43 0.50 0.54 0.58 0.66
Nebraska 0.62 0.70 0.73 0.77 0.85
Nevada 0.44 0.38 0.35 0.32 0.26
New Hampshire 0.52 0.59 0.62 0.66 0.73
New Jersey 3.40 3.52 3.59 3.65 3.77
New Mexico 0.54 0.53 0.53 0.53 0.52
New York 9.48 10.29 10.70 11.10 11.91
North Carolina 2.89 2.64 2.52 2.39 2.14
North Dakota 0.33 0.45 0.51 0.56 0.68
Ohio 4.91 4.97 5.00 5.02 5.08
Oklahoma 1.20 1.10 1.05 1.00 0.89
Oregon 1.01 1.07 1.10 1.13 1.19
Pennsylvania 5.49 5.82 5.99 6.16 6.50
Rhode Island 0.51 0.56 0.58 0.60 0.65
South Carolina 1.29 1.14 1.06 0.98 0.83
South Dakota 0.36 0.43 0.47 0.51 0.58
Tennessee 1.94 1.80 1.73 1.66 1.53
Texas 5.73 4.86 4.43 4.00 3.13
Utah 0.58 0.62 0.64 0.66 0.71
Vermont 0.30 0.37 0.41 0.45 0.52
Virginia 2.83 2.61 2.50 2.39 2.18
Washington 1.61 1.72 1.77 1.83 1.94
West Virginia 0.95 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.92
Wisconsin 2.26 2.59 2.75 2.92 3.25
Wyoming 0.20 0.23 0.24 0.25 0.28
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1453
7.1. The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ
A useful exercise is to correlate the values of aðrÞ and
aðD=FÞ; that is, for a given value of D=F determine the
value of r such that aðrÞ achieves an allocation
percentage ‘‘equivalent’’ to aðD=FÞ: The limits of the
relation are obvious:
lim
D=F-N
aiðD=FÞ ¼ gi ¼ lim
r-0
aiðrÞ;
lim
D=F-1
aiðD=FÞ ¼ fi ¼ lim
r-1
aiðrÞ
and so we are interested in the correspondence between
aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ for 0oro1: A correspondence using a
least-squares criteria is derived in Theorem 4.
Theorem 5. For a given value of D=F; the final allocation
percentages specified by aðD=FÞ correspond to aðrÞ ¼
rf þ ð1 � rÞg for the least-squares estimator
r ¼ rðD=FÞ ¼
P
aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ �
P
giðfi � giÞP
ðfi � giÞ
2
Proof. See Appendix C.
The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ is
determined through the value of rðD=FÞ shown in
Fig. 8 and provides a useful means to interpret the
HH condition in terms of a simple (linear) allocation
mechanism. For example, when D=F ¼ 1:3; the value of
r that ‘‘equates’’ aðD=FÞ in the least-squares sense with
aðrÞ is given by r ¼ 0:25; or in other words, when D=F ¼
1:3; the allocation mechanism determined through
Option B is roughly equivalent to taking 25% of the
1981 formula values plus 75% of the 1984 formula
values g: The main use of Fig. 8 is as a tool to establish
the relation between competing alternative policies:
* For a given value of D=F; the user can determine how
the average state HH allotment aðD=FÞ distributes
funds in terms of the allocation mechanism aðrÞ ¼
rf þ ð1 � rÞg:
* Since the value of aðrÞ and aðD=FÞ are equivalent
under the derived correspondence, the fairness
criteria employed for aðD=FÞ translates to aðrÞ under
rðD=FÞ:
* A decision maker that can determine a range of
acceptable percentage values for the contribution of f
to the final allotment mechanism can use the
functional rðD=FÞ to determine acceptable D=F
ratios.
7.2. Induced hold-harmless allotment percentages
To illustrate one application of the correspondence
the allotment percentage induced through a reduced
trigger level is computed.
The correspondence functional rðD=FÞ describes the
percentage of the HH provision funding that is allocated
according to the 1981 formula. Hence, using the
correspondence we can determine the effective weight
of the 1981 formula as a function of the trigger level.
Given rðD=FÞ and the historic LIHEAP funding levels
from 1981–2002, the ratio D=F is computed each year
based on the regular appropriation D and trigger level
F; rðD=FÞ is computed, and then the average value of
rðD=FÞ reported:
/rðD=FÞS ¼
P2002
t¼1981 rðD=F; tÞ
21
:
The value /rðD=FÞS describes the expected contribu-
tion of the 1981 formula allotment to the final allotment
percentages for a given value of F:
In Fig. 9 the contribution of the 1981 formula to the
final allotment percentages as a function of the
trigger level F is shown. Since the current trigger
level is F ¼ $1:975B; Fig. 9 illustrates that 98% of
the LIHEAP funds has effectively been allocated based
on the 1981 formula, with 2% of the funds allocated
using the 1984 formula. If F ¼ $1B; then based on
historic levels of LIHEAP funding, 28% of federal
dollars would have been allocated using the 1981
formula with the remaining 72% allocated with the
1984 formula.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1
1.
1
1.
2
1.
3
1.
4
1.
5
1.
6
1.
7
1.
8
1.
9 2
D/F
r
(%
)
Fig. 8. The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ:
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.975 1.75 1.5 1.25 1 0.75 0.5 0.25
F ($B)
r
(%
)
Fig. 9. Induced allotment percentage of the HH-GB provision
based
on LIHEAP funding levels, 1981–2002.
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581454
7.3. Re-interpreting the primary hold-harmless provision
The LIHEAP allocation percentages under the
primary HH provision (Option B) can be interpreted
in a manner analogous to the allotment block proce-
dure. Recall that for states iAfNg;
AiðF; DÞ ¼ Ffi þ Ei ¼ Ffi þ gðDgi � FfiÞ
¼ ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi
or
aiðF; DÞ ¼ ð1 � gÞkfi þ ggi;
where k ¼ F=D and g ¼ X =Q: For a given value of D >
F; ko1; and so the term kfi represents a reduction in
the 1981 formula percentage. As D increases, k
approaches zero while the term g approaches one (recall
Theorem 1), indicating that the contribution to aiðF; DÞ
from fi will approach zero. The LIHEAP allocation
percentages in Option B is thus similar in structure to
the allotment block procedure, but while the parameter r
is a decision parameter, the value of k and g is dependent
on D=F and is not controllable unless the ratio D=F is
legislated.
8. Simplified legislative road map
The main issues surrounding the LIHEAP debate are
summarized as follows:
* The 1981 distribution formula is not an appropriate
baseline.
* Corporate scandals are sexy and good publicity
issues, while government ‘‘scandals’’ resist debate.
* Impetus to change LIHEAP will always be an uphill
struggle since the votes for change simply do not add
up for any of the alternatives described.
* Full ‘‘disclosure’’ and transparency may help lead to
change.
* Shame is a good motivator for change.
* Arguments should be based on essential facts and a
clear storyline.
A legislative ‘‘road map’’ of sorts is suggested to help
push LIHEAP along in the right direction. Since a
simple count of votes is not expected to add up in favor
of changing the LIHEAP allocation mechanism, the
story presented must be moral tale and based on
established facts. Shame is used as the primary
motivator for change.
Fact 1: The high trigger level established within the
1984 re-authorization legislation has disabled the
application of the 1984 formula.
Shame/result: The 1981 formula is still being used to
distribute LIHEAP funding to this day (inequitable
program).
Fact 2: The 1981 formula allotments hold little
meaning 20 years after their creation and should not
be used to distribute federal dollars.
Shame/result: LIHEAP allotments to states are not
distributed in a rational manner (poorly executed
program).
Fact 3: The primary intent of LIHEAP is to assist
low-income households meet their home energy needs.
Shame/result: LIHEAP funds are not being distrib-
uted in accord with the program intent (irrational
program).
9. Conclusions
The purpose of this paper was to propose policy
alternatives for distributing LIHEAP funds to states and
to quantify the impact of each alternative. Three policy
alternatives were examined.
In the first alternative, the LIHEAP trigger level is
nullified and the HH-GB provisions attached to the
allocation are eliminated. The 1984 formula is applied in
‘‘pure’’ form unencumbered by the weight of additional
provisions or conditions. This policy alternative paral -
lels the Bush Administration position expressed in the
FY 2003 federal budget and is the simplest and probably
the best of the three options considered, although it is
not expected to develop the political support necessary
to achieve passage.
In the second alternative, the primary HH-GB
provision of the LIHEAP statute is maintained but the
trigger level when it is enabled is reduced. Regular
appropriations for LIHEAP generally do not exceed the
current trigger F ¼ $1:975B; and in fact, have only
exceeded this level twice in the past 17 years—the last
time in FY 1986. At one time (15-years ago) the values
of D and F were roughly comparable, while today F
appears as a large (mostly unattainable) upper bound.
Reducing the current trigger level increases the like-
lihood that the 1984 formula will be applied, and since
this alternative does not involve the complete disman-
tling of the legislative statute, it is also likely to garner
more political support. It should be mentioned, how -
ever, that even under this alternative a majority of states
are still worse off under the new allocation percentages,
and hence, even the passage of compromise legislation
might fail to generate sufficient support. Legislation that
sponsors a trigger-level reduction must be crafted to
ensure the reduction is significant or further drift
between D and F may result in the future. Re-adjusting
F downward may yield the desired outcome, but from a
programmatic perspective, also perpetrates the applica-
tion/justification of the 1981 formula, which is con-
sidered a major drawback.
In the third alternative, a simple allocation mechan-
ism was examined that set-aside a given percentage of
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1455
the regular appropriation to be used exclusively with the
1981 formula with the remaining funds allocated under
the 1984 formula. The advantage of this mechanism is
that the 1984 formula will always be incorporated within
the allotment procedure regardless of the level of regular
appropriation, and hence the downside risk (i.e., when
DpF ) is always covered. On the other hand, it may be
difficult to negotiate the value of r; and once selected, r
fixes the allotment percentages and does not allow the
upside potential of the 1984 formula (i.e., when D > F )
to be realized. Since the upside potential of the 1984
formula has only a low probability of occurrence,
however, this does not seem to be an extenuating factor.
‘‘Mixing’’ the formula allocations is also not a preferred
procedure from a legislative or methodological perspec-
tive, although as shown in Theorem 4, a correspondence
does exists between the mixed formula and the triggered
hold-harmless provision. Hence, the user can always
view the allotment block procedure in terms of a trigger-
level enabled mechanism.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to acknowledge the role
Carolyn Drake had in introducing the LIHEAP
problem to the authors and suggesting its initial
formulation. Her encouragement, guidance, and pa-
tience is kindly recognized. The authors would also like
to thank Kathy Baskin, Elizabeth Jones, Beth Osborne,
Ed Rissing, and Fred Zeytoonjian for their support,
insight, and useful criticisms of this work. Funding for
this research was provided in part by the Southern
States Energy Board, but all opinions, findings, and
results remain the responsibility of the authors.
Appendix A. Derivation of the LIHEAP structure
equations
Theorem 1. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under
the primary HH-GB provision yields state allotments
according to the following recipe:
AiðF; DÞ ¼
Dfi; iAfSg; DpF;
Ffi; iAfHg; D > F;
Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg; D > F;
8><
>:
where fSg ¼ fHg,fNg; fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g;
fNg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgip1g; Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ; g ¼ X =Q;
X ¼ D � F; and Q ¼
P
iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ:
Proof. If DpF; then following the current LIHEAP
statute, AiðF; DÞ ¼ Dfi for all iAfSg: If D > F; then
partition fSg into two sets according to whether state i
satisfies Ffi > Dgi or FfipDgi: The class of states labeled
fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g are the HH states which are held
at their statutory floor. The class of states labeled fNg ¼
fi j Ffi=Dgip1g will have an allotment falling above
their floor. All states in fHg are assigned their statutory
floor, while states in fNg are assigned their statutory
floor plus an amount Ei that needs to be determined
AiðF; DÞ ¼
Ffi; iAfHg;
Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg:
(
Since statutory floors are maintained across all states,
the HH-GB provision in essence captures F of the
regular appropriated dollars D:
D ¼
X
iAfSg
AiðF; DÞ ¼
X
iAfHg
Ffi þ
X
iAfNg
ðFfi þ EiÞ
¼
X
iAfHg
Ffi þ
X
iAfNg
Ffi þ
X
iAfNg
Ei
¼ F
X
iAfSg
fi þ
X
iAfNg
Ei ¼ F þ
X
iAfNg
Ei:
The value
X ¼
X
iAfNg
Ei ¼ D � F
represents the dollars available to the states in fNg after
the statutory floor money is assigned to all the states in
fSg:
To determine the extra allotment that each state in
fNg receives, state i’s allotment ‘‘above the floor’’
Dgi � Ffi; iAfNg
is computed, and since
Q ¼
X
iAfNg
ðDgi � FfiÞ > X ;
the value of Q will need to be reduced so that it matches
the available funds X : The value of X is thus a binding
constraint. The reduction factor g ¼ X =Q is applied
across each state’s money above the floor, and the value
of Ei is calculated as
Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ:
Observe that the sum of the ‘‘extra’’ state allotments is by
construction equal to the available funds X as required:X
iAfNg
Ei ¼ g
X
iAfNg
ðDgi � FfiÞ
¼
X
Q
X
iAfNg
ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ X : &
Theorem 2. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under
the primary HH-GB yields the following limiting relations:
lim
D=F-1
aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi;
lim
D=F-N
aiðF; DÞ ¼ gi:
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581456
Proof. By the definition of the allocation mechanism,
when D=F-1; it is clear that
lim
D=F-1
aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi; iAfSg:
On the other hand, as the ratio D=F increases it is clear
that #fHg-0 and fNg-fSg: Then since Q ¼P
iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ;
lim
D=F-N
X
iAfNg
ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼
X
iAfSg
ðDgi � FfiÞ
¼ D
X
iAfSg
gi � F
X
iAfSg
fi ¼ D � F;
i.e.,
lim
D=F-N
g ¼ lim
D=F-N
X
Q
¼
D � F
D � F
¼ 1:
Then since AiðF; DÞ ¼ Ffi þ Ei ¼ Ffi þ gðDgi � FfiÞ ¼
ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi;
lim
D=F-N
AiðF; DÞ ¼ lim
g-1
½ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi
¼ Dgi
or
lim
D=F-N
aiðF; DÞ ¼
AiðF; DÞ
D
¼ gi: &
Appendix B. One-dimensional LIHEAP system measures
Theorem 3. For D > F; the LIHEAP allocation mechan-
ism under the primary HH-GB provision yield state
allotment percentages
aiðF; DÞ ¼
F
D
fi; iAfHg;
F
D
fi þ
Ei
D
; iAfNg
(
that are functions of the ratio F/D.
Proof. Let k ¼ F=Da0: It is sufficient to show that
aiðF; DÞ is a constant:
(i) If iAfHg; then aiðF; DÞ ¼ ðF=DÞfi ¼ kfi; which is a
constant since fi is constant.
(ii) If iAfNg; then aiðF; DÞ ¼ ðF=DÞfi þ ðEi=DÞ ¼ kfi þ
ðEi=DÞ:
It is sufficient to show Ei=D is constant.
Ei
D
¼
X
DQ
ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼
X
Q
gi �
F
D
fi
�
¼
X
Q
ðgi � kfiÞ ¼ k
0 X
Q
;
where k0 ¼ gi � kfi is constant since gi is constant. Now
X =Q ¼ X =D=Q=D and
X
D
¼
D � F
D
¼ 1 �
F
D
¼ 1 � k
a constant, and
Q
D
¼
D
P
iAfNg gi � F
P
iAfNg fi
D
¼
X
iAfNg
gi �
F
D
X
iAfNg
fi ¼
X
iAfNg
gi � k
X
iAfNg
fi:
The summation terms
P
iAfNg fi;
P
iAfHg fi;
P
iAfNg gi;
and
P
iAfHg gi are all constant since the elements of
fHg ¼ i j
Ffi
Dgi
> 1
�
¼ i j k
fi
gi
> 1
�
;
fNg ¼ i j
Ffi
Dgi
p1
�
¼ i j k
fi
gi
p1
�
are constant, and so Q=D is constant, and thus, X =Q is
constant. Hence, aiðF; DÞ is a constant and can be
expressed as aiðF=DÞ; or equivalently, since k ¼
F=Da0; as aiðD=FÞ: &
Theorem 4. The LIHEAP system measures
sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms
of the ratio D=F as sðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; and rðD=FÞ:
Proof. Let k ¼ F=Da0: It suffices to show that
sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ are constants. By definition
of the functionals sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ;
sðF; DÞ ¼
H � G
D
¼
H
D
�
G
D
¼
F
P
iAfHg fi
D
�
D
P
iAfHg gi
D
¼ k
X
iAfHg
fi �
X
iAfHg
gi;
is a constant, and so sðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms of
the ratio sðD=FÞ: Similarly,
iðF; DÞ ¼
H � G
G
¼
H
G
� 1
¼
F
P
iAfHg fi
D
P
iAfHg gi
� 1 ¼ k
P
iAfHg fiP
iAfHg gi
� 1
a constant, and
rðF; DÞ ¼
H � G
M
¼
H
M
�
G
M
¼
F
P
iAfHg fi
D
P
iAfNg gi
�
D
P
iAfHg gi
D
P
iAfNg gi
¼ k
P
iAfHg fiP
iAfNg gi
�
P
iAfHg giP
iAfNg gi
a constant, and so iðF; DÞ and rðF; DÞ can be expressed
as iðD=FÞ and rðD=FÞ: &
Appendix C. Derivation of the least-squares estimator
Theorem 5. For a given value of D/F, the final allocation
percentages specified by aðD=FÞ correspond to aðrÞ ¼
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
1458 1457
rf þ ð1 � rÞg for the least-squares estimator
r ¼ rðD=FÞ ¼
P
aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ �
P
giðfi � giÞP
ðfi � giÞ
2
:
Proof. For a given value of the ratio D=F; the value of r
that minimizes the sum of the squared differences
between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ is determined as follows. Let
f ðrÞ ¼
X
ðaiðD=FÞ � aiðrÞÞ
2:
Then the solution to minr f ðrÞ is determined by solving
dðf ðrÞÞ=dr ¼ 0 orX
ðaiðD=FÞ � aiðrÞÞ
daiðrÞ
dr
¼ 0:
Since aiðrÞ ¼ rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi; dðaiðrÞÞ=dr ¼ fi � gi; and
solving for r yields
r ¼
P
aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ �
P
giðfi � giÞP
ðfi � giÞ
2
:
The second-derivative test yields
d
2
f ðrÞ
dr
¼ �
daiðrÞ
dr
� 2
o0
ensuring that r is a minimum value of f ðrÞ: &
References
Abbey, C.W., 2001. The low-income home energy assistance
program:
how are state allotments determined? CRS Report RS 20893,
Washington, D.C., April.
Colton, R., 1990. Client consumption patterns within an
income-based
energy assistance program. Journal of Economic Issues 24 (4),
1079–1093.
General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1986. Low Income
Energy
Assistance: state responses to 1984 amendments. Report to
Congressional Committees, GAO/HRD-86-92, Washington,
D.C., May.
General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1987. Energy
conservation:
funding state energy assistance programs. Fact Sheet for the
Ranking Minority Member, Committee on the Budget, United
State Senate, GAO/RCED-87-114FS, Washington, D.C., March.
General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1990. Low Income
Home
Energy Assistance: a program overview. Briefing Report to the
Chairman, Subcommittee on Human Resources, Committee on
Education and Labor, House of Representatives, GAO/HRD-91-
1-BR, Washington, D.C., October.
Gish, M., 2000. The low-income home energy assistance
program.
CRS Report 94-211, Washington, D.C., June.
Higgins, L., Lutzenhiser, L., 1995. Ceremonial equity: low -
income
energy assistance and the failure of socio-environmental policy.
Social Problems 42 (4), 468–492.
Kennedy, J.M., 1987. Public support for residential energy
assistance.
Sociology and Social Research 71, 308–311.
Kingsley, G.A., 1992. US energy conservation policy: themes
and
trends. Policy Studies Journal 20, 114–123.
Landsberg, H.H., Dukert, J.M., 1981. High Energy Costs:
Uneven?
Unfair? Unavoidable? Johns Hopkins University Press,
Baltimore,
MD.
Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1983. Report
to
Congress For Fiscal Year 1982, US Department of Human
Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of
Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, November.
Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1985. Report
to
Congress For Fiscal Year 1983, US Department of Human
Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of
Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, May.
Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1994. Report
to
Congress For Fiscal Year 1993, US Department of Human
Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of
Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, October.
Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 2000. Report
to
Congress For Fiscal Year 1996, US Department of Human
Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of
Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance,
September.
Pataki, G.E. (Governor), 2001. Statement of the Coalition of
Northeastern Governors to the House Appropriations Subcom-
mittee on Interior and Related Agencies regarding FY 2002
appropriations for the US Department of Energy’s
Weatherization
Assistance Program and State Energy Program, April 16.
Patton, P., Hodges, J. (Governors), 2001. Resolution regarding
the
national energy policy. Southern Governors’ Association 67th
Annual Meeting, Lexington, KY, September 9.
Stoltzfus, E., 2002. The low-income home energy assistance
program
(LIHEAP). CRS Report 94-211, Washington, D.C., January.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–
14581458
CRS Report for Congress
Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and
Current Law
Libby Perl
Specialist in Housing Policy
September 8, 2010
Congressional Research Service
7-5700
www.crs.gov
RL33275
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service
Summary
The Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP)
provides funds to states, the
District of Columbia, U.S. territories and commonwealths, and
Indian tribal organizations
(collectively referred to as grantees) primarily to help low -
income households pay home energy
expenses. The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of
funding: regular funds (sometimes
referred to as block grant funds) and emergency contingency
funds. Regular funds are allocated to
grantees based on a formula, while contingency funds may be
released to one or more grantees at
the discretion of the Secretary of the Department of Health and
Human Services based on
emergency need.
Regular LIHEAP funds are allocated to the states according to a
formula that has a long and
complicated history. (Tribes receive funds based on either their
number of federally eligible
LIHEAP households compared to the total number in the state
or on agreements with their states,
whereas territories receive a set percentage of total LIHEAP
regular funds.) In 1980, Congress
created the predecessor program to LIHEAP, the Low Income
Energy Assistance Program
(LIEAP) as part of the Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act (P.L.
96-223). Because Congress was
particularly concerned with the high costs of heating, funds
under LIEAP were distributed
according to a multi-step formula that benefitted cold-weather
states. In 1981, Congress enacted
LIHEAP as part of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act
(P.L. 97-35), replacing LIEAP.
However, the LIHEAP statute specified that states would
continue to receive the same percentage
of regular funds that they did under the LIEAP formula.
When Congress reauthorized LIHEAP in 1984 as part of the
Human Services Reauthorization Act
(P.L. 98-558), it changed the program’s formula by requiring
the use of more recent population
and energy data and requiring that HHS consider both heating
and cooling costs of low-income
households (a change from the focus on the heating needs of all
households). The effect of these
changes meant that, in general, funds would be shifted from
cold-weather states to warm-weather
states. To prevent a dramatic shift of funds, Congress added two
“hold-harmless” provisions to
the formula. The result of these provisions is a current law,
three-tiered formula (sometimes
referred to as the “new” formula), the application of which
depends on the amount of regular
funds that Congress appropriates.
The Tier I formula is used to allocate funds when the total
LIHEAP regular fund appropriation is
less than or equal to the equivalent of a hypothetical FY1984
appropriation of $1.975 billion.
Above this level, funds are allocated according to Tier II of the
formula, which includes a hold-
harmless level to prevent certain states from losing LIHEAP
funds. Finally, Tier III applies to
appropriations at or above $2.25 billion, and includes a second
hold-harmless provision, the hold-
harmless rate. Since FY1986, LIHEAP regular fund
appropriations have exceeded the equivalent
of an FY1984 appropriation of $1.975 billion in FY2006, when
the regular fund appropriation
was $2.48 billion; in FY2008, when appropriations slightly
exceeded the trigger; and in FY2009
and FY2010, when Congress directed that $840 million be
distributed according to the “new”
LIHEAP formula.
This report will be updated when new formula data are released
and when proposed funding
levels change (see Appendix C).
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service
Contents
Introduction
...............................................................................................
................................. 1
Predecessor Programs to LIHEAP
...............................................................................................
2
Community Services Administration Energy Assistance
Programs......................................... 2
Low Income Energy Assistance Program (LIEAP)
................................................................ 5
The LIEAP
Formula..................................................................................
...................... 6
Enactment of LIHEAP
...............................................................................................
................. 8
Continued Use of the LIEAP Formula
................................................................................... 9
The 1984 LIHEAP Reauthorization: A New Formula
............................................................ 9
Formula Discussions
...............................................................................................
........ 9
Introduction of a Hold-Harmless
Level.......................................................................... 10
Introduction of a Hold-Harmless Rate
........................................................................... 10
LIHEAP Formula Statutory Language
........................................................................... 11
Determining LIHEAP Regular Fund Allotments Using the
“New” Formula ............................... 12
Calculating the New Formula Rates
.................................................................................... 12
Using the New Formula Rates to Allocate Funds to the States
............................................. 14
Tier I: Below $1.975
Billion....................................................................................
...... 15
Tier II: From $1.975 Billion up to $2.25 Billion
............................................................ 15
Tier III: At or Above $2.25 Billion
................................................................................ 16
Implementation of the “New” LIHEAP Formula
................................................................. 17
Figures
Figure B-1. Estimated Low Income Home Energy Assistance
(LIHEAP) Allocations at
Various Hypothetical Appropriations Levels for Three Types of
States ................................... 27
Tables
Table 1. Select Energy Assistance Formulas, FY1975-FY1980
.................................................... 4
Table 2. Distribution of Funds Under
LIEAP............................................................................... 8
Table 3. Low-Income Home Energy Program (LIHEAP): “Old”
and “New” Allotment
Rates by State,
2010.......................................................................................
........................ 17
Table 4. Recent State Allotment Rates Under the “New”
LIHEAP Formula ............................... 20
Table A-1. LIHEAP Estimated State Allotments for Regular
Funds at Various
Hypothetical Appropriation Levels
......................................................................................... 23
Table C-1. LIHEAP Actual State Regular Fund Allotments for
FY2006 through FY2010
and Estimated FY2011 Allotments
......................................................................................... 30
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service
Appendixes
Appendix A. Estimated Allotments to the States Under Various
Hypothetical
Appropriations Levels
...............................................................................................
............. 22
Appendix B. Further Depiction of How State Allotments Depend
Upon Appropriation
Levels
...............................................................................................
..................................... 26
Appendix C. Actual LIHEAP Regular Fund Allocations to the
States, FY2006-FY2010
and Estimated Allocations,
FY2011...................................................................................
..... 28
Contacts
Author Contact Information
...............................................................................................
....... 34
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service 1
Introduction
The Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP)
is a block grant program
administered by the Department of Health and Human Services
(HHS) under which the federal
government gives annual grants to states, the District of
Columbia, U.S. territories and
commonwealths, and Indian tribal organizations to operate
multi-component home energy
assistance programs for needy households.1 Established in 1981
by Title XXVI of P.L. 97-35, the
Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act, LIHEAP has been
reauthorized and amended a number of
times, most recently in 2005, when P.L. 109-58, the Energy
Policy Act, authorized annual regular
LIHEAP funds at $5.1 billion per year from FY2005 through
FY2007.2
The federal LIHEAP statute has very broad guidelines, with
almost all decisions regarding the
program’s operation made by the states. Recipients may be
helped with their heating and cooling
costs, receive crisis assistance, have weatherizing expenses
paid, or receive other aid designed to
reduce their home energy needs. Households with incomes up to
150% of the federal poverty
income guidelines or, if greater, 60% of the state median
income, are federally eligible for
LIHEAP benefits. States may adopt lower income limits, but no
household with income below
110% of the poverty guidelines may be considered ineligible.
Note, however, that in the FY2009
and FY2010 appropriations acts (P.L. 110-329 and P.L. 111-
117), Congress gave states the
authority to raise eligibility limits to 75% of state median
income. The most current HHS data
show that an estimated 5.5 million households received winter
heating or winter crisis assistance
in FY2006 (the largest share of LIHEAP funds pay for heating
assistance).3
The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of program funding:
regular funds—sometimes
referred to as block grant funds—and emergency contingency
funds. Regular funds are allotted to
states on the basis of the LIHEAP statutory formula, which was
enacted as part of the Human
Services Reauthorization Act of 1984 (P.L. 98-558).4 The way
in which regular funds are
allocated to states depends on the amount of funds appropriated
by Congress. The second type of
LIHEAP funds, emergency contingency funds, may be released
and allotted to one or more states
at the discretion of the President and the Secretary of HHS.5
The funds may be released at any
point in the fiscal year to meet additional home energy
assistance needs created by a natural
disaster or other emergency.6
The remainder of this report discusses only the history and
methods of distributing regular
LIHEAP funds.
1 For additional information on LIHEAP, see CRS Report
RL31865, The Low Income Home Energy Assistance
Program (LIHEAP): Program and Funding, by Libby Perl.
2 LIHEAP is codified at 42 U.S.C. §§8621-8630.
3 U.S. Department of Health and Human Services,
Administration for Children and Families, FY2006 LIHEAP
Report
to Congress, April 22, 2009, p. 21.
4 The formula section is codified at 42 U.S.C. §8623.
5 Depending on how Congress appropriates them, contingency
funds may remain available for distribution in more than
one fiscal year or they may expire with the fiscal year for which
they were appropriated.
6 The statutory definition of emergency includes a significant
home energy supply shortage or disruption, a significant
increase in the cost of home energy, a significant increase in
home energy disconnections, a significant increase in
participation in a public benefit program, a significant increase
in unemployment, or an event meeting such criteria as
the Secretary determines to be appropriate. 42 U.S.C. §8622.
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service 2
Predecessor Programs to LIHEAP
The mid- to late-1970s, a time marked by rapidly rising fuel
prices, also marked the beginning of
federal energy assistance funding for low-income households.
The first national program to help
low-income households was created in early 1975 to assist
families with energy conservation
primarily through home weatherization. This assistance was
provided through a new Emergency
Energy Conservation Program (EECP), enacted as part of the
Headstart, Economic Opportunity,
and Community Partnership Act of 1974 (P.L. 93-644). The
funds were administered by the
Community Services Administration (CSA), the successor
agency to the Office of Economic
Opportunity, which was responsible for many of the programs
created as part of the 1964 war on
poverty. Beginning in 1977, funds were also made available
through the CSA to help families
directly pay for fuel (as opposed to weatherization expenses)
via a variety of programs. Each of
these programs had in common a focus on the need for heating
assistance (versus cooling
assistance).
Congress continued to appropriate funds for energy assistance
programs through FY1980, at
which point a new program, the Low Income Energy Assistance
Program (LIEAP) was enacted
as part of the Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act of 1980 (P.L.
96-223). LIEAP, which was
administered by the Department of Health and Human Services
(HHS), was funded for one year,
FY1981, before the creation of LIHEAP. Like the CSA
programs, LIEAP emphasized heating
over cooling needs. This preference was reflected in both the
CSA program formulas and the
LIEAP set of formulas, which used variables that benefitted
cold-weather states to determine how
funds would be distributed. The LIEAP set of formulas
continues to have relevance for the way in
which LIHEAP funds are distributed. This section of the report
describes these predecessor
programs to LIHEAP and their distribution formulas.
Community Services Administration Energy Assistance
Programs
On January 4, 1975, President Ford signed into law the
Headstart, Economic Opportunity, and
Community Partnership Act of 1974 (P.L. 93-644), which
contained funds for a new program,
called the Emergency Energy Conservation Program (EECP).
The program was to be
administered by the Community Services Administration (CSA),
and its purpose was
to enable low-income individuals and families, including the
elderly and the near poor, to
participate in energy conservation programs designed to lessen
the impact of the high cost of
energy ... and to reduce ... energy consumption.
The law governing EECP listed a number of eligible activities
in which states could participate,
including energy conservation and education programs;
weatherization assistance; loans and
grants for the purchase of energy conservation technologies;
alternative fuel supplies; and fuel
voucher and stamp programs. Despite the variety of activities
that could be funded through the
program, the first CSA funding notice regarding the program
limited eligible activities to
“winterizing” homes and to giving emergency assistance “to
prevent hardship or danger to health
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service 3
due to utility shutoff or lack of fuel.”7 During the four years the
EECP was funded, the majority
of funds were used for weatherization expenses.8
EECP funds were distributed to states via a formula that
benefitted those states with high heating
costs. One formula variable in particular, a measure of
“coldness” called heating degree days,
benefitted cold-weather states. Heating degree days measure the
extent to which a day’s average
temperature falls below 65° Fahrenheit. For example, a day with
an average temperature of 50°
results in a measure of 15 heating degree days. Because heating
degree days are higher in cold
weather states, including the heating degree day variable in a
formula favors states with greater
heating needs. Squaring the heating degree days magnifies this
effect.9 The EECP formula took
the number of population-weighted heating degree days in each
state, squared them, and
multiplied the result by the number of households in poverty
that owned their homes to determine
how funds would be allocated.10 The CSA acknowledged the
emphasis on heating needs in its
formula, stating that the FY1975 allocation “was heavily
weighted to the coldest areas.”11 In the
three fiscal years that followed the first appropriation for the
EECP, from FY1976 through
FY1978, the CSA changed somewhat the way in which it
allocated funds to the states; however,
the factors continued to favor cold-weather states through use of
either heating degree days or
heating degree days squared.12
The first year that Congress specifically appropriated funds for
direct assistance to help low-
income households (those at or below 125% of poverty) pay
their energy costs (instead of funds
that went primarily for weatherization and conservation
activities) was FY1977. The FY1977
Supplemental Appropriations Act (P.L. 95-26) provided $200
million for a Special Crisis
Intervention Program to be administered by CSA. States could
use funds to make direct payments
to fuel providers on behalf of low-income families lacking the
financial resources to pay their
energy bills. The CSA directed states to target households
where utilities had been shut off (or
were threatened with shut off) and who could prove dire need
due to large energy bills.13
Although the law did not reserve funds exclusively for heating
costs, the way in which funds
were allocated to the states emphasized heating need. Funds
were distributed to the states based
on a formula that used (1) heating degree days squared, (2) the
number of households in poverty,
(3) the number of persons above age 65 with incomes below
125% of poverty, and (4) the relative
cost of fuel in the region.14 Congress again appropriated $200
million for crisis intervention in
7 Community Services Administration, “Character and Scope of
Specific Community Action Programs: Emergency
Energy Conservation Program,” Federal Register, vol. 40, no.
145, July 28, 1975, p. 31603.
8 See, for example, House Appropriations Committee, report to
accompany H.R. 4877, the FY1977 Supplemental
Appropriations Act, 95th Cong., 1st sess., H.Rept. 95-68, March
11, 1977: “The funds in this program are used primarily
to purchase materials to insulate the homes of low -income
families.”
9 For example, if a southern state experiences 700 heating
degree days in a year and a northern state experiences 7,000,
the northern state has 10 times as many heating degree days as
the southern state. However, if both numbers are
squared, the northern state has 100 times as many heating
degree days as the southern state.
10 Community Services Administration, “Emergency Energy
Conservation Program: Submission of Funding Plans,”
Federal Register, vol. 41, no. 208, October 27, 1976, p. 47096.
11 Federal Register, vol. 41, no. 208, October 27, 1976, p.
47096.
12 See Ibid., pp. 47096-47097.
13 Community Services Administration, “Special Crisis
Intervention Program: General Information, Application
Procedures, and Post Grant Requirements,” Federal Register,
vol. 42, no. 125, June 29, 1977, p. 33240.
14 The formula was described in the Senate Appropriations
Committee report to accompany H.R. 4877, the FY1977
Supplemental Appropriations Act, 95th Cong., 1st sess., S.Rept.
95-64, March 24, 1977. The CSA implemented this
formula, which it described in guidance to the states. See the
Federal Register, Ibid.
The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law
Congressional Research Service 4
both FY1978 and FY1979.15 In FY1978, funds were available
to households with the need for
assistance as the result of an energy-related emergency such as
lack of fuel, a natural disaster, fuel
shortages, and widespread unemployment.16 In FY1979, funds
were made available to assist
families facing “substantially increased energy costs and/ or life-
or health-threatening situations
caused by winter-related energy emergencies.”17
In FY1980, Congress appropriated a total of $1.6 billion for
energy assistance. Of this amount,
$400 million was appropriated for the Energy Crisis Assistance
Program (ECAP, a CSA program
similar to the Special Crisis Intervention Program) through two
separate appropriations.18 The
remainder, $1.2 billion, was appropriated as part of the FY1980
Department of the Interior
Appropriations Act (P.L. 96-126) to the Department of Health,
Education, and Welfare (HEW, the
predecessor to HHS) for cash assistance and crisis intervention
due to high energy costs. This
appropriation to HEW is sometimes referred to as Low Income
Supplemental Energy Allowances.
Of this $1.2 billion, $400 million was to be distributed
specifically to recipients of Supplemental
Security Income (SSI). The rest of the funds appropriated to
HEW, approximately $800 million,
as well as the ECAP funds, were distributed to states on the
basis of three factors: heating degree
days squared, the number of households below 125% of poverty,
and the difference in home
heating energy expenditures between 1978 and 1979. The
formula used to distribute the $400
million for SSI recipients used these same factors but also
included the number of SSI recipients
in each state relative to the national total.
Table 1. Select Energy Assistance Formulas, FY1975-FY1980
Emergency Energy
Conservation Program:a
FY1975
(P.L. 93-644)
Special Crisis
Intervention Program:b
FY1977
(P.L. 95-26)
Low Income Supplemental Energy
Allowances:c
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa
Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa

More Related Content

Similar to Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa

A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...
A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...
A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...New York Public Transit Association
 
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional Meetings
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional MeetingsARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional Meetings
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional MeetingsCSW
 
ARRA Overview
ARRA OverviewARRA Overview
ARRA OverviewCSW
 
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Scott Clausen
 
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)Brad Keithley
 
Public Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxPublic Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxBedri Muktar
 
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1Dylan Potter
 
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined Reporting
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined ReportingAre Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined Reporting
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined ReportingBrian Strahle
 
Five Debates over Macroeconomic Policy
Five Debates over Macroeconomic PolicyFive Debates over Macroeconomic Policy
Five Debates over Macroeconomic PolicyTuul Tuul
 
LABI 2010 Presentation
LABI 2010 PresentationLABI 2010 Presentation
LABI 2010 PresentationTana Trichel
 
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Tiago Nunes
 
Bybdh economics of state governments
Bybdh economics of state governmentsBybdh economics of state governments
Bybdh economics of state governmentsMeshack Kitunguu
 
The Fair Property Assessment Plan
The Fair Property Assessment PlanThe Fair Property Assessment Plan
The Fair Property Assessment PlanDaoshi Tsuruchi
 
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docx
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docxBased upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docx
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docxaman341480
 

Similar to Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa (20)

A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...
A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...
A Global Perspective on Public Transit's Current State of Affairs - Stephen D...
 
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional Meetings
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional MeetingsARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional Meetings
ARRA Overview Illinois Workforce Partnership Regional Meetings
 
ARRA Overview
ARRA OverviewARRA Overview
ARRA Overview
 
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
 
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)
Department of Revenue, Potential Fiscal and Revenue Options (6.4.2015)
 
Public Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptxPublic Finance slides.pptx
Public Finance slides.pptx
 
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1
DEREGULATION OF ENERGY1
 
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined Reporting
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined ReportingAre Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined Reporting
Are Tax Havens Pushing States to Worldwide Combined Reporting
 
Stimulus Senate Power Point
Stimulus Senate Power PointStimulus Senate Power Point
Stimulus Senate Power Point
 
tnm1004.pdf
tnm1004.pdftnm1004.pdf
tnm1004.pdf
 
Five Debates over Macroeconomic Policy
Five Debates over Macroeconomic PolicyFive Debates over Macroeconomic Policy
Five Debates over Macroeconomic Policy
 
LABI 2010 Presentation
LABI 2010 PresentationLABI 2010 Presentation
LABI 2010 Presentation
 
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
 
Bybdh economics of state governments
Bybdh economics of state governmentsBybdh economics of state governments
Bybdh economics of state governments
 
The Fair Property Assessment Plan
The Fair Property Assessment PlanThe Fair Property Assessment Plan
The Fair Property Assessment Plan
 
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docx
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docxBased upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docx
Based upon your review of the Performance Audit of Colorado Low-Inco.docx
 
Southwest California Legislative Council 2016 Ballot Prop - positions
Southwest California Legislative Council 2016 Ballot Prop - positionsSouthwest California Legislative Council 2016 Ballot Prop - positions
Southwest California Legislative Council 2016 Ballot Prop - positions
 
Field Essay
Field EssayField Essay
Field Essay
 
House budget
House budgetHouse budget
House budget
 
Group 6
Group 6Group 6
Group 6
 

More from TanaMaeskm

Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docx
Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docxNine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docx
Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docx
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docxNewspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docx
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docxTanaMaeskm
 
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docx
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docxNew York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docx
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docxTanaMaeskm
 
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docx
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docxNice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docx
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docxTanaMaeskm
 
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docx
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docxNIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docx
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docx
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docxNice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docx
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docx
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docxNewsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docx
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docx
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docxNicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docx
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docxTanaMaeskm
 
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docx
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docxNew and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docx
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docxTanaMaeskm
 
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docx
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docxNew and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docx
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docxTanaMaeskm
 
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docx
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docxNew essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docx
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docx
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docxNeurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docx
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docx
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docxNeurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docx
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docx
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docxNeeds to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docx
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docxTanaMaeskm
 
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docx
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docxNeed to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docx
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docx
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docxNelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docx
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docx
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docxNegotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docx
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docxTanaMaeskm
 
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docx
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docxNeeds to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docx
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docxTanaMaeskm
 
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docx
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docxNeeds quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docx
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docxTanaMaeskm
 
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docx
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docxneed to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docx
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docxTanaMaeskm
 

More from TanaMaeskm (20)

Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docx
Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docxNine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docx
Nine-year-old Wandas teacher notices that for the past few weeks,.docx
 
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docx
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docxNewspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docx
Newspapers frequently feature stories on how various democratic prin.docx
 
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docx
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docxNew York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docx
New York UniversityType of InstitutionA four-year Private .docx
 
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docx
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docxNice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docx
Nice thought process and good example of foot into the door” ).docx
 
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docx
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docxNIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docx
NIST and Risk Governance and Risk Management Please respond to the.docx
 
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docx
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docxNice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docx
Nice thought process ;)!Some in social media agree with your v.docx
 
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docx
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docxNewsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docx
Newsletter pertaining to an oceanographic environmental issue 1500.docx
 
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docx
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docxNicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docx
Nicole Martins is the controller at UMC Corp., a publicly-traded man.docx
 
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docx
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docxNew and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docx
New and Orignal work. Please cite in MLA citation and use in text ci.docx
 
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docx
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docxNew and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docx
New and Origninal work. The topic is already provided below and I ne.docx
 
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docx
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docxNew essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docx
New essay -- minimum 300 words3 resources used NO cover sheet or.docx
 
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docx
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docxNeurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docx
Neurological DisordersNeurological disorders, such as headaches, s.docx
 
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docx
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docxNeurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docx
Neurodevelopmental and Neurocognitive Disorders Paper··I.docx
 
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docx
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docxNeeds to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docx
Needs to be done by 8pm central time!!!!!!An important aspect .docx
 
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docx
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docxNeed to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docx
Need to know about 504 plan and IEP.  I need to research the process.docx
 
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docx
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docxNelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docx
Nelson Carson is a 62-year-old man who presents to his private pract.docx
 
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docx
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docxNegotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docx
Negotiation strategiesUsing the text Negotiation Readings, Exerc.docx
 
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docx
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docxNeeds to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docx
Needs to be done in the next 3-4 hours .docx
 
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docx
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docxNeeds quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docx
Needs quotes and needs to be citied!!about 2 pages.NO PLAGARISM..docx
 
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docx
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docxneed to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docx
need to work on my present assignment using my last assignment as .docx
 

Recently uploaded

Mixin Classes in Odoo 17 How to Extend Models Using Mixin Classes
Mixin Classes in Odoo 17  How to Extend Models Using Mixin ClassesMixin Classes in Odoo 17  How to Extend Models Using Mixin Classes
Mixin Classes in Odoo 17 How to Extend Models Using Mixin ClassesCeline George
 
Understanding Accommodations and Modifications
Understanding  Accommodations and ModificationsUnderstanding  Accommodations and Modifications
Understanding Accommodations and ModificationsMJDuyan
 
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptx
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptxThird Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptx
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptxAmita Gupta
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibitjbellavia9
 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptxMaritesTamaniVerdade
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfPoh-Sun Goh
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Jisc
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsTechSoup
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxAmanpreet Kaur
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseSpellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseAnaAcapella
 
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxUnit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxVishalSingh1417
 
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning PresentationSOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentationcamerronhm
 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxDenish Jangid
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingTechSoup
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfAdmir Softic
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxVishalSingh1417
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...pradhanghanshyam7136
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Mixin Classes in Odoo 17 How to Extend Models Using Mixin Classes
Mixin Classes in Odoo 17  How to Extend Models Using Mixin ClassesMixin Classes in Odoo 17  How to Extend Models Using Mixin Classes
Mixin Classes in Odoo 17 How to Extend Models Using Mixin Classes
 
Understanding Accommodations and Modifications
Understanding  Accommodations and ModificationsUnderstanding  Accommodations and Modifications
Understanding Accommodations and Modifications
 
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptx
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptxThird Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptx
Third Battle of Panipat detailed notes.pptx
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
 
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
2024-NATIONAL-LEARNING-CAMP-AND-OTHER.pptx
 
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdfMicro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
Micro-Scholarship, What it is, How can it help me.pdf
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
 
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The BasicsIntroduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
Introduction to Nonprofit Accounting: The Basics
 
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptxSKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
SKILL OF INTRODUCING THE LESSON MICRO SKILLS.pptx
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please PractiseSpellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
Spellings Wk 3 English CAPS CARES Please Practise
 
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptxUnit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
Unit-IV; Professional Sales Representative (PSR).pptx
 
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptxAsian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
Asian American Pacific Islander Month DDSD 2024.pptx
 
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning PresentationSOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
SOC 101 Demonstration of Learning Presentation
 
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptxBasic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
Basic Civil Engineering first year Notes- Chapter 4 Building.pptx
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdfKey note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
Key note speaker Neum_Admir Softic_ENG.pdf
 
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptxUnit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
Unit-V; Pricing (Pharma Marketing Management).pptx
 
Spatium Project Simulation student brief
Spatium Project Simulation student briefSpatium Project Simulation student brief
Spatium Project Simulation student brief
 
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...Kodo Millet  PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
Kodo Millet PPT made by Ghanshyam bairwa college of Agriculture kumher bhara...
 

Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458LIHEAP reconsideredMa

  • 1. Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441–1458 LIHEAP reconsidered Mark J. Kaiser*, Allan G. Pulsipher Center for Energy Studies, Louisiana State University, One East Fraternity Circle, Baton Rouge, LA 70803-0301, USA Abstract The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP) is a federal block grant program established in 1981 to help low- income households meet a portion of their home energy costs. The manner in which LIHEAP funds are allocated to states, however, has been a contentious issue since the inception of the program. In 1984, the Health and Human Services developed a new formula to increase equity among the states by incorporating state cooling requirements in an equal weighting scheme with state heating requirements. In addition to the new distribution formula, various provisions were also included in the LIHEAP re- authorization amendment that specified when and how the 1984 formula could
  • 2. be employed. These provisions have turned out to be so constraining, however, that they have effectively disabled the 1984 formula. The purpose of this paper is to introduce realistic policy alternatives to the current LIHEAP allocation mechanism and to examine the impact of each alternative. Three options are discussed ranging from the complete elimination of the hold- harmless (HH) provisions to a proposal that maintains the primary HH provision but reduces the trigger level when it is enabled. A simple allotment block distribution based on mixing the two competing funding formulas is also considered. The models presented in this paper represent the first time that policy alternatives to the LIHEAP allocation mechanism has been examined within an analytic framework. r 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP) was authorized by Congress through Title XXVI of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1981, and currently authorized through the end of FY 2004 by the Coats Human Services Re-authorization Act of 1998, P.L.105-285, enacted on October 27, 1998, www.acf.dhhs.gov. The Low-Income Home Energy Assistance Act of
  • 3. 1981 established the Low-Income Home Energy Assis- tance block grant program to help eligible households meet home energy costs. States can provide assistance to low-income households through various program com- ponents, including home heating and cooling assistance, energy crisis assistance, and home weatherization (General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1986): * Home energy assistance consists of helping low- income households pay heating and cooling costs. Grantees provide assistance in the form of cash, vouchers, coupons, and two-party checks to eligible households, and may make payments to landlords or home energy suppliers on behalf of eligible house- holds. * Energy crisis assistance includes funding for weather- related, supply shortages, and other household energy-related emergencies. States provide cash, shelter, emergency supplies, or supplemental heating sources to households without heat or in imminent danger of having their fuel supplies terminated. * Weatherization assistance includes funding for low - cost residential weatherization or other energy- related home repair. LIHEAP is limited to households that include recipients of aid to families with dependent children, supplemen- tary security income, food stamps, or certain veteran’s benefits. Households with incomes less than 150% of the poverty level, or less than 60% of the state’s median income, whichever is greater, also qualify under the statute.
  • 4. The LIHEAP is a block grant program, meaning that the state can—within the statutory requirements— choose their method of administration, eligibility criteria, benefit levels, and funding levels for program activities. A number of legislative amendments over the years have placed some restrictions on state program discretion; for example, no more than 25% of LIHEAP ARTICLE IN PRESS *Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-225-578-4554; fax: +1-225- 578- 4541. E-mail address: [email protected] (M.J. Kaiser). 0301-4215/03/$ - see front matter r 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 0 1 - 4 2 1 5 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 2 0 0 - 8 funds can be used for weatherization and no more than 10% can be spent on state administration costs. States can transfer a maximum of 10% of their funds to other block grants and cannot carry more than 15% of their allotment to the succeeding fiscal year. The General Accounting Office by legislative mandate is required to evaluate LIHEAP, and as requested by various government units, have produced a number of reports on the program, e.g., General Accounting Office, US Congress (1986, 1987, 1990). A handful of academic papers on federal energy assistance programs
  • 5. are scattered throughout the literature (Colton, 1990; Higgins and Lutzenhiser, 1995; Kennedy, 1987; Kings- ley, 1992; Landsberg and Dukert, 1981), including a few Congressional Research Service reports (Abbey, 2001; Gish, 2000; Stoltzfus, 2002) and numerous LIHEAP reports to Congress (Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1983, 1985, 1994, 2000). The federal government distributes funds to states for LIHEAP using a legislated formula. The LIHEAP formula was originally legislated in 1981 and then revised in 1984 in large measure due to political pressure from many warm-weather states that maintained that the 1981 formula over-allocated funds to cold-weather states. Pursuant to the re-authorization amendment for LIHEAP in 1984, the Health and Human Services developed a new formula to increase the overall equity among the states. The LIHEAP formula was revised to incorporate state cooling requirements in an equal weighting scheme with state heating requirements, but various additional conditions were also included in the amendment that specified when and how the 1984 formula could be employed. To ‘‘turn-on’’ the 1984 formula for instance, LIHEAP’s regular appropriation is required to exceed a minimum threshold level of $1.975 billion, but because program commitment to LIHEAP has fallen over the years, the revised allocation mechanism has only rarely been applied—specifically, twice over the past 17 years, and last during FY 1986. The primary intent of the 1984 legislation to increase the overall equity of the distribution of LIHEAP funds has thus failed miserably, and so there is a need to examine alternative allotment methods to bring the 1984 formula ‘‘back into’’ the allocation mechanism as intended by the legislation. The primary purpose of this
  • 6. paper is to suggest viable policy alternatives to the current legislative framework and to develop an analytic model to quantify the impact of each alternative. The present work represents the first time that alternative allocation mechanisms to LIHEAP have been modeled and presented publicly. This model not only provides legislators insight on competing policy proposals, but also hopefully, provides a forum and stimulus for future debate. The outline of the paper is as follows. The current LIHEAP statute is discussed in Section 2, followed by a summary of LIHEAP funding levels in Section 3 and a general description in Section 4 of three realistic policy alternatives. In Sections 5–7 the policy alternatives are examined. In Section 5, a comparison of the 1981 and 1984 formula allocation formulas are discussed by state and region, and in Section 6, the effect of a trigger-level reduction on state allotments and system measures are outlined. In Section 7 a block allotment procedure is described which combines the 1981 and 1984 formula. In Section 8 conclusions complete the paper. To maintain focus on the policy proposals, the theoretical foundation of the allocation mechanisms are maintained in separate appendices. 2. The LIHEAP statute The LIHEAP statute currently assigns each state and the District of Columbia an allotment percentage based on the value of the regular appropriation $D for the fiscal year. One of three cases can occur depending on the value of D: Case I : Dp$1:975B
  • 7. Case II : $1:975BoDo$2:25B Case III : DX$2:25B Case I: Dp$1:975B: When the regular appropriation in a fiscal year is less than or equal to $1.975B, the 1981 formula is employed to determine state allocation percentages. In other words, the 1981 formula repre- sents a default condition if regular appropriation does not exceed the trigger F ¼ $1:975B: The 1981 allocation percentages shown in Table 1 are now over 20-years old and the arbitrary basis of their ‘‘derivation’’ forgotten by the legislative community. Further, and more importantly, since regular appropriations have fallen below the trigger level every year for the past 15 years (and counting), the high frequency of usage of the 1981 formula has helped to create a sense of ‘‘acceptance’’ and ‘‘validity’’ for its application, which is anything but satisfactory. Three main ‘‘problems’’ exist with the 1981 formula: (1) The 1981 formula represented the outcome of a political process as opposed to being based on good science. (2) The 1981 formula was poorly designed, extremely complex, and arbitrarily ‘‘derived’’ in a manner that strongly favored cold-weather climates. (3) The 1981 formula is a ‘‘static’’ formula that fixed the allocation percentages of states based on pre- 1980 data for state climate, fuel price, demographic, and expenditure patterns. The 1981 formula is unusually easy to criticize and very difficult to defend. It is important to recognize
  • 8. ARTICLE IN PRESS M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581442 that the 1981 formula was designed in response to conditions specific to the times that emphasized the rapidly increasing fuel oil prices in the Northeast during the late 1970s. The formula allocation caused great consternation on the part of many warm-weather states 1 and the continued application of the 1981 formula remains one of the better-kept ‘‘secrets’’ in Washington. The primary shortcomings of the 1981 formula are easy to recognize: The 1981 formula does not nor cannot reflect the current low-income demographic, consump- tion, and fuel price mix in the country (since the data on which the formula is based is over 20-years old), and further, the formula itself cannot be ‘‘updated’’ to reflect more recent data (since the allocation mechanism is a static design). The most egregious aspect of the 1981 formula is that the allocation mechanism does not distribute funds based on the need for home energy assistance. Instead, the 1981 formula defines need in a mysterious and complicated fashion primarily in terms of the home heating needs of cold-climate states. A complex and convoluted formula is not necessarily a ‘‘bad’’ formula, but unfortunately—and more to the
  • 9. point—it is not clear what the 1981 state allocation percentages mean or if they identify the need for home energy assistance. Four separate formulas are entangled with the 1981 formula allotment—two House of Representatives formula alternatives, the FY 1980 state allotment, and the Windfall Profit Tax Act formula— commingled with pro-rata reductions, weak hold-harm- less (HH) provisions, and arbitrary formula compar- isons. And as each one of the four formulas is biased toward cold-climate states, no matter what procedural elements are invoked, a biased 2 cold-climate formula remains a biased cold-climate formula. Pursuant to the re-authorization amendment for LIHEAP in 1984, the 1981 formula was completely revised in the ‘‘1984 formula’’, but for the 1984 formula to be ‘‘turned-on’’ the regular appropriation must exceed $1.975B. Case II: $1:975BoDo$2:25B: When the regular appropriation exceeds $1.975B in a fiscal year, then an allocation mechanism based on the 1984 formula coupled with two HH provisions is adopted. The first HH condition, or primary HH provision, is enabled when D > $1:975B: When DX$2:25B a second HH provision kicks in. The 1984 formula, or ‘‘new formula’’, was established to provide a mechanism to distribute LIHEAP funds based solely on the home energy needs of low-income ARTICLE IN PRESS
  • 10. Table 1 LIHEAP allocation percentages according to the 1981 and 1984 formula State 1981 Formula (%) 1984 Formula (%) Statutory floor ($M) Alabama 0.86 1.68 16.99 Alaska 0.55 0.36 10.84 Arizona 0.42 1.25 8.21 Arkansas 0.66 1.21 12.96 California 4.61 6.00 91.12 Colorado 1.61 1.15 31.77 Connecticut 2.10 1.40 41.45 Delaware 0.28 0.37 5.50 D.C. 0.33 0.27 6.44
  • 11. Florida 1.36 4.16 26.88 Georgia 1.08 2.68 21.25 Hawaii 0.11 0.12 2.14 Idaho 0.63 0.28 12.39 Illinois 5.81 5.30 114.72 Indiana 2.63 2.21 51.94 Iowa 1.86 1.22 36.81 Kansas 0.86 1.07 16.91 Kentucky 1.37 1.73 27.03 Louisiana 0.88 1.79 17.37 Maine 1.36 0.55 26.85 Maryland 1.61 2.26 31.74 Massachusetts 4.20 2.91 82.91 Michigan 5.51 4.82 108.92 Minnesota 3.97 1.68 78.47 Mississippi 0.74 1.87 14.56 Missouri 2.32 2.41 45.82 Montana 0.74 0.35 14.54
  • 12. Nebraska 0.92 0.55 18.21 Nevada 0.20 0.51 3.86 New Hampshire 0.79 0.45 15.69 New Jersey 3.90 3.28 76.97 New Mexico 0.52 0.54 10.28 New York 12.72 8.68 251.34 North Carolina 1.90 3.14 37.45 North Dakota 0.80 0.21 15.79 Ohio 5.14 4.86 101.49 Oklahoma 0.79 1.31 15.61 Oregon 1.25 0.95 24.62 Pennsylvania 6.84 5.15 134.99 Rhode Island 0.69 0.47 13.65 South Carolina 0.68 1.44 13.49 South Dakota 0.65 0.29 12.83 Tennessee 1.39 2.08 27.38 Texas 2.26 6.60 44.71 Utah 0.75 0.54 14.76
  • 13. Vermont 0.60 0.23 11.76 Virginia 1.96 3.05 38.66 Washington 2.05 1.50 40.50 West Virginia 0.91 0.96 17.89 Wisconsin 3.58 1.93 70.63 Wyoming 0.30 0.18 5.91 1 ‘‘It has only been through the making of legislative history with regard to this and previous appropriations bills for this program that the prejudice favoring cold-weather energy bill assistance and opposing hot-weather energy bill assistance has developedy it is counter to the American tradition of fair play. I would urge the Congress to re- examine its conscience and design a fairer solution’’. Additional view of Bill Alexander, Low Income Energy Assistance, House of Representatives Report No. 96-1244, August 21, 1980. 2 Granted, the home heating needs of cold-climate states were particularly severe in the early 1980s but the incorporation of
  • 14. these same factors today is not defendable. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1443 households—where ‘‘home energy’’ was interpreted to mean the heating and cooling requirements of house- holds. According to Section 2604(a)(2) of P.L. 97-35 as amended by P.L.98-558, ‘‘y For fiscal year 1985 and thereafter, a state’s allotment percentage is the percentage which expen- ditures for home energy by low-income households in that state bears to such expenditures in all statesy’’ The 1984 formula was a significant improvement over the 1981 formula in terms of its transparency and equity and in many regards can be considered the ‘‘ideal’’ mechanism to distribute LIHEAP funds: (1) The 1984 formula determines state allocation percentages according to a simple, easy-to-under- stand, and science-based mechanism using estimates of state expenditures for the Btu requirements of low-income households for each fuel source con- tributing to home heating and cooling needs. (2) The 1984 formula is extremely well designed and easy-to-defend and is based on the ‘‘best-available’’ statistical data. (3) The 1984 formula is a dynamic allocation that is
  • 15. updated annually to normalize for changes in weather patterns (heating and cooling degree-days) and fuel prices (coal, electricity, fuel oil, liquid petroleum gases, and natural gas) at the state level. The 1984 formula allocations are shown in Table 1 alongside the 1981 allotments, but unlike the 1981 percentage allocation values, the 1984 formula values do not represent the final state allotment percentages. The final allotment percentages can only be calculated after the regular appropriation D is known for the fiscal year and the impact of the HH and give-back (GB) provisions are incorporated within the allocation mechanism. The HH condition establishes a statutory floor for each state determined by the 1981 formula allocation and the appropriation level F ¼ $1:975B as shown in Table 1. If a state does not achieve its statutory floor under the appropriation D and 1984 formula allotment, then it is held ‘‘harmless’’ at its floor. The funds necessary to maintain states at their floor is mandated by a GB provision which specifies that all states above their floor will have their allotments reduced propor- tionally until the funds required to make-up the deficit is achieved. Since the funds necessary to make-up the deficit come from states that benefit under the new allocation mechanism, these states effective allotment percentages are reduced from their 1984 allotment. Case III: DX$2:25B: When the regular appropriation for a given fiscal year is equal to or exceeds $2.25B, then another HH and GB condition is triggered, referred to as the secondary HH-GB provision or the LTOP (less than 1%) provision. The LTOP provision stipulates that
  • 16. any state that receives less than 1% of the total allotment funding at the appropriation level D cannot have a smaller allotment percentage than its allotment percentage at $2.14B. The impact of the secondary HH- GB provision acts to maintai n a set of states at their allotment percentage achieved at $2.14B. Since a set of states are maintained at an allotment percentage that is higher than dictated by the primary HH-GB provision, the complementary set of states which are not affected by the LTOP provision provide the funds required to satisfy this condition. The inclusion of the secondary HH-GB provision is interesting because it indicates the ‘‘mind-set’’ of the legislators at the time the LIHEAP statute was revised. It was expected, or at least anticipated, that regular appropriations for LIHEAP would increase in the years ahead and might conceivably even exceed $2.25B! As it turns out, however, due to factors such as the oil price crash of 1986 and the Emergency Deficit Control Act, funding levels for LIHEAP in the years following the 1984 re-authorization plummeted. 3. LIHEAP funding levels The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of program funds: regular block grant and emergency. Regular funds are authorized under Section 2602(b) of the LIHEAP statute and are currently allocated according to the mechanism described in Section 2. Emergency funds are authorized under 2602(e) of the LIHEAP statute and are authorized and distributed at ARTICLE IN PRESS Table 2
  • 17. LIHEAP funding history, 1981–2002 FY Regular appropriation ($B) Emergency ($M) 1981 1.850 1982 1.875 1983 1.975 1984 2.075 1985 2.100 1986 2.010 1987 1.825 1988 1.532 1989 1.383 1990 1.393 50 1991 1.415 195 1992 1.500 1993 1.346 1994 1.439 298 1995 1.319 100 1996 0.900 180
  • 18. 1997 1.000 215 1998 1.000 160 1999 1.100 180 2000 1.100 744 2001 1.400 456 2002 1.700 M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581444 the discretion of the President and Secretary of the Health and Human Services at any point in time in the fiscal year. The funding history of LIHEAP is shown in Table 2. The average value of LIHEAP regular appropriation from 1981–2002 is EðDÞ ¼ $1:51B with a standard deviation of sðDÞ ¼ $0:37B: Observe that since the LIHEAP program was reauthorized in 1984, funding levels have exceeded the trigger level $1.975B only during FY 1985 and FY 1986. 4. Policy proposals The principal condition that has prevented the application of the 1984 formula is immediately clear. The level of the regular funding appropriated for LIHEAP over the years has not achieved the legislated trigger, and so by default, the 1981 formula—despite its obvious shortcomings—has become the effective alloca-
  • 19. tion mechanism for federal funding. To address the failure of the 1984 legislation, three suggestions follow: * Eliminate the trigger level, * Reduce the trigger level or * Devise an alternative allocation mechanism. These suggestions are formalized as the following options: Option A: Eliminate the HH-GB provisions and apply the 1984 formula allocation at a zero trigger level. Option B: Reduce the trigger level of the HH-GB provision and eliminate the LTOP provision. Option C: Apply an allocation mechanism based on a linear combination of the 1981 and 1984 formula values. A brief description of each option is now provided followed in Sections 5–7 by models that explore the impact of each alternative. Option A: This is the most dramatic approach, the simplest, and arguably the most equitable. Unfortu- nately, Option A is also unlikely to garner the political support necessary to achieve passage. The purpose of LIHEAP is to assist low-income households meet the costs of home energy. This purpose is clear and unambiguous and a very good allocation mechanism already exists in the 1984 formula to satisfy this objective—and in fact it is doubtful that a ‘‘better’’ formula can be developed unless the legislative mandate
  • 20. of LIHEAP radically changes—but for the past 15 years the 1984 formula could not be employed since the trigger level to turn it ‘‘on’’ has never been attained. Hence, by eliminating the HH provisions and setting the trigger point to zero, the 1984 formula will serve as the new default formula. The basic premise of Option A is that any use of the 1981 formula perpetrates a distribution of funds that is inequitable since the allocation is not based on the home energy needs of low-income households. The manner in which LIHEAP funds should be distributed to states should mimic the state’s home energy expenditures 3 paid by low-income households. Interestingly, this also appears to be the Bush Administration position. 4 Although Option A is believed to be the fairest, simplest and best way to revise LIHEAP, it may not be politically viable or develop a strong enough coalition of support, especially in the Senate since a majority of states realize a smaller allotment percentage under the 1984 formula. The fight in Congress over Option A will be especially difficult since Senators are not likely to vote their state a lower allotment percentage to ‘‘right the wrongs’’ of an archaic and cryptic formula. Be that as it may, if legislators can be convinced to move on LIHEAP—perhaps for the sake of good government, good conscience, or daresay, a good formula—viability may hinge on maintaining some form of the HH
  • 21. condition as opposed to the complete elimination of the statutory floor. One simple means to accomplish this task is to simply re-set the trigger level of F downward as proposed in Option B. Option B: Any revision to LIHEAP should be realistic and based on a politically viable strategy. The value of the trigger point F currently represents a level that has not, nor likely will, be surpassed in the future, and hence its adjustment downward is necessary to ensure that a more equitable allocation mechanism be applied to future LIHEAP funding. The value of the trigger point was set by legislative mandate and over time has lost its relation to D: At one time (15-years ago) the values of D and F were roughly comparable, while today F appears as an upper bound that is unlikely to be exceeded. There is also some precedence for trigger re-adjust- ment. When the HH-GB provision was initially devised in 1984, F was set at the FY 1984 appropriation level of $2.075B. In 1986, when the regular appropriation fell below the required trigger, the value of F was reduced to the FY 1983 level of $1.975 to bring the 1984 formula back ‘‘in’’ the allocation mechanism. 5 Unfortunately, FY 1986 represented the last year in which program appropriations exceeded $1.975B, and subsequent to this time no further action has been taken to address this issue and/or re-adjust F: ARTICLE IN PRESS
  • 22. 3 Home energy expenditures paid by low-income households is also relatively easy to estimate, and so there is no technical difficulties associated with the computation. 4 ‘‘y The legislatively established formula currently used to distribute LIHEAP block grant funds to states is based on 20- year old population and winter heating cost data. The Administration is interested in options that would make block grant allocations more equitable by basing the formula on current home energy expenditures paid by low-income households’’. Bush Administration LIHEAP Budget for Fiscal Year 2003. 5 Apparently LIHEAP re-authorization legislation was still fresh in legislators minds. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1445
  • 23. The ideal equitable allocation mechanism would be based on the 1984 formula with no provisions attached (Option A), but because of the historical precedence to couple the 1984 formula with HH and GB provisions, and the need to satisfy a majority of votes in the Senate, Option B is likely to be viewed as compromise legislation. Option C: An alternative approach to maintain the application of the 1981 formula that does not rely explicitly on re-adjusting the trigger level F is to set-aside a certain percentage ðrÞ of the regular appro- priation to be used with the 1981 formula, rD; and then to apply the 1984 formula to the remaining funds, ð1 � rÞD: This has an advantage over Option B since regardless of the appropriation level the 1984 formula would always be applied to the same portion of the regular appropriation. 6 Option C ensures application of the 1984 formula with no ‘‘downside risk’’ as in Option B, but it also foregoes the ‘‘upside potential’’ when D > F: On methodological grounds a formula mix is not especially appealing, but as will be demonstrated in Section 7, a linear combination of the 1981 and 1984 formula is equivalent to Option B under a suitable correspondence. A summary of the three options is depicted in Table 3 along with a brief description of their advantages and disadvantages.
  • 24. 5. A comparison of the 1981 and 1984 formula allotments The 1981 formula is for all practical purposes a ‘‘perpetual’’ formula since the funding levels required to ‘‘turn-on’’ the new allocation mechanism has only rarely been achieved in the past and is unlikely to be attained in the future. The HH and GB provisions associated with the allocation mechanism are therefore relaxed and the trigger level required to turn-on the 1984 formula is set equal to zero. A direct comparison is performed between the old and new formula allotment percentages by state and region. 5.1. Comparison by state If the vectors f and g denote the 1981 and 1984 state allotment percentages: f ¼ ðf1; y; f51Þ; 0ofio1; X fi ¼ 1; g ¼ ðg1; y; g51Þ; 0ogio1; X gi ¼ 1; then the set of states that would benefit from a formula change is denoted fBg ¼ fi j fiogig; while the set of states that would be harmed is denoted fCg ¼ fi j fi > gig:
  • 25. The sets fBg and fCg partition the 50 states and District of Columbia (D.C.) according to states that ‘‘benefit’’ and are ‘‘harmed’’ by the formula change. If a state’s 1984 formula allotment percentage is greater than its ARTICLE IN PRESS Table 3 A comparison of three policy options Policy Description Advantages Disadvantages Option A Eliminate the primary and Simple Senate fight secondary HH-GB provisions Fair Large percentage change in state allotment and nullify the trigger level Rational mechanism Satisfies original intent of LIHEAP Bush Administration position House passage likely Option B Maintain the primary HH-GB Maintains form of Maintains convoluted formula provision but reduce the statute Not a rational mechanism for distribution trigger level when it is enabled Enables 1984 Level of fairness
  • 26. not guaranteed formula Compromise formula Senate support more likely Option C Apply an allotment based Simple Formula mix on a linear combination Easy to understand Not a rational mechanism for distribution of the 1981 and 1984 No downside risk Foregoes upside potential formula values Correspondence with Option B 6 Under Option B, if F is re-set at a value that is ‘‘too high’’ (say $1.5B) and D again drifts downward away from F; then the same inequity will return to the distribution. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581446 1981 allotment percentage, fiogi; then state i is said to benefit from the new policy. In Table 4, 23 states are shown to benefit under
  • 27. Option A while 28 states would be harmed. States that benefit realize a percentage change in their allotment ranging from 4% (New Mexico, Missouri) to 200% (Arizona, Florida) while states that are harmed range from �6% (Ohio) to �74% (North Dakota). A graphical representation of allotment percentage changes is depicted in Fig. 1. The average percentage change for states in fBg and fCg is 81% and �35%; respectively. Eight states in fBg realize an allocation percentage change greater than 100% (FL, AZ, TX, NV, MS, GA, SC, LA), while seven states in fCg realize a change in allocation percentage greater than 50% (ND, VT, MN, ID, SD, ME, MT). Under the 1984 formula allotment, the set of states that benefit from the new policy would realize a 20.4% increase in total allotment, which would be transferred from the states in fCg:7 The total amount of money transferred depends on the value of D; e.g., if D ¼ $1B; then $204M would be transferred under Option A from fCg to fBg: All states are impacted by the new policy. The expected annual difference in state allocations is com- puted in Table 4 based on the 1981–2002 average annual regular appropriations for LIHEAP, EðDÞ ¼ $1:51B; multiplied by the difference in allotment percentages, gi � fi: The ‘‘big winners’’ under Option A include Texas ($65M), Florida ($42M), Georgia ($24M), California ($20M), and North Carolina ($18M), while states that lose money include New York ð�$61MÞ; Minnesota ð�$35MÞ; Pennsylvania ð�$25MÞ; Wisconsin ð�$25MÞ; and Massachusetts ð�$19MÞ: See Fig. 2 for a graph of the expected annual difference in funding under Option A. The average annual difference in funding levels in
  • 28. fBg and fCg is $13.4M and �$11:0M; respectively. The top five states in fCg represent nearly 60% of the total funds that would be reallocated under Option A to the top five states in fBg: The remaining funds are transferred among the 41 other states in fBg and fCg: To provide a rough measure of the degree of inequity that has been promulgated over the past decade through the continued use of the 1981 formula, refer to the last column in Table 4. The values depicted are based on the ARTICLE IN PRESS -100 -50 0 50 100 150 200 250 S ta te s Percentage Change (%) {C} {B} Fig. 1. State LIHEAP allotment percentage change: 1981 vs. 1984 formula. Table 4 The impact of using the 1984 formula allocation State Percentage
  • 29. change (%) Expected annual difference ($M) 10-year cumulative impact ($M) Alabama 95.02 12.34 112.80 Alaska �34.34 �2.85 �26.02 Arizona 200.42 12.59 115.07 Arkansas 84.80 8.40 76.82 California 29.93 20.85 190.62 Colorado �28.38 �6.89 �63.03 Connecticut �33.41 �10.59 �96.79 Delaware 33.73 1.42 12.97 D.C. �17.24 �0.85 �7.76 Florida 205.14 42.15 385.35 Georgia 148.79 24.17 221.00 Hawaii 7.21 0.12 1.08
  • 30. Idaho �55.66 �5.27 �48.22 Illinois �8.77 �7.70 �70.35 Indiana �15.88 �6.31 �57.65 Iowa �34.33 �9.66 �88.34 Kansas 24.40 3.15 28.84 Kentucky 26.51 5.48 50.08 Louisiana 103.62 13.76 125.77 Maine �54.82 �11.26 �102.89 Maryland 40.82 9.91 90.55 Massachusetts �30.64 �19.42 �177.56 Michigan �12.63 �10.52 �96.20 Minnesota �57.74 �34.64 �316.65 Mississippi 153.94 17.14 156.69 Missouri 3.98 1.40 12.76 Montana �52.58 �5.84 �53.43 Nebraska �40.55 �5.64 �51.60 Nevada 159.36 4.70 42.97 New Hampshire �42.59 �5.15 �47.11 New Jersey �15.97 �9.40 �85.89 New Mexico 3.62 0.28 2.60 New York �31.87 �61.23 �559.73 North Carolina 65.31 18.70 170.97 North Dakota �73.56 �8.88 �81.18 Ohio �5.56 �4.31 �39.42 Oklahoma 65.51 7.82 71.50 Oregon �23.96 �4.51 �41.23
  • 31. Pennsylvania �24.64 �25.43 �232.51 Rhode Island �32.56 �3.40 �31.06 South Carolina 110.44 11.39 104.13 South Dakota �55.35 �5.43 �49.62 Tennessee 49.99 10.47 95.68 Texas 191.33 65.41 597.96 Utah �27.92 �3.15 �28.81 Vermont �62.14 �5.59 �51.09 Virginia 55.88 16.52 151.00 Washington �27.08 �8.38 �76.65 West Virginia 5.56 0.76 6.95 Wisconsin �45.98 �24.83 �226.98 Wyoming �39.63 �1.79 �16.37 7 Capital redistribution is a zero-sum game. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1447 LIHEAP cumulative allotments from 1992–2002, $13.80B, multiplied by the allocation differential, gi � fi: The values shown give an indication of what states can expect to gain and/or lose over the next decade should Option A be implemented. 5.2. Comparison by region Regional comparisons are especially insightful since
  • 32. they indicate the inequity that the 1984 legislation was originally intended to address. Assign each state to one of four census regions: Northeast, North Central, South, and West, as shown in Table 5. The percentage of the total appropriation by region according to the 1981 and 1984 formula allocation is shown in Table 6. States that benefit from Option A are drawn predominately from the South and to a lesser extent the West and North Central regions. No state in the Northeast benefits from a formula change, and hence it is not surprising that the Northeast forms a strong and vocal coalition against any changes to LIHEAP’s status quo (Pataki, 2001). Relative to the 1984 formula, the Northeast and North Central states receive a 17.6% over-allotment of funds, which are effectively being withdrawn from the South. The Southern states mean- while have expressed dissatisfaction with the mechanism that promotes this distribution although their criticism remains rather soft (Patton and Hodges, 2001) con- sidering the duration and extent of the inequity— although political considerations may also be at work here. The Western region as a class does not realize a noticeable difference in allotment percentages under the two formulas, although individual states may realize significant variation, e.g., Arizona (200%), California (30%), Nevada (159%), Idaho ð�56%Þ; Oregon ð�24%Þ and Washington ð�27%Þ: 5.3. The cumulative allocation A description of the cumulative percentage allotment provides further insight into the allocation mechanism. Under the 1981 formula, nine states receive 53% of LIHEAP funds (NY, PA, IL, MI, OH, CA, MA, MN,
  • 33. NJ); 19 states receive 75% of total funds (WI, IN, MO, TX, CT, WA, VA, NC, IA, CO), and 33 states receive 90% of funds. Under the 1984 formula, 10 states receive 52% of LIHEAP funds (NY, TX, CA, IL, PA, OH, MI, FL, NJ, NC); 20 states receive 75% of the funds (VA, MS, GA, MO, MD, IN, TN, WI, MI, LA); and 30 states receive 90% of the funds. The placement of states under the two formulas shift slightly, and from a global perspective the allotments are quite similar. Under the 1981 formula allocation, 25 states receive less than 1% of the total funding, while with the 1984 formula, 19 states receive less than a 1% allocation. A cumulative representation of the two allocations can be compared by first ordering the elements in descending rank and then perform a cumulative summation. The result in Fig. 3 shows the curves to be nearly identical. The 1984 cumulative curve falls ever so below the 1981 curve indicating an allocation that distributes funds in aggregate slightly more evenly across states. ARTICLE IN PRESS -80 -60 -40 -20 0 20 40 60 80 S ta te s Expected Annual Difference ($M) {C} {B} Fig. 2. Expected difference in annual LIHEAP allotments: 1981 vs.
  • 34. 1984 formula. Table 6 Percentage of the total appropriation by census region Region 1981 Allotment (%) 1984 Allotment (%) Difference (%) Northeast 33.2 23.2 �10.0 North Central 34.1 26.5 �7.5 South 19.0 36.6 17.6 West 13.7 13.7 — Table 5
  • 35. State assignment via census region Northeast North Central South West Connecticut Illinois Alabama a Alaska Maine Indiana Arkansas a Arizona a Massachusetts Iowa Delaware a California a New Hampshire Kansas a D.C. Colorado New Jersey Michigan Florida a Hawaii a New York Minnesota Georgia a Idaho
  • 36. Pennsylvania Missouri a Kentucky a Montana Rhode Island Nebraska Louisiana a Nevada a Vermont North Dakota Maryland a New Mexico a Ohio Mississippi a Oregon South Dakota North Carolina a Utah Wisconsin Oklahoma a Washington
  • 37. South Carolina a Wyoming Tennessee a Texas a Virginia a West Virginia a a Indicate states that benefit from the application of the 1984 formula allotment. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581448 6. The effect of a trigger-level reduction Application of the 1981 formula to distribute funds is considered fundamentally unfair since it does not satisfy the intent of LIHEAP nor does it allocate federal dollars in a rational manner. Application of the 1984 formula was originally tied to a HH provision to protect states from receiving less money under the new formula. Unfortunately, regular appropriations for LIHEAP fell
  • 38. after the 1984 legislation was passed and has come in under the threshold 15 of the last 17 years, and so by default, the problematic 1981 formula continues to be used to distribute federal dollars. The primary problem with the LIHEAP allocation mechanism is due to the fact that the trigger level F was set nearly two decades ago at a value commensurate to mid-1980 appropriation levels, while actual (real) appropriations began to slide shortly after the 1984 legislation was passed. Today, the trigger level F ¼ $1:975B is not representative of current LIHEAP appropriation levels and future appropriation is not expected to reach F ¼ $1:975B—let alone surpass F to ‘‘turn-on’’ the 1984 formula. To increase the chance of allocating some funds with the 1984 formula, it is necessary to lower the value of the trigger. Ultimately, the value of F will need to be negotiated, and so it is useful to understand how the selection of F impacts global measures and individual state allotments. The basic idea of Option B is to set F at a level below the expected value of D: 6.1. Theoretical structure The LIHEAP allocation mechanism described in Section 2 is first simplified by eliminating the secondary HH provision, and for analytical purposes, the value of F is considered variable. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism is constructed according to Theorem 1 and its limiting relations are proved in Theorem 2. Theorem 1. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under the primary HH-GB provision yields state allotments
  • 39. according to the following recipe: AiðF; DÞ ¼ Dfi; iAfSg; DpF; Ffi; iAfHg; D > F; Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg; D > F; 8>< >: where fSg ¼ fHg,fNg; fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g; fNg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgip1g; Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ; g ¼ X =Q; X ¼ D � F; and Q ¼ P iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ: Proof. See Appendix A. Theorem 2. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under the primary HH-GB yields the following limiting rela- tions: lim D=F-1 aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi; lim D=F-N aiðF; DÞ ¼ gi:
  • 40. Proof. See Appendix A. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism described in Theorem 1 and system measures derived from the mechanism can be expressed as a function of the ratio D=F as shown in Theorems 3 and 4. Theorem 3. For D > F; the LIHEAP allocation mechan- ism under the primary HH-GB provision yields state allotment percentages aiðF; DÞ ¼ F D fi; iAfHg; F D fi þ Ei D ; iAfNg ( that are functions of the ratio F=D: Proof. See Appendix B. Theorem 4. The LIHEAP system measures sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms of the ratio D=F as sðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; and rðD=FÞ:
  • 41. ARTICLE IN PRESS 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 1 4 7 1 0 1 3 1 6 1 9 2 2 2 5
  • 43. v e P e rc e n ta g e 1981 allotment 1984 allotment Fig. 3. The 1981 and 1984 cumulative percentage LIHEAP allotment. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1449 Proof. See Appendix B. 6.2. Universal tableaux Application of the theoretical structure is now presented. Theorem 1 describes how to construct state allotments and Theorem 2 presents the limiting cases when D ¼ F and DbF: The result of Theorems 3 and 4 demonstrate that the LIHEAP allocation percen- tages, aiðF; DÞ; and aggregate measures sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ—which are a function of F and D—can
  • 44. be expressed in terms of one variable, the ratio D=F: This is not only a very convenient result but also quite useful since rather than enumerate all the various combinations of F and D sepa- rately, e.g., F ¼ 1; D ¼ ð1; 1:25; 1:5; 1:75; 2:0; yÞ; F ¼ 1:5; D ¼ ð1:5; 1:75; 2:0; 2:25; 2:5; 2:75; 3:0; yÞ; etc. one ‘‘universal tableaux’’ suffices to present all relevant allocation percentages and aggregate measures. The aggregate measures employed are empirically derived and are defined formally as follows: H ¼ P iAH Ffi Amount of money allocated to H under the imposition of the HH provision ($) G ¼ P iAH Dgi Amount of money allocated to H if the HH provision was eliminated ($) N ¼ P iAN Ffi þ X Amount of money allocated to N under the imposition of the HH provision ($) X ¼ D � F Money available for distribu- tion after all state statutory floors are maintained ($)
  • 45. M ¼ P iAN Dgi Amount of money allocated to N if the HH provision was eliminated ($) sðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=D Percentage of money trans- ferred from N to H relative to the total appropriation D; 0psðD=FÞp1 rðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=M Percentage reduction in the funding allocation to N due to the imposition of the HH-GB provision, 0prðD=FÞp1 iðD=FÞ ¼ ðH � GÞ=G Percentage increase in the fund- ing allocation to H due to the imposition of the HH-GB pro- vision, 0piðD=FÞp1 pðD=FÞ ¼ H=D Percentage of the total funds D allocated to H Due to the imposition of the HH-GB pro- vision, 0ppðD=FÞp1 qðD=FÞ ¼ G=D Percentage of the total funds D allocated to H if the HH-GB provision was eliminated, 0pqðD=FÞp1 H The number of states in H N The number of states in N
  • 46. Application of the tableaux follows three steps: Step 1: Assume D: Step 2: Select F: Step 3: Compute D=F: * If D=Fp1; then read the row of Table 7 (or column of Table 8) for D=F ¼ 1: * If 1oD=Fp3; then select the row (or column) for D=F closest to the ratio value. * If D=F > 3; then read the row (or column) for D=F ¼ 3: The tableaux is easy to use and the results are bound through the limiting relations described in Theorem 2. A few examples illustrate the application of the tableaux. Example. (a) If D ¼ $1:3B and F ¼ $0:5B; then D=F ¼ 2:6 and the row for D=F ¼ 2:5 should be used in Table 7 and the column for D=F ¼ 2:5 should be used in Table 8. (b) If D ¼ $1:5B and F ¼ $1B; then use the row and column in Tables 7 and 8 corresponding to D=F ¼ 1:5: ARTICLE IN PRESS Table 7 The impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP parameters as a function of D=F for the appropriation level D ($B) and trigger
  • 47. level F ($B) D=F sðD=FÞ rðD=FÞ iðD=FÞ pðD=FÞ qðD=FÞ #fHg #fNg 1.00 20.5 42.4 39.5 72.3 51.8 28 23 1.05 17.0 35.3 32.9 68.8 51.8 28 23 1.10 14.1 24.1 33.8 55.7 41.7 28 23 1.15 11.7 18.5 31.7 48.5 36.8 25 26 1.20 9.7 14.2 31.0 41.1 31.3 23 28 1.25 8.1 11.7 26.0 39.2 31.1 22 29 1.30 6.6 9.5 21.2 37.7 31.1 22 29 1.35 5.3 7.1 21.2 30.3 25.0 20 31 1.40 4.3 5.4 19.5 26.0 21.8 17 34 1.45 3.4 4.2 17.8 22.2 18.9 16 35 1.50 2.8 3.1 28.9 12.6 9.7 13 38 1.55 2.5 2.7 36.8 9.2 6.8 11 40 1.60 2.2 2.4 32.5 9.0 6.8 11 40 1.65 1.9 2.1 28.5 8.7 6.8 11 40 1.70 1.7 1.8 27.8 7.7 6.0 9 42 1.75 1.5 1.6 24.2 7.5 6.0 9 42
  • 48. 1.80 1.3 1.3 22.6 6.8 5.6 8 43 1.85 1.1 1.1 19.3 6.7 5.6 8 43 1.90 1.0 1.0 26.1 4.6 3.6 7 44 1.95 0.8 0.9 22.9 4.5 3.6 7 44 2.00 0.7 0.8 19.8 4.4 3.6 7 44 2.25 0.3 0.3 11.3 2.7 2.4 4 47 2.50 0.1 0.1 27.7 0.5 0.4 2 49 2.75 0.1 0.1 37.5 0.3 0.2 1 50 3.00 0.1 0.1 26.0 0.3 0.2 1 50 M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581450 (c) If D ¼ $0:8B and F ¼ $0:75B; then D=F ¼ 1:067 and the row for D=F ¼ 1:05 should be used in Table 7 and the column entry for D=F ¼ 1:1 used in Table 8. The impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP parameters sðD=FÞ; rðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ; qðD=FÞ; #fHg and #fNg presented in Table 7 are graphed in Figs. 4–6. In Table 8 the final LIHEAP allocation percentages under the primary HH-GB provision as a function of D=F is depicted. To determine state allotment dollars for a given value of D and F; compute D=F; retrieve the appropriate final allotment
  • 49. ARTICLE IN PRESS Table 8 Final LIHEAP allocation percentages under the primary HH-GB provision as a function of D=F State 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.0 2.5 3.0 Alabama 0.86 1.13 1.32 1.45 1.54 1.59 1.61 1.63 1.64 1.65 1.66 1.67 1.68 Alaska 0.55 0.50 a 0.46 a 0.42 a 0.39 a 0.37 a 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 Arizona 0.42 0.72 0.92 1.04 1.13 1.17 1.19 1.21 1.22 1.23 1.23 1.25 1.25 Arkansas 0.66 0.84 0.97 1.06 1.12 1.15 1.17 1.18 1.19 1.20 1.21 1.21 1.21
  • 50. California 4.61 4.90 5.20 5.45 5.65 5.77 5.82 5.87 5.90 5.92 5.94 5.99 5.99 Colorado 1.61 1.46 a 1.34 a 1.24 a 1.15 1.15 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.15 Connecticut 2.10 1.91 a 1.75 a 1.61 a 1.50 a 1.40 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.39 1.40 1.40 Delaware 0.28 0.30 0.32 0.34 0.35 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.37 0.37 0.37 0.37 0.37 D.C. 0.33 0.30 a 0.27 a
  • 51. 0.27 0.26 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.27 Florida 1.36 2.38 3.04 3.46 3.74 3.90 3.97 4.02 4.06 4.08 4.10 4.15 4.15 Georgia 1.08 1.64 2.02 2.27 2.43 2.52 2.57 2.60 2.62 2.64 2.65 2.68 2.68 Hawaii 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 Idaho 0.63 0.57 a 0.52 a 0.48 a 0.45 a 0.42 a 0.39 a 0.37 a 0.35 a
  • 52. 0.33 a 0.31 a 0.28 0.28 Illinois 5.81 5.29 a 5.13 5.11 5.15 5.19 5.21 5.23 5.24 5.25 5.26 5.29 5.30 Indiana 2.63 2.39 a 2.20 2.17 2.17 2.18 2.18 2.19 2.19 2.20 2.20 2.21 2.21 Iowa 1.86 1.69 a 1.55 a 1.43 a 1.33 a 1.24 a 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 1.22 Kansas 0.86 0.89 0.94 0.97 1.01 1.03 1.04 1.04 1.05 1.05 1.06
  • 53. 1.06 1.06 Kentucky 1.37 1.44 1.51 1.58 1.63 1.67 1.68 1.70 1.70 1.71 1.77 1.73 1.73 Louisiana 0.88 1.19 1.40 1.54 1.64 1.70 1.72 1.74 1.75 1.76 1.77 1.79 1.79 Maine 1.36 1.24 a 1.13 a 1.05 a 0.97 a 0.91 a 0.85 a 0.80 a 0.76 a 0.72 a 0.68
  • 54. a 0.61 0.61 Maryland 1.61 1.78 1.92 2.04 2.12 2.17 2.19 2.21 2.22 2.23 2.24 2.26 2.26 Massachusetts 4.20 3.82 a 3.50 a 3.23 a 3.00 a 2.90 2.90 2.89 2.90 2.90 2.90 2.91 2.91 Michigan 5.51 5.01 a 4.74 4.69 4.70 4.73 4.74 4.76 4.77 4.78 4.79 4.81 4.82 Minnesota 3.97 3.61 a 3.31 a 3.06 a 2.84
  • 55. a 2.65 a 2.48 a 2.34 a 2.21 a 2.09 a 1.99 a 1.68 1.68 Mississippi 0.74 1.14 1.41 1.58 1.70 1.76 1.79 1.82 1.83 1.84 1.85 1.87 1.87 Missouri 2.32 2.23 2.24 2.27 2.31 2.35 2.36 2.37 2.38 2.39 2.39 2.41 2.41 Montana 0.74 0.67 a 0.61 a 0.57 a
  • 57. 0.61 a 0.58 a 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.55 Nevada 0.20 0.31 0.38 0.43 0.46 0.48 0.49 0.49 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.51 0.51 New Hampshire 0.79 0.72 a 0.66 a 0.61 a 0.57 a 0.53 a 0.50 a 0.47 a 0.45 0.45 0.45 0.45 0.45 New Jersey 3.90 3.54 a
  • 58. 3.26 3.21 3.21 3.22 3.23 3.24 3.24 3.25 3.26 3.27 3.27 New Mexico 0.52 0.50 0.50 0.51 0.52 0.52 0.53 0.53 0.53 0.53 0.54 0.54 0.54 New York 12.72 11.57 a 10.60 a 9.79 a 9.09 a 8.66 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.63 8.66 8.67 North Carolina 1.90 2.28 2.56 2.76 2.90 2.99 3.03 3.06 3.08 3.09 3.10 3.13 3.13 North Dakota 0.80 0.73 a 0.67 a 0.62 a 0.57 a 0.53
  • 59. a 0.50 a 0.47 a 0.44 a 0.42 a 0.40 a 0.32 a 0.27 a Ohio 5.14 4.74 a 4.64 4.65 4.70 4.74 4.76 4.78 4.80 4.81 4.82 4.85 4.85 Oklahoma 0.79 0.95 1.07 1.15 1.21 1.25 1.26 1.28 1.28 1.29 1.30 1.31 1.31 Oregon 1.25 1.13 a 1.04 a
  • 60. 0.96 a 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.95 0.95 Pennsylvania 6.84 6.21 a 5.70 a 5.26 a 5.12 5.10 5.10 5.11 5.11 5.12 5.13 5.15 5.15 Rhode Island 0.69 0.63 a 0.58 a 0.53 a 0.49 a 0.47 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.47 0.47 South Carolina 0.68 0.94 1.12 1.24 1.31 1.36 1.38 1.40 1.41 1.42 1.42 1.44 1.44 South Dakota 0.65 0.59 a
  • 61. 0.54 a 0.50 a 0.46 a 0.43 a 0.41 a 0.38 a 0.36 a 0.34 a 0.32 a 0.29 0.29 Tennessee 1.39 1.58 1.74 1.85 1.94 1.99 2.01 2.03 2.04 2.05 2.06 2.08 2.08 Texas 2.26 3.84 4.86 5.52 5.95 6.20 6.31 6.39 6.45 6.49 6.52 6.58 6.59
  • 62. Utah 0.75 0.68 a 0.62 a 0.58 a 0.54 0.54 0.53 0.53 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.54 Vermont 0.60 0.54 a 0.50 a 0.46 a 0.43 a 0.40 a 0.37 a 0.35 a 0.33 a 0.31
  • 63. a 0.30 a 0.24 a 0.23 a Virginia 1.96 2.28 2.53 2.71 2.84 2.92 2.95 2.98 3.00 3.01 3.02 3.05 3.05 Washington 2.05 1.86 a 1.71 a 1.58 a 1.49 1.49 1.48 1.48 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 West Virginia 0.91 0.88 0.88 0.90 0.92 0.93 0.93 0.94 0.95 0.95 0.95 0.95 0.96 Wisconsin 3.58 3.25 a 2.98 a 2.75 a
  • 64. 2.55 a 2.38 a 2.24 a 2.10 a 1.99 a 1.93 1.93 1.93 1.93 Wyoming 0.30 0.27 a 0.25 a 0.23 a 0.21 a 0.20 a 0.19 a
  • 65. 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 a Designates membership in H: M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1451 percentage depicted in Table 8, and then multiply by the value of D: AiðD=FÞ ¼ DaiðD=FÞ: The functionals sðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ; and qðD=FÞ are defined in terms of the regular appropriation D; while rðD=FÞ is defined in terms of the money allocated to the states that fall within the set fNg: When D=F ¼ 1 þ E; the 28 states in fHg control 72% of the total funds allocated to the program, and as D increases, pðF; DÞ ¼ H=D declines since the number of states within fHg will decrease and with it the amount of money that fHg controls. This is shown in Fig. 4. At D=F ¼ 1:15; roughly half of the states control half of the total appropriation. The value of qðF; DÞ ¼ G=D represents the proportion of funds that the states fHg would control without the HH-GB provision. The difference between pðF; DÞ and qðF; DÞ—equivalent to sðF; DÞ— represents the distortion of the 1984 formula in percentage terms relative to the total appropriation. In Fig. 5 the impact of the primary HH-GB provision on the functional rðD=FÞ represents the percentage reduc- tion in the funding allocation to fNg due to the HH-GB provision. The counting functions #fHg and #fNg
  • 66. count the number of elements of fHg and fNg and is depicted in Fig. 6. The counting functionals are mirror images of one another since #fHg þ #fNg ¼ 51; and as D=F increases, #fHg-0 and fNg-fSg: 6.3. Regional distribution The state allocation percentages depicted in Table 8 are aggregated according to region and presented ARTICLE IN PRESS 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 1 1. 1 1. 2 1. 3 1. 4 1.
  • 68. ) s (D/F) p (D/F) q (D/F) Fig. 4. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP functionals sðD=FÞ; pðD=FÞ; and qðD=FÞ: 0 10 20 30 40 50 1 1. 1 1. 2 1. 3 1. 4 1. 5 1.
  • 69. 6 1. 7 1. 8 1. 9 2 D/F P e rc e n ta g e ( % ) r (D/F) Fig. 5. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on LIHEAP functional rðD=FÞ: 0
  • 72. m b e r o f S ta te s #{H} #{N} Fig. 6. Impact of the primary HH-GB provision on the LIHEAP counting functionals #fHg and #fNg: M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581452 graphically in Fig. 7 as a function of D=F: The limits of the distribution for the 1981 formula allotment ðD=Fp1Þ and the 1984 allotment ðD=FX1:5Þ represent the endpoints of the graph and were described previously in Table 6. As the ratio D=F increases federal allocation percentage in the Northeast and North Central regions are reallocated to the South, while the Western region maintains an essentially constant allot- ment percentage over the entire range of D=F: As D=F
  • 73. exceeds 1.5 the allotment percentages stabilize as the impact of the HH-GB provision significantly declines. Recall from Table 7 that when D=F ¼ 1:5 less than 3% of the regular appropriation is required to satisfy the HH provision. 7. Allotment block procedure An alternative approach to distribute funds that does not depend on selecting a specific value of F is to ‘‘set- aside’’ a given percentage of the regular appropriation to be used with the 1981 formula and then to apply the 1984 formula to the remaining funds. This mechanism does not hold states harmless in the sense described by the LIHEAP statute or in the trigger-level re-adjust- ment, but can be correlated with these allotment procedures using an approximating algebraic correspon- dence. If the percentage of funds allocated through the 1981 formula is denoted by r; then a state’s allotment dollars for a given fiscal year is given by AiðrÞ ¼ rDfi þ ð1 � rÞDgi and its allotment percentage is ai ¼ Ai=D or aiðrÞ ¼ rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi; 0oro1: The allotment percentage is a linear combination of fi and gi and so aðrÞ ¼ ða1; y; a51Þ is an allotment percentage sinceX aiðrÞ ¼ X
  • 74. ðrfi þ ð1 � rÞgiÞ ¼ r X fi þ ð1 � rÞ X gi ¼ 1: The value of aðrÞ as a function of r is shown in Table 9. ARTICLE IN PRESS 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 1 1. 05 1.
  • 75. 1 1. 15 1. 2 1. 25 1. 3 1. 35 1. 4 1. 45 1. 5 D/F P e rc e n ta g e ( %
  • 76. ) Northeast North Central South West Fig. 7. Regional distributional of funds. Table 9 Weighted linear combination of the 1981 and 1984 formula, aiðrÞ ¼ rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi State r 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.8 Alabama 1.51 1.35 1.27 1.19 1.02 Alaska 0.40 0.44 0.45 0.47 0.51 Arizona 1.08 0.92 0.83 0.75 0.58 Arkansas 1.11 0.99 0.93 0.88 0.77 California 5.72 5.44 5.30 5.17 4.89 Colorado 1.24 1.33 1.38 1.43 1.52 Connecticut 1.54 1.68 1.75 1.82 1.96
  • 77. Delaware 0.35 0.33 0.33 0.32 0.30 D.C. 0.28 0.29 0.30 0.30 0.31 Florida 3.59 3.04 2.76 2.48 1.92 Georgia 2.36 2.04 1.88 1.72 1.40 Hawaii 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 Idaho 0.35 0.42 0.45 0.49 0.56 Illinois 5.40 5.50 5.55 5.60 5.71 Indiana 2.30 2.38 2.42 2.46 2.55 Iowa 1.35 1.48 1.54 1.61 1.74 Kansas 1.02 0.98 0.96 0.94 0.90 Kentucky 1.66 1.59 1.55 1.51 1.44 Louisiana 1.61 1.43 1.33 1.24 1.06 Maine 0.76 0.91 0.99 1.06 1.21 Maryland 2.13 2.00 1.93 1.87 1.74 Massachusetts 3.17 3.43 3.55 3.68 3.94 Michigan 4.96 5.10 5.17 5.24 5.38 Minnesota 2.14 2.60 2.83 3.06 3.51 Mississippi 1.65 1.42 1.30 1.19 0.96
  • 78. Missouri 2.39 2.38 2.37 2.36 2.34 Montana 0.43 0.50 0.54 0.58 0.66 Nebraska 0.62 0.70 0.73 0.77 0.85 Nevada 0.44 0.38 0.35 0.32 0.26 New Hampshire 0.52 0.59 0.62 0.66 0.73 New Jersey 3.40 3.52 3.59 3.65 3.77 New Mexico 0.54 0.53 0.53 0.53 0.52 New York 9.48 10.29 10.70 11.10 11.91 North Carolina 2.89 2.64 2.52 2.39 2.14 North Dakota 0.33 0.45 0.51 0.56 0.68 Ohio 4.91 4.97 5.00 5.02 5.08 Oklahoma 1.20 1.10 1.05 1.00 0.89 Oregon 1.01 1.07 1.10 1.13 1.19 Pennsylvania 5.49 5.82 5.99 6.16 6.50 Rhode Island 0.51 0.56 0.58 0.60 0.65 South Carolina 1.29 1.14 1.06 0.98 0.83 South Dakota 0.36 0.43 0.47 0.51 0.58 Tennessee 1.94 1.80 1.73 1.66 1.53
  • 79. Texas 5.73 4.86 4.43 4.00 3.13 Utah 0.58 0.62 0.64 0.66 0.71 Vermont 0.30 0.37 0.41 0.45 0.52 Virginia 2.83 2.61 2.50 2.39 2.18 Washington 1.61 1.72 1.77 1.83 1.94 West Virginia 0.95 0.94 0.93 0.93 0.92 Wisconsin 2.26 2.59 2.75 2.92 3.25 Wyoming 0.20 0.23 0.24 0.25 0.28 M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1453 7.1. The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ A useful exercise is to correlate the values of aðrÞ and aðD=FÞ; that is, for a given value of D=F determine the value of r such that aðrÞ achieves an allocation percentage ‘‘equivalent’’ to aðD=FÞ: The limits of the relation are obvious: lim D=F-N aiðD=FÞ ¼ gi ¼ lim r-0 aiðrÞ;
  • 80. lim D=F-1 aiðD=FÞ ¼ fi ¼ lim r-1 aiðrÞ and so we are interested in the correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ for 0oro1: A correspondence using a least-squares criteria is derived in Theorem 4. Theorem 5. For a given value of D=F; the final allocation percentages specified by aðD=FÞ correspond to aðrÞ ¼ rf þ ð1 � rÞg for the least-squares estimator r ¼ rðD=FÞ ¼ P aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ � P giðfi � giÞP ðfi � giÞ 2 Proof. See Appendix C. The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ is determined through the value of rðD=FÞ shown in Fig. 8 and provides a useful means to interpret the HH condition in terms of a simple (linear) allocation mechanism. For example, when D=F ¼ 1:3; the value of r that ‘‘equates’’ aðD=FÞ in the least-squares sense with
  • 81. aðrÞ is given by r ¼ 0:25; or in other words, when D=F ¼ 1:3; the allocation mechanism determined through Option B is roughly equivalent to taking 25% of the 1981 formula values plus 75% of the 1984 formula values g: The main use of Fig. 8 is as a tool to establish the relation between competing alternative policies: * For a given value of D=F; the user can determine how the average state HH allotment aðD=FÞ distributes funds in terms of the allocation mechanism aðrÞ ¼ rf þ ð1 � rÞg: * Since the value of aðrÞ and aðD=FÞ are equivalent under the derived correspondence, the fairness criteria employed for aðD=FÞ translates to aðrÞ under rðD=FÞ: * A decision maker that can determine a range of acceptable percentage values for the contribution of f to the final allotment mechanism can use the functional rðD=FÞ to determine acceptable D=F ratios. 7.2. Induced hold-harmless allotment percentages To illustrate one application of the correspondence the allotment percentage induced through a reduced trigger level is computed. The correspondence functional rðD=FÞ describes the percentage of the HH provision funding that is allocated according to the 1981 formula. Hence, using the correspondence we can determine the effective weight of the 1981 formula as a function of the trigger level. Given rðD=FÞ and the historic LIHEAP funding levels from 1981–2002, the ratio D=F is computed each year
  • 82. based on the regular appropriation D and trigger level F; rðD=FÞ is computed, and then the average value of rðD=FÞ reported: /rðD=FÞS ¼ P2002 t¼1981 rðD=F; tÞ 21 : The value /rðD=FÞS describes the expected contribu- tion of the 1981 formula allotment to the final allotment percentages for a given value of F: In Fig. 9 the contribution of the 1981 formula to the final allotment percentages as a function of the trigger level F is shown. Since the current trigger level is F ¼ $1:975B; Fig. 9 illustrates that 98% of the LIHEAP funds has effectively been allocated based on the 1981 formula, with 2% of the funds allocated using the 1984 formula. If F ¼ $1B; then based on historic levels of LIHEAP funding, 28% of federal dollars would have been allocated using the 1981 formula with the remaining 72% allocated with the 1984 formula. ARTICLE IN PRESS 0 0.2 0.4
  • 84. D/F r (% ) Fig. 8. The correspondence between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ: 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.975 1.75 1.5 1.25 1 0.75 0.5 0.25 F ($B) r (% ) Fig. 9. Induced allotment percentage of the HH-GB provision based on LIHEAP funding levels, 1981–2002. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581454
  • 85. 7.3. Re-interpreting the primary hold-harmless provision The LIHEAP allocation percentages under the primary HH provision (Option B) can be interpreted in a manner analogous to the allotment block proce- dure. Recall that for states iAfNg; AiðF; DÞ ¼ Ffi þ Ei ¼ Ffi þ gðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi or aiðF; DÞ ¼ ð1 � gÞkfi þ ggi; where k ¼ F=D and g ¼ X =Q: For a given value of D > F; ko1; and so the term kfi represents a reduction in the 1981 formula percentage. As D increases, k approaches zero while the term g approaches one (recall Theorem 1), indicating that the contribution to aiðF; DÞ from fi will approach zero. The LIHEAP allocation percentages in Option B is thus similar in structure to the allotment block procedure, but while the parameter r is a decision parameter, the value of k and g is dependent on D=F and is not controllable unless the ratio D=F is legislated. 8. Simplified legislative road map The main issues surrounding the LIHEAP debate are summarized as follows: * The 1981 distribution formula is not an appropriate
  • 86. baseline. * Corporate scandals are sexy and good publicity issues, while government ‘‘scandals’’ resist debate. * Impetus to change LIHEAP will always be an uphill struggle since the votes for change simply do not add up for any of the alternatives described. * Full ‘‘disclosure’’ and transparency may help lead to change. * Shame is a good motivator for change. * Arguments should be based on essential facts and a clear storyline. A legislative ‘‘road map’’ of sorts is suggested to help push LIHEAP along in the right direction. Since a simple count of votes is not expected to add up in favor of changing the LIHEAP allocation mechanism, the story presented must be moral tale and based on established facts. Shame is used as the primary motivator for change. Fact 1: The high trigger level established within the 1984 re-authorization legislation has disabled the application of the 1984 formula. Shame/result: The 1981 formula is still being used to distribute LIHEAP funding to this day (inequitable program). Fact 2: The 1981 formula allotments hold little meaning 20 years after their creation and should not be used to distribute federal dollars.
  • 87. Shame/result: LIHEAP allotments to states are not distributed in a rational manner (poorly executed program). Fact 3: The primary intent of LIHEAP is to assist low-income households meet their home energy needs. Shame/result: LIHEAP funds are not being distrib- uted in accord with the program intent (irrational program). 9. Conclusions The purpose of this paper was to propose policy alternatives for distributing LIHEAP funds to states and to quantify the impact of each alternative. Three policy alternatives were examined. In the first alternative, the LIHEAP trigger level is nullified and the HH-GB provisions attached to the allocation are eliminated. The 1984 formula is applied in ‘‘pure’’ form unencumbered by the weight of additional provisions or conditions. This policy alternative paral - lels the Bush Administration position expressed in the FY 2003 federal budget and is the simplest and probably the best of the three options considered, although it is not expected to develop the political support necessary to achieve passage. In the second alternative, the primary HH-GB provision of the LIHEAP statute is maintained but the trigger level when it is enabled is reduced. Regular appropriations for LIHEAP generally do not exceed the current trigger F ¼ $1:975B; and in fact, have only exceeded this level twice in the past 17 years—the last
  • 88. time in FY 1986. At one time (15-years ago) the values of D and F were roughly comparable, while today F appears as a large (mostly unattainable) upper bound. Reducing the current trigger level increases the like- lihood that the 1984 formula will be applied, and since this alternative does not involve the complete disman- tling of the legislative statute, it is also likely to garner more political support. It should be mentioned, how - ever, that even under this alternative a majority of states are still worse off under the new allocation percentages, and hence, even the passage of compromise legislation might fail to generate sufficient support. Legislation that sponsors a trigger-level reduction must be crafted to ensure the reduction is significant or further drift between D and F may result in the future. Re-adjusting F downward may yield the desired outcome, but from a programmatic perspective, also perpetrates the applica- tion/justification of the 1981 formula, which is con- sidered a major drawback. In the third alternative, a simple allocation mechan- ism was examined that set-aside a given percentage of ARTICLE IN PRESS M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1455 the regular appropriation to be used exclusively with the 1981 formula with the remaining funds allocated under the 1984 formula. The advantage of this mechanism is that the 1984 formula will always be incorporated within the allotment procedure regardless of the level of regular appropriation, and hence the downside risk (i.e., when DpF ) is always covered. On the other hand, it may be
  • 89. difficult to negotiate the value of r; and once selected, r fixes the allotment percentages and does not allow the upside potential of the 1984 formula (i.e., when D > F ) to be realized. Since the upside potential of the 1984 formula has only a low probability of occurrence, however, this does not seem to be an extenuating factor. ‘‘Mixing’’ the formula allocations is also not a preferred procedure from a legislative or methodological perspec- tive, although as shown in Theorem 4, a correspondence does exists between the mixed formula and the triggered hold-harmless provision. Hence, the user can always view the allotment block procedure in terms of a trigger- level enabled mechanism. Acknowledgements The authors would like to acknowledge the role Carolyn Drake had in introducing the LIHEAP problem to the authors and suggesting its initial formulation. Her encouragement, guidance, and pa- tience is kindly recognized. The authors would also like to thank Kathy Baskin, Elizabeth Jones, Beth Osborne, Ed Rissing, and Fred Zeytoonjian for their support, insight, and useful criticisms of this work. Funding for this research was provided in part by the Southern States Energy Board, but all opinions, findings, and results remain the responsibility of the authors. Appendix A. Derivation of the LIHEAP structure equations Theorem 1. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under the primary HH-GB provision yields state allotments
  • 90. according to the following recipe: AiðF; DÞ ¼ Dfi; iAfSg; DpF; Ffi; iAfHg; D > F; Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg; D > F; 8>< >: where fSg ¼ fHg,fNg; fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g; fNg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgip1g; Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ; g ¼ X =Q; X ¼ D � F; and Q ¼ P iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ: Proof. If DpF; then following the current LIHEAP statute, AiðF; DÞ ¼ Dfi for all iAfSg: If D > F; then partition fSg into two sets according to whether state i satisfies Ffi > Dgi or FfipDgi: The class of states labeled fHg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgi > 1g are the HH states which are held at their statutory floor. The class of states labeled fNg ¼ fi j Ffi=Dgip1g will have an allotment falling above their floor. All states in fHg are assigned their statutory floor, while states in fNg are assigned their statutory floor plus an amount Ei that needs to be determined AiðF; DÞ ¼ Ffi; iAfHg; Ffi þ Ei; iAfNg:
  • 91. ( Since statutory floors are maintained across all states, the HH-GB provision in essence captures F of the regular appropriated dollars D: D ¼ X iAfSg AiðF; DÞ ¼ X iAfHg Ffi þ X iAfNg ðFfi þ EiÞ ¼ X iAfHg Ffi þ X iAfNg Ffi þ X
  • 92. iAfNg Ei ¼ F X iAfSg fi þ X iAfNg Ei ¼ F þ X iAfNg Ei: The value X ¼ X iAfNg Ei ¼ D � F represents the dollars available to the states in fNg after the statutory floor money is assigned to all the states in fSg: To determine the extra allotment that each state in fNg receives, state i’s allotment ‘‘above the floor’’
  • 93. Dgi � Ffi; iAfNg is computed, and since Q ¼ X iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ > X ; the value of Q will need to be reduced so that it matches the available funds X : The value of X is thus a binding constraint. The reduction factor g ¼ X =Q is applied across each state’s money above the floor, and the value of Ei is calculated as Ei ¼ gðDgi � FfiÞ: Observe that the sum of the ‘‘extra’’ state allotments is by construction equal to the available funds X as required:X iAfNg Ei ¼ g X iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ X Q
  • 94. X iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ X : & Theorem 2. The LIHEAP allocation mechanism under the primary HH-GB yields the following limiting relations: lim D=F-1 aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi; lim D=F-N aiðF; DÞ ¼ gi: ARTICLE IN PRESS M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581456 Proof. By the definition of the allocation mechanism, when D=F-1; it is clear that lim D=F-1 aiðF; DÞ ¼ fi; iAfSg: On the other hand, as the ratio D=F increases it is clear that #fHg-0 and fNg-fSg: Then since Q ¼P
  • 95. iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ; lim D=F-N X iAfNg ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ X iAfSg ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ D X iAfSg gi � F X iAfSg fi ¼ D � F; i.e., lim D=F-N g ¼ lim D=F-N X
  • 96. Q ¼ D � F D � F ¼ 1: Then since AiðF; DÞ ¼ Ffi þ Ei ¼ Ffi þ gðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi; lim D=F-N AiðF; DÞ ¼ lim g-1 ½ð1 � gÞFfi þ gDgi ¼ Dgi or lim D=F-N aiðF; DÞ ¼ AiðF; DÞ D ¼ gi: & Appendix B. One-dimensional LIHEAP system measures Theorem 3. For D > F; the LIHEAP allocation mechan- ism under the primary HH-GB provision yield state
  • 97. allotment percentages aiðF; DÞ ¼ F D fi; iAfHg; F D fi þ Ei D ; iAfNg ( that are functions of the ratio F/D. Proof. Let k ¼ F=Da0: It is sufficient to show that aiðF; DÞ is a constant: (i) If iAfHg; then aiðF; DÞ ¼ ðF=DÞfi ¼ kfi; which is a constant since fi is constant. (ii) If iAfNg; then aiðF; DÞ ¼ ðF=DÞfi þ ðEi=DÞ ¼ kfi þ ðEi=DÞ: It is sufficient to show Ei=D is constant. Ei D ¼
  • 98. X DQ ðDgi � FfiÞ ¼ X Q gi � F D fi � ¼ X Q ðgi � kfiÞ ¼ k 0 X Q ; where k0 ¼ gi � kfi is constant since gi is constant. Now X =Q ¼ X =D=Q=D and X D ¼
  • 99. D � F D ¼ 1 � F D ¼ 1 � k a constant, and Q D ¼ D P iAfNg gi � F P iAfNg fi D ¼ X iAfNg gi � F D
  • 100. X iAfNg fi ¼ X iAfNg gi � k X iAfNg fi: The summation terms P iAfNg fi; P iAfHg fi; P iAfNg gi; and P iAfHg gi are all constant since the elements of fHg ¼ i j Ffi Dgi > 1
  • 101. � ¼ i j k fi gi > 1 � ; fNg ¼ i j Ffi Dgi p1 � ¼ i j k fi gi p1 � are constant, and so Q=D is constant, and thus, X =Q is constant. Hence, aiðF; DÞ is a constant and can be expressed as aiðF=DÞ; or equivalently, since k ¼ F=Da0; as aiðD=FÞ: &
  • 102. Theorem 4. The LIHEAP system measures sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms of the ratio D=F as sðD=FÞ; iðD=FÞ; and rðD=FÞ: Proof. Let k ¼ F=Da0: It suffices to show that sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ are constants. By definition of the functionals sðF; DÞ; iðF; DÞ; and rðF; DÞ; sðF; DÞ ¼ H � G D ¼ H D � G D ¼ F P iAfHg fi D � D P
  • 103. iAfHg gi D ¼ k X iAfHg fi � X iAfHg gi; is a constant, and so sðF; DÞ can be expressed in terms of the ratio sðD=FÞ: Similarly, iðF; DÞ ¼ H � G G ¼ H G � 1 ¼ F P iAfHg fi
  • 104. D P iAfHg gi � 1 ¼ k P iAfHg fiP iAfHg gi � 1 a constant, and rðF; DÞ ¼ H � G M ¼ H M � G M ¼ F P iAfHg fi D
  • 105. P iAfNg gi � D P iAfHg gi D P iAfNg gi ¼ k P iAfHg fiP iAfNg gi � P iAfHg giP iAfNg gi a constant, and so iðF; DÞ and rðF; DÞ can be expressed as iðD=FÞ and rðD=FÞ: & Appendix C. Derivation of the least-squares estimator Theorem 5. For a given value of D/F, the final allocation percentages specified by aðD=FÞ correspond to aðrÞ ¼ ARTICLE IN PRESS
  • 106. M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 1458 1457 rf þ ð1 � rÞg for the least-squares estimator r ¼ rðD=FÞ ¼ P aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ � P giðfi � giÞP ðfi � giÞ 2 : Proof. For a given value of the ratio D=F; the value of r that minimizes the sum of the squared differences between aðD=FÞ and aðrÞ is determined as follows. Let f ðrÞ ¼ X ðaiðD=FÞ � aiðrÞÞ 2: Then the solution to minr f ðrÞ is determined by solving dðf ðrÞÞ=dr ¼ 0 orX ðaiðD=FÞ � aiðrÞÞ daiðrÞ dr
  • 107. ¼ 0: Since aiðrÞ ¼ rfi þ ð1 � rÞgi; dðaiðrÞÞ=dr ¼ fi � gi; and solving for r yields r ¼ P aiðD=FÞðfi � giÞ � P giðfi � giÞP ðfi � giÞ 2 : The second-derivative test yields d 2 f ðrÞ dr ¼ � daiðrÞ dr � 2 o0 ensuring that r is a minimum value of f ðrÞ: & References
  • 108. Abbey, C.W., 2001. The low-income home energy assistance program: how are state allotments determined? CRS Report RS 20893, Washington, D.C., April. Colton, R., 1990. Client consumption patterns within an income-based energy assistance program. Journal of Economic Issues 24 (4), 1079–1093. General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1986. Low Income Energy Assistance: state responses to 1984 amendments. Report to Congressional Committees, GAO/HRD-86-92, Washington, D.C., May. General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1987. Energy conservation: funding state energy assistance programs. Fact Sheet for the Ranking Minority Member, Committee on the Budget, United State Senate, GAO/RCED-87-114FS, Washington, D.C., March. General Accounting Office, US Congress, 1990. Low Income Home Energy Assistance: a program overview. Briefing Report to the
  • 109. Chairman, Subcommittee on Human Resources, Committee on Education and Labor, House of Representatives, GAO/HRD-91- 1-BR, Washington, D.C., October. Gish, M., 2000. The low-income home energy assistance program. CRS Report 94-211, Washington, D.C., June. Higgins, L., Lutzenhiser, L., 1995. Ceremonial equity: low - income energy assistance and the failure of socio-environmental policy. Social Problems 42 (4), 468–492. Kennedy, J.M., 1987. Public support for residential energy assistance. Sociology and Social Research 71, 308–311. Kingsley, G.A., 1992. US energy conservation policy: themes and trends. Policy Studies Journal 20, 114–123. Landsberg, H.H., Dukert, J.M., 1981. High Energy Costs: Uneven? Unfair? Unavoidable? Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD.
  • 110. Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1983. Report to Congress For Fiscal Year 1982, US Department of Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, November. Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1985. Report to Congress For Fiscal Year 1983, US Department of Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, May. Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 1994. Report to Congress For Fiscal Year 1993, US Department of Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance, October. Low Income Home Energy Assistance Programs, 2000. Report to Congress For Fiscal Year 1996, US Department of Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of Community Services, Division of Energy Assistance,
  • 111. September. Pataki, G.E. (Governor), 2001. Statement of the Coalition of Northeastern Governors to the House Appropriations Subcom- mittee on Interior and Related Agencies regarding FY 2002 appropriations for the US Department of Energy’s Weatherization Assistance Program and State Energy Program, April 16. Patton, P., Hodges, J. (Governors), 2001. Resolution regarding the national energy policy. Southern Governors’ Association 67th Annual Meeting, Lexington, KY, September 9. Stoltzfus, E., 2002. The low-income home energy assistance program (LIHEAP). CRS Report 94-211, Washington, D.C., January. ARTICLE IN PRESS M.J. Kaiser, A.G. Pulsipher / Energy Policy 31 (2003) 1441– 14581458 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
  • 112. The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Libby Perl Specialist in Housing Policy September 8, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL33275 The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service Summary The Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP) provides funds to states, the District of Columbia, U.S. territories and commonwealths, and Indian tribal organizations (collectively referred to as grantees) primarily to help low - income households pay home energy expenses. The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of funding: regular funds (sometimes referred to as block grant funds) and emergency contingency funds. Regular funds are allocated to grantees based on a formula, while contingency funds may be released to one or more grantees at
  • 113. the discretion of the Secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services based on emergency need. Regular LIHEAP funds are allocated to the states according to a formula that has a long and complicated history. (Tribes receive funds based on either their number of federally eligible LIHEAP households compared to the total number in the state or on agreements with their states, whereas territories receive a set percentage of total LIHEAP regular funds.) In 1980, Congress created the predecessor program to LIHEAP, the Low Income Energy Assistance Program (LIEAP) as part of the Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act (P.L. 96-223). Because Congress was particularly concerned with the high costs of heating, funds under LIEAP were distributed according to a multi-step formula that benefitted cold-weather states. In 1981, Congress enacted LIHEAP as part of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act (P.L. 97-35), replacing LIEAP. However, the LIHEAP statute specified that states would continue to receive the same percentage of regular funds that they did under the LIEAP formula. When Congress reauthorized LIHEAP in 1984 as part of the Human Services Reauthorization Act (P.L. 98-558), it changed the program’s formula by requiring the use of more recent population and energy data and requiring that HHS consider both heating and cooling costs of low-income households (a change from the focus on the heating needs of all households). The effect of these changes meant that, in general, funds would be shifted from cold-weather states to warm-weather
  • 114. states. To prevent a dramatic shift of funds, Congress added two “hold-harmless” provisions to the formula. The result of these provisions is a current law, three-tiered formula (sometimes referred to as the “new” formula), the application of which depends on the amount of regular funds that Congress appropriates. The Tier I formula is used to allocate funds when the total LIHEAP regular fund appropriation is less than or equal to the equivalent of a hypothetical FY1984 appropriation of $1.975 billion. Above this level, funds are allocated according to Tier II of the formula, which includes a hold- harmless level to prevent certain states from losing LIHEAP funds. Finally, Tier III applies to appropriations at or above $2.25 billion, and includes a second hold-harmless provision, the hold- harmless rate. Since FY1986, LIHEAP regular fund appropriations have exceeded the equivalent of an FY1984 appropriation of $1.975 billion in FY2006, when the regular fund appropriation was $2.48 billion; in FY2008, when appropriations slightly exceeded the trigger; and in FY2009 and FY2010, when Congress directed that $840 million be distributed according to the “new” LIHEAP formula. This report will be updated when new formula data are released and when proposed funding levels change (see Appendix C).
  • 115. The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service Contents Introduction ............................................................................................... ................................. 1 Predecessor Programs to LIHEAP ............................................................................................... 2 Community Services Administration Energy Assistance Programs......................................... 2 Low Income Energy Assistance Program (LIEAP) ................................................................ 5 The LIEAP Formula.................................................................................. ...................... 6 Enactment of LIHEAP ............................................................................................... ................. 8 Continued Use of the LIEAP Formula ................................................................................... 9 The 1984 LIHEAP Reauthorization: A New Formula ............................................................ 9 Formula Discussions ............................................................................................... ........ 9 Introduction of a Hold-Harmless Level.......................................................................... 10 Introduction of a Hold-Harmless Rate
  • 116. ........................................................................... 10 LIHEAP Formula Statutory Language ........................................................................... 11 Determining LIHEAP Regular Fund Allotments Using the “New” Formula ............................... 12 Calculating the New Formula Rates .................................................................................... 12 Using the New Formula Rates to Allocate Funds to the States ............................................. 14 Tier I: Below $1.975 Billion.................................................................................... ...... 15 Tier II: From $1.975 Billion up to $2.25 Billion ............................................................ 15 Tier III: At or Above $2.25 Billion ................................................................................ 16 Implementation of the “New” LIHEAP Formula ................................................................. 17 Figures Figure B-1. Estimated Low Income Home Energy Assistance (LIHEAP) Allocations at Various Hypothetical Appropriations Levels for Three Types of States ................................... 27 Tables Table 1. Select Energy Assistance Formulas, FY1975-FY1980 .................................................... 4 Table 2. Distribution of Funds Under
  • 117. LIEAP............................................................................... 8 Table 3. Low-Income Home Energy Program (LIHEAP): “Old” and “New” Allotment Rates by State, 2010....................................................................................... ........................ 17 Table 4. Recent State Allotment Rates Under the “New” LIHEAP Formula ............................... 20 Table A-1. LIHEAP Estimated State Allotments for Regular Funds at Various Hypothetical Appropriation Levels ......................................................................................... 23 Table C-1. LIHEAP Actual State Regular Fund Allotments for FY2006 through FY2010 and Estimated FY2011 Allotments ......................................................................................... 30 The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service Appendixes Appendix A. Estimated Allotments to the States Under Various Hypothetical Appropriations Levels ...............................................................................................
  • 118. ............. 22 Appendix B. Further Depiction of How State Allotments Depend Upon Appropriation Levels ............................................................................................... ..................................... 26 Appendix C. Actual LIHEAP Regular Fund Allocations to the States, FY2006-FY2010 and Estimated Allocations, FY2011................................................................................... ..... 28 Contacts Author Contact Information ............................................................................................... ....... 34 The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service 1 Introduction The Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP) is a block grant program administered by the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) under which the federal government gives annual grants to states, the District of Columbia, U.S. territories and
  • 119. commonwealths, and Indian tribal organizations to operate multi-component home energy assistance programs for needy households.1 Established in 1981 by Title XXVI of P.L. 97-35, the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act, LIHEAP has been reauthorized and amended a number of times, most recently in 2005, when P.L. 109-58, the Energy Policy Act, authorized annual regular LIHEAP funds at $5.1 billion per year from FY2005 through FY2007.2 The federal LIHEAP statute has very broad guidelines, with almost all decisions regarding the program’s operation made by the states. Recipients may be helped with their heating and cooling costs, receive crisis assistance, have weatherizing expenses paid, or receive other aid designed to reduce their home energy needs. Households with incomes up to 150% of the federal poverty income guidelines or, if greater, 60% of the state median income, are federally eligible for LIHEAP benefits. States may adopt lower income limits, but no household with income below 110% of the poverty guidelines may be considered ineligible. Note, however, that in the FY2009 and FY2010 appropriations acts (P.L. 110-329 and P.L. 111- 117), Congress gave states the authority to raise eligibility limits to 75% of state median income. The most current HHS data show that an estimated 5.5 million households received winter heating or winter crisis assistance in FY2006 (the largest share of LIHEAP funds pay for heating assistance).3 The LIHEAP statute provides for two types of program funding: regular funds—sometimes
  • 120. referred to as block grant funds—and emergency contingency funds. Regular funds are allotted to states on the basis of the LIHEAP statutory formula, which was enacted as part of the Human Services Reauthorization Act of 1984 (P.L. 98-558).4 The way in which regular funds are allocated to states depends on the amount of funds appropriated by Congress. The second type of LIHEAP funds, emergency contingency funds, may be released and allotted to one or more states at the discretion of the President and the Secretary of HHS.5 The funds may be released at any point in the fiscal year to meet additional home energy assistance needs created by a natural disaster or other emergency.6 The remainder of this report discusses only the history and methods of distributing regular LIHEAP funds. 1 For additional information on LIHEAP, see CRS Report RL31865, The Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP): Program and Funding, by Libby Perl. 2 LIHEAP is codified at 42 U.S.C. §§8621-8630. 3 U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, FY2006 LIHEAP Report to Congress, April 22, 2009, p. 21. 4 The formula section is codified at 42 U.S.C. §8623. 5 Depending on how Congress appropriates them, contingency funds may remain available for distribution in more than one fiscal year or they may expire with the fiscal year for which they were appropriated. 6 The statutory definition of emergency includes a significant home energy supply shortage or disruption, a significant
  • 121. increase in the cost of home energy, a significant increase in home energy disconnections, a significant increase in participation in a public benefit program, a significant increase in unemployment, or an event meeting such criteria as the Secretary determines to be appropriate. 42 U.S.C. §8622. The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service 2 Predecessor Programs to LIHEAP The mid- to late-1970s, a time marked by rapidly rising fuel prices, also marked the beginning of federal energy assistance funding for low-income households. The first national program to help low-income households was created in early 1975 to assist families with energy conservation primarily through home weatherization. This assistance was provided through a new Emergency Energy Conservation Program (EECP), enacted as part of the Headstart, Economic Opportunity, and Community Partnership Act of 1974 (P.L. 93-644). The funds were administered by the Community Services Administration (CSA), the successor agency to the Office of Economic Opportunity, which was responsible for many of the programs created as part of the 1964 war on poverty. Beginning in 1977, funds were also made available through the CSA to help families directly pay for fuel (as opposed to weatherization expenses) via a variety of programs. Each of these programs had in common a focus on the need for heating assistance (versus cooling
  • 122. assistance). Congress continued to appropriate funds for energy assistance programs through FY1980, at which point a new program, the Low Income Energy Assistance Program (LIEAP) was enacted as part of the Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act of 1980 (P.L. 96-223). LIEAP, which was administered by the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS), was funded for one year, FY1981, before the creation of LIHEAP. Like the CSA programs, LIEAP emphasized heating over cooling needs. This preference was reflected in both the CSA program formulas and the LIEAP set of formulas, which used variables that benefitted cold-weather states to determine how funds would be distributed. The LIEAP set of formulas continues to have relevance for the way in which LIHEAP funds are distributed. This section of the report describes these predecessor programs to LIHEAP and their distribution formulas. Community Services Administration Energy Assistance Programs On January 4, 1975, President Ford signed into law the Headstart, Economic Opportunity, and Community Partnership Act of 1974 (P.L. 93-644), which contained funds for a new program, called the Emergency Energy Conservation Program (EECP). The program was to be administered by the Community Services Administration (CSA), and its purpose was to enable low-income individuals and families, including the elderly and the near poor, to participate in energy conservation programs designed to lessen
  • 123. the impact of the high cost of energy ... and to reduce ... energy consumption. The law governing EECP listed a number of eligible activities in which states could participate, including energy conservation and education programs; weatherization assistance; loans and grants for the purchase of energy conservation technologies; alternative fuel supplies; and fuel voucher and stamp programs. Despite the variety of activities that could be funded through the program, the first CSA funding notice regarding the program limited eligible activities to “winterizing” homes and to giving emergency assistance “to prevent hardship or danger to health The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service 3 due to utility shutoff or lack of fuel.”7 During the four years the EECP was funded, the majority of funds were used for weatherization expenses.8 EECP funds were distributed to states via a formula that benefitted those states with high heating costs. One formula variable in particular, a measure of “coldness” called heating degree days, benefitted cold-weather states. Heating degree days measure the extent to which a day’s average temperature falls below 65° Fahrenheit. For example, a day with an average temperature of 50° results in a measure of 15 heating degree days. Because heating
  • 124. degree days are higher in cold weather states, including the heating degree day variable in a formula favors states with greater heating needs. Squaring the heating degree days magnifies this effect.9 The EECP formula took the number of population-weighted heating degree days in each state, squared them, and multiplied the result by the number of households in poverty that owned their homes to determine how funds would be allocated.10 The CSA acknowledged the emphasis on heating needs in its formula, stating that the FY1975 allocation “was heavily weighted to the coldest areas.”11 In the three fiscal years that followed the first appropriation for the EECP, from FY1976 through FY1978, the CSA changed somewhat the way in which it allocated funds to the states; however, the factors continued to favor cold-weather states through use of either heating degree days or heating degree days squared.12 The first year that Congress specifically appropriated funds for direct assistance to help low- income households (those at or below 125% of poverty) pay their energy costs (instead of funds that went primarily for weatherization and conservation activities) was FY1977. The FY1977 Supplemental Appropriations Act (P.L. 95-26) provided $200 million for a Special Crisis Intervention Program to be administered by CSA. States could use funds to make direct payments to fuel providers on behalf of low-income families lacking the financial resources to pay their energy bills. The CSA directed states to target households where utilities had been shut off (or were threatened with shut off) and who could prove dire need
  • 125. due to large energy bills.13 Although the law did not reserve funds exclusively for heating costs, the way in which funds were allocated to the states emphasized heating need. Funds were distributed to the states based on a formula that used (1) heating degree days squared, (2) the number of households in poverty, (3) the number of persons above age 65 with incomes below 125% of poverty, and (4) the relative cost of fuel in the region.14 Congress again appropriated $200 million for crisis intervention in 7 Community Services Administration, “Character and Scope of Specific Community Action Programs: Emergency Energy Conservation Program,” Federal Register, vol. 40, no. 145, July 28, 1975, p. 31603. 8 See, for example, House Appropriations Committee, report to accompany H.R. 4877, the FY1977 Supplemental Appropriations Act, 95th Cong., 1st sess., H.Rept. 95-68, March 11, 1977: “The funds in this program are used primarily to purchase materials to insulate the homes of low -income families.” 9 For example, if a southern state experiences 700 heating degree days in a year and a northern state experiences 7,000, the northern state has 10 times as many heating degree days as the southern state. However, if both numbers are squared, the northern state has 100 times as many heating degree days as the southern state. 10 Community Services Administration, “Emergency Energy Conservation Program: Submission of Funding Plans,” Federal Register, vol. 41, no. 208, October 27, 1976, p. 47096. 11 Federal Register, vol. 41, no. 208, October 27, 1976, p. 47096. 12 See Ibid., pp. 47096-47097. 13 Community Services Administration, “Special Crisis
  • 126. Intervention Program: General Information, Application Procedures, and Post Grant Requirements,” Federal Register, vol. 42, no. 125, June 29, 1977, p. 33240. 14 The formula was described in the Senate Appropriations Committee report to accompany H.R. 4877, the FY1977 Supplemental Appropriations Act, 95th Cong., 1st sess., S.Rept. 95-64, March 24, 1977. The CSA implemented this formula, which it described in guidance to the states. See the Federal Register, Ibid. The LIHEAP Formula: Legislative History and Current Law Congressional Research Service 4 both FY1978 and FY1979.15 In FY1978, funds were available to households with the need for assistance as the result of an energy-related emergency such as lack of fuel, a natural disaster, fuel shortages, and widespread unemployment.16 In FY1979, funds were made available to assist families facing “substantially increased energy costs and/ or life- or health-threatening situations caused by winter-related energy emergencies.”17 In FY1980, Congress appropriated a total of $1.6 billion for energy assistance. Of this amount, $400 million was appropriated for the Energy Crisis Assistance Program (ECAP, a CSA program similar to the Special Crisis Intervention Program) through two separate appropriations.18 The remainder, $1.2 billion, was appropriated as part of the FY1980 Department of the Interior Appropriations Act (P.L. 96-126) to the Department of Health,
  • 127. Education, and Welfare (HEW, the predecessor to HHS) for cash assistance and crisis intervention due to high energy costs. This appropriation to HEW is sometimes referred to as Low Income Supplemental Energy Allowances. Of this $1.2 billion, $400 million was to be distributed specifically to recipients of Supplemental Security Income (SSI). The rest of the funds appropriated to HEW, approximately $800 million, as well as the ECAP funds, were distributed to states on the basis of three factors: heating degree days squared, the number of households below 125% of poverty, and the difference in home heating energy expenditures between 1978 and 1979. The formula used to distribute the $400 million for SSI recipients used these same factors but also included the number of SSI recipients in each state relative to the national total. Table 1. Select Energy Assistance Formulas, FY1975-FY1980 Emergency Energy Conservation Program:a FY1975 (P.L. 93-644) Special Crisis Intervention Program:b FY1977 (P.L. 95-26) Low Income Supplemental Energy Allowances:c