SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 18
Download to read offline
international journal of health planning and management 
Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
Published online 29 November 2007 in Wiley InterScience 
(www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/hpm.914 
Extending social health insurance to the 
informal sector in Kenya. An assessment 
of factors affecting demand 
Inke Mathauer1*, y, Jean-Olivier Schmidt2 and Maurice Wenyaa3 
1Department of Health Systems Financing (HSF), World Health Organization, 1211 Geneva 
27, Switzerland 
2GTZ German Technical Cooperation, Eschborn, Germany 
3National Hospital Insurance Fund, Kenya 
SUMMARY 
This paper contributes to analysing and understanding the demand for (social) health insurance 
of informal sector workers in Kenya by assessing their perceptions and knowledge of and 
concerns regarding health insurance and the Kenyan National Hospital Insurance Fund 
(NHIF). It serves to explore how informal sector workers could be integrated into the NHIF. 
To collect data, focus group discussions were held with organized groups of informal sector 
workers of different types across the country, backed up by a self-administered questionnaire 
completed by heads of NHIF area branch offices. 
It was found that the most critical barrier to NHIF enrolment is the lack of knowledge of 
informal sector workers about the NHIF, its enrolment option and procedures for informal 
sector workers. Inability to pay is a critical factor for some, but people were, in principle, 
interested in health insurance, and thus willing to pay for it. 
In sum, the mix of demand-side determinants for enrolling in the NHIF is not as complex as 
expected. This is good news, as these demand-side determinants can be addressed with 
a well-designed strategy, focusing on awareness raising and information, improvement 
of insurance design features and setting differentiated and affordable contribution rates. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 
key words: social health insurance; informal sector; health insurance demand; Kenya 
INTRODUCTION 
There is growing international consensus on the importance of extending social 
protection in health to the whole population (ILO, 2001a, 2001b; Carrin and Preker, 
2004; WHA, 2005; Gottret and Schieber, 2006) in order to reduce financial barriers 
* Correspondence to: Dr I. Mathauer, Department of Health Systems Financing (HSF), World Health 
Organization, 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland. E-mail: mathaueri@who.int 
yThis article was written when Inke Mathauer was associated with GTZ. She is currently working for the 
World Health Organization. All views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not 
necessarily represent the views of GTZ, NHIF or WHO. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
to health care services for the needy and to avoid catastrophic health expenditures 
(Kawabata et al., 2002). The option of social health insurance as a financing 
mechanism generating additional resources in typically chronically underfinanced 
health systems is receiving increasing attention (GTZ/ILO/WHO 2006a, Carrin and 
James, 2004; WHA, 2005), for the informal sector too (GTZ/ILO/WHO, 2006b). 
However, one of the major challenges to social health insurance in developing 
countries is integration of the expanding informal sector and inclusion of the poor. 
Various low-income countries (Ghana, Kenya, Kyrgyz Republic, the Philippines, 
Tanzania and Viet Nam) and mid-income countries (South Korea, Mexico), which 
have introduced or are in the process of expanding social health insurance, are being 
faced with this. 
The informal sector is characterized by low and non-regular, non-taxed incomes, 
insecure employment and self-employment without social security (Canagarajah and 
Setharaman, 2001; cf. ILO, 2002 and Xaba et al., 2002). It is difficult to assess the 
income of informal sector workers, on the basis of which social security contributions 
can be deducted. Hence policymakers wishing to introduce or upscale a national social 
health insurance for the informal sector and to include the poor are faced with a number 
of questions regarding insurance scheme design with respect to enrolment, revenue 
collection, risk pooling and purchasing of health services. Another critical task is 
promoting demand for and acceptability of social health insurance among informal 
sector workers during the introduction and scaling-up phase. 
Promotion of demand and acceptability starts froma sound understanding of factors 
affecting demand among informal sector workers and the poor. However, the literature 
addressing demand-side factors of health insurance in low-income countries is limited. 
Econometric studies look at socio-demographic and socio-economic household and 
individual determinants such as age, sex, income, education and their correlation with 
health insurance ownership. It is found that persons with higher income and higher 
education are more likely to have health insurance (Xu et al., 2006 for Kenya, Kirigia 
et al., 2005 for South Africa, Bhat and Jain, 2006 for India).Yet econometric studies do 
not state why people have joined an insurance scheme, and especially why peoplewith 
lower incomes, in whom we are particularly interested, have not joined. Research into 
people’s preferences (Monheit and Primoff Vistness, 2004 for the USA) emphasizes 
the need to look beyond demographic and income factors to understand people’s 
reasoning and decision making. Other studies have tried to assess willingness and 
ability to pay for health insurance (Asenso-Okyere et al., 1997; Arhin, 1997; 
Mathiyazhagan, 1998; Asfaw, 2002; Dongh et al., 2003; Osei-Akoto, 2003; Ahuja and 
Ju¨tting, 2004; Akazili et al., 2005; Dror, 2006). 
This paper intends to contribute to the understanding of demand for (social) health 
insurance among informal sector workers in Kenya by assessing their perceptions, 
knowledge and concerns regarding health insurance and the Kenyan National 
Hospital Insurance Fund (NHIF). 
This assessment serves to explore how informal sector workers could be integrated 
into the NHIF. The guiding questions are: 
 Why have informal sector workers joined or not joined the NHIF as voluntary 
members? 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
52 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 53 
 Is there willingness among informal sector workers to join the NHIF through 
group membership? 
These questions are all the more relevant in the light of the proposed National 
Social Health Insurance Act, which aims to expand insurance coverage to the whole 
population. This Act was passed by parliament in December 2004, but has not yet 
been signed by the President and instead has been returned to parliament for further 
deliberations. In this context, the NHIF has begun to introduce various changes to 
increase membership and benefits. 
The paper is structured as follows. The next section outlines the country context of 
Kenya for this study. Section ‘Determinants Affecting Demand’ outlines the 
conceptual framework and hypotheses regarding determinants affecting demand for 
health insurance of informal sector workers. The methodology is described in Section 
‘Methodology’, followed by a presentation and discussion of findings (Section 
‘Findings and Discussion’). The final section offers conclusions and recommendations 
pointing to a way forward (Section ‘Conclusion and Recommendations’). 
COUNTRY CONTEXT 
Fifty-six per cent of the Kenyan population are poor by the World Bank definition, 
namely living on one dollar or less a day per capita (CBS, 2005). According to the 
national health accounts, more than a third of the poor who were ill did not seek care, 
compared with only 15% of the rich. Fifty-two per cent of poor households cited 
financial difficulties as the principal reason for not accessing health care (MoH, 2005a). 
Furthermore, 7.7% of poor householdswere facedwith catastrophic health expenditure, 
i.e. out-of-pocket payments exceeding 40% of disposable household income (Xu et al., 
2006). Expanding access to health care for the informal sector and the poor is therefore 
an important objective of the Kenyan health sector strategy (MoH, 2005b). 
Household survey data show that the large majority of Kenyans (98% of the 
lowest, 96% of the 2nd and 95% of the 3rd quintile) have no health insurance, 
whereas 12% of the 4th and 25% of the highest quintile do have insurance (Xu et al., 
2006). Private health insurance specifically is only accessible to the higher-income 
segment (Vinard and Basaza, 2006, Nderitu in Kimani et al., 2004). Commu-nity- 
based health insurance (CBHI) is not yet far developed in Kenya. Since its 
introduction in 1999, about 32 schemes have been set up so far with about 170 000 
beneficiaries covered, as data from the Kenya Community-Based Health Financing 
Association of 2006 show. 
Under the current law of the 1998 NHIF Act, NHIF membership is mandatory 
for all civil servants and formal sector employees. The formal sector comprises 
those employers registered with the registrar of companies. In 2005, an estimated 
1.5 million primary contributors were enrolled in this population group, thus 
accounting with their dependents for an estimated total of about 5 million Kenyans 
(NHIF, 2005). Monthly contribution rates through payroll deductions range from 120 
Kenyan Shillings (KES) (USD 1.60) for a monthly income of KES 5000–5999 (USD 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
66.67–80.00) to KES 320 (USD 4.27) for an income above KES 15 000 (USD 
200.00) (as of 2006). 
The self-employed and informal sector workers, i.e. all persons who are not formal 
sector employees, can join the scheme on a voluntary basis. They pay a flat-rate 
contribution of KES 160 (USD 2.13) per month for their entire nuclear family. This 
contribution rate corresponds to an income range of KES 7000–8000 (USD 
93.33–106.67) for formal sector workers. The informal sector is very heterogeneous, 
including some better-off income groups with a much higher income than those 
formal sector employees with the corresponding contribution rate of KES 160, but 
also many poor people with an income far below KES 7000 (Kimani et al., 2004). 
The informal sector consists of what can be called semi-formal employees, often 
organized in large regional or national associations, such as taxi, matatu (bus drivers) 
and jua kali1 associations or farmer cooperatives. Domestically employed workers 
(e.g. house helpers, gardeners) form another large segment, as do the ‘self-employed’, 
like farmers, fishermen, pastoralists, hawkers etc. Many of these may not 
be organized in groups or associations based on their occupation, but gather in 
community-based organizations (women’s groups, self-help groups, loan groups, 
religious associations, etc.). 
Whereas contributions from formal sector employees are deducted from the 
monthly payroll, informal sector members had to make upfront annual payments of 
KES 1920 at NHIF area offices, of which there were 23 across the country in 2006. In 
the event of default, the penalty amounted to five times the monthly contribution rate. 
But this practice as well as the upfront payment obligation are now being changed. 
Previously, the contribution covered primarily the costs of bed occupancy (‘bed 
costs’) for inpatient care, whereas the remaining costs had to be borne directly by the 
patient. Since 2004, extension of the benefit package has been underway to cover up 
to 100% of inpatient care, depending on the hospital’s services and the negotiated 
daily rebate. Co-payment rates thus vary across hospitals, which send their claims to 
the NHIF to be reimbursed retrospectively. 
The NHIF’s current strategy aims to increase enrolment of the informal sector 
considerably (NHIF, 2005). So far, however, only 110 000 self-employed/informal 
sector workers have enrolled as NHIF members (ibid). With their dependants, these 
make up an additional half million Kenyans with cover.With a Kenyan population of 
32.7 million and an estimated 6–7 million workers in the growing informal economy 
(Boquier, 2005), there is a large potential for expanding (currently voluntary) 
membership, all the more so in the light of current spending on health. Private health 
care expenditure per capita amounts to KES 56 a month on average, and KES 330 for 
an average family of five, which adds up to around 12% of total household non-food 
expenditure for the poor (CBS, 2005; MoH, 2005a). Hence, the NHIF package for 
KES 160 per family and month would seem likely to attract more than just 110 000 
self-employed/informal sector people. Thus there is need to understand why many 
more informal sector workers have not joined the NHIF as one of the few available 
options of health insurance. 
1Jua kali means ‘‘‘under the hot sun’’’ and is the Swahili term for informal sector workers, as they operate 
in little stalls and workshops as vendors, manufacturers, mechanics, etc. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
54 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 55 
DETERMINANTS AFFECTING DEMAND: CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK 
AND HYPOTHESES 
Analytically, factors that facilitate the extension and scaling-up of health insurance 
can be divided into supply-side and demand-side factors. Whether a household 
demands and is willing to buy insurance depends on the perceived difference 
between the level of expected utility with insurance and expected utility without 
insurance (cf. Kirigia et al., 2005). The perceived difference and expected utility are 
determined by various factors, which can be grouped into the following categories: 
(1) personal/household characteristics; (2) health care market characteristics; (3) 
community characteristics; (4) insurance scheme design features and (5) availability 
of risk management alternatives. These are specified further in Table 1. 
Socio-demographic characteristics and risk aversion are not assessed in this study 
as the chosen methodology does not allow for further insights into these. However, 
the studies available on Africa suggest that households are in general risk averse with 
regard to health care (Arhin-Tenkorang, 2001). Based on a review of literature, 
consideration of the Kenyan context and discussions with resource persons, the 
following key issues relating to demand are considered to be particularly relevant for 
the Kenyan context. 
Knowledge of full health care costs 
The value attached to and demand for health insurance are influenced by knowledge 
of the full costs of health care and experience or knowledge of how and when health 
care costs become ‘catastrophic’. In other words, health insurance would have 
diminishing marginal utility for someone who underestimates the high costs of 
inpatient care and also the likelihood of high-risk events by comparison with 
someone who is fully aware of the high cost of inpatient care and whose demand 
would therefore be higher (Cutler/Zeckhauser 2000 in Osei-Akoto, 2003). 
Availability of quality health care 
Even if the potential benefit of health insurance is seen, there is no utility in insurance 
if informal sector workers have no geographical access to health facilities that are 
accredited by a health insurance. Similarly, the non-availability of quality health care 
services (including lack of drugs and other quality deficits) negatively affects 
demand for health insurance (cf. Carrin, 2003). Thus if informal sector workers 
perceive quality of health care as a problem, health insurance membership will be 
less attractive to them. 
Absence of alternative risk management institutions 
The availability and effectiveness of protection through alternative risk management 
institutions that cater for meeting people’s health care needs and costs would 
decrease demand for health insurance. Informal institutions such as group saving 
mechanisms usually constitute ex-post-risk management strategies that help to 
prevent or reduce catastrophic health expenditure. Yet as Waelkens et al. (2005) 
point out, there are various constraints (institutional, social and financial) that limit 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
Table 1. Determinants affecting demand for health insurance 
Community 
characteristics 
Personal and 
household 
characteristics 
Health care 
characteristics 
Insurance scheme 
design features 
Availability of risk 
management 
alternatives 
Solidarity and 
reciprocity, trust 
among and across 
communities 
Socio-demographic 
aspects, affecting 
risk (perceptions), 
e.g., household size, 
sex, age, health 
status. 
Geographical 
access to health 
care 
Attractive 
contribution rates 
and level of co-payments, 
level of 
penalties 
Waivers and 
exemption 
Social capital Preferences and risk 
aversion 
Quality of services 
and availability of 
drugs 
Attractive benefit 
package 
Community-based 
health insurance 
and similar forms 
Familiarity with 
formal institutions 
Knowledge of costs 
and price sensitivity 
Costs and variability Adequate payment 
modes (frequency, 
timing, place of 
collection, flexibility) 
Solidarity groups to 
cater for high cost 
events 
Notion on 
insurability of health 
(illness is not 
destiny) 
Income and ability to 
pay 
Catastrophic illness 
costs 
Appropriate 
enrolment 
procedures, 
enrolment unit 
Understanding and 
acceptability of 
insurance principles 
Anticipated quality 
through health 
insurance ownership 
Options for 
community 
participation 
Credibility of fund 
managers 
The more pronounced these are, the higher the utility. 
The more attractive 
and customer-oriented 
these are, 
the higher the utility 
The more effective 
these are in 
providing financial 
protection, the lower 
the demand for 
insurance 
(Source: Table constructed from a collection of factors as mentioned byWiesmann and Ju¨tting, 2001; Carrin, 2003; 
Osei-Akoto, 2003). 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
56 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 57 
their effectiveness, more so in a changing world in which the traditional mechanisms 
are less adept.Waivers and exemptions equally serve to provide financial protection. 
However, they have not been particularly effective in Kenya (Bitran and Giedion, 
2003) and there are no clear waiver policy and criteria so far. Given the access 
barriers to health services faced by a large part of the population (see Section 
‘Country Context’), it is questionable to what extent the existing risk management 
institutions provide sufficient support and financial protection. 
According to Ahuja and Ju¨tting (2003), community-based health insurance is 
more aligned to people’s needs than state or private insurance mechanisms. If this is 
the case there may be competition between CBHIs and the NHIF in those areas of 
Kenya where they exist. 
Spirit of solidarity 
In Kenya there is a strong spirit of harambee, a Swahili word meaning ‘let’s pull 
together’. This refers to people sharing and supporting each other within their 
community (Adili, 2003). Like group saving and other solidarity group activities, it is 
based on voluntary reciprocity. Hence, our hypothesis is that the spirit of solidarity in 
Kenya is in principle conducive to the logic of a social health insurance. 
Understanding and acceptance of the insurance rationale 
The literature on community insurance refers to people’s limited understanding and 
acceptance of the insurance rationale. Low-income households may therefore 
initially be reluctant to join insurance schemes because they do not readily like the 
idea of ‘paying’ for services they might not use (Brown and Churchill, 2000). 
Platteau (1997) argues that people join such micro-insurance arrangements based on 
the principle of ‘balanced reciprocity’. This means that members expect a roughly 
equal return from their contribution or payment, rather than being guided by a ‘true 
logic of mutual insurance’ with winners and losers through income redistribution 
between ‘lucky’ and ‘unlucky’ individuals (ibid). On the other hand, according to 
Ju¨tting (2001), if solidarity is strong, people may be less concerned whether the 
benefits of their contributions accrue to themselves or to other community members. 
Credibility of and trust in fund management 
Lack of credibility and trust in fund managers may negatively affect demand for 
health insurance (cf. Wiesmann and Ju¨tting, 2001; Schneider, 2004). In Kenya, 
where corruption in public services and parastatals has been a huge problem, they 
have been often faced with negative attitudes. Hence the NHIF, a parastatal, might 
equally suffer from these perceptions, thus decreasing demand for NHIF 
membership. 
Customer-oriented insurance scheme design features 
Insurance scheme design features, particularly the benefit package, payment modes 
and the enrolment basis (as an individual or family), influence people’s expected 
utility of health insurance (Carrin, 2003; Schneider, 2004). For the Kenyan case, our 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
hypothesis is that for many informal sector workers the relatively high amount of 
upfront payment and (previously) inflexible collection schedules constitute barriers 
to joining the NHIF. 
Ability to pay 
Finally, demand for health insurance is also determined by the ability to pay 
membership contributions. Lack of money is indeed a major reason why many do not 
join (cf. Preker et al., 2002; Ju¨tting, 2004 for Senegal). As expenditure studies show, 
higher-income quintiles are more likely to be covered by an insurance (Carrin et al., 
2005), which is also the case for Kenya (Xu et al., 2006). In Kenya, the non-poor 
spend 2.6% of non-food expenditure on health insurance schemes, while this figure is 
only 0.7% for the poor (CBS, 2000). However, studies of community-based health 
insurance schemes in East Africa also reveal that the majority of members fall below 
the poverty line (Waelkens et al., 2005). Hence in Kenya, even though about 30% of 
the population are extremely poor, it is argued that the ‘better-off’ segments in the 
informal sector are able to make contributions (cf. MoH, 2004). 
In sum, there seems to be a complex mix of factors, some of them suggesting low 
demand, while others anticipate a demand for health insurance. 
METHODOLOGY 
Given the advantages of group membership as the basis for enrolment of informal 
sector workers, foremost among these being reduced adverse selection, the preferred 
data collection method was to encounter organized groups in the informal sector 
through focus group discussions (FGDs). Trained facilitators moderated the FGDs 
with a key questionnaire, a process which lasted about 2 h. Participants’ in-group 
discussions knew relatively little about health insurance and the NHIF. The 
facilitators therefore explained the principles of health insurance in more detail 
during the latter part of the FGDs in order to discuss health insurance notions and 
views of respondents. At the end, facilitators further explained NHIF procedures, 
depending on respondents’ questions. A self-administered questionnaire was 
distributed to and filled in by all heads of the 23 NHIF area offices and six additional 
deputies who were present during one of their management meetings. This made it 
possible to compare the FGD results with the judgment of this senior management 
group, most of whom have been working for the NHIF for several years. 
A total of 19 focus group discussions were undertaken, covering a range of 
different types of informal sector worker groups (see Table 2). The group size was 
mostly around 10–15 participants. Groups were selected based on purposive 
sampling with the help of NHIF area branch officers, whereby the base of the group 
members was supposed to be outside towns in peri-urban or semi-rural settings. One 
group type was to be met per area. Thus groups were met within a radius of 70 km 
from the provincial capitals in four out of seven provinces (Central,Western, Eastern 
and Rift Valley provinces). Only a handful of all respondents encountered were 
NHIF members. 
In a first step, a content analysis of the FGD data identified determinants affecting 
the demand-side, guided by our initial hypotheses. Secondly, these issues were 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
58 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 59 
Table 2. Types of groups encountered and group characteristics 
Group type No. of groups Income activities Sex 
Taxi/conductor associations 2 Transport Men only 
Jua kali association group 1 Manual workers 
(metal, carpentry) 
Mixed 
Farmer groups 3 Farming Mixed 
Loan support groups 4 Jua kali (small-scale 
business) 
Women only (1), 
mixed (3) 
CBD groups 3 CBD, (joint) income 
generating activities 
Women only 
Self-help groups 4 Farming, jua kali Mixed 
Women’s self-help groups 3 Farming, jua kali Women only 
CBD: Community-based distribution of family planning methods (condoms, pills). 
Mainly small shop, stall and hawking activities. 
classified into four degrees of barriers to enrolment: ‘major’, ‘medium’, ‘minor’, ‘not 
at all’, based on the relevance and the level of concern expressed by the discussion 
group members. 
This sample is not representative of all informal sector workers in Kenya. The 
external validity of the findings remains limited to informal sector workers and 
groups that share the following characteristics: 
 They are willing and able to join in and contribute to group/community work; 
 Many of them are poor but still have some monetary income on a more or less 
regular basis; 
 They are well-established and stable groups that are registered and known in the 
community; 
 The informal sector workers are aged between 18 and 50. 
The chosen areas are highly populated with a thriving informal sector and many 
informal sector groups; cash flows in these areas are higher than in the North and 
North-Eastern parts of the country (CBS, 2005). 
Reliability of the results of the focus group discussions is assumed to be high, as 
different facilitator teams found the same patterns (‘investigator triangulation’). 
Likewise, informal interviews with individuals correlated with the FGD information. 
FINDINGS AND DISCUSSION 
The following findings were made concerning determinants affecting demand, as 
guided by our initial hypotheses: 
Availability of quality health care services 
In the areas studied, geographic access to health care services was not a barrier. 
Discussion participants stated that they could reach NHIF accredited hospitals quite 
easily, although transport by taxi could amount to KES 200–500. This situation may 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
change completely in more remote areas of Kenya. However, the quality of services 
provided at government facilities was considered inadequate, especially the 
non-availability of drugs. In one encounter, group members asked critically, ‘If you 
have to pay for drugs in addition to co-payments, what’s the use of being an NHIF 
member?’ 
Knowledge of true inpatient care costs 
Informal sector workers had a good understanding and knowledge of the costs of 
outpatient and inpatient care in public, private and mission facilities and could 
correctly cite costs of typical medical cases. Comparing these with the contribution 
rates for the NHIF, they saw a great difference from a financial perspective between 
expected utility with and without insurance. They wondered how the high costs of 
inpatient care could be covered with the comparatively low contribution rates. 
Absence of effective alternative risk management institutions 
All discussion group members stated that waivers at hospitals were rare and difficult 
to obtain. People stated that they resorted to borrowing or to selling land, property or 
livestock. Several groups had some form of ‘micro-insurance’ mechanism, pooling 
and saving money on a monthly basis. Other ways to pay for high health care 
expenditure once incurred included fundraising within the group or the community, 
church collections, saving groups (like so-called merry-go-rounds) and harambees. 
Membership in Rotating Saving and Credit Associations also caters for catastrophic 
health care expenditure. Some groups had established an emergency account, where 
each member would contribute around 200 KES for an emergency case. 
However, group members stated that they would happily leave these mechanisms 
aside if they had a better and more reliable alternative, as they could easily cite 
examples of catastrophic health care expenditure where they had difficulties in 
finding sufficient funds. The discussions revealed that informal sector workers may 
not feel completely comfortable with these informal risk management practices. 
After learning about the option of joining the NHIF, one respondent said that ‘it 
can assist you without bothering other people’. Another group felt that with health 
insurance, they would ‘not need to do harambee any more’. As confirmed by key 
informants, harambee is obviously not a favoured way of raising funds. This goes 
along with the finding of Cohen et al. (2003) that harambee is not such an effective 
mechanism as it used to be in the past. The wish to be no longer ‘dependent on 
assistance from their social network’ is also reported from Senegal by Ju¨tting (2001). 
This may reflect the current transition that rural societies are undergoing. Finally, it 
was found that community-based health insurance schemes do not usually constitute 
competition for the NHIF, as there are very few of them and they are concentrated in 
certain areas of Kenya. 
In sum, the effectiveness of these risk management alternatives with respect to 
financial protection through pooling appears to be limited. They cannot be 
considered as an alternative or competition to (social) health insurance and hence as a 
barrier to demand for health insurance. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
60 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 61 
Extent of the spirit of solidarity 
Virtually all group respondents were part of a solidarity mechanism as outlined 
above. People start and join groups mainly to help each other and provide assistance, 
as they realize that they will be stronger in tackling individual high-cost events as a 
group. The amount provided to support community members in need of money to 
pay a hospital bill or a funeral may be fixed, or in other instances may depend on the 
overall bill and on the friendship with the person in need. In many instances, the 
assistance amounted to KES 200 for a hospital bill and was much higher for a funeral 
or a wedding. 
The principle of solidarity within the social health insurance mechanism was 
explained, namely the pooling of risks and funds, resulting in redistribution between 
the better-off and poor, the healthy and the sick. Feedback from the groups suggests 
that this principle appears sensible to them and reflects their value system and 
practice in community and group fundraising, despite the limitations experienced, as 
outlined above. The prevailing experience with these risk sharing institutions may 
thus provide a basis for group enrolment. 
In fact, the idea of joining as a group seemed to be more favourably received and 
accepted than joining as an individual. Respondents referred to group advantages, 
such as ‘being stronger as a group’, or to being able to support each other. Yet a few 
individuals said that they would prefer to join as individuals, as they did not want to 
support others unable to raise KES 160 per month. 
Furthermore, the group discussions showed that people had a preference for equity 
in financing. Respondents considered it unfair for somebody with a low income to 
pay KES 160 a month, if this was what people in the formal sector earning KES 8000 
a month would pay. One group suggested that those without employment should pay 
less and those who have some form of salary should pay more, whereas another group 
stated that they preferred a uniform rate. 
Understanding and acceptance of the insurance rationale 
Many discussion participants, especially the younger, the men, as well as the taxi 
driver/matatu group, knew about the principles of insurance, e.g. through car 
insurance. Yet the majority of respondents had not heard of the concept of health 
insurance (‘bima ya afya’) before. After this was explained to them, one of the main 
concerns about health insurance and the NHIF was what happened to their money 
and whether contributors would receive their money back if they had not fallen sick 
over a longer period. The Kenyan Community-Based Health Financing Association 
reports similar views among its members. 
Clearly, respondents’ initial statements reflecting their understanding and notion 
of health insurance membership related to making pre-payments for a benefit to be 
received later, rather than to mutual sharing and spreading of risk through pooling of 
funds. This is because people experience solidarity as voluntary reciprocity and 
because they practice fund sharing through informal/community risk management 
mechanisms after a catastrophic expenditure event has taken place. As such, 
payments are made ex-post and are equal to the transfer received by a person in need 
(cf. Ahuja and Ju¨ tting, 2003). The notion of making ex-ante payments that are 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
uncoupled from benefits in the future is unfamiliar in the field of health, but not 
unknown in other fields such as house and car insurance, where premiums are not 
paid back either if the event insured against does not occur. 
However, the ongoing discussions also showed that people found the concept of 
health insurance acceptable and useful after realizing that one of its core advantages 
was the pooling of risk and funds, rather than merely making pre-payments. 
Credibility and trust in fund management 
There was no hint or expression suggesting a lack of trust or credibility in fund 
management or the NHIF. When prompted, respondents did not see the point in this 
question. We exclude social desirability responses and rather assume that 
respondents had had no reason to develop any mistrust. 
Customer-oriented insurance scheme design features 
A number of design features had deterred or put people off from (re)joining the 
NHIF: upfront annual payments of KES 1920 are difficult to make. Furthermore, in 
the past, the NHIF had demanded high penalties in cases of default, namely five times 
the payment arrears. Former members of the NHIF, like farmers and taxi drivers who 
had had to step out temporarily, would often want to re-enter, but were impeded as 
they could not afford the penalties. 
Group participants voiced their concern about temporary inability to pay, during 
which period they are not covered by the NHIF. Inability to pay might occur 
especially during sickness periods, when coverage is most needed. There was a 
strong preference for smaller and more frequent contributions rather than one upfront 
payment per year. Especially group respondents located far away from the NHIF area 
offices also expressed their preference for closer payment points and more flexible 
collection schedules. 
Ability to pay 
Many groups have a group solidarity mechanism through which they are able to raise 
and collect substantial amounts of money to be used for emergency cases, such as 
inpatient care or funeral costs. In the various cases, this amounts to about KES 
100–120 a month per family. For example, in a slum in Thika town, each member of a 
small group pays KES 120 a month into an account, which caters for inpatient care 
expenditure. The group members reported that this saving and sharing mechanism 
helped them to cover the costs of inpatient care. Hence people seem to be able to 
make significant monthly contributions in a range similar to NHIF premiums. 
Given that the majority of respondents had had no experience with health 
insurance and the NHIF so far, the discussion on people’s ability became mixed with 
statements on their willingness to pay. The amount that people felt could be raised 
was between KES 100–120. Those with a more regular and higher income, such as 
taxi and matatu drivers, and male respondents from jua kali groups and cooperative 
members, appear to be able and willing to pay KES 160. Anecdotal evidence from 
personal talks with taxi drivers in Nairobi revealed that they pay KES 600 for a 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
62 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 63 
private health insurance package offered to informal sector workers. The FGD also 
revealed that even people with an income of KES 2000 a month are still interested in 
the NHIF and willing to pay. 
In addition to the above factors, three other key demand-side determinants were 
revealed that largely explain currently low enrolment rates of informal sector workers. 
Knowledge and awareness of the NHIF 
Men, taxi/matatu drivers and members of well-organized groups and associations, 
closer to the formal sector and closer to provincial towns, usually had more 
knowledge of and experience with the NHIF. Yet most group members had hardly 
ever heard of health insurance and the NHIF.When they had heard of it (by broadcast 
or from other people), many would not know what it actually meant. Those with 
some knowledge usually had positive associations, like ‘support’, ‘assistance’, 
‘coverage for some expenditure’ or ‘coming in when somebody is sick and 
admitted’. On the other hand, some respondents, who were previously NHIF 
members, reported that they had not even known what their payroll deductions and 
their membership card were good for. 
Knowledge of enrolment option for informal sector workers 
The most striking and uniform reaction was that even when informal sector workers 
knew about the NHIF and what it was, most respondents did not know that informal 
sector workers could join as voluntary members for a monthly contribution of KES 
160 covering the whole family. Again, men and taxi/matatu drivers were generally 
somewhat better informed. In virtually every encounter, statements of the kind ‘this 
is only for the rich’, ‘this is only for the employed’, or ‘this is not for us’ were voiced. 
Therefore, as respondents said, they would not pay attention even to radio messages 
about the NHIF, as they would not feel concerned and addressed by them. These 
statements also clearly expressed feelings of exclusion. 
Knowledge of enrolment proceedings 
Another serious obstacle to enrolling with the NHIF was lack of knowledge about 
where and how to enrol. When those who were aware of the NHIF’s offer for 
informal sector workers were asked directly why they had not joined, typical answers 
were, ‘no one ever approached me’, ‘no one ever asked me’ or ‘I did not know how 
and where to register’. The lack of information seeking appears to be linked to the 
feeling of informal sector workers that they are not addressed. 
Hence not only is there an information asymmetry between insurers and their 
potential insured concerning the insurance market, but also such information is 
actually largely lacking among the latter. This lack of knowledge about enrolment 
options among a large group of respondents somewhat conceals the effect of other 
demand factors, as it impedes any explicit assessment of expected utilities. 
The following Table 3 below summarizes the extent to which these determinants 
are major, minor or in no way barriers to demand for health insurance and to joining 
the NHIF. The shaded cells indicate the FGD results, whereas the numbers show the 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
Table 3. Barriers to joining the NHIF 
No 
barrier 
Minor 
barrier 
Medium 
barrier 
Major 
barrier 
1. Availability of quality health care 
8 8 13 
2. Knowledge of true hospital costs 
12 15 2 
3. Absence of risk management 
alternatives 
13 11 2 2 
4. Extent of spirit of solidarity 
5. Understanding and acceptance of 
insurance rationale 
6. Customer-oriented insurance 
scheme design features 
7. Credibility and trust in fund 
management 
6 13 9 1 
8. Ability to pay 
7 7 15 
9. Knowledge and awareness of 
NHIF 
5 8 16 
10. Knowledge of enrolment option 
for informal sector workers 
2 2 13 9 
11. Knowledge of enrolment 
proceedings 
3 7 13 5 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
64 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 65 
responses of NHIF area officers’ judgment.2 Overall, the latter confirm the FGD 
assessment, except that they were more concerned about geographical access to 
quality health services, particularly for people living in remote areas. 
The table reveals that the most critical barrier to NHIF enrolment is the informal 
sector workers’ lack of knowledge of the NHIF and its enrolment option and 
procedures for informal sector workers. They do not feel addressed as a target group, 
even if they hear about NHIF through radio advertisements. For some groups, ability 
to pay is a constraint, but for others it is not. Insurance scheme design features are 
also of great importance, but the results suggest that that the relevance of insurance 
scheme design features has partly been weakened for the majority of respondents 
who lacked knowledge of the enrolment option. 
CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS 
The key finding is that the majority of informal sector workers do not know about 
NHIF and their option to join. It is difficult to assess expected utilities when 
information about insurance is incomplete or lacking. Thus it is crucial that research 
into demand for health insurance is not based on the assumption that people have 
complete information on the insurance market, especially when researching 
preferences or socio-demographic factors. 
Yet after information and explanations were provided, informal sector workers 
were, in principle, interested in health insurance coverage. It was also revealed that 
many of them could raise considerable contribution rates, for some even above the 
informal sector contribution rate of KES 160. Further, discussions showed that they 
were also willing to pay depending on their ability. This is similar to the findings of 
Cohen et al. (2003) that in general people are favourably disposed to the concept of 
health insurance. Yet, several of the insurance design scheme factors are not adapted 
to people’s needs and preferences. 
In sum, the mix of determinants affecting demand for enrolling in the NHIF is not 
as complex as initially expected. This is good news, as the factors identified can be 
addressed with a well-designed social marketing strategy. In response to the above 
areas of concern, such a strategy should combine the following key areas: 
1. Awareness raising and provision of information via different channels and 
methodologies, packaged for different target groups with different information 
and educational levels. 
2. Improvement of insurance scheme design features, such as flexible payment 
schedules, accessible payment points and a revised ‘penalty’ system for those 
wanting to re-join. 
3. Setting affordable and differentiated contribution rates that take account of informal 
sector workers’ varying abilities to pay and of their concern for financial equity. 
The FGD findings also suggest that group enrolment is a viable option for 
extending coverage to the informal sector and that differentiation of contribution 
2The self-administered questionnaires distributed to NHIF area officers did not contain all issues that were 
ultimately revealed in the FGD, which explains the three empty lines. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
could be based on group characteristics, as further outlined in Mathauer and Schmidt, 
2006, similar to initiatives in other countries (Soonman, 2005 for the Philippines). 
Likewise, a demand-oriented strategy to increase enrolment needs to be combined 
with a supply-side approach. Sound revenue and expenditure projections are 
necessary, including estimations under various scenarios of the utilization rates and 
contribution levels of informal sector workers. 
Finally, while a focus on well organized groups and associations and on those able 
to pay for health insurance is crucial at the beginning to demonstrate success and 
impact, it is equally important to target and support specifically poorer informal 
sector workers who may not be able to pay any NHIF contributions. The emphasis on 
a pro-poor approach caters to the mandate of a social health insurance and to the 
national policy of ensuring equitable access to health care. More research into 
targeting subsidies to poor informal sector workers who are unable to pay is needed 
to assess how this can best be achieved. 
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 
The empirical findings presented in this paper were the basis for GTZ’s advisory 
work in the field of extending coverage to informal sector workers. 
We are grateful to all participating NHIF managers and officers for the good 
discussions, their support and organization of informal sector group meetings on the 
ground. Valuable input was provided by Kokonya Achieng and Eireen Nyamongo, 
who facilitated the focus group discussion and contributed to data collection. Lastly, 
without the openness of numerous Kenyan informal sector workers in sharing their 
views and concerns regarding health insurance, this assessment would not have been 
possible. We also thank the anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. 
REFERENCES 
Adili. 2003. Harambee: the spirit of giving or reaping? Issue 37 of June2, 2003 (a news service 
from Transparency International-Kenya). 
Ahuja R, Ju¨tting J. 2003. Design of incentives in community-based health insurance schemes. 
Working paper No. 95, Indian Council for Research on International Economics Relations: 
New Delhi, February 2003. 
Ahuja R, Ju¨tting J. 2004. Are the poor too poor to demand health insurance? J Microfinance 
5(1): 1–20. 
Akazili J, Anto F, Anyorigiya T, et al. 2005. The Perception and Demand for Mutual Health 
Insurance in the Kassana-Nankana District of Northern Ghana. The Ghanaian-Dutch 
Collaboration for Health Research and Development: Accra. 
Arhin DC. 1997. Are people in Ghana wiling to pay for health care? Paper presented at the 
fifteenth annual conference of the German Association of Tropical Paediatricians, Kiel, 
23–25 January 1997. 
Arhin-Tenkorang D. 2001. Health Insurance for the Informal Sector in Africa. Design 
Features, Risk Protection, and Resource Mobilization. NHP Discussion Paper, World 
Bank: Washington. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
66 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 67 
Asenso-Okyere WK, Osei-Akoto I, Anum A, Appiah EN. 1997.Willingness to pay for health 
insurance in a developing economy. A pilot study of the informal sector of Ghana using 
contingent valuation. Health Policy 42(3): 223–237. 
Asfaw A. 2002. Costs of Illness, Health Care Demand Behaviour, and Willingness to Pay for 
Potential Health Insurance Schemes: the Case of Rural Ethiopia. Working Paper, ZEF: 
Bonn. 
Bhat R, Jain N. 2006. Factoring Affecting the Demand for Health Insurance in a Micro 
Insurance Scheme. Working Paper No. 2006-07-02, Indian Institute of Management: 
Ahmedabad. 
Bitran R, Giedion U. 2003. Waivers and Exemptions for Health Services in Developing 
Countries. Social Protection Discussion Paper Series No. 0308, World Bank: Washington. 
Boquier P. 2005. Informal Sector versus Informal Contracts in Nairobi, Kenya. DIALWorking 
Paper, DIAL: Paris. 
Brown W, Churchill CF. 2000. Insurance Provision in Low-income Communities. Part II: 
Initial Lessons from Micro-insurance Experiments for the Poor. Micro-enterprise best 
practices, Development Alternatives Inc.: Bethesda. 
Canagarajah S, Setharaman S. 2001. Social Protection and the Informal Sector in Developing 
Countries: Challenges and Opportunities. World Bank Series, World Bank: Washington. 
Carrin G. 2003. Community-based Health Insurance Schemes in Developing Countries: Facts, 
Problems and Perspectives. Department of Health Financing and Stewardship. WHO/EIP: 
Geneva. 
Carrin G, James C. 2004. Key performance indicators for the implementation of social health 
insurance. Appl Health Econ Health Pol 4(1): 15–22. 
Carrin G, Preker S (eds). 2004. Health Financing for Poor People. Resource Mobilization and 
Risk Sharing. World Bank: Washington. 
Carrin G, Waelkens MP, Criel B. 2005. Community-based health insurance in developing 
countries: A study of its contribution to the performance of health financing systems. Trop 
Med Int Health 10: 799–811. 
CBS. 2000. Second Report on Poverty in Kenya. CBS (Central Bureau of Statistics): Nairobi. 
CBS. 2005. Poverty Map of Kenya. CBS: Nairobi. 
Cohen M, Sebstad J, McCord M. 2003. Reducing Vulnerability: Demand for and Supply of 
Micro-Insurance in East Africa. A Synthesis Report. MicroSave-Africa: Nairobi. 
Dongh H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R. 2003. Willingness-to-pay for 
community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Econ 12(10): 849–862. 
Dror DM. 2006. Health insurance for the poor: myths and realities. Econ Pol Weekly 41(43– 
44): 4541–4543. 
Gottret P, Schieber G (eds). 2006. Health Financing Revisited. A practitioner’s Guidebook. 
World Bank: Washington. 
GTZ, ILO, WHO. 2006a. Berlin recommendations for action, from International Conference 
on Social Health Insurance in Developing Countries, Berlin 5–7 December, 2005. http:// 
www.socialhealthprotection.org/. 
GTZ, ILO, WHO. 2006b http://www.shiconferencemanila.info/. 
ILO. 2001a. Global Campaign on Social Security and Coverage for all. ILO: Geneva. 
ILO. 2001b. Social Security. A New Consensus. ILO: Geneva. 
ILO. 2002. Decent Work and the Informal Economy. Report VI, International Labour 
Conference, 90th Session, ILO: Geneva. 
Ju¨tting J. 2004. Do community-based health insurance schemes improve poor people’s access 
to health care? Evidence from rural Senegal. World Dev 32(2): 273–288. 
Ju¨tting J. 2001. Health insurance for the rural poor? Community financing scheme in Senegal 
to protect against illness. DþC–Development and Cooperation 6: 4–5. 
Kawabeta K, Xu K, Carrin G. 2002. Preventing impoverishment through protection against 
catastrophic health expenditure. Bull World Health Organ 80: 8. 
Kimani DN, Muthaka DI, Manda DK. 2004. Healthcare financing through health insurance in 
Kenya: The shift to a National Social Health Insurance Fund. KIPPRA Discussion Paper 
No. 42, Kenya Institute for Public Policy Research and Analysis: Nairobi, September 2004. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm
Kirigia JM, Sambo LG, Nganda B, Mwabu GM, Chatora R, Mwase T. 2005. Determinants of 
health insurance ownership among South African women. BMC Health Serv Res 5: 17. 
Mathauer I, Schmidt JO. 2006. Informal sector workers’ perceptions on health insurance and 
NHIF: Opportunities for and obstacles to informal sector enrolment. Study report, GTZ and 
NHIF: Nairobi, May 2006. 
Mathiyazhagan K. 1998. Willingness to pay for rural health insurance through community 
participation in India. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 13(1): 47–67. 
Ministry of Health. 2004. Sessional Paper on National Social Health Insurance in Kenya. 
MoH: Nairobi. 
Ministry of Health. 2005a. Kenya National Health Accounts 2001/02. MoH: Nairobi. 
Ministry of Health. 2005b. National Health Sector Strategic Plan 2005–2015. MoH: Nairobi. 
Monheit AC, Primoff Vistness J. 2004. Health Insurance Enrolment Decision: Understanding 
the role of Preferences for Coverage. ERIUWorking Paper No. 31, University of Michigan: 
Michigan. 
NHIF. 2005. National Hospital Insurance Fund Strategic Plan 2006–2011. NHIF: Nairobi. 
Osei-Akoto I. 2003. Demand for voluntary health insurance by the poor in developing 
countries: evidence from rural Ghana, Paper presented at the conference on ‘‘Staying poor: 
Chronic poverty and development policy’’, IDPM, University of Manchester: Manchester, 
7–9 April, 2003. 
Platteau PP. 1997. Mutual insurance as an elusive concept in traditional rural communities. 
J Dev Stud 33(6): 764–796. 
Preker AS, Carrin G, Dror D, Jakab M, Hsiao W, Arhin-Tenkorang D. 2002. Effectiveness of 
community health financing in meeting the cost of illness. Bull World Health Organ 80: 
143–150. 
Schneider P. 2004. Why should the poor insure? Theories of decision-making in the context of 
health insurance. Health Pol Plan 19(6): 349–355. 
Soonman K. 2005. Segmenting the informal sector with a view to adjusting premiums based on 
ability-to-pay in the Philippines. PhilHealth and GTZ: Manila, September 2005. 
Waelkens MP, SoorsW, Criel B. 2005. The role of social health protection in reducing poverty: 
the case of Africa. ESS Paper No. 22, ILO: Geneva. 
WHA. 2005. Sustainable Health Financing, Universal Coverage and Social Health Insurance. 
C 58th World Health Assembly Resolution (W HA58. 33). WHA: Geneva 
Wiesmann D, Ju¨tting J. 2001. Determinants of viable health insurance schemes in rural 
Sub-Saharan Africa. Quart J Int Agric 50(4): 361–378. 
Xaba J, Horn P, Motala S. 2002. The Informal Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa. ILO: Geneva. 
Xu K, James C, Carrin G, Muchiri S. 2006. An empirical model of access to health care, health 
care expenditure and impoverishment in Kenya: Learning from past reforms and lessons for 
the future. Discussion paper No. 3-2006. HSF/WHO: Geneva. 
Vinard P, Basaza R. 2006.E ´ 
valuation des conditions pre´alables au de´veloppement de syste`mes 
assuranciels contre le risque maladie en Afrique de l’Est: Strate´gies d’intervention dans 
le domaine du financement de la sante´ au Kenya, Ouganda et Tanzania. Rapport 
final. Re´publique franc¸aise. Ministe`re des affaires e´trange`res. Direction ge´ne´rale de la 
Coope´ration et du De´veloppement: Paris, March 2006. 
Copyright # 2007 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. 
DOI: 10.1002/hpm 
68 I. MATHAUER ET AL.

More Related Content

What's hot

Health care financing in India
Health care financing in IndiaHealth care financing in India
Health care financing in IndiaSubraham Pany
 
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...HFG Project
 
Health care finance in india
Health care finance in indiaHealth care finance in india
Health care finance in indiavishal soyam
 
Health financing within the overall health system
Health financing within the overall health systemHealth financing within the overall health system
Health financing within the overall health systemHFG Project
 
711201935
711201935711201935
711201935IJRAT
 
Healthcare financing
Healthcare financingHealthcare financing
Healthcare financingmailanoop11
 
An insight of strategies for improving
An insight of strategies for improvingAn insight of strategies for improving
An insight of strategies for improvingWorld-Academic Journal
 
Health care financing
Health care financing Health care financing
Health care financing Pharm Net
 
Incoherent policies pachanee and wibulpolprasert
Incoherent policies  pachanee and wibulpolprasertIncoherent policies  pachanee and wibulpolprasert
Incoherent policies pachanee and wibulpolprasertNithimar Or
 
Healthcare in Emerging Countries
Healthcare in Emerging CountriesHealthcare in Emerging Countries
Healthcare in Emerging CountriesKausik Lahiri
 
Universal health care in the United States
Universal health care in the United StatesUniversal health care in the United States
Universal health care in the United StatesHussain Al-ghawi
 
Alternative forms of health financing
Alternative forms of health financingAlternative forms of health financing
Alternative forms of health financingLyla Latif
 
Approaches of financing health care in kenya
Approaches of  financing  health care in kenyaApproaches of  financing  health care in kenya
Approaches of financing health care in kenyaJoseph Mwania
 
Health Insurance Presentation
Health Insurance PresentationHealth Insurance Presentation
Health Insurance PresentationDEEPAK TIWARI
 
Health Financing Within the Overall Health System
Health Financing Within the Overall Health SystemHealth Financing Within the Overall Health System
Health Financing Within the Overall Health SystemHFG Project
 

What's hot (20)

Public financing of healh in developing countries: a cross-national systemati...
Public financing of healh in developing countries: a cross-national systemati...Public financing of healh in developing countries: a cross-national systemati...
Public financing of healh in developing countries: a cross-national systemati...
 
Health care financing in India
Health care financing in IndiaHealth care financing in India
Health care financing in India
 
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...
Linkages Between the Essential Health Services Package and Government-Sponsor...
 
Health care finance in india
Health care finance in indiaHealth care finance in india
Health care finance in india
 
Health financing within the overall health system
Health financing within the overall health systemHealth financing within the overall health system
Health financing within the overall health system
 
711201935
711201935711201935
711201935
 
Healthcare financing
Healthcare financingHealthcare financing
Healthcare financing
 
An insight of strategies for improving
An insight of strategies for improvingAn insight of strategies for improving
An insight of strategies for improving
 
Health financing in india
Health financing in indiaHealth financing in india
Health financing in india
 
Health care financing
Health care financing Health care financing
Health care financing
 
Incoherent policies pachanee and wibulpolprasert
Incoherent policies  pachanee and wibulpolprasertIncoherent policies  pachanee and wibulpolprasert
Incoherent policies pachanee and wibulpolprasert
 
Healthcare in Emerging Countries
Healthcare in Emerging CountriesHealthcare in Emerging Countries
Healthcare in Emerging Countries
 
Universal health care in the United States
Universal health care in the United StatesUniversal health care in the United States
Universal health care in the United States
 
FINANCING HEALTH
FINANCING HEALTHFINANCING HEALTH
FINANCING HEALTH
 
Alternative forms of health financing
Alternative forms of health financingAlternative forms of health financing
Alternative forms of health financing
 
Approaches of financing health care in kenya
Approaches of  financing  health care in kenyaApproaches of  financing  health care in kenya
Approaches of financing health care in kenya
 
Health Insurance Presentation
Health Insurance PresentationHealth Insurance Presentation
Health Insurance Presentation
 
Health Financing Within the Overall Health System
Health Financing Within the Overall Health SystemHealth Financing Within the Overall Health System
Health Financing Within the Overall Health System
 
Sustaining Health Care Financing Schemes in Ghana
Sustaining Health Care Financing Schemes in GhanaSustaining Health Care Financing Schemes in Ghana
Sustaining Health Care Financing Schemes in Ghana
 
5.social health insurance nrs
5.social health insurance nrs5.social health insurance nrs
5.social health insurance nrs
 

Viewers also liked

Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries Dr Lendy Spires
 
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14Dr Lendy Spires
 
Country case studies KENYA
Country case studies KENYACountry case studies KENYA
Country case studies KENYADr Lendy Spires
 
Policy options for arctic environment governance environmental governance
Policy options for arctic environment governance   environmental governancePolicy options for arctic environment governance   environmental governance
Policy options for arctic environment governance environmental governanceDr Lendy Spires
 
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpoliciesDr Lendy Spires
 
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...Dr Lendy Spires
 
Indigenous peoples and peacebuilding
Indigenous peoples and peacebuildingIndigenous peoples and peacebuilding
Indigenous peoples and peacebuildingDr Lendy Spires
 
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...Dr Lendy Spires
 
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries Dr Lendy Spires
 
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_planDr Lendy Spires
 
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous PeoplesReport of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous PeoplesDr Lendy Spires
 

Viewers also liked (11)

Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
 
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14
Bs dec88.0036.4843.031.003.dec1988.14
 
Country case studies KENYA
Country case studies KENYACountry case studies KENYA
Country case studies KENYA
 
Policy options for arctic environment governance environmental governance
Policy options for arctic environment governance   environmental governancePolicy options for arctic environment governance   environmental governance
Policy options for arctic environment governance environmental governance
 
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies
1818 file monitoringgovernmentpolicies
 
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...
Global governance, indigenous peoples and the right to prior consultation in ...
 
Indigenous peoples and peacebuilding
Indigenous peoples and peacebuildingIndigenous peoples and peacebuilding
Indigenous peoples and peacebuilding
 
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...
KIMBERLEY PROCESS THROUGH AN AFRICAN LENS: Reimagining responsibilities and d...
 
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries Policy options for arctic environment governance   fisheries
Policy options for arctic environment governance fisheries
 
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan
2014 g20 financial_inclusion_action_plan
 
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous PeoplesReport of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples
Report of the Special Rapporteur on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples
 

Similar to Extending social health insurance to the informal sector in kenya

Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...
Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...
Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...Alexander Decker
 
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi ghana
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi   ghanaFinancing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi   ghana
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi ghanaAlexander Decker
 
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...Alexander Decker
 
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...Alexander Decker
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...IJCSEA Journal
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...IJCSEA Journal
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...IJCSEA Journal
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...IJCSEA Journal
 
Social Health Insurance Reexamined
Social Health Insurance ReexaminedSocial Health Insurance Reexamined
Social Health Insurance ReexaminedEyesWideOpen2008
 
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...HFG Project
 
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand Access
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand AccessHealthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand Access
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand AccessCognizant
 
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?EyesWideOpen2008
 
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...David Lambert Tumwesigye
 
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...Indian Institute of Management, Calcutta
 
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...HFG Project
 
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rights
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rightsA new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rights
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rightsLisa Hallgarten
 
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Health
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In HealthTmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Health
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Healthjorismichielsen
 

Similar to Extending social health insurance to the informal sector in kenya (20)

Health financing in ghana
Health financing in ghanaHealth financing in ghana
Health financing in ghana
 
Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...
Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...
Prospects and challenges of implementing a sustainable national health insura...
 
Final Abraka work
Final  Abraka workFinal  Abraka work
Final Abraka work
 
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi ghana
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi   ghanaFinancing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi   ghana
Financing a tertiary level health facility in kumasi ghana
 
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...
A study into the financial sustainability of offinso mutual health insurance ...
 
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...
Socio economic differentials in health care seeking behaviour and out-of-pock...
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
 
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
REALTIME NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE SCHEME (RNHIS): MEANS TO ACHIEVE HEALTH FO...
 
Social Health Insurance Reexamined
Social Health Insurance ReexaminedSocial Health Insurance Reexamined
Social Health Insurance Reexamined
 
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...
Community Health Financing as a Pathway to Universal Health Coverage: Synthes...
 
Health Care Abuse
Health Care AbuseHealth Care Abuse
Health Care Abuse
 
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand Access
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand AccessHealthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand Access
Healthcare Insurance Evolution in India: An Opportunity to Expand Access
 
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?
Health insurance in low-income countries - Where is the evidence that it works?
 
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...
Exploring the Potential Role Of Community Health Insurance Schemes In A Natio...
 
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...
Awareness and willingness to pay for health insurance and it's financial bene...
 
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...
Policy Brief: What Steps Are Countries Taking To Implement Pro-Poor Universal...
 
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rights
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rightsA new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rights
A new health and development paradigm post-2015: grounded in human rights
 
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Health
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In HealthTmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Health
Tmih Michielsen Et Al. (2010) Transformative Social Protection In Health
 

Extending social health insurance to the informal sector in kenya

  • 1. international journal of health planning and management Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. Published online 29 November 2007 in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/hpm.914 Extending social health insurance to the informal sector in Kenya. An assessment of factors affecting demand Inke Mathauer1*, y, Jean-Olivier Schmidt2 and Maurice Wenyaa3 1Department of Health Systems Financing (HSF), World Health Organization, 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland 2GTZ German Technical Cooperation, Eschborn, Germany 3National Hospital Insurance Fund, Kenya SUMMARY This paper contributes to analysing and understanding the demand for (social) health insurance of informal sector workers in Kenya by assessing their perceptions and knowledge of and concerns regarding health insurance and the Kenyan National Hospital Insurance Fund (NHIF). It serves to explore how informal sector workers could be integrated into the NHIF. To collect data, focus group discussions were held with organized groups of informal sector workers of different types across the country, backed up by a self-administered questionnaire completed by heads of NHIF area branch offices. It was found that the most critical barrier to NHIF enrolment is the lack of knowledge of informal sector workers about the NHIF, its enrolment option and procedures for informal sector workers. Inability to pay is a critical factor for some, but people were, in principle, interested in health insurance, and thus willing to pay for it. In sum, the mix of demand-side determinants for enrolling in the NHIF is not as complex as expected. This is good news, as these demand-side determinants can be addressed with a well-designed strategy, focusing on awareness raising and information, improvement of insurance design features and setting differentiated and affordable contribution rates. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. key words: social health insurance; informal sector; health insurance demand; Kenya INTRODUCTION There is growing international consensus on the importance of extending social protection in health to the whole population (ILO, 2001a, 2001b; Carrin and Preker, 2004; WHA, 2005; Gottret and Schieber, 2006) in order to reduce financial barriers * Correspondence to: Dr I. Mathauer, Department of Health Systems Financing (HSF), World Health Organization, 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland. E-mail: mathaueri@who.int yThis article was written when Inke Mathauer was associated with GTZ. She is currently working for the World Health Organization. All views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of GTZ, NHIF or WHO. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
  • 2. to health care services for the needy and to avoid catastrophic health expenditures (Kawabata et al., 2002). The option of social health insurance as a financing mechanism generating additional resources in typically chronically underfinanced health systems is receiving increasing attention (GTZ/ILO/WHO 2006a, Carrin and James, 2004; WHA, 2005), for the informal sector too (GTZ/ILO/WHO, 2006b). However, one of the major challenges to social health insurance in developing countries is integration of the expanding informal sector and inclusion of the poor. Various low-income countries (Ghana, Kenya, Kyrgyz Republic, the Philippines, Tanzania and Viet Nam) and mid-income countries (South Korea, Mexico), which have introduced or are in the process of expanding social health insurance, are being faced with this. The informal sector is characterized by low and non-regular, non-taxed incomes, insecure employment and self-employment without social security (Canagarajah and Setharaman, 2001; cf. ILO, 2002 and Xaba et al., 2002). It is difficult to assess the income of informal sector workers, on the basis of which social security contributions can be deducted. Hence policymakers wishing to introduce or upscale a national social health insurance for the informal sector and to include the poor are faced with a number of questions regarding insurance scheme design with respect to enrolment, revenue collection, risk pooling and purchasing of health services. Another critical task is promoting demand for and acceptability of social health insurance among informal sector workers during the introduction and scaling-up phase. Promotion of demand and acceptability starts froma sound understanding of factors affecting demand among informal sector workers and the poor. However, the literature addressing demand-side factors of health insurance in low-income countries is limited. Econometric studies look at socio-demographic and socio-economic household and individual determinants such as age, sex, income, education and their correlation with health insurance ownership. It is found that persons with higher income and higher education are more likely to have health insurance (Xu et al., 2006 for Kenya, Kirigia et al., 2005 for South Africa, Bhat and Jain, 2006 for India).Yet econometric studies do not state why people have joined an insurance scheme, and especially why peoplewith lower incomes, in whom we are particularly interested, have not joined. Research into people’s preferences (Monheit and Primoff Vistness, 2004 for the USA) emphasizes the need to look beyond demographic and income factors to understand people’s reasoning and decision making. Other studies have tried to assess willingness and ability to pay for health insurance (Asenso-Okyere et al., 1997; Arhin, 1997; Mathiyazhagan, 1998; Asfaw, 2002; Dongh et al., 2003; Osei-Akoto, 2003; Ahuja and Ju¨tting, 2004; Akazili et al., 2005; Dror, 2006). This paper intends to contribute to the understanding of demand for (social) health insurance among informal sector workers in Kenya by assessing their perceptions, knowledge and concerns regarding health insurance and the Kenyan National Hospital Insurance Fund (NHIF). This assessment serves to explore how informal sector workers could be integrated into the NHIF. The guiding questions are: Why have informal sector workers joined or not joined the NHIF as voluntary members? Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 52 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 3. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 53 Is there willingness among informal sector workers to join the NHIF through group membership? These questions are all the more relevant in the light of the proposed National Social Health Insurance Act, which aims to expand insurance coverage to the whole population. This Act was passed by parliament in December 2004, but has not yet been signed by the President and instead has been returned to parliament for further deliberations. In this context, the NHIF has begun to introduce various changes to increase membership and benefits. The paper is structured as follows. The next section outlines the country context of Kenya for this study. Section ‘Determinants Affecting Demand’ outlines the conceptual framework and hypotheses regarding determinants affecting demand for health insurance of informal sector workers. The methodology is described in Section ‘Methodology’, followed by a presentation and discussion of findings (Section ‘Findings and Discussion’). The final section offers conclusions and recommendations pointing to a way forward (Section ‘Conclusion and Recommendations’). COUNTRY CONTEXT Fifty-six per cent of the Kenyan population are poor by the World Bank definition, namely living on one dollar or less a day per capita (CBS, 2005). According to the national health accounts, more than a third of the poor who were ill did not seek care, compared with only 15% of the rich. Fifty-two per cent of poor households cited financial difficulties as the principal reason for not accessing health care (MoH, 2005a). Furthermore, 7.7% of poor householdswere facedwith catastrophic health expenditure, i.e. out-of-pocket payments exceeding 40% of disposable household income (Xu et al., 2006). Expanding access to health care for the informal sector and the poor is therefore an important objective of the Kenyan health sector strategy (MoH, 2005b). Household survey data show that the large majority of Kenyans (98% of the lowest, 96% of the 2nd and 95% of the 3rd quintile) have no health insurance, whereas 12% of the 4th and 25% of the highest quintile do have insurance (Xu et al., 2006). Private health insurance specifically is only accessible to the higher-income segment (Vinard and Basaza, 2006, Nderitu in Kimani et al., 2004). Commu-nity- based health insurance (CBHI) is not yet far developed in Kenya. Since its introduction in 1999, about 32 schemes have been set up so far with about 170 000 beneficiaries covered, as data from the Kenya Community-Based Health Financing Association of 2006 show. Under the current law of the 1998 NHIF Act, NHIF membership is mandatory for all civil servants and formal sector employees. The formal sector comprises those employers registered with the registrar of companies. In 2005, an estimated 1.5 million primary contributors were enrolled in this population group, thus accounting with their dependents for an estimated total of about 5 million Kenyans (NHIF, 2005). Monthly contribution rates through payroll deductions range from 120 Kenyan Shillings (KES) (USD 1.60) for a monthly income of KES 5000–5999 (USD Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 4. 66.67–80.00) to KES 320 (USD 4.27) for an income above KES 15 000 (USD 200.00) (as of 2006). The self-employed and informal sector workers, i.e. all persons who are not formal sector employees, can join the scheme on a voluntary basis. They pay a flat-rate contribution of KES 160 (USD 2.13) per month for their entire nuclear family. This contribution rate corresponds to an income range of KES 7000–8000 (USD 93.33–106.67) for formal sector workers. The informal sector is very heterogeneous, including some better-off income groups with a much higher income than those formal sector employees with the corresponding contribution rate of KES 160, but also many poor people with an income far below KES 7000 (Kimani et al., 2004). The informal sector consists of what can be called semi-formal employees, often organized in large regional or national associations, such as taxi, matatu (bus drivers) and jua kali1 associations or farmer cooperatives. Domestically employed workers (e.g. house helpers, gardeners) form another large segment, as do the ‘self-employed’, like farmers, fishermen, pastoralists, hawkers etc. Many of these may not be organized in groups or associations based on their occupation, but gather in community-based organizations (women’s groups, self-help groups, loan groups, religious associations, etc.). Whereas contributions from formal sector employees are deducted from the monthly payroll, informal sector members had to make upfront annual payments of KES 1920 at NHIF area offices, of which there were 23 across the country in 2006. In the event of default, the penalty amounted to five times the monthly contribution rate. But this practice as well as the upfront payment obligation are now being changed. Previously, the contribution covered primarily the costs of bed occupancy (‘bed costs’) for inpatient care, whereas the remaining costs had to be borne directly by the patient. Since 2004, extension of the benefit package has been underway to cover up to 100% of inpatient care, depending on the hospital’s services and the negotiated daily rebate. Co-payment rates thus vary across hospitals, which send their claims to the NHIF to be reimbursed retrospectively. The NHIF’s current strategy aims to increase enrolment of the informal sector considerably (NHIF, 2005). So far, however, only 110 000 self-employed/informal sector workers have enrolled as NHIF members (ibid). With their dependants, these make up an additional half million Kenyans with cover.With a Kenyan population of 32.7 million and an estimated 6–7 million workers in the growing informal economy (Boquier, 2005), there is a large potential for expanding (currently voluntary) membership, all the more so in the light of current spending on health. Private health care expenditure per capita amounts to KES 56 a month on average, and KES 330 for an average family of five, which adds up to around 12% of total household non-food expenditure for the poor (CBS, 2005; MoH, 2005a). Hence, the NHIF package for KES 160 per family and month would seem likely to attract more than just 110 000 self-employed/informal sector people. Thus there is need to understand why many more informal sector workers have not joined the NHIF as one of the few available options of health insurance. 1Jua kali means ‘‘‘under the hot sun’’’ and is the Swahili term for informal sector workers, as they operate in little stalls and workshops as vendors, manufacturers, mechanics, etc. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 54 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 5. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 55 DETERMINANTS AFFECTING DEMAND: CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK AND HYPOTHESES Analytically, factors that facilitate the extension and scaling-up of health insurance can be divided into supply-side and demand-side factors. Whether a household demands and is willing to buy insurance depends on the perceived difference between the level of expected utility with insurance and expected utility without insurance (cf. Kirigia et al., 2005). The perceived difference and expected utility are determined by various factors, which can be grouped into the following categories: (1) personal/household characteristics; (2) health care market characteristics; (3) community characteristics; (4) insurance scheme design features and (5) availability of risk management alternatives. These are specified further in Table 1. Socio-demographic characteristics and risk aversion are not assessed in this study as the chosen methodology does not allow for further insights into these. However, the studies available on Africa suggest that households are in general risk averse with regard to health care (Arhin-Tenkorang, 2001). Based on a review of literature, consideration of the Kenyan context and discussions with resource persons, the following key issues relating to demand are considered to be particularly relevant for the Kenyan context. Knowledge of full health care costs The value attached to and demand for health insurance are influenced by knowledge of the full costs of health care and experience or knowledge of how and when health care costs become ‘catastrophic’. In other words, health insurance would have diminishing marginal utility for someone who underestimates the high costs of inpatient care and also the likelihood of high-risk events by comparison with someone who is fully aware of the high cost of inpatient care and whose demand would therefore be higher (Cutler/Zeckhauser 2000 in Osei-Akoto, 2003). Availability of quality health care Even if the potential benefit of health insurance is seen, there is no utility in insurance if informal sector workers have no geographical access to health facilities that are accredited by a health insurance. Similarly, the non-availability of quality health care services (including lack of drugs and other quality deficits) negatively affects demand for health insurance (cf. Carrin, 2003). Thus if informal sector workers perceive quality of health care as a problem, health insurance membership will be less attractive to them. Absence of alternative risk management institutions The availability and effectiveness of protection through alternative risk management institutions that cater for meeting people’s health care needs and costs would decrease demand for health insurance. Informal institutions such as group saving mechanisms usually constitute ex-post-risk management strategies that help to prevent or reduce catastrophic health expenditure. Yet as Waelkens et al. (2005) point out, there are various constraints (institutional, social and financial) that limit Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 6. Table 1. Determinants affecting demand for health insurance Community characteristics Personal and household characteristics Health care characteristics Insurance scheme design features Availability of risk management alternatives Solidarity and reciprocity, trust among and across communities Socio-demographic aspects, affecting risk (perceptions), e.g., household size, sex, age, health status. Geographical access to health care Attractive contribution rates and level of co-payments, level of penalties Waivers and exemption Social capital Preferences and risk aversion Quality of services and availability of drugs Attractive benefit package Community-based health insurance and similar forms Familiarity with formal institutions Knowledge of costs and price sensitivity Costs and variability Adequate payment modes (frequency, timing, place of collection, flexibility) Solidarity groups to cater for high cost events Notion on insurability of health (illness is not destiny) Income and ability to pay Catastrophic illness costs Appropriate enrolment procedures, enrolment unit Understanding and acceptability of insurance principles Anticipated quality through health insurance ownership Options for community participation Credibility of fund managers The more pronounced these are, the higher the utility. The more attractive and customer-oriented these are, the higher the utility The more effective these are in providing financial protection, the lower the demand for insurance (Source: Table constructed from a collection of factors as mentioned byWiesmann and Ju¨tting, 2001; Carrin, 2003; Osei-Akoto, 2003). Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 56 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 7. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 57 their effectiveness, more so in a changing world in which the traditional mechanisms are less adept.Waivers and exemptions equally serve to provide financial protection. However, they have not been particularly effective in Kenya (Bitran and Giedion, 2003) and there are no clear waiver policy and criteria so far. Given the access barriers to health services faced by a large part of the population (see Section ‘Country Context’), it is questionable to what extent the existing risk management institutions provide sufficient support and financial protection. According to Ahuja and Ju¨tting (2003), community-based health insurance is more aligned to people’s needs than state or private insurance mechanisms. If this is the case there may be competition between CBHIs and the NHIF in those areas of Kenya where they exist. Spirit of solidarity In Kenya there is a strong spirit of harambee, a Swahili word meaning ‘let’s pull together’. This refers to people sharing and supporting each other within their community (Adili, 2003). Like group saving and other solidarity group activities, it is based on voluntary reciprocity. Hence, our hypothesis is that the spirit of solidarity in Kenya is in principle conducive to the logic of a social health insurance. Understanding and acceptance of the insurance rationale The literature on community insurance refers to people’s limited understanding and acceptance of the insurance rationale. Low-income households may therefore initially be reluctant to join insurance schemes because they do not readily like the idea of ‘paying’ for services they might not use (Brown and Churchill, 2000). Platteau (1997) argues that people join such micro-insurance arrangements based on the principle of ‘balanced reciprocity’. This means that members expect a roughly equal return from their contribution or payment, rather than being guided by a ‘true logic of mutual insurance’ with winners and losers through income redistribution between ‘lucky’ and ‘unlucky’ individuals (ibid). On the other hand, according to Ju¨tting (2001), if solidarity is strong, people may be less concerned whether the benefits of their contributions accrue to themselves or to other community members. Credibility of and trust in fund management Lack of credibility and trust in fund managers may negatively affect demand for health insurance (cf. Wiesmann and Ju¨tting, 2001; Schneider, 2004). In Kenya, where corruption in public services and parastatals has been a huge problem, they have been often faced with negative attitudes. Hence the NHIF, a parastatal, might equally suffer from these perceptions, thus decreasing demand for NHIF membership. Customer-oriented insurance scheme design features Insurance scheme design features, particularly the benefit package, payment modes and the enrolment basis (as an individual or family), influence people’s expected utility of health insurance (Carrin, 2003; Schneider, 2004). For the Kenyan case, our Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 8. hypothesis is that for many informal sector workers the relatively high amount of upfront payment and (previously) inflexible collection schedules constitute barriers to joining the NHIF. Ability to pay Finally, demand for health insurance is also determined by the ability to pay membership contributions. Lack of money is indeed a major reason why many do not join (cf. Preker et al., 2002; Ju¨tting, 2004 for Senegal). As expenditure studies show, higher-income quintiles are more likely to be covered by an insurance (Carrin et al., 2005), which is also the case for Kenya (Xu et al., 2006). In Kenya, the non-poor spend 2.6% of non-food expenditure on health insurance schemes, while this figure is only 0.7% for the poor (CBS, 2000). However, studies of community-based health insurance schemes in East Africa also reveal that the majority of members fall below the poverty line (Waelkens et al., 2005). Hence in Kenya, even though about 30% of the population are extremely poor, it is argued that the ‘better-off’ segments in the informal sector are able to make contributions (cf. MoH, 2004). In sum, there seems to be a complex mix of factors, some of them suggesting low demand, while others anticipate a demand for health insurance. METHODOLOGY Given the advantages of group membership as the basis for enrolment of informal sector workers, foremost among these being reduced adverse selection, the preferred data collection method was to encounter organized groups in the informal sector through focus group discussions (FGDs). Trained facilitators moderated the FGDs with a key questionnaire, a process which lasted about 2 h. Participants’ in-group discussions knew relatively little about health insurance and the NHIF. The facilitators therefore explained the principles of health insurance in more detail during the latter part of the FGDs in order to discuss health insurance notions and views of respondents. At the end, facilitators further explained NHIF procedures, depending on respondents’ questions. A self-administered questionnaire was distributed to and filled in by all heads of the 23 NHIF area offices and six additional deputies who were present during one of their management meetings. This made it possible to compare the FGD results with the judgment of this senior management group, most of whom have been working for the NHIF for several years. A total of 19 focus group discussions were undertaken, covering a range of different types of informal sector worker groups (see Table 2). The group size was mostly around 10–15 participants. Groups were selected based on purposive sampling with the help of NHIF area branch officers, whereby the base of the group members was supposed to be outside towns in peri-urban or semi-rural settings. One group type was to be met per area. Thus groups were met within a radius of 70 km from the provincial capitals in four out of seven provinces (Central,Western, Eastern and Rift Valley provinces). Only a handful of all respondents encountered were NHIF members. In a first step, a content analysis of the FGD data identified determinants affecting the demand-side, guided by our initial hypotheses. Secondly, these issues were Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 58 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 9. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 59 Table 2. Types of groups encountered and group characteristics Group type No. of groups Income activities Sex Taxi/conductor associations 2 Transport Men only Jua kali association group 1 Manual workers (metal, carpentry) Mixed Farmer groups 3 Farming Mixed Loan support groups 4 Jua kali (small-scale business) Women only (1), mixed (3) CBD groups 3 CBD, (joint) income generating activities Women only Self-help groups 4 Farming, jua kali Mixed Women’s self-help groups 3 Farming, jua kali Women only CBD: Community-based distribution of family planning methods (condoms, pills). Mainly small shop, stall and hawking activities. classified into four degrees of barriers to enrolment: ‘major’, ‘medium’, ‘minor’, ‘not at all’, based on the relevance and the level of concern expressed by the discussion group members. This sample is not representative of all informal sector workers in Kenya. The external validity of the findings remains limited to informal sector workers and groups that share the following characteristics: They are willing and able to join in and contribute to group/community work; Many of them are poor but still have some monetary income on a more or less regular basis; They are well-established and stable groups that are registered and known in the community; The informal sector workers are aged between 18 and 50. The chosen areas are highly populated with a thriving informal sector and many informal sector groups; cash flows in these areas are higher than in the North and North-Eastern parts of the country (CBS, 2005). Reliability of the results of the focus group discussions is assumed to be high, as different facilitator teams found the same patterns (‘investigator triangulation’). Likewise, informal interviews with individuals correlated with the FGD information. FINDINGS AND DISCUSSION The following findings were made concerning determinants affecting demand, as guided by our initial hypotheses: Availability of quality health care services In the areas studied, geographic access to health care services was not a barrier. Discussion participants stated that they could reach NHIF accredited hospitals quite easily, although transport by taxi could amount to KES 200–500. This situation may Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 10. change completely in more remote areas of Kenya. However, the quality of services provided at government facilities was considered inadequate, especially the non-availability of drugs. In one encounter, group members asked critically, ‘If you have to pay for drugs in addition to co-payments, what’s the use of being an NHIF member?’ Knowledge of true inpatient care costs Informal sector workers had a good understanding and knowledge of the costs of outpatient and inpatient care in public, private and mission facilities and could correctly cite costs of typical medical cases. Comparing these with the contribution rates for the NHIF, they saw a great difference from a financial perspective between expected utility with and without insurance. They wondered how the high costs of inpatient care could be covered with the comparatively low contribution rates. Absence of effective alternative risk management institutions All discussion group members stated that waivers at hospitals were rare and difficult to obtain. People stated that they resorted to borrowing or to selling land, property or livestock. Several groups had some form of ‘micro-insurance’ mechanism, pooling and saving money on a monthly basis. Other ways to pay for high health care expenditure once incurred included fundraising within the group or the community, church collections, saving groups (like so-called merry-go-rounds) and harambees. Membership in Rotating Saving and Credit Associations also caters for catastrophic health care expenditure. Some groups had established an emergency account, where each member would contribute around 200 KES for an emergency case. However, group members stated that they would happily leave these mechanisms aside if they had a better and more reliable alternative, as they could easily cite examples of catastrophic health care expenditure where they had difficulties in finding sufficient funds. The discussions revealed that informal sector workers may not feel completely comfortable with these informal risk management practices. After learning about the option of joining the NHIF, one respondent said that ‘it can assist you without bothering other people’. Another group felt that with health insurance, they would ‘not need to do harambee any more’. As confirmed by key informants, harambee is obviously not a favoured way of raising funds. This goes along with the finding of Cohen et al. (2003) that harambee is not such an effective mechanism as it used to be in the past. The wish to be no longer ‘dependent on assistance from their social network’ is also reported from Senegal by Ju¨tting (2001). This may reflect the current transition that rural societies are undergoing. Finally, it was found that community-based health insurance schemes do not usually constitute competition for the NHIF, as there are very few of them and they are concentrated in certain areas of Kenya. In sum, the effectiveness of these risk management alternatives with respect to financial protection through pooling appears to be limited. They cannot be considered as an alternative or competition to (social) health insurance and hence as a barrier to demand for health insurance. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 60 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 11. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 61 Extent of the spirit of solidarity Virtually all group respondents were part of a solidarity mechanism as outlined above. People start and join groups mainly to help each other and provide assistance, as they realize that they will be stronger in tackling individual high-cost events as a group. The amount provided to support community members in need of money to pay a hospital bill or a funeral may be fixed, or in other instances may depend on the overall bill and on the friendship with the person in need. In many instances, the assistance amounted to KES 200 for a hospital bill and was much higher for a funeral or a wedding. The principle of solidarity within the social health insurance mechanism was explained, namely the pooling of risks and funds, resulting in redistribution between the better-off and poor, the healthy and the sick. Feedback from the groups suggests that this principle appears sensible to them and reflects their value system and practice in community and group fundraising, despite the limitations experienced, as outlined above. The prevailing experience with these risk sharing institutions may thus provide a basis for group enrolment. In fact, the idea of joining as a group seemed to be more favourably received and accepted than joining as an individual. Respondents referred to group advantages, such as ‘being stronger as a group’, or to being able to support each other. Yet a few individuals said that they would prefer to join as individuals, as they did not want to support others unable to raise KES 160 per month. Furthermore, the group discussions showed that people had a preference for equity in financing. Respondents considered it unfair for somebody with a low income to pay KES 160 a month, if this was what people in the formal sector earning KES 8000 a month would pay. One group suggested that those without employment should pay less and those who have some form of salary should pay more, whereas another group stated that they preferred a uniform rate. Understanding and acceptance of the insurance rationale Many discussion participants, especially the younger, the men, as well as the taxi driver/matatu group, knew about the principles of insurance, e.g. through car insurance. Yet the majority of respondents had not heard of the concept of health insurance (‘bima ya afya’) before. After this was explained to them, one of the main concerns about health insurance and the NHIF was what happened to their money and whether contributors would receive their money back if they had not fallen sick over a longer period. The Kenyan Community-Based Health Financing Association reports similar views among its members. Clearly, respondents’ initial statements reflecting their understanding and notion of health insurance membership related to making pre-payments for a benefit to be received later, rather than to mutual sharing and spreading of risk through pooling of funds. This is because people experience solidarity as voluntary reciprocity and because they practice fund sharing through informal/community risk management mechanisms after a catastrophic expenditure event has taken place. As such, payments are made ex-post and are equal to the transfer received by a person in need (cf. Ahuja and Ju¨ tting, 2003). The notion of making ex-ante payments that are Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 12. uncoupled from benefits in the future is unfamiliar in the field of health, but not unknown in other fields such as house and car insurance, where premiums are not paid back either if the event insured against does not occur. However, the ongoing discussions also showed that people found the concept of health insurance acceptable and useful after realizing that one of its core advantages was the pooling of risk and funds, rather than merely making pre-payments. Credibility and trust in fund management There was no hint or expression suggesting a lack of trust or credibility in fund management or the NHIF. When prompted, respondents did not see the point in this question. We exclude social desirability responses and rather assume that respondents had had no reason to develop any mistrust. Customer-oriented insurance scheme design features A number of design features had deterred or put people off from (re)joining the NHIF: upfront annual payments of KES 1920 are difficult to make. Furthermore, in the past, the NHIF had demanded high penalties in cases of default, namely five times the payment arrears. Former members of the NHIF, like farmers and taxi drivers who had had to step out temporarily, would often want to re-enter, but were impeded as they could not afford the penalties. Group participants voiced their concern about temporary inability to pay, during which period they are not covered by the NHIF. Inability to pay might occur especially during sickness periods, when coverage is most needed. There was a strong preference for smaller and more frequent contributions rather than one upfront payment per year. Especially group respondents located far away from the NHIF area offices also expressed their preference for closer payment points and more flexible collection schedules. Ability to pay Many groups have a group solidarity mechanism through which they are able to raise and collect substantial amounts of money to be used for emergency cases, such as inpatient care or funeral costs. In the various cases, this amounts to about KES 100–120 a month per family. For example, in a slum in Thika town, each member of a small group pays KES 120 a month into an account, which caters for inpatient care expenditure. The group members reported that this saving and sharing mechanism helped them to cover the costs of inpatient care. Hence people seem to be able to make significant monthly contributions in a range similar to NHIF premiums. Given that the majority of respondents had had no experience with health insurance and the NHIF so far, the discussion on people’s ability became mixed with statements on their willingness to pay. The amount that people felt could be raised was between KES 100–120. Those with a more regular and higher income, such as taxi and matatu drivers, and male respondents from jua kali groups and cooperative members, appear to be able and willing to pay KES 160. Anecdotal evidence from personal talks with taxi drivers in Nairobi revealed that they pay KES 600 for a Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 62 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 13. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 63 private health insurance package offered to informal sector workers. The FGD also revealed that even people with an income of KES 2000 a month are still interested in the NHIF and willing to pay. In addition to the above factors, three other key demand-side determinants were revealed that largely explain currently low enrolment rates of informal sector workers. Knowledge and awareness of the NHIF Men, taxi/matatu drivers and members of well-organized groups and associations, closer to the formal sector and closer to provincial towns, usually had more knowledge of and experience with the NHIF. Yet most group members had hardly ever heard of health insurance and the NHIF.When they had heard of it (by broadcast or from other people), many would not know what it actually meant. Those with some knowledge usually had positive associations, like ‘support’, ‘assistance’, ‘coverage for some expenditure’ or ‘coming in when somebody is sick and admitted’. On the other hand, some respondents, who were previously NHIF members, reported that they had not even known what their payroll deductions and their membership card were good for. Knowledge of enrolment option for informal sector workers The most striking and uniform reaction was that even when informal sector workers knew about the NHIF and what it was, most respondents did not know that informal sector workers could join as voluntary members for a monthly contribution of KES 160 covering the whole family. Again, men and taxi/matatu drivers were generally somewhat better informed. In virtually every encounter, statements of the kind ‘this is only for the rich’, ‘this is only for the employed’, or ‘this is not for us’ were voiced. Therefore, as respondents said, they would not pay attention even to radio messages about the NHIF, as they would not feel concerned and addressed by them. These statements also clearly expressed feelings of exclusion. Knowledge of enrolment proceedings Another serious obstacle to enrolling with the NHIF was lack of knowledge about where and how to enrol. When those who were aware of the NHIF’s offer for informal sector workers were asked directly why they had not joined, typical answers were, ‘no one ever approached me’, ‘no one ever asked me’ or ‘I did not know how and where to register’. The lack of information seeking appears to be linked to the feeling of informal sector workers that they are not addressed. Hence not only is there an information asymmetry between insurers and their potential insured concerning the insurance market, but also such information is actually largely lacking among the latter. This lack of knowledge about enrolment options among a large group of respondents somewhat conceals the effect of other demand factors, as it impedes any explicit assessment of expected utilities. The following Table 3 below summarizes the extent to which these determinants are major, minor or in no way barriers to demand for health insurance and to joining the NHIF. The shaded cells indicate the FGD results, whereas the numbers show the Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 14. Table 3. Barriers to joining the NHIF No barrier Minor barrier Medium barrier Major barrier 1. Availability of quality health care 8 8 13 2. Knowledge of true hospital costs 12 15 2 3. Absence of risk management alternatives 13 11 2 2 4. Extent of spirit of solidarity 5. Understanding and acceptance of insurance rationale 6. Customer-oriented insurance scheme design features 7. Credibility and trust in fund management 6 13 9 1 8. Ability to pay 7 7 15 9. Knowledge and awareness of NHIF 5 8 16 10. Knowledge of enrolment option for informal sector workers 2 2 13 9 11. Knowledge of enrolment proceedings 3 7 13 5 Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 64 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 15. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 65 responses of NHIF area officers’ judgment.2 Overall, the latter confirm the FGD assessment, except that they were more concerned about geographical access to quality health services, particularly for people living in remote areas. The table reveals that the most critical barrier to NHIF enrolment is the informal sector workers’ lack of knowledge of the NHIF and its enrolment option and procedures for informal sector workers. They do not feel addressed as a target group, even if they hear about NHIF through radio advertisements. For some groups, ability to pay is a constraint, but for others it is not. Insurance scheme design features are also of great importance, but the results suggest that that the relevance of insurance scheme design features has partly been weakened for the majority of respondents who lacked knowledge of the enrolment option. CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS The key finding is that the majority of informal sector workers do not know about NHIF and their option to join. It is difficult to assess expected utilities when information about insurance is incomplete or lacking. Thus it is crucial that research into demand for health insurance is not based on the assumption that people have complete information on the insurance market, especially when researching preferences or socio-demographic factors. Yet after information and explanations were provided, informal sector workers were, in principle, interested in health insurance coverage. It was also revealed that many of them could raise considerable contribution rates, for some even above the informal sector contribution rate of KES 160. Further, discussions showed that they were also willing to pay depending on their ability. This is similar to the findings of Cohen et al. (2003) that in general people are favourably disposed to the concept of health insurance. Yet, several of the insurance design scheme factors are not adapted to people’s needs and preferences. In sum, the mix of determinants affecting demand for enrolling in the NHIF is not as complex as initially expected. This is good news, as the factors identified can be addressed with a well-designed social marketing strategy. In response to the above areas of concern, such a strategy should combine the following key areas: 1. Awareness raising and provision of information via different channels and methodologies, packaged for different target groups with different information and educational levels. 2. Improvement of insurance scheme design features, such as flexible payment schedules, accessible payment points and a revised ‘penalty’ system for those wanting to re-join. 3. Setting affordable and differentiated contribution rates that take account of informal sector workers’ varying abilities to pay and of their concern for financial equity. The FGD findings also suggest that group enrolment is a viable option for extending coverage to the informal sector and that differentiation of contribution 2The self-administered questionnaires distributed to NHIF area officers did not contain all issues that were ultimately revealed in the FGD, which explains the three empty lines. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 16. could be based on group characteristics, as further outlined in Mathauer and Schmidt, 2006, similar to initiatives in other countries (Soonman, 2005 for the Philippines). Likewise, a demand-oriented strategy to increase enrolment needs to be combined with a supply-side approach. Sound revenue and expenditure projections are necessary, including estimations under various scenarios of the utilization rates and contribution levels of informal sector workers. Finally, while a focus on well organized groups and associations and on those able to pay for health insurance is crucial at the beginning to demonstrate success and impact, it is equally important to target and support specifically poorer informal sector workers who may not be able to pay any NHIF contributions. The emphasis on a pro-poor approach caters to the mandate of a social health insurance and to the national policy of ensuring equitable access to health care. More research into targeting subsidies to poor informal sector workers who are unable to pay is needed to assess how this can best be achieved. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The empirical findings presented in this paper were the basis for GTZ’s advisory work in the field of extending coverage to informal sector workers. We are grateful to all participating NHIF managers and officers for the good discussions, their support and organization of informal sector group meetings on the ground. Valuable input was provided by Kokonya Achieng and Eireen Nyamongo, who facilitated the focus group discussion and contributed to data collection. Lastly, without the openness of numerous Kenyan informal sector workers in sharing their views and concerns regarding health insurance, this assessment would not have been possible. We also thank the anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. REFERENCES Adili. 2003. Harambee: the spirit of giving or reaping? Issue 37 of June2, 2003 (a news service from Transparency International-Kenya). Ahuja R, Ju¨tting J. 2003. Design of incentives in community-based health insurance schemes. Working paper No. 95, Indian Council for Research on International Economics Relations: New Delhi, February 2003. Ahuja R, Ju¨tting J. 2004. Are the poor too poor to demand health insurance? J Microfinance 5(1): 1–20. Akazili J, Anto F, Anyorigiya T, et al. 2005. The Perception and Demand for Mutual Health Insurance in the Kassana-Nankana District of Northern Ghana. The Ghanaian-Dutch Collaboration for Health Research and Development: Accra. Arhin DC. 1997. Are people in Ghana wiling to pay for health care? Paper presented at the fifteenth annual conference of the German Association of Tropical Paediatricians, Kiel, 23–25 January 1997. Arhin-Tenkorang D. 2001. Health Insurance for the Informal Sector in Africa. Design Features, Risk Protection, and Resource Mobilization. NHP Discussion Paper, World Bank: Washington. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 66 I. MATHAUER ET AL.
  • 17. EXTENDING SHI TO THE INFORMAL SECTOR 67 Asenso-Okyere WK, Osei-Akoto I, Anum A, Appiah EN. 1997.Willingness to pay for health insurance in a developing economy. A pilot study of the informal sector of Ghana using contingent valuation. Health Policy 42(3): 223–237. Asfaw A. 2002. Costs of Illness, Health Care Demand Behaviour, and Willingness to Pay for Potential Health Insurance Schemes: the Case of Rural Ethiopia. Working Paper, ZEF: Bonn. Bhat R, Jain N. 2006. Factoring Affecting the Demand for Health Insurance in a Micro Insurance Scheme. Working Paper No. 2006-07-02, Indian Institute of Management: Ahmedabad. Bitran R, Giedion U. 2003. Waivers and Exemptions for Health Services in Developing Countries. Social Protection Discussion Paper Series No. 0308, World Bank: Washington. Boquier P. 2005. Informal Sector versus Informal Contracts in Nairobi, Kenya. DIALWorking Paper, DIAL: Paris. Brown W, Churchill CF. 2000. Insurance Provision in Low-income Communities. Part II: Initial Lessons from Micro-insurance Experiments for the Poor. Micro-enterprise best practices, Development Alternatives Inc.: Bethesda. Canagarajah S, Setharaman S. 2001. Social Protection and the Informal Sector in Developing Countries: Challenges and Opportunities. World Bank Series, World Bank: Washington. Carrin G. 2003. Community-based Health Insurance Schemes in Developing Countries: Facts, Problems and Perspectives. Department of Health Financing and Stewardship. WHO/EIP: Geneva. Carrin G, James C. 2004. Key performance indicators for the implementation of social health insurance. Appl Health Econ Health Pol 4(1): 15–22. Carrin G, Preker S (eds). 2004. Health Financing for Poor People. Resource Mobilization and Risk Sharing. World Bank: Washington. Carrin G, Waelkens MP, Criel B. 2005. Community-based health insurance in developing countries: A study of its contribution to the performance of health financing systems. Trop Med Int Health 10: 799–811. CBS. 2000. Second Report on Poverty in Kenya. CBS (Central Bureau of Statistics): Nairobi. CBS. 2005. Poverty Map of Kenya. CBS: Nairobi. Cohen M, Sebstad J, McCord M. 2003. Reducing Vulnerability: Demand for and Supply of Micro-Insurance in East Africa. A Synthesis Report. MicroSave-Africa: Nairobi. Dongh H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R. 2003. Willingness-to-pay for community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Econ 12(10): 849–862. Dror DM. 2006. Health insurance for the poor: myths and realities. Econ Pol Weekly 41(43– 44): 4541–4543. Gottret P, Schieber G (eds). 2006. Health Financing Revisited. A practitioner’s Guidebook. World Bank: Washington. GTZ, ILO, WHO. 2006a. Berlin recommendations for action, from International Conference on Social Health Insurance in Developing Countries, Berlin 5–7 December, 2005. http:// www.socialhealthprotection.org/. GTZ, ILO, WHO. 2006b http://www.shiconferencemanila.info/. ILO. 2001a. Global Campaign on Social Security and Coverage for all. ILO: Geneva. ILO. 2001b. Social Security. A New Consensus. ILO: Geneva. ILO. 2002. Decent Work and the Informal Economy. Report VI, International Labour Conference, 90th Session, ILO: Geneva. Ju¨tting J. 2004. Do community-based health insurance schemes improve poor people’s access to health care? Evidence from rural Senegal. World Dev 32(2): 273–288. Ju¨tting J. 2001. Health insurance for the rural poor? Community financing scheme in Senegal to protect against illness. DþC–Development and Cooperation 6: 4–5. Kawabeta K, Xu K, Carrin G. 2002. Preventing impoverishment through protection against catastrophic health expenditure. Bull World Health Organ 80: 8. Kimani DN, Muthaka DI, Manda DK. 2004. Healthcare financing through health insurance in Kenya: The shift to a National Social Health Insurance Fund. KIPPRA Discussion Paper No. 42, Kenya Institute for Public Policy Research and Analysis: Nairobi, September 2004. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm
  • 18. Kirigia JM, Sambo LG, Nganda B, Mwabu GM, Chatora R, Mwase T. 2005. Determinants of health insurance ownership among South African women. BMC Health Serv Res 5: 17. Mathauer I, Schmidt JO. 2006. Informal sector workers’ perceptions on health insurance and NHIF: Opportunities for and obstacles to informal sector enrolment. Study report, GTZ and NHIF: Nairobi, May 2006. Mathiyazhagan K. 1998. Willingness to pay for rural health insurance through community participation in India. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 13(1): 47–67. Ministry of Health. 2004. Sessional Paper on National Social Health Insurance in Kenya. MoH: Nairobi. Ministry of Health. 2005a. Kenya National Health Accounts 2001/02. MoH: Nairobi. Ministry of Health. 2005b. National Health Sector Strategic Plan 2005–2015. MoH: Nairobi. Monheit AC, Primoff Vistness J. 2004. Health Insurance Enrolment Decision: Understanding the role of Preferences for Coverage. ERIUWorking Paper No. 31, University of Michigan: Michigan. NHIF. 2005. National Hospital Insurance Fund Strategic Plan 2006–2011. NHIF: Nairobi. Osei-Akoto I. 2003. Demand for voluntary health insurance by the poor in developing countries: evidence from rural Ghana, Paper presented at the conference on ‘‘Staying poor: Chronic poverty and development policy’’, IDPM, University of Manchester: Manchester, 7–9 April, 2003. Platteau PP. 1997. Mutual insurance as an elusive concept in traditional rural communities. J Dev Stud 33(6): 764–796. Preker AS, Carrin G, Dror D, Jakab M, Hsiao W, Arhin-Tenkorang D. 2002. Effectiveness of community health financing in meeting the cost of illness. Bull World Health Organ 80: 143–150. Schneider P. 2004. Why should the poor insure? Theories of decision-making in the context of health insurance. Health Pol Plan 19(6): 349–355. Soonman K. 2005. Segmenting the informal sector with a view to adjusting premiums based on ability-to-pay in the Philippines. PhilHealth and GTZ: Manila, September 2005. Waelkens MP, SoorsW, Criel B. 2005. The role of social health protection in reducing poverty: the case of Africa. ESS Paper No. 22, ILO: Geneva. WHA. 2005. Sustainable Health Financing, Universal Coverage and Social Health Insurance. C 58th World Health Assembly Resolution (W HA58. 33). WHA: Geneva Wiesmann D, Ju¨tting J. 2001. Determinants of viable health insurance schemes in rural Sub-Saharan Africa. Quart J Int Agric 50(4): 361–378. Xaba J, Horn P, Motala S. 2002. The Informal Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa. ILO: Geneva. Xu K, James C, Carrin G, Muchiri S. 2006. An empirical model of access to health care, health care expenditure and impoverishment in Kenya: Learning from past reforms and lessons for the future. Discussion paper No. 3-2006. HSF/WHO: Geneva. Vinard P, Basaza R. 2006.E ´ valuation des conditions pre´alables au de´veloppement de syste`mes assuranciels contre le risque maladie en Afrique de l’Est: Strate´gies d’intervention dans le domaine du financement de la sante´ au Kenya, Ouganda et Tanzania. Rapport final. Re´publique franc¸aise. Ministe`re des affaires e´trange`res. Direction ge´ne´rale de la Coope´ration et du De´veloppement: Paris, March 2006. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley Sons, Ltd. Int J Health Plann Mgmt 2008; 23: 51–68. DOI: 10.1002/hpm 68 I. MATHAUER ET AL.