SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 13
Download to read offline
Recent shifts in the
governance of education
towards markets and
privatization and their
implications for
educational opportunities
for all
Privatisation as a concept can be defined in
numerous ways and with it connotations as to
its intent and social objectives. Belfield and
Levin (2002) provide a broad definition in
terms of privatisation of the education system
in which they state that “privatization is the
transfer of activities, assets and
responsibilities from government/public
institutions and organizations to private
individuals and agencies” (Belfield & Levin,
2002, p.19). Education at all levels is
experiencing significant adjustment in
response to growing global competition and
pressure on governments to rein in the
ballooning expenditure associated with the
provision of education. Belfield and Levin’s
(2002) definition of privatisation tends to
oversimplify the mechanisms by which
privatisation is being implemented and
rationale that has shifted a fundamentally
supply driven model to one where the
demand of the market dictates. Their
definition as succinct as it is raises questions
as to the future role of the State and
economic levers it will retain to fulfil the
social responsibilities entrusted to it.
Lundberg (1994) in his early and arguably
insightful analysis of Australia’s reformist
educational policy exposes the reality behind
the political vernacular concealed within the
rhetoric of ‘competition’, ‘open’ and ‘free’ as
acknowledgement that markets and with it
privatisation of vocational education had
deep ideological roots. The foundations of
vocational training had been set though the
implications of open market regimes were yet
to be realised. Lundberg however highlights
the implications associated with relinquished
control of centralised education by the State
and intimates the requirement for regulatory
control to ensure integrity and industry
confidence is maintained. While much of the
discourse tends to concentrate on
privatisation of the school and university
sectors, the trend is one that is being
replicated in the vocational education and
training field. Parallels clearly can be drawn
across all sectors though in the VET sector the
drivers tend to be expressed in economic
imperatives rather than social equity
measures. Australia’s VET system had
matured and was exposed to the realities of
global competition. The humanist influences
that underpinned the Keynsian philosophies
of the Kangan reforms had run their course.
The paradigm of neoliberal principles was
consolidating what was to become a quantum
shift in the future of vocational training
provision and with it questions of social equity
and quality outcomes. The die had been cast
and with it vocational training was to be
inextricably connected with the fluctuations
of markets and the foibles of domestic and
global policy.
Internationally, the World Bank paved the
way for emerging third world economies
identifying the growing demand for skilled
labour and technicians as the basis upon
which to build economic prosperity through
increased productivity. Education in terms of
‘private consumption’ varied significantly
across the OECD nations with levels of
expenditure ranging from 2 per cent in
Portugal and Sweden to 22 per cent in
Germany and the United States (WTO, 1998).
Across sub-Saharan Africa however and
nations such as Togo, Nigeria, Brazil, and
Colombia there was a sense of urgency for
governments to address the reality that global
competition and demand for skilled labour
would dictate their capacity to participate and
1 | P a g e
prosper on the world stage (Middleton,
Ziderman & Van Adams, 1991). The World
Bank's position was unequivocal arguing that
the role of the private sector and its
engagement in vocational training provision
across the developing world would form the
basis of economic reform and future global
prosperity. The Uruguay round of meetings of
the World Trade Organisation (WTO) signalled
the impetus for change and questioned the
hegemonic dictum of the State as education
providers (Fitz & Beers, 2002; Hirtt. 2002).
Liberalisation of the education system and
support for open markets were now the
mantra of international reformist discourse
(Hirtt, 2000).
Anderson (2005) in his analysis of the VET
reforms that were reshaping the Australian
Vocational Education and Training (VET)
landscape argued that the language of supply
and demand based economic principles was
promoted on the basis of ‘competition’ and
‘choice’. In many ways the departure of
governments as the traditional provider of
training was mirroring neo-liberal policy being
embraced internationally. Conjecture remains
as to whether social equity as opposed to
economic pragmatism was the overwhelming
driver across nations that were facing
expanding education costs with managing
competing fiscal obligations. In the Essential
Service Commissions review of fee structure
of Victoria’s VET system cost, content and
quality were common to all stakeholders
though acknowledged that governments and
policy makers also had a role to ensure
equitable access to education and training
was not hindered by policy outcomes
(Essential Services Commission, 2011). A new
obligation of the State was also identified
within this report which was to manage the
risk associated with market failure.
The implication of market reform centred on
privatisation of education needs to be
evaluated on numerous levels. Economic
benefit may well be the underlying intent
however equity, opportunity and diversity of
educational experience which is the politically
palatable argument needs to be tested as do
the unintended consequences that
privatisation has revealed. Australia as with
many nations across the OECD have
embarked upon neoliberal reform across all
sectors of education. Vocational training and
its Keynsian ideologies have been supplanted
by the vagaries of market dynamics within the
ideological veil of free enterprise, competition
and social equity.
Globalisation’s influence continues to steer
the direction of education policy and
stimulates debate as to the social and
economic implications of those that guide it.
In the analysis that follows, education and in
particular vocational training has been
influenced at both the global and domestic
level. Globally, the leitmotif of governments
globally is managing competing demands on
the finite economic resources at their
disposal. Education remains a significant
economic impost for nations that have
established their credentials however for
those emerging nations riding the crest of the
economic wave, a skilled workforce is likely to
come crashing down on foreign shores.
Privatisation – An
International Perspective
Privatisation of education is a phenomenon
being adopted by governments around the
world invariably cloaked in terms such as
'choice', 'accountability', contestability' or
'effectiveness' (Ball & Youdell, 2007;
Anderson, 2005). While reference to
privatisation of public education does not
enter into the lexicon of government, the
desire to emulate the strategies applied
within the private sector is being adopted by
governments around the world. Ball and
Youdell (2007) categorise privatisation of
public education on the basis of how change
is superimposed over the often entrenched
workplace practices. Commercialisation of the
public sector and transfer of practices more
2 | P a g e
akin to those perpetuated in private business
is characteristic of 'endogenous' privatisation
governments may adopt. Conversely, a free
enterprise approach where public entities are
placed in direct competition with private
sector entrants is characteristic of 'exogenous'
privatisation. Belfield and Levin (2002)
however argue that privatisation policies are
instigated by governments through a variety
of mechanisms, often in combination and
invariably influenced by economic reality or
ideological faith in free markets. They argue
that privatisation is introduced by
governments increasing competition by
opening up the education market to private
providers. Alternatively the costs of education
are progressively transferred to the
consumers (parents, employers, students) or
in other instances education providers are
afforded greater autonomy with decision
making coming from within rather than from
the State.
The significance of vocational education as a
vehicle to drive the transformation of
emerging economies has not been lost on
governments. Sharma (2014) succinctly
describes the transformation that will have to
take place across the Indian vocational
training system if it is to compete on the
international stage. The magnitude of the
challenges that face this nation is reinforced
in Sharma’s analysis of the economic upheaval
that this nation is about to confront. Over the
next 20 years India is anticipating a million
people each month to enter the labour force
(Sharma, 2014). Underlying all this is the
capacity of the nation to service the skills
needs that will be the driving force of the
nation’s economy. For developing economies
such as India the capacity to meet the skills
and educational development of its
population are immense and will constitute
significant changes in how training is
provided.
Privatisation of the training system is
presented as a plausible solution to the rapid
and viable development of the nation’s
populace. Contrary to the concerns raised
within the west, the embracing of
privatisation of the education system is both a
pragmatic and economic response to meeting
the nation’s demand for skilled labour. The
‘Three Buckets of Reform’ proposed by
Sharma reinforces the recalibration of training
provision in India to better align with the
vocational skilling system’s capacity to
provide ‘quantity’, ‘quality’ and
‘inclusiveness’. With over half of the youth in
India being either skill deprived or un-
employable the motivation to address these
deficiencies is both poignant and palpable.
This shift towards market lead systems has its
detractors particularly where the explosion in
numbers of private education providers are
destabilising the dominance of the centralist,
government funded public system. Private
Training Establishments (PTEs) in New Zealand
are experiencing unprecedented growth as it
has maintained a liberal and open market
approach to competition from the private
sector (Hirtt, 2000; Appanna & Gounder,
2011). Stimulated by the New Public
Management (NPM) model the traditional
role of the public service provider is being
challenged on numerous economic, political,
global and as Gruening (2001) argues a
behavioural-administrative science front. For
publicly funded training systems such as those
in New Zealand and Australia and the
underlying classical democratic theory that
has been the cornerstone of these
institutions, the future of TAFE in Australia or
PTEs in New Zealand as the dominant training
provider is being sorely tested.
New Public Management (NPM) stems from
the United Kingdom under Margaret Thatcher
and local governments in the United States as
a reaction by government public
bureaucracies to fiscal restraint and economic
recession (Hood, 1991, Gruening, 2001;
O'Flynn, 2007). As a management philosophy
it has cemented its credentials in the
teleological realm of public sector
bureaucracy beyond the global north and
3 | P a g e
been embraced within the public sectors of
New Zealand and Australia. Interestingly Hood
(1991) associates the stimulus that has
contributed to this reformist policy of the
public sector as promulgated from the
endogenous and exogenous forces that Ball
and Youdell (2007) identify as influencers of
public policy.
Gruening (2001) however questions whether
NPM constitutes a paradigm shift as such
though acknowledges that it is how
governments in New Zealand have packaged
managerial elements of this reformist
movement that signify real change. In his
detailed analysis of theoretical approaches to
public sector management he identifies
characteristics in each that correspond to
those now labelled as NPM. Characteristics
that encompass 'budget cuts', 'customer
concept', 'competition' and 'privatisation' are
on their own strategies often employed by
government agencies. As strategies in their
own right they are by no means revolutionary.
What is transformative is that each has
coalesced into a reform movement that
influences not just those organisations at the
centre of government service provision but
many such as public training providers who
have more recently been placed on the
periphery of the public domain.
Exponents of the NPM movement of which
New Zealand and Australia had embraced was
for the public service a quantum shift in
administrative organisation and indirect
acknowledgement that governments had
continued to fail in delivering efficiencies and
transparency (O'Flynn, 2007). The role of
government as service supplier was being
scrutinised with separation between purchase
and supply of services by the State reinforcing
the support of market efficiencies to expedite
social reform. Flynn (2007) and Gruening
(2001) acknowledge NPM as a force driving
change from within though neither critically
analyse the global externalities that may be
driving reform. Appana and Gounda (2011)
however implicate globalisation and
competition based efficiencies as causal
agents.
Education across most OECD countries
represents a significant part of their
respective government's expenditure and
during periods of fiscal restraint the capacity
of nations to maintain funding levels
continues to experience pressure from
competing public demands. Growing disquiet
first during the Regan presidency and
continuing through the Clinton
administration, the attention of policy makers
was drawn to what was seen as a failure of
the public education system in America
(Fusarelli & Johnson, 2004). Growing criticism
of the school system was directed at a public
entity that was unaccountable and
uncoordinated in the services it provided.
Cohen, March, and Olsen, (1972) associated
the policy disconnect and identified failure of
the education system as characteristic of
‘organized anarchies’ built on fluid
arrangements and inconsistencies resulting in
lack of coherent direction. Drawing upon the
management practices of the private sector,
public education embarked on major reform
that embraced market based philosophies
where output is measured and competition is
encouraged.
In what Fusarelli and Johnson (2004) refer to
as a 'neo-corporatist' approach, the school
system was being coerced to embrace the
NPM practices of corporate America where
competition and the power of free enterprise
were destined to deliver efficiencies and
increased productivity. The ‘Garbage Can
Model’ elucidated by Cohen et al., (1972)
presents a school management system based
on decision making that was at best well
intended though fundamentally flawed. The
‘Garbage Can Model’ as a repository for
potential solutions to problems may well
archives its objective though as a decision
making tool its effectiveness is questionable.
Politically, the solution was simple. The
education system required the stimulus from
the commercial world to engender a sense of
4 | P a g e
competition and response to market demand
by overlaying the desire to succeed in
contrast to a public instrumentality that was
seen to be complacent and unresponsive to
change. For the established private education
providers this shift in government policy
presented opportunity to further consolidate
their position as a serious player within an
increasingly more open and competitive
market.
Privatisation of education systems in parts of
the world has seen the expansion of lucrative,
corporate entities or ‘Education Management
Organisations’, attracted by neoliberal
governments that are receding from their
traditional supply oriented role to one
influenced by market demand. England and
the United States are nations that have well
established policies that have liberalised
education provision though as Fitz and Beers
(2002) suggest, the approach adopted is
different. Reganomics and Thatcherism of the
1980s reflected a period in education policy
formation where governments were looking
towards the private sector as models of
efficiency and business acumen during a
period of increased fiscal restraint and
diminished capacity of governments to service
burgeoning social welfare demands. The
exposure of the ‘new and juicy targets’ (Hirtt,
2002) to free enterprise or the ‘predators’ of
free enterprise was the depiction conveyed by
commentators such as Hirtt in reference to
the Millennium Round of the World Trade
Organisation (WTO) meeting in Seattle.
Similar disparaging remarks were directed at
private education providers in Chile with
private education providers described as
‘creaming’ the system in the advent of
privatisation (Torche, 2005).
Zajda (2004) in his critique of global education
reform argues that there is a paradoxical
ambivalence by the State in their pursuit of
free markets maintained under the guise of
purported decline in education standards.
Failure of United States education in the
1980s and early 1990s were also being
questioned as student graduating were falling
behind comparable nations (Milne, 1998).
Milne's historical analysis of America's
education policy during this period captures
the attitude of policy makers at the time that
attributed failure directly with educators and
fundamental teaching standards. The paradox
however persists within decentralist rhetoric
yet surreptitious hegemonic policy of the
State that welcomed privatisation as the
panacea of economic and social stability. The
paradox referred to by Zajda (2004) is
epitomised in the United States neo-liberal
and increasingly corporatisation vocational
education policy that accentuates social
stratification and educational inequity (Lakes
& Carter, 2009).
Neoliberal driven reform of education
systems across many OECD nations has its
basis in ideology as much as it does in
economic pragmatism. In 1981 Chile
implemented a rapid and expansive
restructuring of its education system in
response to identified inequities across the
diverse socioeconomic groups. Reformist
policies in Chile provide one example of an
education system that has experienced radical
change as a result of internal political
upheaval and market oriented economic
transformation (Torche, 2005), (Tapia, 2003).
Chile’s implementation of a voucher system
paved the way for subsidised education to be
provided to the public as well as the growing
number of private schools therefore
effectively allowing fundamental market
mechanisms to determine the future of the
school system. Enrolments in the private
sector schools increased from 15 per cent to
33 percent between 1981 and 1996 (Belfield
& Levin, 2002). Decentralisation of public
education and introduction of a voucher
system was formulated around increasing
access to education. However as Torche
asserts the strategy only confirmed the
embedded social inequities or “persistent
inequality” that has been replicated by
5 | P a g e
governments intent on broadening access to
education.
Chile’s liberal reform of the education sector
was predicated on the decentralised provision
of education and transfer of responsibility to
private entities with the intent to encourage
increased equity and economic efficiencies
(Martinez, 2001). The socioeconomic
stratification of Chile’s education system was
accentuated as students from wealthier
sectors of the community gravitated to the
fee paying private schools. Likewise, private
schools were also drawn to regions where
family incomes could sustain the additional
fees. The public schools by default met the
needs of low income families and unlike the
private system they were compelled by law to
accept all voucher funded students (Torche,
2005). Liberalisation of education and access
to public funding afforded to the private
sector instigated an exodus of students from
the public municipal system to the subsidised
private provider. Consequently, there has
been a marked decline in the resourcing of
public education as the State relinquishes
responsibility and participates as a passive
observer and increasingly submissive
facilitator (Tapia, 2003). As Tapia succinctly
stated 'the state had washed its hands of
overseeing public education...' (Tapia, 2003,
p.6). Essentially education equity and access
was delivered however only to those who
could pay and for the public system they were
to be sustained on dwindling government
expenditure.
Commencing under Pinochet’s authoritarian
regime the Chilean education reform agenda
was purported to be motivated by social
equity issues and the right of citizens to freely
engage with new education opportunities.
Privatisation of the dominant public education
system was to be the wedge that would foster
free enterprise and expand education’s reach
to those who had been excluded. Educational
stratification that Tapia (2003) and Torche
(2005) identify as inadvertent consequences
of market operated mechanisms has been
experienced across both developed and
developing nations around the globe. While
the discussion so far has focused on primary
and secondary schooling and to a lesser
extent university education, the vocational
system has also been subject to significant
change. Middleton et al. (1991) had some
years earlier identified the contribution of
vocational training particularly in the third
world however emphasised that the function
of the State was to manage economic
‘distortions’ that may arise in a training
environment that was entrusting the private
sector to deliver. More recently vocational
education has experienced significant growth
accounting for 53 per cent of all enrolments
with 500,000 workers annually participating in
enterprise based ‘non formal vocational
training’ (Martinez, 2001). Martinez while
acknowledging the growth of the private
sector delivery of training, maintains that
State involvement is sustained through
consultative arrangements. The establishment
of Regional Councils for Work-Related
Education (CRETs) provides a forum by which
government can affect policy under the
auspices of free enterprise. Chile's education
reform continue though now it is the Bachelet
government that faces protests from students
and the Confederation of Parents and
Guardians (Confepa) opposed to further
reform of an already heavily privatised
system. Chile's enthusiasm for privatisation
continues to generate disquiet among
segments of the population with concerns
that liberal policy will encourage private
education providers to increase fees, further
disadvantaging the poor who have no
alternative other than attend an already
under resourced public system (Radio New
Zealand News, 2014).
Vocational education has been subject to
similar neoliberal reform as has primary and
secondary school systems around the globe.
Global economic forces and exposure to
growing competition and preference towards
market oriented policy has seen governments
6 | P a g e
progressively relinquish direct control of the
publicly funded vocational system. While
Spöttl (2008) provocatively asserted that
education providers should be focusing their
sites on the epitome of consumerism and the
free market reality of the stock exchange.
Vocational training as with the rest of the
education system were being criticised for
their disconnect with the shifting economic
and social demands of increasingly
interconnected nation States. The era of
Fordist principles was coming to an end and
attention towards the capability of the
broader education system to support an
increasingly competitive and dynamic global
economy was exposing the perceived inertia
of the public vocational system to meet
growing economic demands.
Privatisation of VET in
Australia
To appreciate the significance of the
structural changes that have taken place
within the Australian vocational system there
is a necessity to firstly look at the
transformation from a historical and
evolutionary perspective. Post-war
development was founded on Australia’s
strengthening relationship with America and
fundamental capitalist policies of the then
Menzies coalition government. In terms of its
historical development, vocational training
was built upon the desire to support those
within society that were prone to the
adversity and inequity of economic
development while meeting the needs of
industry hungry for skilled labour. For what
was later to become the brand, Technical and
Further Education (TAFE) the polarity
between pedagogic aspiration and economic
reality has remodelled the existing vocational
stage. It was the release of the Kangan Report
in 1974 that not only established TAFE as a
name but articulated the social obligations
that vocational education was to be
entrusted. Contrary to views held today,
Kangan did not see the role of TAFE merely as
the servant to industry and provider of skilled
labour but had a responsibility to service the
vocational interests of all people (Clarke,
1992). This position however was later to be
challenged as Keynsian economic settlement
made way for the free markets of neoliberal
policy.
Australia's vocational education and training
system has been the centre of turbulent and
sometimes vibrant debate. Kim Beasley in
1974 as Minister for Education in the Whitlam
Labour government epitomises the political
rhetoric with the educational reality that
contributed to the diminished status of
vocational training. As highlighted by
Rushbrook (2010), Beazley's commitment to
addressing the 'Cinderella' status of
vocational training was in part
acknowledgement of successive government's
neglect of the system though recognition of
its role as a training provider in delivering the
skills to meet the needs of industry.
Education as a social equity debate was a
fundamental part of the Labour doctrine
however at a time when Keynsian settlement
and the Welfare State were making way for
neoliberal reform the social democratic ideals
were being circumvented by the economic
reality of an increasingly global economy.
Indications that Australia's training system
was soon to enter a new phase was intimated
in the review conducted by Dawkins and
Holding (1984). It was here that the primarily
TAFE sector who delivered vocational training
for industry was to gain some sense that
change and with it their dominance was likely
to be tested. Dawkins and Holding were
calling for a VET sector that was responsive to
the emerging needs of industry but was also
able to provide a quality outcome that would
allow the nation to compete on the
international arena. The call to have increased
private sector investment in training was the
precursor to the open training markets that
exist today.
7 | P a g e
Goozee (2001) in her historical analysis of the
vocational system in Australia, presents a very
different picture to the one that resides
today. From its inception it was an institution
based on the simple premise that training and
education is a right not just to the privileged
but to those who k the fundamental basis
upon which nation's wealth was to prosper.
Though TAFE as is understood today is a far
cry from how it was conceived, the
fundamental social obligations that has been
its foundation is in the light of the globalised
economy being challenged by successive
governments and the very industries it was
designed to serve. The TAFE system is in many
ways at a watershed in terms of its relevance
to a dynamic and increasingly global
workplace and its ability to recalibrate the
way it provides the future training needs of
industry.
The significance of the transformation
emerging needs to be interpreted as Chappel
(1998) refers to as the era of 'new
vocationalism' in which fundamental changes
within the VET system is currently reshaping
the future of education and training in
Australia. The identity of TAFE as the sole
provider of vocational training has been
relinquished however Chappel argues the
pedagogy and institutional practices of
trainers has also been forfeited. Chappel is
fighting multiple fronts all of which have some
substance though the implications of change
that have had a negative impact on the public
system have also reverberated throughout
the private RTOs though with contrasting
repercussions.
In May 1990 the joint meeting of state labour
education ministers set terms of reference for
an enquiry into the provision of vocational
training in Australia as well as industry’s
contribution to the reform agenda. Later to
become known as the ‘Deveson Report’ the
comprehensive assessment set the stage for
what was to become a major shift away from
the social welfare obligations of TAFE as
outlined in the 1974 Kangan Report. By
September of that same year, and under
growing government concerns of increased
global fiscal debt the report’s findings
reiterated the economic imperative for the
vocational sector to respond to the needs of
the economy (Deveson, 1990). For TAFE this
report signalled that governments were
questioning their capacity to sustain
ballooning training expenditure, a concern
further reinforced by the economic turmoil
that was attributed to the lack of financial
restraint that was the hallmark of the 1980s.
Deveson (1990) found that the TAFE system
was failing to respond to the needs of the
industry it was designed to serve, to the
extent that businesses were withdrawing
support for the public provider. Industry was
not solely dependent upon the TAFE system
to service its skills requirements with data
contained in the report indicating 51 per cent
of the Australian industry training market
being expended on salaries for in-house
trainers. The report’s findings suggested that
TAFE providers were becoming unresponsive
and increasingly less relevant to industry.
What McDowell, Oliver, Persson, Fairbrother,
Wetzlar, Buchanan and Shipstone (2011)
highlighted in their report and followed over
twenty years later was that the financial
burden of training was to be shared by
industry as well as government. Mc Dowell et
al. (2011) however was primarily focused on
apprenticeship recruitment though industry’s
vocational training disconnect had been well
entrenched. Employers having effectively
abandoned the VET system in preference to
customised programs that satisfied their
immediate requirements was a signal for
reform. The role of the State as supplier of
vocational training was changing and
Australia’s VET system was progressively
being remodelled by market demand.
Since the late 1990s Australia's VET system
has witnessed a progressively diminishing role
of government as the supplier of education
and training. The National Agreement for
Skills and Workforce Development (NASWD)
8 | P a g e
set ambitious targets to double the number of
people with a diploma or advanced diploma
by 2020 and halve the number or working
Australians with a Certificate III or higher by
2020 (Leung, McVicar, Polidano and Zhang,
2014). Dawkins and Holding (1987) had clearly
identified Australia's declining levels of
education participation and skills acquisition
which presented real barriers to future
prosperity. The TAFE brand was well
established in the Australian training psyche
however governments were cognisant of the
reality that future skills needs of the nation
was predicated on a training system that was
responsive to the changing dynamics of the
economy. Competition which was to drive
training reform was constrained by the
domination of the public provider as was the
industrial award systems of the institutes that
inhibited their ability to compete in an open
market (Anderson, 2005).
Belfield and Levin's (2002) analysis of
privatisation based reform of the school and
tertiary sectors draws a number of parallels to
the transformation underway with the VET
system both in Australia and internationally.
Their 'evaluative criteria' sets out a
framework that examines the ascribed
benefits of privatisation against the inherent
consequences that can be attributed to this
reformist agenda. Questions of choice,
efficiency, equity and social cohesiveness are
objectives that they maintain form the basis
of measuring privatisation's contribution to
civil society. They are equally relevant in
establishing some rational debate over similar
changes across the VET system. Lundberg
(1994) had already signalled that the
dynamics of public training provision had
shifted through the National Framework for
Recognition of Training (NFROT) which
opened up the doors for private providers and
future competition.
The TAFE system in Victoria has been the
educational trailblazer as far as privatisation
and open competition of vocational training is
concerned. In July 2009 the state labour
government instigated a major reform of the
vocational system in response to concerns
from industry that TAFE providers were failing
to respond to the significant changes looming
for the Victorian economy. Victoria with its
traditional manufacturing base was similar to
other sectors of the Australian and
international community that was
experiencing a shift towards new industries
where they could compete globally.
Research conducted by Anderson (2005)
provides some insight into how the
implementation of market mechanisms had
impacted on the VET sector and the reaction
of providers, industry and students to the new
paradigm. His 2001 findings concluded that
over the ten years since in what was to be the
first tranche of national VET reform had
achieved mixed outcomes. Creating a VET
system that was more engaged and
responsive to the needs of major industry
stakeholders was a quantifiable and positive
outcome. The VET consumer was
experiencing greater choice in terms of access
to education which was directly related to
increased private provider entry. Social equity
obligations and economic efficiencies were
however compromised as were accessibility
to training by small to medium enterprises
where thin markets prevailed.
State governments nationally have initiated
variants of the demand driven reform of the
VET system with varying degrees of
enthusiasm and impact. Under the ‘Council of
Australian Governments (COAG) National
Partnerships Agreement on Skills Reform’ a
bilateral agreement between the
Commonwealth and state and territory
governments was established that was to
better align the VET system with the skills
demands of industry. Victoria under the title
‘Skills for Growth’ was the first state to
implement an open and contestable training
market. Other states were to follow having
observed Victoria’s transition to this new
model with initiatives ‘Skills for All’ (South
Australia), ’Great skills. Real opportunities.’
9 | P a g e
(Queensland), ‘Smart and Skilled’ (New South
Wales) and ‘FutureSkills WA’ (Western
Australia). Victoria incorporated an additional
incentive under the banner of the ‘Victorian
Training Guarantee’ (VTG) which with
additional Federal Government funding
uncapped the number of subsidised
enrolments. The training guarantee was in
effect an entitlement to a guaranteed training
place with a VET provider which was designed
to stimulate competition and access
particularly to equity groups (disabled
students and CALD students) which had
previously been underrepresented within the
VET student cohort (Leung et al., 2014).
Now five years since implementation of the
VTG, Leung et al. (2014) using comparative
data analysis found that enrolments had
increased significantly with most of the
growth within the private sector. Between
2008 and 2011 private provider enrolments
had increased by 300 per cent while the
public TAFE provider experienced minimal
change. Early data suggested healthy
competition was taking place between the
public and private providers and skills
acquisition targets were being achieved.
Victoria has been the trailblazer of VET reform
though state and territory compatriots quietly
observed the repercussions of seemingly
unfettered expenditure within a burgeoning
private sector training system. The Victorian
Training Market Report (DEECD, 2014)
provides some positive insight into the
demand driven training reforms though
overlooks the 40 per cent of VET graduates
surveyed that reported that their training had
not improved their employment status within
six months of completion. Superficial analysis
would suggest that the exploitation of an
open and contestable training market was the
inevitable consequence however the inherent
failure can also be attributed to the
deficiencies in timely regulatory control.
Privatisation of education and training in
conjunction with disjointed policy has
contributed to the fragmentation of the
sector and decline of Australia’s VET sector
(Noonan, Burke, Wade and Pilcher, 2014). In
Noonan et al. in their recent analysis of
education expenditure data suggests that
while Victoria has increased its investment in
the sector other states and territories have
recorded zero to negative growth over the
same period. The investment disparity is
further evident when comparative
expenditure between education sectors
indicates a decline in public expenditure
compared with increased relative investment
in the school and university sectors.
The impact privatisation is having across all
sectors of education continues to polarise
Advocates for reform identify the economic
reality that ever increasing government
expenditure on education is financially
unsustainable and limits their capacity to
service such demands as public health,
national defence and welfare support for the
aged or disadvantaged (Belfield & Levin,
2002).
Belfield and Levin (2002) pose that
privatisation may be motivated by
fundamental ideologies that can be attributed
to the rise of neoliberal oriented policies
across much of the OECD affiliated nations. It
is the right of the individual to choose that is
paramount as it is the right to support free
enterprise. Detractors however argue that the
marketisation of education places in question
the rhetoric of access, equity and increased
quality that free market advocates espouse.
Quality education should not be determined
by affluence and wealth nor should education
become a commodity that generates profits
for opportunistic private enterprises.
Education however is well entrenched in the
principles of free markets and open
competition and as Hirtt (2000) argues the
liberalisation of trade between nations as
ratified within the General Agreement of
Trade in Services (GATS) heralded a
transformative shift in the role of the state in
terms of education provider. Globally,
10 | P a g e
privatisation of vocational education presents
mixed response. Education budgets continue
to be stretched with emerging economies
embracing the injection of foreign, private
investment by global education providers.
Free trade agreements have extended their
coverage to private education services in
search of new and potentially lucrative
markets.
The drive to meet growing global competition
through a skilled workforce is a message that
is repeated across nations; large and small,
and emerging economies or those who have
consolidated their global credentials. The
rationale that supports privatisation does not
maintain global consensus though its
influence in the shaping education and
training sectors is profound. Privatisation in
the developing world provides opportunity to
those within the community otherwise
excluded from education either due to
financial constraint of the State or incapacity
to develop the infrastructure required to
support its needs. Conversely, developed
economies such as the United States, Britain
and Australia question the social inequities
that devolution of state responsibilities to
private and profit motivated entities.
The threat of entrepreneurial opportunism of
dubious practices of private education and
training providers continues to capture the
headlines however what this tends to
overlook is the social stratification between
those who can afford to pay and those who
cannot. The policy rhetoric that often
underpins the push towards marketisation of
education is symptomatic of a global trend
towards neo-liberal philosophies that shifts
responsibility of the State to the vagaries of
the free market. The paradox that Zajda
(2004), Hirtt (2002), Tapia (2003) and Torche
(2005) elude to is the hegemonic influence of
the State within a decentralist, open market
policy that promises to drive economic
growth and prosperity in an increasingly
competitive global marketplace. What
remains to be seen is whether diminishing
public provision and funding of education
truly creates opportunity for all or as already
emerging, simply entrench the social
inequities that exist.
11 | P a g e
References
Anderson, D. (2005). Trading places: The
impacts of market reform in vocational
education and training. NCVER. Adelaide, SA.
Appanna, S., & Goundar, S. (2011).
Deregulation and control in international
education: What happens in private training
establishments in NZ? International Journal
for Educational Integrity, 7(2), 53-62.
Ball, S., & Youdell, D. (2007). Hidden
privatisation in public education. Education
Review. Retrieved from http://old.ei-
ie.org/annualreport2007/upload/content_trsl
_images/440/Hidden_privatisation-EN.pdf
Belfield, C., & Levin, H. (2002). Education
privatization: causes, consequences and
planning implications. In UNESCO (Ed.),
Fundamentals of Educational Planning (Vol.
74, 83pp.). Paris, France: United Nations
Educational, Scientific and Cultural
Organization.
Chappell, C. (1998). Changing TAFE in new
times. Vocational Education and Training,
23(2), 17.
Clarke, E. (1992). Technical Further Education
in Queensland: A History 1860-1990.
Historical Perspectives on Contemporary
Issues in Queensland Education.
Cohen, M., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. F. (1972).
A garbage can model of organizational choice.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(1), 1-25.
Dawkins, J., & Holding, A. (1987). Skills for
Australia. Commonwealth of Australia.
Canberra: AGPS.
DEECD. (2014). Victorian Training Market
Report: Half year 2014. Department of
Education and Early Childhood Development,
Victoria State Government. Unpublished
version.
Deveson, I., & Committee, A. T. C. R. (1990).
Training costs of award restructuring: report
of the Training Costs Review Committee
[Deveson report]. Canberra: Australian
Government Publishing Service.
Essential Services Commission (2011). VET Fee
and Funding Review – Volume 1: Blueprint for
Change, September
Fitz, J., & Beers, B. (2002). Education
Management Organisations and the
Privatisation of Public Education: A Cross-
National Comparison of the USA and Britain.
Comparative Education, 38(2), 137-154. doi:
10.2307/3099781
Fusarelli, L., & Johnson, B. (2004). Educational
Governance and the New Public
Management. Public Administration and
Management: An Interactive Journal, 9(2),
118-127.
Goozee, G. (2001). The Development of TAFE
in Australia. NCVER. Adelaide. Retrieved from
http://www.ncver.edu.au/publications/574.ht
ml
Gruening, G. (2001). Origin and theoretical
basis of New Public Management.
International Public Management Journal, 4,
1–25.
Hirtt, N. (2000). Will education go to market?
The UNESCO Courier, 53, 14-16.
Hirtt, N. (2002). The ‘Millennium Round’ and
the Liberalisation of the Education Market. In
I. Lohmann & R. Rilling (Eds.), Die verkaufte
Bildung (pp. 15-27): VS Verlag für
Sozialwissenschaften.
Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all
seasons. Public Administration, 69, 3-19.
Leung, F., McVicar, D., Polidano, C. & Zhang,
R. (2014) Early impacts of the Victorian
Training Guarantee on VET enrolments and
graduate outcomes.
Lundberg, D. (1994). Calling the tune: market-
responsive vocational education: a discussion
paper. Adelaide: NCVER.
12 | P a g e
Martínez, E. (2001). Financing Schemes for
Vocational Education and Training in Chile.
Paper presented at the Improving VET
Systems, Montego Bay, Jamaica.
McDowell, J., Australia. Department of
Education, E., Relations, W., Oliver, D.,
Persson, M., Fairbrother, R., Shipstone, T.
(2011). A shared responsibility:
apprenticeships for the 21st Century.
Canberra: DEEWR.
Middleton, John; Ziderman, Adrian; Van
Adams, Arvil. 1991. Vocational and technical
education and training. A World Bank policy
paper. Washington, DC : The World Bank.
http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/
1991/05/699987/vocational-technical-
education-training, Accessed October 17
2014.
Milne, A. (Ed.) (1998). Educational reform and
vocational education. National Assessment of
Vocational Education. Washington, DC.
Retrieved from
http://files.eric.ed.gov/fulltext/ED421659.pdf
Viewed October 1 2014.
Noonan, P., Burke, G., Wade, A., & Pilcher, S.
(2014). Expenditure on education and training
in Australia: Analysis and background paper.
Mitchell Institute for Health and Education
Policy. Melbourne, Australia.
O’Flynn, J. (2007). From New Public
Management to Public Value: Paradigmatic
Change and Managerial Implications. The
Australian Journal of Public Administration,
66(3), 353–366. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-
8500.2007.00545.x
Radio New Zealand News (2014). Chile's
education reform sparks protest. Retrieved 26
October from
http://www.radionz.co.nz/news/world/25781
6/chile's-education-reform-sparks-protest
Rushbrook, P. (2010). Bringing Cinderella to
the ball: constructing a federal system of
technical and further education in Australia,
1971-1975. Journal of Educational
Administration and History, 42(1), 33-54. doi:
10.1080/00220620903462140
Sharma, N. (2014). Private Sector in
Vocational Education. Indian Journal of
Industrial Relations, 49(3), 409-421.
Spöttl, G. (2008). Autonomy of (Vocational)
Schools as an Answer to Structural Changes.
Policy Futures in Education, 6(2), 257-264.
Tapia, M. M. (2003). The privatisation of
education in Chile. Regional Office for Latin
America. Retrieved from http://download.ei-
ie.org/docs/IRISDocuments/Research%20Web
site%20Documents/2009-00035-01-E.pdf,
Viewed October 6 2014.
Torche, F. (2005). Privatization Reform and
Inequality of Educational Opportunity: The
Case of Chile. Sociology of Education,
78(October), 316–343.
WTO. (1998). Council for the Trade in
Services-education: Background Note by the
Secretariat,. Retrieved from
http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/thewt
o_e.htm#secretariat
Zajda, J. (2004). Decentralisation and
privatisation in education: the role of the
state. Paper presented at the AARE 2004,
University of Melbourne.
13 | P a g e

More Related Content

What's hot

Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in NigeriaInvestment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeriapaperpublications3
 
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...Alexander Decker
 
Education as an investment
Education as an investmentEducation as an investment
Education as an investmentathulyavijayan
 
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...Ijcem Journal
 
The public sector efficiency in the education department
The public sector efficiency in the education departmentThe public sector efficiency in the education department
The public sector efficiency in the education departmentAlexander Decker
 
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st century
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st centuryRe-thinking adult basic education in the 21st century
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st centurySubmissionResearchpa
 
Workforce development evaluation
Workforce development evaluationWorkforce development evaluation
Workforce development evaluationhmendoza716
 
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...SubmissionResearchpa
 
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentation
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentationO'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentation
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentationalbertgalt
 
Vibhuti patel economics of eduation
Vibhuti patel economics of eduationVibhuti patel economics of eduation
Vibhuti patel economics of eduationVIBHUTI PATEL
 
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeria
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeriaRole of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeria
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeriaAlexander Decker
 
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...Dr. Rosemarie Sibbaluca-Guirre
 
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeria
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeriaExploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeria
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeriaAlexander Decker
 
Higher Education and Equality in India
Higher Education and Equality in IndiaHigher Education and Equality in India
Higher Education and Equality in Indiainventionjournals
 
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...ijmvsc
 

What's hot (20)

Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in NigeriaInvestment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
 
Case study tech voc
Case study tech vocCase study tech voc
Case study tech voc
 
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...
Principals’ perception of entrepreneurship education as a management strategy...
 
Education as an investment
Education as an investmentEducation as an investment
Education as an investment
 
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...
A comparative-statistical-analysis-on-the-educational-system-in-european-coun...
 
The public sector efficiency in the education department
The public sector efficiency in the education departmentThe public sector efficiency in the education department
The public sector efficiency in the education department
 
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st century
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st centuryRe-thinking adult basic education in the 21st century
Re-thinking adult basic education in the 21st century
 
Workforce development evaluation
Workforce development evaluationWorkforce development evaluation
Workforce development evaluation
 
F031202036040
F031202036040F031202036040
F031202036040
 
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...
The role of institutional collaborations in combating covid-19 in dessie, sou...
 
The Challenges of Micro and Small Enterprises in the Case of Jimma Genet Woreda
The Challenges of Micro and Small Enterprises in the Case of Jimma Genet WoredaThe Challenges of Micro and Small Enterprises in the Case of Jimma Genet Woreda
The Challenges of Micro and Small Enterprises in the Case of Jimma Genet Woreda
 
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentation
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentationO'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentation
O'Meara Econ Lit Review pressentation
 
Vibhuti patel economics of eduation
Vibhuti patel economics of eduationVibhuti patel economics of eduation
Vibhuti patel economics of eduation
 
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeria
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeriaRole of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeria
Role of the state in managing entrepreneurial tertiary education in nigeria
 
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...
MAP 504 INTERNATIONALIZATION OF EDUCATION:FUTURE AND WORLDWIDE TRENDS IN MASS...
 
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeria
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeriaExploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeria
Exploration of pragmatic funding sources in funding higher education in nigeria
 
Fifty Years of Bangladesh: Achievement in Population Sector
Fifty Years of Bangladesh: Achievement in Population SectorFifty Years of Bangladesh: Achievement in Population Sector
Fifty Years of Bangladesh: Achievement in Population Sector
 
Higher Education and Equality in India
Higher Education and Equality in IndiaHigher Education and Equality in India
Higher Education and Equality in India
 
Education in national develioment
Education in national develiomentEducation in national develioment
Education in national develioment
 
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...
Study on the economic impact of employment small businesses loans under the f...
 

Similar to Globalisation

Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approach
Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approachEducation and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approach
Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approachPremier Publishers
 
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher education
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher educationGlobal Imperatives and New arenas for Higher education
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher educationshashi2278
 
The role of education in economic development
The role of education in economic developmentThe role of education in economic development
The role of education in economic developmentalishadoll2
 
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermore
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermoreAcademies everything to everyone for learning evermore
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermoreSuzie McGuiggan
 
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...Awais e Siraj
 
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in India
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in IndiaExperiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in India
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in IndiaVikramjit Singh
 
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit Higher
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit HigherChapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit Higher
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit HigherEstelaJeffery653
 
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docx
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docxRunning head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docx
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docxwlynn1
 
Human capital and development
Human capital and developmentHuman capital and development
Human capital and developmentSpringer
 
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific Research
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific ResearchExternalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific Research
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific ResearchIJITE
 
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCHEXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCHIJITE
 
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?UniversitasGadjahMada
 
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands Industrial Incl...
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands  Industrial Incl...IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands  Industrial Incl...
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands Industrial Incl...CINEC Campus
 
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeria
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in NigeriaRestructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeria
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeriaiosrjce
 
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement of
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement ofThe role of knowledge management towards the achievement of
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement ofAlexander Decker
 
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysia
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysiaEducation expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysia
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysiaAlexander Decker
 
Unit x emerging trends in education English Notes
Unit x emerging trends in education English NotesUnit x emerging trends in education English Notes
Unit x emerging trends in education English NotesThanavathi C
 

Similar to Globalisation (20)

Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approach
Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approachEducation and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approach
Education and Economic Growth in Uganda: A cointegration approach
 
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher education
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher educationGlobal Imperatives and New arenas for Higher education
Global Imperatives and New arenas for Higher education
 
The role of education in economic development
The role of education in economic developmentThe role of education in economic development
The role of education in economic development
 
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermore
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermoreAcademies everything to everyone for learning evermore
Academies everything to everyone for learning evermore
 
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...
Role of vocational education training (vet) policy in creating high skill soc...
 
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in India
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in IndiaExperiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in India
Experiments and Prospects of Globalisation Towards Higher Education in India
 
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit Higher
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit HigherChapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit Higher
Chapter 1The Contemporary Provision of For-Profit Higher
 
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docx
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docxRunning head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docx
Running head HIGHER EDUCATION POLICIES1HIGHER EDUCATION POLIC.docx
 
Human capital and development
Human capital and developmentHuman capital and development
Human capital and development
 
828 Notes..pdf
828 Notes..pdf828 Notes..pdf
828 Notes..pdf
 
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific Research
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific ResearchExternalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific Research
Externalities in Education, Scientific Knowledge and Scientific Research
 
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCHEXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH
EXTERNALITIES IN EDUCATION, SCIENTIFIC KNOWLEDGE AND SCIENTIFIC RESEARCH
 
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?
DO EDUCATION LEVELS MAT TER ON INDONESIAN ECONOM IC GROWTH?
 
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands Industrial Incl...
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands  Industrial Incl...IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands  Industrial Incl...
IJ SDR 2021 Shaping the Education to Meet the Global Demands Industrial Incl...
 
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeria
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in NigeriaRestructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeria
Restructuring Educational Goals for National and Economic Development in Nigeria
 
04 Yagna
04 Yagna04 Yagna
04 Yagna
 
Ac4301157160
Ac4301157160Ac4301157160
Ac4301157160
 
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement of
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement ofThe role of knowledge management towards the achievement of
The role of knowledge management towards the achievement of
 
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysia
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysiaEducation expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysia
Education expenditure and economic growth a causal analysis for malaysia
 
Unit x emerging trends in education English Notes
Unit x emerging trends in education English NotesUnit x emerging trends in education English Notes
Unit x emerging trends in education English Notes
 

Globalisation

  • 1. Recent shifts in the governance of education towards markets and privatization and their implications for educational opportunities for all Privatisation as a concept can be defined in numerous ways and with it connotations as to its intent and social objectives. Belfield and Levin (2002) provide a broad definition in terms of privatisation of the education system in which they state that “privatization is the transfer of activities, assets and responsibilities from government/public institutions and organizations to private individuals and agencies” (Belfield & Levin, 2002, p.19). Education at all levels is experiencing significant adjustment in response to growing global competition and pressure on governments to rein in the ballooning expenditure associated with the provision of education. Belfield and Levin’s (2002) definition of privatisation tends to oversimplify the mechanisms by which privatisation is being implemented and rationale that has shifted a fundamentally supply driven model to one where the demand of the market dictates. Their definition as succinct as it is raises questions as to the future role of the State and economic levers it will retain to fulfil the social responsibilities entrusted to it. Lundberg (1994) in his early and arguably insightful analysis of Australia’s reformist educational policy exposes the reality behind the political vernacular concealed within the rhetoric of ‘competition’, ‘open’ and ‘free’ as acknowledgement that markets and with it privatisation of vocational education had deep ideological roots. The foundations of vocational training had been set though the implications of open market regimes were yet to be realised. Lundberg however highlights the implications associated with relinquished control of centralised education by the State and intimates the requirement for regulatory control to ensure integrity and industry confidence is maintained. While much of the discourse tends to concentrate on privatisation of the school and university sectors, the trend is one that is being replicated in the vocational education and training field. Parallels clearly can be drawn across all sectors though in the VET sector the drivers tend to be expressed in economic imperatives rather than social equity measures. Australia’s VET system had matured and was exposed to the realities of global competition. The humanist influences that underpinned the Keynsian philosophies of the Kangan reforms had run their course. The paradigm of neoliberal principles was consolidating what was to become a quantum shift in the future of vocational training provision and with it questions of social equity and quality outcomes. The die had been cast and with it vocational training was to be inextricably connected with the fluctuations of markets and the foibles of domestic and global policy. Internationally, the World Bank paved the way for emerging third world economies identifying the growing demand for skilled labour and technicians as the basis upon which to build economic prosperity through increased productivity. Education in terms of ‘private consumption’ varied significantly across the OECD nations with levels of expenditure ranging from 2 per cent in Portugal and Sweden to 22 per cent in Germany and the United States (WTO, 1998). Across sub-Saharan Africa however and nations such as Togo, Nigeria, Brazil, and Colombia there was a sense of urgency for governments to address the reality that global competition and demand for skilled labour would dictate their capacity to participate and 1 | P a g e
  • 2. prosper on the world stage (Middleton, Ziderman & Van Adams, 1991). The World Bank's position was unequivocal arguing that the role of the private sector and its engagement in vocational training provision across the developing world would form the basis of economic reform and future global prosperity. The Uruguay round of meetings of the World Trade Organisation (WTO) signalled the impetus for change and questioned the hegemonic dictum of the State as education providers (Fitz & Beers, 2002; Hirtt. 2002). Liberalisation of the education system and support for open markets were now the mantra of international reformist discourse (Hirtt, 2000). Anderson (2005) in his analysis of the VET reforms that were reshaping the Australian Vocational Education and Training (VET) landscape argued that the language of supply and demand based economic principles was promoted on the basis of ‘competition’ and ‘choice’. In many ways the departure of governments as the traditional provider of training was mirroring neo-liberal policy being embraced internationally. Conjecture remains as to whether social equity as opposed to economic pragmatism was the overwhelming driver across nations that were facing expanding education costs with managing competing fiscal obligations. In the Essential Service Commissions review of fee structure of Victoria’s VET system cost, content and quality were common to all stakeholders though acknowledged that governments and policy makers also had a role to ensure equitable access to education and training was not hindered by policy outcomes (Essential Services Commission, 2011). A new obligation of the State was also identified within this report which was to manage the risk associated with market failure. The implication of market reform centred on privatisation of education needs to be evaluated on numerous levels. Economic benefit may well be the underlying intent however equity, opportunity and diversity of educational experience which is the politically palatable argument needs to be tested as do the unintended consequences that privatisation has revealed. Australia as with many nations across the OECD have embarked upon neoliberal reform across all sectors of education. Vocational training and its Keynsian ideologies have been supplanted by the vagaries of market dynamics within the ideological veil of free enterprise, competition and social equity. Globalisation’s influence continues to steer the direction of education policy and stimulates debate as to the social and economic implications of those that guide it. In the analysis that follows, education and in particular vocational training has been influenced at both the global and domestic level. Globally, the leitmotif of governments globally is managing competing demands on the finite economic resources at their disposal. Education remains a significant economic impost for nations that have established their credentials however for those emerging nations riding the crest of the economic wave, a skilled workforce is likely to come crashing down on foreign shores. Privatisation – An International Perspective Privatisation of education is a phenomenon being adopted by governments around the world invariably cloaked in terms such as 'choice', 'accountability', contestability' or 'effectiveness' (Ball & Youdell, 2007; Anderson, 2005). While reference to privatisation of public education does not enter into the lexicon of government, the desire to emulate the strategies applied within the private sector is being adopted by governments around the world. Ball and Youdell (2007) categorise privatisation of public education on the basis of how change is superimposed over the often entrenched workplace practices. Commercialisation of the public sector and transfer of practices more 2 | P a g e
  • 3. akin to those perpetuated in private business is characteristic of 'endogenous' privatisation governments may adopt. Conversely, a free enterprise approach where public entities are placed in direct competition with private sector entrants is characteristic of 'exogenous' privatisation. Belfield and Levin (2002) however argue that privatisation policies are instigated by governments through a variety of mechanisms, often in combination and invariably influenced by economic reality or ideological faith in free markets. They argue that privatisation is introduced by governments increasing competition by opening up the education market to private providers. Alternatively the costs of education are progressively transferred to the consumers (parents, employers, students) or in other instances education providers are afforded greater autonomy with decision making coming from within rather than from the State. The significance of vocational education as a vehicle to drive the transformation of emerging economies has not been lost on governments. Sharma (2014) succinctly describes the transformation that will have to take place across the Indian vocational training system if it is to compete on the international stage. The magnitude of the challenges that face this nation is reinforced in Sharma’s analysis of the economic upheaval that this nation is about to confront. Over the next 20 years India is anticipating a million people each month to enter the labour force (Sharma, 2014). Underlying all this is the capacity of the nation to service the skills needs that will be the driving force of the nation’s economy. For developing economies such as India the capacity to meet the skills and educational development of its population are immense and will constitute significant changes in how training is provided. Privatisation of the training system is presented as a plausible solution to the rapid and viable development of the nation’s populace. Contrary to the concerns raised within the west, the embracing of privatisation of the education system is both a pragmatic and economic response to meeting the nation’s demand for skilled labour. The ‘Three Buckets of Reform’ proposed by Sharma reinforces the recalibration of training provision in India to better align with the vocational skilling system’s capacity to provide ‘quantity’, ‘quality’ and ‘inclusiveness’. With over half of the youth in India being either skill deprived or un- employable the motivation to address these deficiencies is both poignant and palpable. This shift towards market lead systems has its detractors particularly where the explosion in numbers of private education providers are destabilising the dominance of the centralist, government funded public system. Private Training Establishments (PTEs) in New Zealand are experiencing unprecedented growth as it has maintained a liberal and open market approach to competition from the private sector (Hirtt, 2000; Appanna & Gounder, 2011). Stimulated by the New Public Management (NPM) model the traditional role of the public service provider is being challenged on numerous economic, political, global and as Gruening (2001) argues a behavioural-administrative science front. For publicly funded training systems such as those in New Zealand and Australia and the underlying classical democratic theory that has been the cornerstone of these institutions, the future of TAFE in Australia or PTEs in New Zealand as the dominant training provider is being sorely tested. New Public Management (NPM) stems from the United Kingdom under Margaret Thatcher and local governments in the United States as a reaction by government public bureaucracies to fiscal restraint and economic recession (Hood, 1991, Gruening, 2001; O'Flynn, 2007). As a management philosophy it has cemented its credentials in the teleological realm of public sector bureaucracy beyond the global north and 3 | P a g e
  • 4. been embraced within the public sectors of New Zealand and Australia. Interestingly Hood (1991) associates the stimulus that has contributed to this reformist policy of the public sector as promulgated from the endogenous and exogenous forces that Ball and Youdell (2007) identify as influencers of public policy. Gruening (2001) however questions whether NPM constitutes a paradigm shift as such though acknowledges that it is how governments in New Zealand have packaged managerial elements of this reformist movement that signify real change. In his detailed analysis of theoretical approaches to public sector management he identifies characteristics in each that correspond to those now labelled as NPM. Characteristics that encompass 'budget cuts', 'customer concept', 'competition' and 'privatisation' are on their own strategies often employed by government agencies. As strategies in their own right they are by no means revolutionary. What is transformative is that each has coalesced into a reform movement that influences not just those organisations at the centre of government service provision but many such as public training providers who have more recently been placed on the periphery of the public domain. Exponents of the NPM movement of which New Zealand and Australia had embraced was for the public service a quantum shift in administrative organisation and indirect acknowledgement that governments had continued to fail in delivering efficiencies and transparency (O'Flynn, 2007). The role of government as service supplier was being scrutinised with separation between purchase and supply of services by the State reinforcing the support of market efficiencies to expedite social reform. Flynn (2007) and Gruening (2001) acknowledge NPM as a force driving change from within though neither critically analyse the global externalities that may be driving reform. Appana and Gounda (2011) however implicate globalisation and competition based efficiencies as causal agents. Education across most OECD countries represents a significant part of their respective government's expenditure and during periods of fiscal restraint the capacity of nations to maintain funding levels continues to experience pressure from competing public demands. Growing disquiet first during the Regan presidency and continuing through the Clinton administration, the attention of policy makers was drawn to what was seen as a failure of the public education system in America (Fusarelli & Johnson, 2004). Growing criticism of the school system was directed at a public entity that was unaccountable and uncoordinated in the services it provided. Cohen, March, and Olsen, (1972) associated the policy disconnect and identified failure of the education system as characteristic of ‘organized anarchies’ built on fluid arrangements and inconsistencies resulting in lack of coherent direction. Drawing upon the management practices of the private sector, public education embarked on major reform that embraced market based philosophies where output is measured and competition is encouraged. In what Fusarelli and Johnson (2004) refer to as a 'neo-corporatist' approach, the school system was being coerced to embrace the NPM practices of corporate America where competition and the power of free enterprise were destined to deliver efficiencies and increased productivity. The ‘Garbage Can Model’ elucidated by Cohen et al., (1972) presents a school management system based on decision making that was at best well intended though fundamentally flawed. The ‘Garbage Can Model’ as a repository for potential solutions to problems may well archives its objective though as a decision making tool its effectiveness is questionable. Politically, the solution was simple. The education system required the stimulus from the commercial world to engender a sense of 4 | P a g e
  • 5. competition and response to market demand by overlaying the desire to succeed in contrast to a public instrumentality that was seen to be complacent and unresponsive to change. For the established private education providers this shift in government policy presented opportunity to further consolidate their position as a serious player within an increasingly more open and competitive market. Privatisation of education systems in parts of the world has seen the expansion of lucrative, corporate entities or ‘Education Management Organisations’, attracted by neoliberal governments that are receding from their traditional supply oriented role to one influenced by market demand. England and the United States are nations that have well established policies that have liberalised education provision though as Fitz and Beers (2002) suggest, the approach adopted is different. Reganomics and Thatcherism of the 1980s reflected a period in education policy formation where governments were looking towards the private sector as models of efficiency and business acumen during a period of increased fiscal restraint and diminished capacity of governments to service burgeoning social welfare demands. The exposure of the ‘new and juicy targets’ (Hirtt, 2002) to free enterprise or the ‘predators’ of free enterprise was the depiction conveyed by commentators such as Hirtt in reference to the Millennium Round of the World Trade Organisation (WTO) meeting in Seattle. Similar disparaging remarks were directed at private education providers in Chile with private education providers described as ‘creaming’ the system in the advent of privatisation (Torche, 2005). Zajda (2004) in his critique of global education reform argues that there is a paradoxical ambivalence by the State in their pursuit of free markets maintained under the guise of purported decline in education standards. Failure of United States education in the 1980s and early 1990s were also being questioned as student graduating were falling behind comparable nations (Milne, 1998). Milne's historical analysis of America's education policy during this period captures the attitude of policy makers at the time that attributed failure directly with educators and fundamental teaching standards. The paradox however persists within decentralist rhetoric yet surreptitious hegemonic policy of the State that welcomed privatisation as the panacea of economic and social stability. The paradox referred to by Zajda (2004) is epitomised in the United States neo-liberal and increasingly corporatisation vocational education policy that accentuates social stratification and educational inequity (Lakes & Carter, 2009). Neoliberal driven reform of education systems across many OECD nations has its basis in ideology as much as it does in economic pragmatism. In 1981 Chile implemented a rapid and expansive restructuring of its education system in response to identified inequities across the diverse socioeconomic groups. Reformist policies in Chile provide one example of an education system that has experienced radical change as a result of internal political upheaval and market oriented economic transformation (Torche, 2005), (Tapia, 2003). Chile’s implementation of a voucher system paved the way for subsidised education to be provided to the public as well as the growing number of private schools therefore effectively allowing fundamental market mechanisms to determine the future of the school system. Enrolments in the private sector schools increased from 15 per cent to 33 percent between 1981 and 1996 (Belfield & Levin, 2002). Decentralisation of public education and introduction of a voucher system was formulated around increasing access to education. However as Torche asserts the strategy only confirmed the embedded social inequities or “persistent inequality” that has been replicated by 5 | P a g e
  • 6. governments intent on broadening access to education. Chile’s liberal reform of the education sector was predicated on the decentralised provision of education and transfer of responsibility to private entities with the intent to encourage increased equity and economic efficiencies (Martinez, 2001). The socioeconomic stratification of Chile’s education system was accentuated as students from wealthier sectors of the community gravitated to the fee paying private schools. Likewise, private schools were also drawn to regions where family incomes could sustain the additional fees. The public schools by default met the needs of low income families and unlike the private system they were compelled by law to accept all voucher funded students (Torche, 2005). Liberalisation of education and access to public funding afforded to the private sector instigated an exodus of students from the public municipal system to the subsidised private provider. Consequently, there has been a marked decline in the resourcing of public education as the State relinquishes responsibility and participates as a passive observer and increasingly submissive facilitator (Tapia, 2003). As Tapia succinctly stated 'the state had washed its hands of overseeing public education...' (Tapia, 2003, p.6). Essentially education equity and access was delivered however only to those who could pay and for the public system they were to be sustained on dwindling government expenditure. Commencing under Pinochet’s authoritarian regime the Chilean education reform agenda was purported to be motivated by social equity issues and the right of citizens to freely engage with new education opportunities. Privatisation of the dominant public education system was to be the wedge that would foster free enterprise and expand education’s reach to those who had been excluded. Educational stratification that Tapia (2003) and Torche (2005) identify as inadvertent consequences of market operated mechanisms has been experienced across both developed and developing nations around the globe. While the discussion so far has focused on primary and secondary schooling and to a lesser extent university education, the vocational system has also been subject to significant change. Middleton et al. (1991) had some years earlier identified the contribution of vocational training particularly in the third world however emphasised that the function of the State was to manage economic ‘distortions’ that may arise in a training environment that was entrusting the private sector to deliver. More recently vocational education has experienced significant growth accounting for 53 per cent of all enrolments with 500,000 workers annually participating in enterprise based ‘non formal vocational training’ (Martinez, 2001). Martinez while acknowledging the growth of the private sector delivery of training, maintains that State involvement is sustained through consultative arrangements. The establishment of Regional Councils for Work-Related Education (CRETs) provides a forum by which government can affect policy under the auspices of free enterprise. Chile's education reform continue though now it is the Bachelet government that faces protests from students and the Confederation of Parents and Guardians (Confepa) opposed to further reform of an already heavily privatised system. Chile's enthusiasm for privatisation continues to generate disquiet among segments of the population with concerns that liberal policy will encourage private education providers to increase fees, further disadvantaging the poor who have no alternative other than attend an already under resourced public system (Radio New Zealand News, 2014). Vocational education has been subject to similar neoliberal reform as has primary and secondary school systems around the globe. Global economic forces and exposure to growing competition and preference towards market oriented policy has seen governments 6 | P a g e
  • 7. progressively relinquish direct control of the publicly funded vocational system. While Spöttl (2008) provocatively asserted that education providers should be focusing their sites on the epitome of consumerism and the free market reality of the stock exchange. Vocational training as with the rest of the education system were being criticised for their disconnect with the shifting economic and social demands of increasingly interconnected nation States. The era of Fordist principles was coming to an end and attention towards the capability of the broader education system to support an increasingly competitive and dynamic global economy was exposing the perceived inertia of the public vocational system to meet growing economic demands. Privatisation of VET in Australia To appreciate the significance of the structural changes that have taken place within the Australian vocational system there is a necessity to firstly look at the transformation from a historical and evolutionary perspective. Post-war development was founded on Australia’s strengthening relationship with America and fundamental capitalist policies of the then Menzies coalition government. In terms of its historical development, vocational training was built upon the desire to support those within society that were prone to the adversity and inequity of economic development while meeting the needs of industry hungry for skilled labour. For what was later to become the brand, Technical and Further Education (TAFE) the polarity between pedagogic aspiration and economic reality has remodelled the existing vocational stage. It was the release of the Kangan Report in 1974 that not only established TAFE as a name but articulated the social obligations that vocational education was to be entrusted. Contrary to views held today, Kangan did not see the role of TAFE merely as the servant to industry and provider of skilled labour but had a responsibility to service the vocational interests of all people (Clarke, 1992). This position however was later to be challenged as Keynsian economic settlement made way for the free markets of neoliberal policy. Australia's vocational education and training system has been the centre of turbulent and sometimes vibrant debate. Kim Beasley in 1974 as Minister for Education in the Whitlam Labour government epitomises the political rhetoric with the educational reality that contributed to the diminished status of vocational training. As highlighted by Rushbrook (2010), Beazley's commitment to addressing the 'Cinderella' status of vocational training was in part acknowledgement of successive government's neglect of the system though recognition of its role as a training provider in delivering the skills to meet the needs of industry. Education as a social equity debate was a fundamental part of the Labour doctrine however at a time when Keynsian settlement and the Welfare State were making way for neoliberal reform the social democratic ideals were being circumvented by the economic reality of an increasingly global economy. Indications that Australia's training system was soon to enter a new phase was intimated in the review conducted by Dawkins and Holding (1984). It was here that the primarily TAFE sector who delivered vocational training for industry was to gain some sense that change and with it their dominance was likely to be tested. Dawkins and Holding were calling for a VET sector that was responsive to the emerging needs of industry but was also able to provide a quality outcome that would allow the nation to compete on the international arena. The call to have increased private sector investment in training was the precursor to the open training markets that exist today. 7 | P a g e
  • 8. Goozee (2001) in her historical analysis of the vocational system in Australia, presents a very different picture to the one that resides today. From its inception it was an institution based on the simple premise that training and education is a right not just to the privileged but to those who k the fundamental basis upon which nation's wealth was to prosper. Though TAFE as is understood today is a far cry from how it was conceived, the fundamental social obligations that has been its foundation is in the light of the globalised economy being challenged by successive governments and the very industries it was designed to serve. The TAFE system is in many ways at a watershed in terms of its relevance to a dynamic and increasingly global workplace and its ability to recalibrate the way it provides the future training needs of industry. The significance of the transformation emerging needs to be interpreted as Chappel (1998) refers to as the era of 'new vocationalism' in which fundamental changes within the VET system is currently reshaping the future of education and training in Australia. The identity of TAFE as the sole provider of vocational training has been relinquished however Chappel argues the pedagogy and institutional practices of trainers has also been forfeited. Chappel is fighting multiple fronts all of which have some substance though the implications of change that have had a negative impact on the public system have also reverberated throughout the private RTOs though with contrasting repercussions. In May 1990 the joint meeting of state labour education ministers set terms of reference for an enquiry into the provision of vocational training in Australia as well as industry’s contribution to the reform agenda. Later to become known as the ‘Deveson Report’ the comprehensive assessment set the stage for what was to become a major shift away from the social welfare obligations of TAFE as outlined in the 1974 Kangan Report. By September of that same year, and under growing government concerns of increased global fiscal debt the report’s findings reiterated the economic imperative for the vocational sector to respond to the needs of the economy (Deveson, 1990). For TAFE this report signalled that governments were questioning their capacity to sustain ballooning training expenditure, a concern further reinforced by the economic turmoil that was attributed to the lack of financial restraint that was the hallmark of the 1980s. Deveson (1990) found that the TAFE system was failing to respond to the needs of the industry it was designed to serve, to the extent that businesses were withdrawing support for the public provider. Industry was not solely dependent upon the TAFE system to service its skills requirements with data contained in the report indicating 51 per cent of the Australian industry training market being expended on salaries for in-house trainers. The report’s findings suggested that TAFE providers were becoming unresponsive and increasingly less relevant to industry. What McDowell, Oliver, Persson, Fairbrother, Wetzlar, Buchanan and Shipstone (2011) highlighted in their report and followed over twenty years later was that the financial burden of training was to be shared by industry as well as government. Mc Dowell et al. (2011) however was primarily focused on apprenticeship recruitment though industry’s vocational training disconnect had been well entrenched. Employers having effectively abandoned the VET system in preference to customised programs that satisfied their immediate requirements was a signal for reform. The role of the State as supplier of vocational training was changing and Australia’s VET system was progressively being remodelled by market demand. Since the late 1990s Australia's VET system has witnessed a progressively diminishing role of government as the supplier of education and training. The National Agreement for Skills and Workforce Development (NASWD) 8 | P a g e
  • 9. set ambitious targets to double the number of people with a diploma or advanced diploma by 2020 and halve the number or working Australians with a Certificate III or higher by 2020 (Leung, McVicar, Polidano and Zhang, 2014). Dawkins and Holding (1987) had clearly identified Australia's declining levels of education participation and skills acquisition which presented real barriers to future prosperity. The TAFE brand was well established in the Australian training psyche however governments were cognisant of the reality that future skills needs of the nation was predicated on a training system that was responsive to the changing dynamics of the economy. Competition which was to drive training reform was constrained by the domination of the public provider as was the industrial award systems of the institutes that inhibited their ability to compete in an open market (Anderson, 2005). Belfield and Levin's (2002) analysis of privatisation based reform of the school and tertiary sectors draws a number of parallels to the transformation underway with the VET system both in Australia and internationally. Their 'evaluative criteria' sets out a framework that examines the ascribed benefits of privatisation against the inherent consequences that can be attributed to this reformist agenda. Questions of choice, efficiency, equity and social cohesiveness are objectives that they maintain form the basis of measuring privatisation's contribution to civil society. They are equally relevant in establishing some rational debate over similar changes across the VET system. Lundberg (1994) had already signalled that the dynamics of public training provision had shifted through the National Framework for Recognition of Training (NFROT) which opened up the doors for private providers and future competition. The TAFE system in Victoria has been the educational trailblazer as far as privatisation and open competition of vocational training is concerned. In July 2009 the state labour government instigated a major reform of the vocational system in response to concerns from industry that TAFE providers were failing to respond to the significant changes looming for the Victorian economy. Victoria with its traditional manufacturing base was similar to other sectors of the Australian and international community that was experiencing a shift towards new industries where they could compete globally. Research conducted by Anderson (2005) provides some insight into how the implementation of market mechanisms had impacted on the VET sector and the reaction of providers, industry and students to the new paradigm. His 2001 findings concluded that over the ten years since in what was to be the first tranche of national VET reform had achieved mixed outcomes. Creating a VET system that was more engaged and responsive to the needs of major industry stakeholders was a quantifiable and positive outcome. The VET consumer was experiencing greater choice in terms of access to education which was directly related to increased private provider entry. Social equity obligations and economic efficiencies were however compromised as were accessibility to training by small to medium enterprises where thin markets prevailed. State governments nationally have initiated variants of the demand driven reform of the VET system with varying degrees of enthusiasm and impact. Under the ‘Council of Australian Governments (COAG) National Partnerships Agreement on Skills Reform’ a bilateral agreement between the Commonwealth and state and territory governments was established that was to better align the VET system with the skills demands of industry. Victoria under the title ‘Skills for Growth’ was the first state to implement an open and contestable training market. Other states were to follow having observed Victoria’s transition to this new model with initiatives ‘Skills for All’ (South Australia), ’Great skills. Real opportunities.’ 9 | P a g e
  • 10. (Queensland), ‘Smart and Skilled’ (New South Wales) and ‘FutureSkills WA’ (Western Australia). Victoria incorporated an additional incentive under the banner of the ‘Victorian Training Guarantee’ (VTG) which with additional Federal Government funding uncapped the number of subsidised enrolments. The training guarantee was in effect an entitlement to a guaranteed training place with a VET provider which was designed to stimulate competition and access particularly to equity groups (disabled students and CALD students) which had previously been underrepresented within the VET student cohort (Leung et al., 2014). Now five years since implementation of the VTG, Leung et al. (2014) using comparative data analysis found that enrolments had increased significantly with most of the growth within the private sector. Between 2008 and 2011 private provider enrolments had increased by 300 per cent while the public TAFE provider experienced minimal change. Early data suggested healthy competition was taking place between the public and private providers and skills acquisition targets were being achieved. Victoria has been the trailblazer of VET reform though state and territory compatriots quietly observed the repercussions of seemingly unfettered expenditure within a burgeoning private sector training system. The Victorian Training Market Report (DEECD, 2014) provides some positive insight into the demand driven training reforms though overlooks the 40 per cent of VET graduates surveyed that reported that their training had not improved their employment status within six months of completion. Superficial analysis would suggest that the exploitation of an open and contestable training market was the inevitable consequence however the inherent failure can also be attributed to the deficiencies in timely regulatory control. Privatisation of education and training in conjunction with disjointed policy has contributed to the fragmentation of the sector and decline of Australia’s VET sector (Noonan, Burke, Wade and Pilcher, 2014). In Noonan et al. in their recent analysis of education expenditure data suggests that while Victoria has increased its investment in the sector other states and territories have recorded zero to negative growth over the same period. The investment disparity is further evident when comparative expenditure between education sectors indicates a decline in public expenditure compared with increased relative investment in the school and university sectors. The impact privatisation is having across all sectors of education continues to polarise Advocates for reform identify the economic reality that ever increasing government expenditure on education is financially unsustainable and limits their capacity to service such demands as public health, national defence and welfare support for the aged or disadvantaged (Belfield & Levin, 2002). Belfield and Levin (2002) pose that privatisation may be motivated by fundamental ideologies that can be attributed to the rise of neoliberal oriented policies across much of the OECD affiliated nations. It is the right of the individual to choose that is paramount as it is the right to support free enterprise. Detractors however argue that the marketisation of education places in question the rhetoric of access, equity and increased quality that free market advocates espouse. Quality education should not be determined by affluence and wealth nor should education become a commodity that generates profits for opportunistic private enterprises. Education however is well entrenched in the principles of free markets and open competition and as Hirtt (2000) argues the liberalisation of trade between nations as ratified within the General Agreement of Trade in Services (GATS) heralded a transformative shift in the role of the state in terms of education provider. Globally, 10 | P a g e
  • 11. privatisation of vocational education presents mixed response. Education budgets continue to be stretched with emerging economies embracing the injection of foreign, private investment by global education providers. Free trade agreements have extended their coverage to private education services in search of new and potentially lucrative markets. The drive to meet growing global competition through a skilled workforce is a message that is repeated across nations; large and small, and emerging economies or those who have consolidated their global credentials. The rationale that supports privatisation does not maintain global consensus though its influence in the shaping education and training sectors is profound. Privatisation in the developing world provides opportunity to those within the community otherwise excluded from education either due to financial constraint of the State or incapacity to develop the infrastructure required to support its needs. Conversely, developed economies such as the United States, Britain and Australia question the social inequities that devolution of state responsibilities to private and profit motivated entities. The threat of entrepreneurial opportunism of dubious practices of private education and training providers continues to capture the headlines however what this tends to overlook is the social stratification between those who can afford to pay and those who cannot. The policy rhetoric that often underpins the push towards marketisation of education is symptomatic of a global trend towards neo-liberal philosophies that shifts responsibility of the State to the vagaries of the free market. The paradox that Zajda (2004), Hirtt (2002), Tapia (2003) and Torche (2005) elude to is the hegemonic influence of the State within a decentralist, open market policy that promises to drive economic growth and prosperity in an increasingly competitive global marketplace. What remains to be seen is whether diminishing public provision and funding of education truly creates opportunity for all or as already emerging, simply entrench the social inequities that exist. 11 | P a g e
  • 12. References Anderson, D. (2005). Trading places: The impacts of market reform in vocational education and training. NCVER. Adelaide, SA. Appanna, S., & Goundar, S. (2011). Deregulation and control in international education: What happens in private training establishments in NZ? International Journal for Educational Integrity, 7(2), 53-62. Ball, S., & Youdell, D. (2007). Hidden privatisation in public education. Education Review. Retrieved from http://old.ei- ie.org/annualreport2007/upload/content_trsl _images/440/Hidden_privatisation-EN.pdf Belfield, C., & Levin, H. (2002). Education privatization: causes, consequences and planning implications. In UNESCO (Ed.), Fundamentals of Educational Planning (Vol. 74, 83pp.). Paris, France: United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization. Chappell, C. (1998). Changing TAFE in new times. Vocational Education and Training, 23(2), 17. Clarke, E. (1992). Technical Further Education in Queensland: A History 1860-1990. Historical Perspectives on Contemporary Issues in Queensland Education. Cohen, M., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. F. (1972). A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(1), 1-25. Dawkins, J., & Holding, A. (1987). Skills for Australia. Commonwealth of Australia. Canberra: AGPS. DEECD. (2014). Victorian Training Market Report: Half year 2014. Department of Education and Early Childhood Development, Victoria State Government. Unpublished version. Deveson, I., & Committee, A. T. C. R. (1990). Training costs of award restructuring: report of the Training Costs Review Committee [Deveson report]. Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service. Essential Services Commission (2011). VET Fee and Funding Review – Volume 1: Blueprint for Change, September Fitz, J., & Beers, B. (2002). Education Management Organisations and the Privatisation of Public Education: A Cross- National Comparison of the USA and Britain. Comparative Education, 38(2), 137-154. doi: 10.2307/3099781 Fusarelli, L., & Johnson, B. (2004). Educational Governance and the New Public Management. Public Administration and Management: An Interactive Journal, 9(2), 118-127. Goozee, G. (2001). The Development of TAFE in Australia. NCVER. Adelaide. Retrieved from http://www.ncver.edu.au/publications/574.ht ml Gruening, G. (2001). Origin and theoretical basis of New Public Management. International Public Management Journal, 4, 1–25. Hirtt, N. (2000). Will education go to market? The UNESCO Courier, 53, 14-16. Hirtt, N. (2002). The ‘Millennium Round’ and the Liberalisation of the Education Market. In I. Lohmann & R. Rilling (Eds.), Die verkaufte Bildung (pp. 15-27): VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften. Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all seasons. Public Administration, 69, 3-19. Leung, F., McVicar, D., Polidano, C. & Zhang, R. (2014) Early impacts of the Victorian Training Guarantee on VET enrolments and graduate outcomes. Lundberg, D. (1994). Calling the tune: market- responsive vocational education: a discussion paper. Adelaide: NCVER. 12 | P a g e
  • 13. Martínez, E. (2001). Financing Schemes for Vocational Education and Training in Chile. Paper presented at the Improving VET Systems, Montego Bay, Jamaica. McDowell, J., Australia. Department of Education, E., Relations, W., Oliver, D., Persson, M., Fairbrother, R., Shipstone, T. (2011). A shared responsibility: apprenticeships for the 21st Century. Canberra: DEEWR. Middleton, John; Ziderman, Adrian; Van Adams, Arvil. 1991. Vocational and technical education and training. A World Bank policy paper. Washington, DC : The World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/ 1991/05/699987/vocational-technical- education-training, Accessed October 17 2014. Milne, A. (Ed.) (1998). Educational reform and vocational education. National Assessment of Vocational Education. Washington, DC. Retrieved from http://files.eric.ed.gov/fulltext/ED421659.pdf Viewed October 1 2014. Noonan, P., Burke, G., Wade, A., & Pilcher, S. (2014). Expenditure on education and training in Australia: Analysis and background paper. Mitchell Institute for Health and Education Policy. Melbourne, Australia. O’Flynn, J. (2007). From New Public Management to Public Value: Paradigmatic Change and Managerial Implications. The Australian Journal of Public Administration, 66(3), 353–366. doi: 10.1111/j.1467- 8500.2007.00545.x Radio New Zealand News (2014). Chile's education reform sparks protest. Retrieved 26 October from http://www.radionz.co.nz/news/world/25781 6/chile's-education-reform-sparks-protest Rushbrook, P. (2010). Bringing Cinderella to the ball: constructing a federal system of technical and further education in Australia, 1971-1975. Journal of Educational Administration and History, 42(1), 33-54. doi: 10.1080/00220620903462140 Sharma, N. (2014). Private Sector in Vocational Education. Indian Journal of Industrial Relations, 49(3), 409-421. Spöttl, G. (2008). Autonomy of (Vocational) Schools as an Answer to Structural Changes. Policy Futures in Education, 6(2), 257-264. Tapia, M. M. (2003). The privatisation of education in Chile. Regional Office for Latin America. Retrieved from http://download.ei- ie.org/docs/IRISDocuments/Research%20Web site%20Documents/2009-00035-01-E.pdf, Viewed October 6 2014. Torche, F. (2005). Privatization Reform and Inequality of Educational Opportunity: The Case of Chile. Sociology of Education, 78(October), 316–343. WTO. (1998). Council for the Trade in Services-education: Background Note by the Secretariat,. Retrieved from http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/thewt o_e.htm#secretariat Zajda, J. (2004). Decentralisation and privatisation in education: the role of the state. Paper presented at the AARE 2004, University of Melbourne. 13 | P a g e