SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 109
Download to read offline
Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending
By T. Renee Bowen, Ying Chen and Hulya Eraslan
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013
April 24, 2013
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 1 / 32
Main Question
Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to
discretionary programs ?
Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous
status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ?
Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher
public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary
programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model.
A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have
enacted mandatory spending programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
Main Question
Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to
discretionary programs ?
Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous
status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ?
Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher
public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary
programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model.
A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have
enacted mandatory spending programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
Main Question
Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to
discretionary programs ?
Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous
status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ?
Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher
public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary
programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model.
A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have
enacted mandatory spending programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
Main Question
Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to
discretionary programs ?
Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous
status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ?
Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher
public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary
programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model.
A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have
enacted mandatory spending programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
Motivation
The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending
programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for
provision of public goods.
Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs.
A breakdown of discretionary spending
A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
Motivation
The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending
programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for
provision of public goods.
Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs.
A breakdown of discretionary spending
A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
Motivation
The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending
programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for
provision of public goods.
Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs.
A breakdown of discretionary spending
A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to
spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every
period over an infinite horizon.
Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure
of polarization.
Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way
to capture persistence of power
The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the
proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails.
What are the institutions that govern the status quo ?
Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each
period; discretionary spending.
Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one
implemented last period; mandatory spending.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
The model & political system
Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both
institutions.
Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect
equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and
extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself.
The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no
bargaining power of the responding party.
Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party
in power changes
Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of
polarization and are more difficult to characterize.
An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is
created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is
now not zero.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
The model & political system
Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both
institutions.
Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect
equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and
extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself.
The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no
bargaining power of the responding party.
Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party
in power changes
Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of
polarization and are more difficult to characterize.
An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is
created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is
now not zero.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
The model & political system
Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both
institutions.
Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect
equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and
extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself.
The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no
bargaining power of the responding party.
Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party
in power changes
Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of
polarization and are more difficult to characterize.
An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is
created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is
now not zero.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
The model & political system
Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both
institutions.
Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect
equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and
extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself.
The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no
bargaining power of the responding party.
Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party
in power changes
Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of
polarization and are more difficult to characterize.
An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is
created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is
now not zero.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
The formal model
Two parties H and L have to divide an exogenously given dollar each
period.
Time is infinite and discrete.
The budget is bt ≡ (gt, xt
H, xt
L) B = y R3
+ : 3
i=1 yi ≤ 1 .
The stage utility for party i from the budget btis :
ui (bt) = xt
i + θi ln(gt), where θi is the weight of the public good
relative to the transfer for party i.
Each party maximizes its discounted dynamic payoff from an infinite
sequence of budgets, ∞
t=0 δtui (bt).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 6 / 32
The political system
A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a
proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p.
At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is
revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt.
If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st.
Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets.
ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status
quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t.
The authors compare two institutions :
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending.
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the
public good only.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
The political system
A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a
proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p.
At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is
revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt.
If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st.
Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets.
ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status
quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t.
The authors compare two institutions :
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending.
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the
public good only.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
The political system
A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a
proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p.
At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is
revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt.
If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st.
Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets.
ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status
quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t.
The authors compare two institutions :
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending.
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the
public good only.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
The political system
A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a
proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p.
At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is
revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt.
If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st.
Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets.
ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status
quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t.
The authors compare two institutions :
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending.
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the
public good only.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
Pareto efficient allocations
max{bt }∞
t=0
∞
t=0
δt
uL(bt
)
s.t
∞
t=0
δt
uH(bt
) ≥ ¯U,
for some ¯U R and bt B for all t.
The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt
L > 0 and
xt
H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for
all t.
In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves
maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL.
Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in
under provision of the public good.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
Pareto efficient allocations
max{bt }∞
t=0
∞
t=0
δt
uL(bt
)
s.t
∞
t=0
δt
uH(bt
) ≥ ¯U,
for some ¯U R and bt B for all t.
The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt
L > 0 and
xt
H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for
all t.
In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves
maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL.
Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in
under provision of the public good.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
Pareto efficient allocations
max{bt }∞
t=0
∞
t=0
δt
uL(bt
)
s.t
∞
t=0
δt
uH(bt
) ≥ ¯U,
for some ¯U R and bt B for all t.
The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt
L > 0 and
xt
H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for
all t.
In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves
maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL.
Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in
under provision of the public good.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
Pareto efficient allocations
max{bt }∞
t=0
∞
t=0
δt
uL(bt
)
s.t
∞
t=0
δt
uH(bt
) ≥ ¯U,
for some ¯U R and bt B for all t.
The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt
L > 0 and
xt
H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for
all t.
In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves
maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL.
Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in
under provision of the public good.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
Markov Perfect Equilibrium
The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium.
In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo
s.
A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions
σi = πi , αi , where
πi
: S → B is a proposal for party i.
αi
: S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i.
πi (s) = (γi (s), xi
H(s), xi
L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the
proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise.
Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just
equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
Markov Perfect Equilibrium
The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium.
In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo
s.
A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions
σi = πi , αi , where
πi
: S → B is a proposal for party i.
αi
: S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i.
πi (s) = (γi (s), xi
H(s), xi
L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the
proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise.
Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just
equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
Markov Perfect Equilibrium
The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium.
In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo
s.
A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions
σi = πi , αi , where
πi
: S → B is a proposal for party i.
αi
: S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i.
πi (s) = (γi (s), xi
H(s), xi
L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the
proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise.
Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just
equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
Equilibrium
For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions :
Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current
period.
Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current
period.
The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other
equilibrium are payoff equivalent):
αi
(s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z
αi
(s, πj
(s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i.
Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium,
the proposed budget is the implemented budget.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
Equilibrium
For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions :
Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current
period.
Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current
period.
The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other
equilibrium are payoff equivalent):
αi
(s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z
αi
(s, πj
(s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i.
Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium,
the proposed budget is the implemented budget.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
Equilibrium
For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions :
Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current
period.
Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current
period.
The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other
equilibrium are payoff equivalent):
αi
(s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z
αi
(s, πj
(s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i.
Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium,
the proposed budget is the implemented budget.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
Equilibrium
Call a strategy profile σ and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)a strategy-payoff pair.
A strategy-payoff pair is an equilibrium if and only if E1-E3 hold.
(E1) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) for any proposal z = (g , xH, xL) B and
status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, αi (s, z) = 1 iff
xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] ≥ Ki (s) (1)
where Ki (s) = xi + θi ln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (s) + pWi (s)] is the continuation
payoff from the status quo.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 11 / 32
Equilibrium
Call a strategy profile σ and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)a strategy-payoff pair.
A strategy-payoff pair is an equilibrium if and only if E1-E3 hold.
(E1) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) for any proposal z = (g , xH, xL) B and
status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, αi (s, z) = 1 iff
xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] ≥ Ki (s) (1)
where Ki (s) = xi + θi ln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (s) + pWi (s)] is the continuation
payoff from the status quo.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 11 / 32
Equilibrium
(E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo
s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies
π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3)
(E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by
Vi (s) = xi
i (s) + θi ln(γi
(s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi
(s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi
(s)))] (4)
Wi (s) = xj
i (s)θi ln(γj
(s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj
(s))) + pWi (ζ(πj
(s)))] (5)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
Equilibrium
(E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo
s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies
π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3)
(E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by
Vi (s) = xi
i (s) + θi ln(γi
(s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi
(s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi
(s)))] (4)
Wi (s) = xj
i (s)θi ln(γj
(s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj
(s))) + pWi (ζ(πj
(s)))] (5)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
Equilibrium
(E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo
s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies
π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3)
(E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by
Vi (s) = xi
i (s) + θi ln(γi
(s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi
(s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi
(s)))] (4)
Wi (s) = xj
i (s)θi ln(γj
(s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj
(s))) + pWi (ζ(πj
(s)))] (5)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
Equilibrium
(E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo
s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies
π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3)
(E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by
Vi (s) = xi
i (s) + θi ln(γi
(s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi
(s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi
(s)))] (4)
Wi (s) = xj
i (s)θi ln(γj
(s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj
(s))) + pWi (ζ(πj
(s)))] (5)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
Equilibrium
(E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo
s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies
π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3)
(E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by
Vi (s) = xi
i (s) + θi ln(γi
(s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi
(s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi
(s)))] (4)
Wi (s) = xj
i (s)θi ln(γj
(s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj
(s))) + pWi (ζ(πj
(s)))] (5)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
Discretionary public spending
Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of
public good spending as well as private transfers is zero.
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ?
Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance
constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ?
Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public
good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1)
The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
Discretionary public spending
Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of
public good spending as well as private transfers is zero.
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ?
Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance
constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ?
Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public
good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1)
The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
Discretionary public spending
Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of
public good spending as well as private transfers is zero.
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ?
Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance
constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ?
Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public
good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1)
The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
Discretionary public spending
Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of
public good spending as well as private transfers is zero.
ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ?
Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance
constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ?
Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public
good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1)
The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
Mandatory public spending One-period model
Mandatory public spending
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g.
First lets look at a one period problem.
The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the
proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous
status quo g.
The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is
(Proposition 2) :
γi
(g) =



θi for g ≤ θi ,
g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =
0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
Mandatory public spending One-period model
Mandatory public spending
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g.
First lets look at a one period problem.
The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the
proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous
status quo g.
The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is
(Proposition 2) :
γi
(g) =



θi for g ≤ θi ,
g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =
0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
Mandatory public spending One-period model
Mandatory public spending
ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g.
First lets look at a one period problem.
The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the
proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous
status quo g.
The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is
(Proposition 2) :
γi
(g) =



θi for g ≤ θi ,
g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =
0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
Mandatory public spending One-period model
One-period model
These strategies given the following payoffs to the proposer i and
responder j respectively in the one-period model:
Vi (g) =



1 − θi + θi ln(θi ) if g ≤ θi ,
1 − g + θi ln(g) if θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θ
1 − θH − θL − θjln(g) + (θH + θL)ln(θH + θL) if θH + θL ≤ g.
and
Wj(g) =
θjln(θi ) if g ≤ θi ,
θjln(g) if θi ≤ g.
What is the solution to the infinite-horizon problem under the
exogenous status quo (g, 0, 0) each period ?
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 15 / 32
Mandatory public spending One-period model
One-period model
These strategies given the following payoffs to the proposer i and
responder j respectively in the one-period model:
Vi (g) =



1 − θi + θi ln(θi ) if g ≤ θi ,
1 − g + θi ln(g) if θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θ
1 − θH − θL − θjln(g) + (θH + θL)ln(θH + θL) if θH + θL ≤ g.
and
Wj(g) =
θjln(θi ) if g ≤ θi ,
θjln(g) if θi ≤ g.
What is the solution to the infinite-horizon problem under the
exogenous status quo (g, 0, 0) each period ?
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 15 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to
the following maximization problem :
π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7)
where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and
Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8)
The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify”
method.
I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main
results.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to
the following maximization problem :
π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7)
where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and
Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8)
The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify”
method.
I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main
results.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to
the following maximization problem :
π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6)
s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7)
where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and
Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8)
The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify”
method.
I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main
results.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting
point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case.
However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an
insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs.
Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its
static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value.
For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to
over-provision of the public good.
The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH
θL
.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting
point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case.
However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an
insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs.
Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its
static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value.
For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to
over-provision of the public good.
The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH
θL
.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model
Infinite-horizon model
The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting
point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case.
However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an
insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs.
Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its
static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value.
For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to
over-provision of the public good.
The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH
θL
.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Low-polarization case
Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)].
The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the
following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period
solution :
(G1) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < g∗
H < θH + θL such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗
i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗
i .
(G2) : If g [g∗
i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for
i, j {H, L}with i = j.
(G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then
γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff
Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di .
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Low-polarization case
Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)].
The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the
following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period
solution :
(G1) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < g∗
H < θH + θL such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗
i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗
i .
(G2) : If g [g∗
i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for
i, j {H, L}with i = j.
(G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then
γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff
Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di .
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Low-polarization case
Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)].
The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the
following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period
solution :
(G1) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < g∗
H < θH + θL such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗
i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗
i .
(G2) : If g [g∗
i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for
i, j {H, L}with i = j.
(G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then
γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff
Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di .
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Low-polarization case
Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)].
The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the
following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period
solution :
(G1) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < g∗
H < θH + θL such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗
i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗
i .
(G2) : If g [g∗
i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for
i, j {H, L}with i = j.
(G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then
γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff
Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di .
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies
(G1)-(G3).
First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL)
and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium.
First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7).
Denote V ∗
i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗
H) = W ∗
L and WH(g∗
L ) = W ∗
H.
Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗
i ,then
Vi (g) = V ∗
i ,xi
i (g) = 1 − g∗
i , xi
j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗
j ,then
Wi (g) = W ∗
i
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies
(G1)-(G3).
First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL)
and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium.
First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7).
Denote V ∗
i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗
H) = W ∗
L and WH(g∗
L ) = W ∗
H.
Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗
i ,then
Vi (g) = V ∗
i ,xi
i (g) = 1 − g∗
i , xi
j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗
j ,then
Wi (g) = W ∗
i
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies
(G1)-(G3).
First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL)
and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium.
First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7).
Denote V ∗
i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗
H) = W ∗
L and WH(g∗
L ) = W ∗
H.
Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗
i ,then
Vi (g) = V ∗
i ,xi
i (g) = 1 − g∗
i , xi
j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗
j ,then
Wi (g) = W ∗
i
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple
(VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies
(G1)-(G3).
First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL)
and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium.
First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7).
Denote V ∗
i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗
H) = W ∗
L and WH(g∗
L ) = W ∗
H.
Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗
i ,then
Vi (g) = V ∗
i ,xi
i (g) = 1 − g∗
i , xi
j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗
j ,then
Wi (g) = W ∗
i
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Now lets look at the case when the responder’s acceptance constraint
is binding i.e over the range g [g∗
i , θH + θL] .
Lemma 3 basically characterizes the dynamic payoff of the proposer
when the status quo is in a range which includes its dynamic ideal.
Lemma 3. Under (G1) and (G2) , if g [g∗
L , g∗
H] , then
VL(g) =
1
1 − δp
[1 − g + θLln(g) + δ(1 − p)W ∗
L ]
and if g [g∗
H, θH + θL] , then
Vi (g) =
(1 − δp)(1 − g)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
+
θi
1 − δ
ln(g)
for all i {H, L} .
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 20 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Now lets look at the case when the responder’s acceptance constraint
is binding i.e over the range g [g∗
i , θH + θL] .
Lemma 3 basically characterizes the dynamic payoff of the proposer
when the status quo is in a range which includes its dynamic ideal.
Lemma 3. Under (G1) and (G2) , if g [g∗
L , g∗
H] , then
VL(g) =
1
1 − δp
[1 − g + θLln(g) + δ(1 − p)W ∗
L ]
and if g [g∗
H, θH + θL] , then
Vi (g) =
(1 − δp)(1 − g)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
+
θi
1 − δ
ln(g)
for all i {H, L} .
Proof : On the board!
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 20 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that
we have already discussed.
The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic
effect through the continuation payoffs.
The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the
incumbent.
The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect.
Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero.
Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be
too low and this leads it to propose g∗
H > θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that
we have already discussed.
The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic
effect through the continuation payoffs.
The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the
incumbent.
The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect.
Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero.
Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be
too low and this leads it to propose g∗
H > θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that
we have already discussed.
The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic
effect through the continuation payoffs.
The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the
incumbent.
The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect.
Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero.
Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be
too low and this leads it to propose g∗
H > θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that
we have already discussed.
The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic
effect through the continuation payoffs.
The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the
incumbent.
The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect.
Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero.
Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be
too low and this leads it to propose g∗
H > θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3)
is that g∗
H < θH + θL.
By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) . This is the condition for
“low-polarization”.
Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all
g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as
well.
The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to
θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers.
This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1
where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL.
This is equivalent to
1 − (θH + θL) ≥
θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
(−ln(θ + θL)). (∗)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3)
is that g∗
H < θH + θL.
By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) . This is the condition for
“low-polarization”.
Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all
g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as
well.
The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to
θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers.
This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1
where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL.
This is equivalent to
1 − (θH + θL) ≥
θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
(−ln(θ + θL)). (∗)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3)
is that g∗
H < θH + θL.
By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) . This is the condition for
“low-polarization”.
Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all
g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as
well.
The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to
θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers.
This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1
where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL.
This is equivalent to
1 − (θH + θL) ≥
θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
(−ln(θ + θL)). (∗)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3)
is that g∗
H < θH + θL.
By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) . This is the condition for
“low-polarization”.
Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all
g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as
well.
The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to
θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers.
This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1
where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL.
This is equivalent to
1 − (θH + θL) ≥
θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
(−ln(θ + θL)). (∗)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of Equilibrium
A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3)
is that g∗
H < θH + θL.
By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) . This is the condition for
“low-polarization”.
Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all
g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as
well.
The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to
θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers.
This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1
where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL.
This is equivalent to
1 − (θH + θL) ≥
θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p)
(1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp)
(−ln(θ + θL)). (∗)
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization the Equilibrium
Proposition 3. Suppose θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there
exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that
satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i,
γi
(g) =



g∗
i for g ≤ g∗
i ,
g for g∗
i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =



0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p)
(1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g
θ+θL
) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g), where g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization the Equilibrium
Proposition 3. Suppose θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there
exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that
satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i,
γi
(g) =



g∗
i for g ≤ g∗
i ,
g for g∗
i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =



0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p)
(1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g
θ+θL
) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g), where g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization the Equilibrium
Proposition 3. Suppose θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there
exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that
satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i,
γi
(g) =



g∗
i for g ≤ g∗
i ,
g for g∗
i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
xi
j (g) =



0 for g ≤ θH + θL,
θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p)
(1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g
θ+θL
) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1.
and xi
i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi
j (g), where g∗
L = θL and g∗
H = 1+δ−2δp
1−δp θH.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of the Equilibrium
Proof : Homework!
Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the
equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw
earlier and the solution to the one-period problem.
Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium
conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals
made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) .
Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical
output from value function iterations.
It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an
equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3).
What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of the Equilibrium
Proof : Homework!
Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the
equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw
earlier and the solution to the one-period problem.
Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium
conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals
made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) .
Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical
output from value function iterations.
It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an
equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3).
What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of the Equilibrium
Proof : Homework!
Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the
equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw
earlier and the solution to the one-period problem.
Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium
conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals
made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) .
Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical
output from value function iterations.
It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an
equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3).
What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case
Characterization of the Equilibrium
Proof : Homework!
Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the
equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw
earlier and the solution to the one-period problem.
Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium
conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals
made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH
θL
< 1−δp
δ(1−p) .
Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical
output from value function iterations.
It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an
equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3).
What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
High-Polarization case
Now suppose θH
θL
> 1−δp
δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from!
Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical
output when this condition holds.
The strategy of party L is the same.
For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗
H is now above the efficient
level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates.
Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status
quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does
not bind at very high levels of the status quo.
Between gH
and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds.
Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
High-Polarization case
Now suppose θH
θL
> 1−δp
δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from!
Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical
output when this condition holds.
The strategy of party L is the same.
For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗
H is now above the efficient
level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates.
Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status
quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does
not bind at very high levels of the status quo.
Between gH
and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds.
Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
High-Polarization case
Now suppose θH
θL
> 1−δp
δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from!
Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical
output when this condition holds.
The strategy of party L is the same.
For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗
H is now above the efficient
level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates.
Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status
quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does
not bind at very high levels of the status quo.
Between gH
and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds.
Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
High-Polarization case
Now suppose θH
θL
> 1−δp
δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from!
Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical
output when this condition holds.
The strategy of party L is the same.
For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗
H is now above the efficient
level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates.
Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status
quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does
not bind at very high levels of the status quo.
Between gH
and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds.
Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
High-Polarization case
Now suppose θH
θL
> 1−δp
δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from!
Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical
output when this condition holds.
The strategy of party L is the same.
For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗
H is now above the efficient
level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates.
Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status
quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does
not bind at very high levels of the status quo.
Between gH
and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds.
Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
Characterizing Equilibrium
Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses
about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair.
(G1’) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < θH + θL < g∗
H such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L}.
(G2’) : If g ≤ g∗
L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗
L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗
L ; if
g [g∗
L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If
g ≥ g∗
L , then WH(g) = KH(g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
Characterizing Equilibrium
Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses
about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair.
(G1’) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < θH + θL < g∗
H such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L}.
(G2’) : If g ≤ g∗
L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗
L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗
L ; if
g [g∗
L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If
g ≥ g∗
L , then WH(g) = KH(g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
Characterizing Equilibrium
Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses
about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair.
(G1’) : ∃ g∗
L & g∗
Hwith g∗
L < θH + θL < g∗
H such that g∗
i argmax fi (g) for
i {H, L}.
(G2’) : If g ≤ g∗
L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗
L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗
L ; if
g [g∗
L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If
g ≥ g∗
L , then WH(g) = KH(g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
Characterizing Equilibrium
(G3’) : ∃ gH
& ˜gH with g∗
L ≤ gH
< gH < θH + θL such that (i)
πH(g) = πH(g∗
H) for g ≤ gH
and g ≥ gH; (ii) if g gH
, g∗
H then
WL(g) = KL(g) ; (iii) if g ≤ gH or if g ≥ θH +θL, then xH
L (g) = 0 and (iv)
γH
(g) =



g∗
H for g ≤ gH
g [θH + θL, g∗
H] for gH
≤ g ≤ gH,
θH + θL for gH ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
g for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ g∗
H,
g∗
H for g∗
H ≤ g
where g is a function satisfying
θLln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)VL(g ) + pWL(g )] = KL(g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 27 / 32
Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case
Characterizing Equilibrium
(G3’) : ∃ gH
& ˜gH with g∗
L ≤ gH
< gH < θH + θL such that (i)
πH(g) = πH(g∗
H) for g ≤ gH
and g ≥ gH; (ii) if g gH
, g∗
H then
WL(g) = KL(g) ; (iii) if g ≤ gH or if g ≥ θH +θL, then xH
L (g) = 0 and (iv)
γH
(g) =



g∗
H for g ≤ gH
g [θH + θL, g∗
H] for gH
≤ g ≤ gH,
θH + θL for gH ≤ g ≤ θH + θL,
g for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ g∗
H,
g∗
H for g∗
H ≤ g
where g is a function satisfying
θLln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)VL(g ) + pWL(g )] = KL(g).
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 27 / 32
Mandatory public spending Dynamics
Equilibrium Dynamics
Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low
polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗
H, then gs = θ∗
H; if go [θ∗
H, θH + θL] , then
gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in
the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go.
The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is
[θ∗
H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton
{θH + θL} in the high-polarization case.
The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the
high-polarization case may be non-monotonic.
Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any
other equilibrium under certain conditions.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
Mandatory public spending Dynamics
Equilibrium Dynamics
Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low
polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗
H, then gs = θ∗
H; if go [θ∗
H, θH + θL] , then
gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in
the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go.
The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is
[θ∗
H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton
{θH + θL} in the high-polarization case.
The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the
high-polarization case may be non-monotonic.
Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any
other equilibrium under certain conditions.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
Mandatory public spending Dynamics
Equilibrium Dynamics
Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low
polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗
H, then gs = θ∗
H; if go [θ∗
H, θH + θL] , then
gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in
the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go.
The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is
[θ∗
H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton
{θH + θL} in the high-polarization case.
The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the
high-polarization case may be non-monotonic.
Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any
other equilibrium under certain conditions.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
Mandatory public spending Dynamics
Comparative Statics
Lets look at some comparative statics in the low polarization case.
Since the highest steady state is constant at the efficient level the
comparative statics on the set of steady states is driven by g∗
H, party
H’s dynamic ideal.
Proposition 7 : g∗
H is decreasing in the persistence of power p and is
increasing in the discount factor δ.
Both results are very intuitive.
Less persistence of power results in public good spending closer to the
efficient level in the steady state.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 29 / 32
Mandatory public spending Dynamics
Comparative Statics
Lets look at some comparative statics in the low polarization case.
Since the highest steady state is constant at the efficient level the
comparative statics on the set of steady states is driven by g∗
H, party
H’s dynamic ideal.
Proposition 7 : g∗
H is decreasing in the persistence of power p and is
increasing in the discount factor δ.
Both results are very intuitive.
Less persistence of power results in public good spending closer to the
efficient level in the steady state.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 29 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs
Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the
low-polarization case and since g∗
H is always greater than θi (static
ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the
efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary.
In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the
public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state.
How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare?
Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is
obvious.
However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the
ex-ante welfare of party L.
This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are
sufficiently patient.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs
Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the
low-polarization case and since g∗
H is always greater than θi (static
ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the
efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary.
In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the
public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state.
How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare?
Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is
obvious.
However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the
ex-ante welfare of party L.
This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are
sufficiently patient.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs
Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the
low-polarization case and since g∗
H is always greater than θi (static
ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the
efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary.
In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the
public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state.
How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare?
Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is
obvious.
However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the
ex-ante welfare of party L.
This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are
sufficiently patient.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs
Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the
low-polarization case and since g∗
H is always greater than θi (static
ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the
efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary.
In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the
public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state.
How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare?
Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is
obvious.
However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the
ex-ante welfare of party L.
This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are
sufficiently patient.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Conclusions
This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of
mandatory programs.
More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good
through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of
public good, compared to discretionary programs.
The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient
and the persistence of power is low.
This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries
have enacted mandatory programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Conclusions
This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of
mandatory programs.
More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good
through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of
public good, compared to discretionary programs.
The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient
and the persistence of power is low.
This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries
have enacted mandatory programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Conclusions
This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of
mandatory programs.
More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good
through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of
public good, compared to discretionary programs.
The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient
and the persistence of power is low.
This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries
have enacted mandatory programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Conclusions
This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of
mandatory programs.
More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good
through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of
public good, compared to discretionary programs.
The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient
and the persistence of power is low.
This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries
have enacted mandatory programs.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Extensions
Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to
this intuitively.
Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget
this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget
each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period.
The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public
good to parties to be stochastic.
Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the
value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there
might be over provision of the public good.
Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Extensions
Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to
this intuitively.
Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget
this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget
each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period.
The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public
good to parties to be stochastic.
Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the
value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there
might be over provision of the public good.
Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Extensions
Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to
this intuitively.
Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget
this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget
each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period.
The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public
good to parties to be stochastic.
Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the
value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there
might be over provision of the public good.
Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Extensions
Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to
this intuitively.
Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget
this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget
each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period.
The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public
good to parties to be stochastic.
Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the
value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there
might be over provision of the public good.
Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts
Extensions
Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to
this intuitively.
Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget
this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget
each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period.
The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public
good to parties to be stochastic.
Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the
value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there
might be over provision of the public good.
Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice.
Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32

More Related Content

Similar to Bowen, chen __eraslan

Political Economy of Health Care Financing Reforms
Political Economy of Health Care Financing ReformsPolitical Economy of Health Care Financing Reforms
Political Economy of Health Care Financing ReformsHFG Project
 
Political economy of healthcare financing reforms
Political economy of healthcare financing reformsPolitical economy of healthcare financing reforms
Political economy of healthcare financing reformsHFG Project
 
Introduction to policy_making_process
Introduction to policy_making_processIntroduction to policy_making_process
Introduction to policy_making_processpasicUganda
 
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022TechSoup
 
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F Bancien
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F BancienPolicy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F Bancien
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F BancienDer Na Fuente Bella
 
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementation
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementationPublic relations in policy evaluation and implementation
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementationBolaji Okusaga
 
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docx
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docxGetty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docx
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docxhanneloremccaffery
 
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentation
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentationAhmad rashid jamal final presentation
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentationahmadrashidjamal
 
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docx
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docxCHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docx
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docxchristinemaritza
 
Public finance
Public finance Public finance
Public finance Tarek Aziz
 
Process of public policy
Process of public policyProcess of public policy
Process of public policyM Ali Kemal
 
eGovernment measurement for policy makers
eGovernment measurement for policy makerseGovernment measurement for policy makers
eGovernment measurement for policy makersePractice.eu
 
Stiglitz
StiglitzStiglitz
StiglitzM R
 
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private Sectors
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private SectorsEffective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private Sectors
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private SectorsE Rey Garcia, MPA, DCS-EIS Candidate
 
POV Leroy White presentation
POV Leroy White presentationPOV Leroy White presentation
POV Leroy White presentationSWF
 

Similar to Bowen, chen __eraslan (20)

Political Economy of Health Care Financing Reforms
Political Economy of Health Care Financing ReformsPolitical Economy of Health Care Financing Reforms
Political Economy of Health Care Financing Reforms
 
Political economy of healthcare financing reforms
Political economy of healthcare financing reformsPolitical economy of healthcare financing reforms
Political economy of healthcare financing reforms
 
Introduction to policy_making_process
Introduction to policy_making_processIntroduction to policy_making_process
Introduction to policy_making_process
 
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022
Building a Grant Strategy for 2021-2022
 
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F Bancien
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F BancienPolicy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F Bancien
Policy report final by Merlinda D Gorriceta, Joy S Sumortin, Derna F Bancien
 
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementation
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementationPublic relations in policy evaluation and implementation
Public relations in policy evaluation and implementation
 
Policy Making
Policy MakingPolicy Making
Policy Making
 
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docx
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docxGetty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docx
Getty ImagesLearning ObjectivesIn this c.docx
 
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentation
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentationAhmad rashid jamal final presentation
Ahmad rashid jamal final presentation
 
Ch14
Ch14 Ch14
Ch14
 
Ch14
Ch14Ch14
Ch14
 
ch4
ch4ch4
ch4
 
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docx
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docxCHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docx
CHAPTER 4The HR Role in Policy, Budget, Performance Management, and .docx
 
Public finance
Public finance Public finance
Public finance
 
Process of public policy
Process of public policyProcess of public policy
Process of public policy
 
eGovernment measurement for policy makers
eGovernment measurement for policy makerseGovernment measurement for policy makers
eGovernment measurement for policy makers
 
THEORETICAL APPROACHES TO PUBLIC POLICY
THEORETICAL APPROACHES TO PUBLIC POLICYTHEORETICAL APPROACHES TO PUBLIC POLICY
THEORETICAL APPROACHES TO PUBLIC POLICY
 
Stiglitz
StiglitzStiglitz
Stiglitz
 
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private Sectors
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private SectorsEffective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private Sectors
Effective Collaboration: Across Public, Nonprofit, and Private Sectors
 
POV Leroy White presentation
POV Leroy White presentationPOV Leroy White presentation
POV Leroy White presentation
 

Recently uploaded

Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...
Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...
Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...gurkirankumar98700
 
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...Igalia
 
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101Paola De la Torre
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking MenDelhi Call girls
 
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt Robison
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt RobisonData Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt Robison
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt RobisonAnna Loughnan Colquhoun
 
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptx
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptxMaximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptx
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptxOnBoard
 
🐬 The future of MySQL is Postgres 🐘
🐬  The future of MySQL is Postgres   🐘🐬  The future of MySQL is Postgres   🐘
🐬 The future of MySQL is Postgres 🐘RTylerCroy
 
Slack Application Development 101 Slides
Slack Application Development 101 SlidesSlack Application Development 101 Slides
Slack Application Development 101 Slidespraypatel2
 
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreter
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreterPresentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreter
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreternaman860154
 
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed texts
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed textsHandwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed texts
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed textsMaria Levchenko
 
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdfhans926745
 
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure serviceWhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure servicePooja Nehwal
 
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time Automation
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time AutomationFrom Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time Automation
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time AutomationSafe Software
 
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024The Digital Insurer
 
How to convert PDF to text with Nanonets
How to convert PDF to text with NanonetsHow to convert PDF to text with Nanonets
How to convert PDF to text with Nanonetsnaman860154
 
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhi
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | DelhiFULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhi
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhisoniya singh
 
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivity
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivityBoost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivity
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivityPrincipled Technologies
 
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...Alan Dix
 
Understanding the Laravel MVC Architecture
Understanding the Laravel MVC ArchitectureUnderstanding the Laravel MVC Architecture
Understanding the Laravel MVC ArchitecturePixlogix Infotech
 
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)Allon Mureinik
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...
Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...
Kalyanpur ) Call Girls in Lucknow Finest Escorts Service 🍸 8923113531 🎰 Avail...
 
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...
Raspberry Pi 5: Challenges and Solutions in Bringing up an OpenGL/Vulkan Driv...
 
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101
Salesforce Community Group Quito, Salesforce 101
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Greater Kailash - I Women Seeking Men
 
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt Robison
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt RobisonData Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt Robison
Data Cloud, More than a CDP by Matt Robison
 
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptx
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptxMaximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptx
Maximizing Board Effectiveness 2024 Webinar.pptx
 
🐬 The future of MySQL is Postgres 🐘
🐬  The future of MySQL is Postgres   🐘🐬  The future of MySQL is Postgres   🐘
🐬 The future of MySQL is Postgres 🐘
 
Slack Application Development 101 Slides
Slack Application Development 101 SlidesSlack Application Development 101 Slides
Slack Application Development 101 Slides
 
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreter
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreterPresentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreter
Presentation on how to chat with PDF using ChatGPT code interpreter
 
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed texts
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed textsHandwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed texts
Handwritten Text Recognition for manuscripts and early printed texts
 
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf
[2024]Digital Global Overview Report 2024 Meltwater.pdf
 
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure serviceWhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 9892124323 ✓Call Girls In Kalyan ( Mumbai ) secure service
 
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time Automation
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time AutomationFrom Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time Automation
From Event to Action: Accelerate Your Decision Making with Real-Time Automation
 
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024
Finology Group – Insurtech Innovation Award 2024
 
How to convert PDF to text with Nanonets
How to convert PDF to text with NanonetsHow to convert PDF to text with Nanonets
How to convert PDF to text with Nanonets
 
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhi
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | DelhiFULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhi
FULL ENJOY 🔝 8264348440 🔝 Call Girls in Diplomatic Enclave | Delhi
 
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivity
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivityBoost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivity
Boost PC performance: How more available memory can improve productivity
 
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...
Swan(sea) Song – personal research during my six years at Swansea ... and bey...
 
Understanding the Laravel MVC Architecture
Understanding the Laravel MVC ArchitectureUnderstanding the Laravel MVC Architecture
Understanding the Laravel MVC Architecture
 
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)
Injustice - Developers Among Us (SciFiDevCon 2024)
 

Bowen, chen __eraslan

  • 1. Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending By T. Renee Bowen, Ying Chen and Hulya Eraslan Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 April 24, 2013 Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 1 / 32
  • 2. Main Question Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to discretionary programs ? Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ? Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model. A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have enacted mandatory spending programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
  • 3. Main Question Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to discretionary programs ? Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ? Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model. A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have enacted mandatory spending programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
  • 4. Main Question Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to discretionary programs ? Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ? Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model. A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have enacted mandatory spending programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
  • 5. Main Question Do mandatory spending programs improve efficiency compared to discretionary programs ? Methodological question : What is the impact of an endogenous status quo on the policy decisions of political parties ? Main Result in a nutshell : Mandatory Programs result in higher public good spending and they ex-ante pareto dominate discretionary programs under certain parametric assumptions of the model. A possible positive explanation of why so many countries have enacted mandatory spending programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 2 / 32
  • 6. Motivation The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for provision of public goods. Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs. A breakdown of discretionary spending A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
  • 7. Motivation The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for provision of public goods. Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs. A breakdown of discretionary spending A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
  • 8. Motivation The authors are interested in the role of mandatory spending programs in driving budget negotiations and the implications for provision of public goods. Mandatory programs vs Discretionary programs. A breakdown of discretionary spending A closer look at Mandatroy programs and their magnitude Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 3 / 32
  • 9. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 10. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 11. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 12. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 13. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 14. The model & political system The parties decide how to allocate an exogenously given budget to spending on a public good and private transfers to each party in every period over an infinite horizon. Parties differ in the value they attach to the public good : A measure of polarization. Each period a party is randomly selected to make a proposal : A way to capture persistence of power The proposer makes a take it or leave it offer, if accepted the proposal is implemented otherwise the status quo prevails. What are the institutions that govern the status quo ? Exogenous status quo, public good spending is equal to 0 each period; discretionary spending. Endogenous status quo, public spending is equal to the one implemented last period; mandatory spending. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 4 / 32
  • 15. The model & political system Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both institutions. Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself. The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no bargaining power of the responding party. Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party in power changes Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of polarization and are more difficult to characterize. An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is now not zero. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
  • 16. The model & political system Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both institutions. Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself. The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no bargaining power of the responding party. Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party in power changes Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of polarization and are more difficult to characterize. An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is now not zero. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
  • 17. The model & political system Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both institutions. Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself. The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no bargaining power of the responding party. Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party in power changes Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of polarization and are more difficult to characterize. An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is now not zero. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
  • 18. The model & political system Status quo allocation to private transfers is zero under both institutions. Under discretionary spending, in the unique markov perfect equilibrium, the party in power under-provides the public good and extracts the maximum possible private transfer for itself. The reasons : No dynamic linkages under discretionary spending, no bargaining power of the responding party. Thus the level of public good spending changes only when the party in power changes Under mandatory spending, equilibrium are governed by the degree of polarization and are more difficult to characterize. An important channel for insurance against power fluctuations is created under mandatory programs, because the status quo payoff is now not zero. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 5 / 32
  • 19. The formal model Two parties H and L have to divide an exogenously given dollar each period. Time is infinite and discrete. The budget is bt ≡ (gt, xt H, xt L) B = y R3 + : 3 i=1 yi ≤ 1 . The stage utility for party i from the budget btis : ui (bt) = xt i + θi ln(gt), where θi is the weight of the public good relative to the transfer for party i. Each party maximizes its discounted dynamic payoff from an infinite sequence of budgets, ∞ t=0 δtui (bt). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 6 / 32
  • 20. The political system A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p. At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt. If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st. Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets. ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t. The authors compare two institutions : ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending. ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the public good only. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
  • 21. The political system A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p. At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt. If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st. Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets. ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t. The authors compare two institutions : ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending. ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the public good only. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
  • 22. The political system A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p. At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt. If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st. Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets. ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t. The authors compare two institutions : ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending. ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the public good only. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
  • 23. The political system A political system with unanimity rule, the probability of being a proposer is markovian. Probability of re-election is p. At the beginning of each time period the identity of the proposer is revealed. The proposer makes an offer zt. If the responding party agrees then bt = zt, otherwise bt = st. Let S ⊆ B be the set of all feasible status quo budgets. ζ : B → S is a function that maps the budget in period t to status quo in period t + 1. So st+1 = ζ(bt) for all t. The authors compare two institutions : ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) for any b; discretionary spending. ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) ; mandatory spending on the public good only. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 7 / 32
  • 24. Pareto efficient allocations max{bt }∞ t=0 ∞ t=0 δt uL(bt ) s.t ∞ t=0 δt uH(bt ) ≥ ¯U, for some ¯U R and bt B for all t. The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt L > 0 and xt H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for all t. In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL. Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in under provision of the public good. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
  • 25. Pareto efficient allocations max{bt }∞ t=0 ∞ t=0 δt uL(bt ) s.t ∞ t=0 δt uH(bt ) ≥ ¯U, for some ¯U R and bt B for all t. The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt L > 0 and xt H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for all t. In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL. Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in under provision of the public good. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
  • 26. Pareto efficient allocations max{bt }∞ t=0 ∞ t=0 δt uL(bt ) s.t ∞ t=0 δt uH(bt ) ≥ ¯U, for some ¯U R and bt B for all t. The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt L > 0 and xt H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for all t. In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL. Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in under provision of the public good. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
  • 27. Pareto efficient allocations max{bt }∞ t=0 ∞ t=0 δt uL(bt ) s.t ∞ t=0 δt uH(bt ) ≥ ¯U, for some ¯U R and bt B for all t. The result : For any Pareto efficient allocation with xt L > 0 and xt H > 0 for some t and t , it must be the case that gt = θH + θL for all t. In contrast the dictator level in any period for party i solves maxg (1 − g) + θi ln(g) and is maximized at θi < θH + θL. Hence party I’s ideal level of public good in any period results in under provision of the public good. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 8 / 32
  • 28. Markov Perfect Equilibrium The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium. In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo s. A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions σi = πi , αi , where πi : S → B is a proposal for party i. αi : S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i. πi (s) = (γi (s), xi H(s), xi L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise. Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
  • 29. Markov Perfect Equilibrium The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium. In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo s. A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions σi = πi , αi , where πi : S → B is a proposal for party i. αi : S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i. πi (s) = (γi (s), xi H(s), xi L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise. Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
  • 30. Markov Perfect Equilibrium The authors consider stationary Markov perfect equilibrium. In the model the payoff-relevant state in any period is the status quo s. A (pure) stationary Markov strategy for party i is a pair of functions σi = πi , αi , where πi : S → B is a proposal for party i. αi : S × B → {0, 1} is an acceptance strategy for party i. πi (s) = (γi (s), xi H(s), xi L(s)) and αi (s, z) = 1 if party i accepts the proposal, z, of party j = i in state s and 0 otherwise. Going forward I will refer to any Markov perfect equilibrium as just equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 9 / 32
  • 31. Equilibrium For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions : Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current period. Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current period. The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other equilibrium are payoff equivalent): αi (s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z αi (s, πj (s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i. Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium, the proposed budget is the implemented budget. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
  • 32. Equilibrium For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions : Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current period. Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current period. The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other equilibrium are payoff equivalent): αi (s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z αi (s, πj (s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i. Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium, the proposed budget is the implemented budget. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
  • 33. Equilibrium For each strategy profile σ = (σH, σL), each party has two functions : Vi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is in power in the current period. Wi (; σ) : dynamic payoff for party i if it is the responder in the current period. The authors restrict attention to equilibrium in which (all other equilibrium are payoff equivalent): αi (s, z) = 1 when party i is indifferent between s and z αi (s, πj (s)) = 1 ∀ s S, i, j {H, L} with j = i. Equilibrium proposals are always accepted and so in such equilibrium, the proposed budget is the implemented budget. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 10 / 32
  • 34. Equilibrium Call a strategy profile σ and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)a strategy-payoff pair. A strategy-payoff pair is an equilibrium if and only if E1-E3 hold. (E1) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) for any proposal z = (g , xH, xL) B and status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, αi (s, z) = 1 iff xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] ≥ Ki (s) (1) where Ki (s) = xi + θi ln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (s) + pWi (s)] is the continuation payoff from the status quo. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 11 / 32
  • 35. Equilibrium Call a strategy profile σ and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)a strategy-payoff pair. A strategy-payoff pair is an equilibrium if and only if E1-E3 hold. (E1) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) for any proposal z = (g , xH, xL) B and status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, αi (s, z) = 1 iff xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] ≥ Ki (s) (1) where Ki (s) = xi + θi ln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (s) + pWi (s)] is the continuation payoff from the status quo. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 11 / 32
  • 36. Equilibrium (E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3) (E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by Vi (s) = xi i (s) + θi ln(γi (s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi (s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi (s)))] (4) Wi (s) = xj i (s)θi ln(γj (s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj (s))) + pWi (ζ(πj (s)))] (5) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
  • 37. Equilibrium (E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3) (E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by Vi (s) = xi i (s) + θi ln(γi (s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi (s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi (s)))] (4) Wi (s) = xj i (s)θi ln(γj (s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj (s))) + pWi (ζ(πj (s)))] (5) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
  • 38. Equilibrium (E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3) (E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by Vi (s) = xi i (s) + θi ln(γi (s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi (s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi (s)))] (4) Wi (s) = xj i (s)θi ln(γj (s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj (s))) + pWi (ζ(πj (s)))] (5) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
  • 39. Equilibrium (E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3) (E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by Vi (s) = xi i (s) + θi ln(γi (s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi (s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi (s)))] (4) Wi (s) = xj i (s)θi ln(γj (s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj (s))) + pWi (ζ(πj (s)))] (5) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
  • 40. Equilibrium (E2) : Given (VH, WH, VL, WL) and αj , for any status quo s = (g, xH, xL) S, πi (s) satisfies π(s) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(z)) + pWi (ζ(z))] (2) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(ζ(z)) + pWj(ζ(z))] ≥ Kj(s) (3) (E3) : Given σ = ((πH, αH), (πL, αL)) the payoff quadruple is given by Vi (s) = xi i (s) + θi ln(γi (s)) + δ[pVi (ζ(πi (s))) + (1 − p)Wi (ζ(πi (s)))] (4) Wi (s) = xj i (s)θi ln(γj (s)) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (ζ(πj (s))) + pWi (ζ(πj (s)))] (5) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 12 / 32
  • 41. Discretionary public spending Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of public good spending as well as private transfers is zero. ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ? Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ? Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1) The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
  • 42. Discretionary public spending Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of public good spending as well as private transfers is zero. ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ? Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ? Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1) The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
  • 43. Discretionary public spending Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of public good spending as well as private transfers is zero. ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ? Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ? Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1) The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
  • 44. Discretionary public spending Benchmark model : Recall that in this case the status quo level of public good spending as well as private transfers is zero. ζ(b) = (0, 0, 0) ∀ b B. What is Ki (s) ? Because of log utility in the public good, the responder’s acceptance constraint is not binding. So what does the proposer do ? Set g = θi every period and there is under-provision of the public good. This equilibrium is unique. (Proposition 1) The equilibrium allocation of public good follows a Markov process. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 13 / 32
  • 45. Mandatory public spending One-period model Mandatory public spending ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g. First lets look at a one period problem. The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous status quo g. The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is (Proposition 2) : γi (g) =    θi for g ≤ θi , g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) = 0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
  • 46. Mandatory public spending One-period model Mandatory public spending ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g. First lets look at a one period problem. The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous status quo g. The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is (Proposition 2) : γi (g) =    θi for g ≤ θi , g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) = 0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
  • 47. Mandatory public spending One-period model Mandatory public spending ζ(b) = (g, 0, 0) for any b = (g, xH, xL) B. Denote status quo as g. First lets look at a one period problem. The one-period problem of the proposer (suppose party i is the proposer) is the one-shot version of problem (E2), with an exogenous status quo g. The unique equilibrium proposal strategy for party i {H, L} is (Proposition 2) : γi (g) =    θi for g ≤ θi , g for θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) = 0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj [ln(g) − ln(θH + θL)] for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 14 / 32
  • 48. Mandatory public spending One-period model One-period model These strategies given the following payoffs to the proposer i and responder j respectively in the one-period model: Vi (g) =    1 − θi + θi ln(θi ) if g ≤ θi , 1 − g + θi ln(g) if θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θ 1 − θH − θL − θjln(g) + (θH + θL)ln(θH + θL) if θH + θL ≤ g. and Wj(g) = θjln(θi ) if g ≤ θi , θjln(g) if θi ≤ g. What is the solution to the infinite-horizon problem under the exogenous status quo (g, 0, 0) each period ? Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 15 / 32
  • 49. Mandatory public spending One-period model One-period model These strategies given the following payoffs to the proposer i and responder j respectively in the one-period model: Vi (g) =    1 − θi + θi ln(θi ) if g ≤ θi , 1 − g + θi ln(g) if θi ≤ g ≤ θH + θ 1 − θH − θL − θjln(g) + (θH + θL)ln(θH + θL) if θH + θL ≤ g. and Wj(g) = θjln(θi ) if g ≤ θi , θjln(g) if θi ≤ g. What is the solution to the infinite-horizon problem under the exogenous status quo (g, 0, 0) each period ? Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 15 / 32
  • 50. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to the following maximization problem : π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7) where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8) The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify” method. I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main results. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
  • 51. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to the following maximization problem : π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7) where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8) The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify” method. I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main results. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
  • 52. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model With an endogenous status quo g, the proposal πi (g) is a solution to the following maximization problem : π(g) argmaxz B xi + θi ln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vi (g ) + pWi (g )] (6) s.t xj + θjln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g ) + pWj(g )] ≥ Kj(g) (7) where Vi and Wi satisfy (E3) and Kj(g) = θjln(g) + δ[(1 − p)Vj(g) + pWj(g)] (8) The authors construct equilibrium using the “guess and verify” method. I will discuss some of their techniques before discussing the main results. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 16 / 32
  • 53. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case. However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs. Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value. For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to over-provision of the public good. The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH θL . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
  • 54. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case. However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs. Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value. For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to over-provision of the public good. The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH θL . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
  • 55. Mandatory public spending Infinite-horizon model Infinite-horizon model The form of the equilibrium strategies and payoffs is a natural starting point to guess the solution to the infinite-horizon case. However now since the status quo is endogenous there will be an insurance effect for the proposer due to the continuation payoffs. Hence the proposer will set the amount of the public good above its static ideal. Could be lower than or higher than the efficient value. For some parameter values the equilibrium outcomes do lead to over-provision of the public good. The authors consider two cases, based on values of θH θL . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 17 / 32
  • 56. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Low-polarization case Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)]. The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period solution : (G1) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < g∗ H < θH + θL such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗ i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗ i . (G2) : If g [g∗ i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for i, j {H, L}with i = j. (G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
  • 57. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Low-polarization case Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)]. The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period solution : (G1) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < g∗ H < θH + θL such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗ i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗ i . (G2) : If g [g∗ i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for i, j {H, L}with i = j. (G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
  • 58. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Low-polarization case Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)]. The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period solution : (G1) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < g∗ H < θH + θL such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗ i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗ i . (G2) : If g [g∗ i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for i, j {H, L}with i = j. (G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
  • 59. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Low-polarization case Define fi (g) ≡ 1 − g + θi ln(g) + δ[pVi (g) + (1 − p)Wi (g)]. The authors look for an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair with the following properties which bear some resemblance to the one period solution : (G1) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < g∗ H < θH + θL such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L} and if g ≤ g∗ i , then πi (g) = πi (g∗), and specifically γi (g) = g∗ i . (G2) : If g [g∗ i , θH + θL], then γi (g) = g and Wj(g) = Kj(g) for i, j {H, L}with i = j. (G3) : For any i, j {H, L}with i = j, if g ≥ θH + θL, then γi (g) = θH + θL, Wj(g) = Kj(g), and the proposer’s equilibrium payoff Vi (g) takes the form Vi (g) = Ci ln(g) + Di . Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 18 / 32
  • 60. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies (G1)-(G3). First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium. First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7). Denote V ∗ i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗ H) = W ∗ L and WH(g∗ L ) = W ∗ H. Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗ i ,then Vi (g) = V ∗ i ,xi i (g) = 1 − g∗ i , xi j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗ j ,then Wi (g) = W ∗ i Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
  • 61. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies (G1)-(G3). First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium. First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7). Denote V ∗ i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗ H) = W ∗ L and WH(g∗ L ) = W ∗ H. Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗ i ,then Vi (g) = V ∗ i ,xi i (g) = 1 − g∗ i , xi j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗ j ,then Wi (g) = W ∗ i Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
  • 62. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies (G1)-(G3). First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium. First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7). Denote V ∗ i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗ H) = W ∗ L and WH(g∗ L ) = W ∗ H. Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗ i ,then Vi (g) = V ∗ i ,xi i (g) = 1 − g∗ i , xi j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗ j ,then Wi (g) = W ∗ i Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
  • 63. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Suppose σ = (σH, σL) and associated payoff quadruple (VH, WH, VL, WL)is an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair that satisfies (G1)-(G3). First the authors establish some properties of σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) and then use those properties to characterize the equilibrium. First consider the problem (6) without imposing the constraint (7). Denote V ∗ i = maxg fi (g), WL(g∗ H) = W ∗ L and WH(g∗ L ) = W ∗ H. Lemma 2. Under (G1), ∀ i, j {H, L}with j = i, (i) if g ≤ g∗ i ,then Vi (g) = V ∗ i ,xi i (g) = 1 − g∗ i , xi j (g) = 0, and (ii) if g ≤ g∗ j ,then Wi (g) = W ∗ i Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 19 / 32
  • 64. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Now lets look at the case when the responder’s acceptance constraint is binding i.e over the range g [g∗ i , θH + θL] . Lemma 3 basically characterizes the dynamic payoff of the proposer when the status quo is in a range which includes its dynamic ideal. Lemma 3. Under (G1) and (G2) , if g [g∗ L , g∗ H] , then VL(g) = 1 1 − δp [1 − g + θLln(g) + δ(1 − p)W ∗ L ] and if g [g∗ H, θH + θL] , then Vi (g) = (1 − δp)(1 − g) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) + θi 1 − δ ln(g) for all i {H, L} . Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 20 / 32
  • 65. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Now lets look at the case when the responder’s acceptance constraint is binding i.e over the range g [g∗ i , θH + θL] . Lemma 3 basically characterizes the dynamic payoff of the proposer when the status quo is in a range which includes its dynamic ideal. Lemma 3. Under (G1) and (G2) , if g [g∗ L , g∗ H] , then VL(g) = 1 1 − δp [1 − g + θLln(g) + δ(1 − p)W ∗ L ] and if g [g∗ H, θH + θL] , then Vi (g) = (1 − δp)(1 − g) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) + θi 1 − δ ln(g) for all i {H, L} . Proof : On the board! Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 20 / 32
  • 66. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that we have already discussed. The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic effect through the continuation payoffs. The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the incumbent. The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect. Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero. Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be too low and this leads it to propose g∗ H > θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
  • 67. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that we have already discussed. The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic effect through the continuation payoffs. The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the incumbent. The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect. Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero. Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be too low and this leads it to propose g∗ H > θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
  • 68. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that we have already discussed. The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic effect through the continuation payoffs. The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the incumbent. The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect. Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero. Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be too low and this leads it to propose g∗ H > θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
  • 69. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium Lemma 4. Under (G1) and G(2) , g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. This basically formalizes the intuition about the insurance effect that we have already discussed. The choice of g by the proposer has a static effect and a dynamic effect through the continuation payoffs. The dynamic effect creates two competing incentives for the incumbent. The insurance effect vs the bargaining effect. Under low polarization the dynamic effect of party L’s proposal is zero. Party H is concerned that if Party L comes in power it will set g to be too low and this leads it to propose g∗ H > θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 21 / 32
  • 70. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3) is that g∗ H < θH + θL. By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . This is the condition for “low-polarization”. Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as well. The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers. This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1 where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL. This is equivalent to 1 − (θH + θL) ≥ θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) (−ln(θ + θL)). (∗) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
  • 71. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3) is that g∗ H < θH + θL. By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . This is the condition for “low-polarization”. Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as well. The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers. This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1 where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL. This is equivalent to 1 − (θH + θL) ≥ θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) (−ln(θ + θL)). (∗) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
  • 72. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3) is that g∗ H < θH + θL. By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . This is the condition for “low-polarization”. Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as well. The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers. This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1 where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL. This is equivalent to 1 − (θH + θL) ≥ θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) (−ln(θ + θL)). (∗) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
  • 73. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3) is that g∗ H < θH + θL. By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . This is the condition for “low-polarization”. Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as well. The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers. This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1 where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL. This is equivalent to 1 − (θH + θL) ≥ θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) (−ln(θ + θL)). (∗) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
  • 74. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of Equilibrium A necessary condition for equilibrium to exist that satisfies (G1)-(G3) is that g∗ H < θH + θL. By Lemma 4, this is satisfied if θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . This is the condition for “low-polarization”. Finally recall in (G3) we guessed that γi (g) = θH + θL for all g ≥ θH + θL. So we need to ensure that this holds in equilibrium as well. The responder should accept a proposal with public spending equal to θH + θL after receiving the rest of the budget as transfers. This holds in equilibrium if and only if αj (g, (θH + θL, xH, xL)) = 1 where xj = 1 − θL − θH, xi = 0 for all g ≥ θH + θL. This is equivalent to 1 − (θH + θL) ≥ θH(1 − δp) − θLδ(1 − p) (1 − δ)(1 + δ − 2δp) (−ln(θ + θL)). (∗) Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 22 / 32
  • 75. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization the Equilibrium Proposition 3. Suppose θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i, γi (g) =    g∗ i for g ≤ g∗ i , g for g∗ i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) =    0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p) (1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g θ+θL ) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g), where g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
  • 76. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization the Equilibrium Proposition 3. Suppose θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i, γi (g) =    g∗ i for g ≤ g∗ i , g for g∗ i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) =    0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p) (1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g θ+θL ) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g), where g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
  • 77. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization the Equilibrium Proposition 3. Suppose θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) and condition (∗) holds. Then there exists an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair σ and (VH, WH, VL, WL) that satisfies (G1)-(G3). Specifically, for i, j {H, L} , j = i, γi (g) =    g∗ i for g ≤ g∗ i , g for g∗ i ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, θH + θL for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. xi j (g) =    0 for g ≤ θH + θL, θj (1−δp)−θi δ(1−p) (1−δ)(1+δ−2δp) ln( g θ+θL ) for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ 1. and xi i (g) = 1 − γi (g) − xi j (g), where g∗ L = θL and g∗ H = 1+δ−2δp 1−δp θH. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 23 / 32
  • 78. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of the Equilibrium Proof : Homework! Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw earlier and the solution to the one-period problem. Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical output from value function iterations. It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3). What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
  • 79. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of the Equilibrium Proof : Homework! Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw earlier and the solution to the one-period problem. Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical output from value function iterations. It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3). What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
  • 80. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of the Equilibrium Proof : Homework! Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw earlier and the solution to the one-period problem. Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical output from value function iterations. It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3). What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
  • 81. Mandatory public spending Low-Polarization case Characterization of the Equilibrium Proof : Homework! Main Idea of the proof : Make an “informed” conjecture about the equilibrium strategies and payoffs based on the lemma-ta that we saw earlier and the solution to the one-period problem. Verify that the conjecture satisfies guesses (G1)-(G3), equilibrium conditions (E1)-(E3) and the assumption on αi that all proposals made on the equilibrium path are satisfied when θH θL < 1−δp δ(1−p) . Lets look at figure 3 in the paper which is an example of numerical output from value function iterations. It shows the parties’ proposal strategies for the public good in an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3). What happens if (∗) fails ? Figure 4. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 24 / 32
  • 82. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case High-Polarization case Now suppose θH θL > 1−δp δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from! Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical output when this condition holds. The strategy of party L is the same. For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗ H is now above the efficient level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates. Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does not bind at very high levels of the status quo. Between gH and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds. Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
  • 83. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case High-Polarization case Now suppose θH θL > 1−δp δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from! Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical output when this condition holds. The strategy of party L is the same. For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗ H is now above the efficient level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates. Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does not bind at very high levels of the status quo. Between gH and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds. Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
  • 84. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case High-Polarization case Now suppose θH θL > 1−δp δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from! Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical output when this condition holds. The strategy of party L is the same. For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗ H is now above the efficient level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates. Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does not bind at very high levels of the status quo. Between gH and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds. Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
  • 85. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case High-Polarization case Now suppose θH θL > 1−δp δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from! Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical output when this condition holds. The strategy of party L is the same. For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗ H is now above the efficient level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates. Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does not bind at very high levels of the status quo. Between gH and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds. Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
  • 86. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case High-Polarization case Now suppose θH θL > 1−δp δ(1−p) . Recall where this condition comes from! Lets take a look at figure 5 which is again an example of numerical output when this condition holds. The strategy of party L is the same. For party H however the dynamic ideal g∗ H is now above the efficient level θH + θL. Insurance motive dominates. Party H’s dynamic ideal is also chosen at very high levels of the status quo, which suggests that the acceptance constraint of party L does not bind at very high levels of the status quo. Between gH and θH + θL, party L’s acceptance constraint binds. Now the authors have to formally characterize the equilibrium. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 25 / 32
  • 87. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case Characterizing Equilibrium Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair. (G1’) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < θH + θL < g∗ H such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L}. (G2’) : If g ≤ g∗ L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗ L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗ L ; if g [g∗ L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If g ≥ g∗ L , then WH(g) = KH(g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
  • 88. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case Characterizing Equilibrium Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair. (G1’) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < θH + θL < g∗ H such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L}. (G2’) : If g ≤ g∗ L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗ L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗ L ; if g [g∗ L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If g ≥ g∗ L , then WH(g) = KH(g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
  • 89. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case Characterizing Equilibrium Motivated by figure 5 the authors the make the following guesses about an equilibrium strategy-payoff pair. (G1’) : ∃ g∗ L & g∗ Hwith g∗ L < θH + θL < g∗ H such that g∗ i argmax fi (g) for i {H, L}. (G2’) : If g ≤ g∗ L , then πL(g) = πL(g∗ L ) and specifically γL(g) = g∗ L ; if g [g∗ L , θH + θL], then γL(g) = g; if g ≥ θH + θL, then γL(g) = θH + θL. If g ≥ g∗ L , then WH(g) = KH(g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 26 / 32
  • 90. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case Characterizing Equilibrium (G3’) : ∃ gH & ˜gH with g∗ L ≤ gH < gH < θH + θL such that (i) πH(g) = πH(g∗ H) for g ≤ gH and g ≥ gH; (ii) if g gH , g∗ H then WL(g) = KL(g) ; (iii) if g ≤ gH or if g ≥ θH +θL, then xH L (g) = 0 and (iv) γH (g) =    g∗ H for g ≤ gH g [θH + θL, g∗ H] for gH ≤ g ≤ gH, θH + θL for gH ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, g for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ g∗ H, g∗ H for g∗ H ≤ g where g is a function satisfying θLln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)VL(g ) + pWL(g )] = KL(g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 27 / 32
  • 91. Mandatory public spending High-Polarization case Characterizing Equilibrium (G3’) : ∃ gH & ˜gH with g∗ L ≤ gH < gH < θH + θL such that (i) πH(g) = πH(g∗ H) for g ≤ gH and g ≥ gH; (ii) if g gH , g∗ H then WL(g) = KL(g) ; (iii) if g ≤ gH or if g ≥ θH +θL, then xH L (g) = 0 and (iv) γH (g) =    g∗ H for g ≤ gH g [θH + θL, g∗ H] for gH ≤ g ≤ gH, θH + θL for gH ≤ g ≤ θH + θL, g for θH + θL ≤ g ≤ g∗ H, g∗ H for g∗ H ≤ g where g is a function satisfying θLln(g ) + δ[(1 − p)VL(g ) + pWL(g )] = KL(g). Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 27 / 32
  • 92. Mandatory public spending Dynamics Equilibrium Dynamics Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗ H, then gs = θ∗ H; if go [θ∗ H, θH + θL] , then gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go. The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is [θ∗ H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton {θH + θL} in the high-polarization case. The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the high-polarization case may be non-monotonic. Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any other equilibrium under certain conditions. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
  • 93. Mandatory public spending Dynamics Equilibrium Dynamics Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗ H, then gs = θ∗ H; if go [θ∗ H, θH + θL] , then gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go. The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is [θ∗ H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton {θH + θL} in the high-polarization case. The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the high-polarization case may be non-monotonic. Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any other equilibrium under certain conditions. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
  • 94. Mandatory public spending Dynamics Equilibrium Dynamics Proposition 5 : In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1)-(G3) in the low polarization case, if go ≤ θ∗ H, then gs = θ∗ H; if go [θ∗ H, θH + θL] , then gs = go; if go ≥ θH + θL. In an equilibrium that satisfies (G1’)-(G4’) in the high polarization case, gs = θH + θL for any go. The equilibrium that was constructed, the set of steady states is [θ∗ H, θH + θL] in the low polarization case and it is the singleton {θH + θL} in the high-polarization case. The dynamics leading to the unique steady state in the high-polarization case may be non-monotonic. Proposition 6 then shows that there are no other steady states in any other equilibrium under certain conditions. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 28 / 32
  • 95. Mandatory public spending Dynamics Comparative Statics Lets look at some comparative statics in the low polarization case. Since the highest steady state is constant at the efficient level the comparative statics on the set of steady states is driven by g∗ H, party H’s dynamic ideal. Proposition 7 : g∗ H is decreasing in the persistence of power p and is increasing in the discount factor δ. Both results are very intuitive. Less persistence of power results in public good spending closer to the efficient level in the steady state. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 29 / 32
  • 96. Mandatory public spending Dynamics Comparative Statics Lets look at some comparative statics in the low polarization case. Since the highest steady state is constant at the efficient level the comparative statics on the set of steady states is driven by g∗ H, party H’s dynamic ideal. Proposition 7 : g∗ H is decreasing in the persistence of power p and is increasing in the discount factor δ. Both results are very intuitive. Less persistence of power results in public good spending closer to the efficient level in the steady state. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 29 / 32
  • 97. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the low-polarization case and since g∗ H is always greater than θi (static ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary. In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state. How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare? Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is obvious. However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the ex-ante welfare of party L. This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are sufficiently patient. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
  • 98. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the low-polarization case and since g∗ H is always greater than θi (static ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary. In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state. How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare? Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is obvious. However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the ex-ante welfare of party L. This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are sufficiently patient. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
  • 99. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the low-polarization case and since g∗ H is always greater than θi (static ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary. In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state. How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare? Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is obvious. However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the ex-ante welfare of party L. This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are sufficiently patient. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
  • 100. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Efficiency Implications of mandatory programs Recall there is no over provision of the public good in the low-polarization case and since g∗ H is always greater than θi (static ideal), hence the level of public good spending is always closer to the efficient level when it is mandatory than when it is discretionary. In the high polarization case there might be over-provision of the public good but as we saw before it is only a transient state. How do mandatory programs affect parties’ welfare? Mandatory programs improve the ex-ante welfare of party H which is obvious. However under certain parametric assumptions they also improve the ex-ante welfare of party L. This happens when the persistence of power is low and parties are sufficiently patient. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 30 / 32
  • 101. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Conclusions This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of mandatory programs. More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of public good, compared to discretionary programs. The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient and the persistence of power is low. This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries have enacted mandatory programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
  • 102. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Conclusions This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of mandatory programs. More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of public good, compared to discretionary programs. The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient and the persistence of power is low. This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries have enacted mandatory programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
  • 103. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Conclusions This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of mandatory programs. More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of public good, compared to discretionary programs. The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient and the persistence of power is low. This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries have enacted mandatory programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
  • 104. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Conclusions This paper provides a framework for the analysis of efficiency of mandatory programs. More specifically, the authors find that provision of the public good through mandatory programs solves the problem of under-provision of public good, compared to discretionary programs. The parties also benefit ex-ante given that they are sufficiently patient and the persistence of power is low. This ex-ante Pareto improvement might explain why many countries have enacted mandatory programs. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 31 / 32
  • 105. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Extensions Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to this intuitively. Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period. The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public good to parties to be stochastic. Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there might be over provision of the public good. Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
  • 106. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Extensions Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to this intuitively. Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period. The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public good to parties to be stochastic. Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there might be over provision of the public good. Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
  • 107. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Extensions Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to this intuitively. Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period. The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public good to parties to be stochastic. Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there might be over provision of the public good. Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
  • 108. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Extensions Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to this intuitively. Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period. The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public good to parties to be stochastic. Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there might be over provision of the public good. Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32
  • 109. Mandatory public spending Welfare Impacts Extensions Endogenise the status quo ? We kind of already know the answer to this intuitively. Endogenous level of the budget. When parties disagree the budget this period is added to the next period. So the level of the budget each period depends upon the policy choices in the previous period. The most natural extension is to allow for the value of the public good to parties to be stochastic. Mandatory programs might be bad in such a case. For example if the value of the public good is low and the status quo is high then there might be over provision of the public good. Endogenise the persistence of power, through the policy choice. Econ 681 Political Economy - Spring 2013 Mandatory vs Discretionary Spending April 24, 2013 32 / 32