SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 120
Chapter Six
Demand
Properties of Demand Functions
Comparative statics analysis of
ordinary demand functions -- the
study of how ordinary demands
x1*(p1,p2,y) and x2*(p1,p2,y) change as
prices p1, p2 and income y change.
Own-Price Changes
How does x1*(p1,p2,y) change as p1
changes, holding p2 and y constant?
Suppose only p1 increases, from p1’
to p1’’ and then to p1’’’.
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’

x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’

p1= p1’’
x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’

p1=
p1’’’

p1= p1’’
x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’

x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’

x1*(p1’)

x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’
p1’
x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)

x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.

p1
p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1

p1’’’
p1’’
p1’

x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1

p1’’’
p1’’
p1’

x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.

p1 price
offer
curve

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1

p1’’’
p1’’
p1’

x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’)

x1*(p1’)

x1*(p1’’)

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
The curve containing all the utilitymaximizing bundles traced out as p 1
changes, with p2 and y constant, is
the p1- price offer curve.
The plot of the x1-coordinate of the p1price offer curve against p1 is the
ordinary demand curve for
commodity 1.
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
Take
a b
U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 x 2 .

Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
Own-Price Changes

a
y
×
a + b p1
and
b
y
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =
×
.
a + b p2
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
p1 price offer curve is
Own-Price Changes

a
y
×
a + b p1
and
b
y
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =
×
.
a + b p2
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
p1 price offer curve is flat
Own-Price Changes

a
y
×
a + b p1
and
b
y
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =
×
.
a + b p2
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
p1 price offer curve is flat and the ordinary
demand curve for commodity 1 is a
Own-Price Changes

a
y
×
a + b p1
and
b
y
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =
×
.
a + b p2
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
p1 price offer curve is flat and the ordinary
demand curve for commodity 1 is a
rectangular hyperbola.
Own-Price Changes
x2

Fixed p2 and y.

x* =
2
by
( a + b )p 2

x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
ay
*
x1 =
x1*(p1’’) + b )p1
(a

x1
Own-Price Changes
x2

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
is
ay
*
x1 =
( a + b )p1

Fixed p2 and y.

x* =
2
by
( a + b )p 2

x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
ay
*
x1 =
x1*(p1’’) + b )p1
(a

x1*

x1
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?

U( x1 , x 2 ) = min{ x1 , x 2} .

Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
Own-Price Changes
*
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

y
.
p1 + p 2
Own-Price Changes
*
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

y
.
p1 + p 2

With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes
smaller x1* and x2*.
Own-Price Changes
*
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

y
.
p1 + p 2

With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes
smaller x1* and x2*.
As

p1 → 0,

y
*
*
x1 = x 2 →
.
p2
Own-Price Changes
*
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =

y
.
p1 + p 2

With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes
smaller x1* and x2*.

y
*
*
.
As p1 → 0, x1 = x 2 →
p2
*
*
As p1 → ∞ , x1 = x 2 → 0.
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’

y/p2
x* =
2

p1’

y
p1’+ p 2

x* =
1

x* =
1

y
p1’+ p 2

x1

y
p1 ’+ p 2

x1*
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’’

y/p2

p1’’
p1’

x* =
2
y
p1’’+ p 2

x* =
1

x* =
1

y
p1’’+ p 2

x1

y
p1’’+ p 2

x1*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’’’

y/p2

p1
p1’’’
p1’’
p1’

x* =
2

x* =
1

y
p1’’’ + p 2
x* =
1

y
p1’’’ + p 2

y
p1’’’ + p 2

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
is
y
*
x1 =
.
p1 + p 2

p1’’’

x2
p1’’

y/p2
x* =
2

p1’

y
p1 + p 2

y
p2
x* =
1

y
p1 + p 2

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-substitutes utility
function?

U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 .

Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
Own-Price Changes
0
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 > p 2

0
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 < p 2

and

y / p1 , if p1 < p 2

y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

x* = 0
2

p1 = p1’ < p2

y
*
x1 =
p1’

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’ < p2
p1’

y x*
*
1
x1 =
p1’

x* = 0
2

y
*
x1 =
p1’

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’’ = p2
p1’

x1*

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’’ = p2
p1’

x1*

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

y
*
x2 =
p2

p1 = p1’’ = p2







*
x2 = 0 
 


y
*
*
x1 =
x1 = 0
p1’’

p1’

x1*

x1
Own-Price Changes

p1

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 = p1’’ = p2

p2 = p1’’

y
*
x2 =
p2







*
x2 = 0 
 


x* = 0
1

y
*
x1 =
p2

p1’

 


y
*
0 ≤ x1 ≤
p2

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.

p1
p1’’’

x2
p2 = p1’’

y
*
x2 =
p2

x* = 0
1

p1’

x* = 0
1

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.

p1

Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1

p1’’’

y
*
x1 =
p1

x2
p2 = p1’’

y
p2

p1 price
offer
curve

p1’

 


y
*
0 ≤ x1 ≤
p2

x1

x1*
Own-Price Changes
Usually we ask “Given the price for
commodity 1 what is the quantity
demanded of commodity 1?”
But we could also ask the inverse
question “At what price for
commodity 1 would a given quantity
of commodity 1 be demanded?”
Own-Price Changes
p1

Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?

p1’

x1*
Own-Price Changes
p1

Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x1’ units.

p1’

x1’

x1*
Own-Price Changes
p1

Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x1’ units.
The inverse question is:
Given x1’ units are
demanded, what is the
price of
x1* commodity 1?
x1’
Own-Price Changes
p1

p1’

Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x1’ units.
The inverse question is:
Given x1’ units are
demanded, what is the
price of
x1* commodity 1?
x1’
Answer: p1’
Own-Price Changes
Taking quantity demanded as given
and then asking what must be price
describes the inverse demand
function of a commodity.
Own-Price Changes
A Cobb-Douglas example:
ay
*
x1 =
( a + b )p1
is the ordinary demand function and

p1 =

ay

*
( a + b ) x1
is the inverse demand function.
Own-Price Changes
A perfect-complements example:
y
*
x1 =
p1 + p 2
is the ordinary demand function and

p1 =

y

− p2

*
x1
is the inverse demand function.
Income Changes
How does the value of x1*(p1,p2,y)
change as y changes, holding both p1
and p2 constant?
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x1
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x1
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’
Income
offer curve
x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1
Income Changes
A plot of quantity demanded against
income is called an Engel curve.
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’
Income
offer curve
x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’
Income
offer curve
x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’

y
y’’’
y’’
y’

x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1*
Income Changes
x2

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’ < y’’ < y’’’
Income
offer curve
x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’

y
y’’’
y’’
y’

x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’ x1*
x1’’
Income Changes
x2

y

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’’’
y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’
Income
offer curve

x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*
Income Changes
x2

y

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’’’
y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’
Income
offer curve

x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*
Income Changes
x2

y

Fixed p1 and p2.

y’’’
y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’
Income
offer curve y

x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’

y’’’
y’’
y’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’ x1*
x1’’
Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences
An example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the CobbDouglas case.
a b
U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 x 2 .

The ordinary demand equations are
*
x1 =

ay
by
*
; x2 =
.
( a + b )p1
( a + b )p 2
Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences
*
x1 =

ay
by
*
; x2 =
.
( a + b )p1
( a + b )p 2

Rearranged to isolate y, these are:

( a + b )p1 *
y=
x1 Engel curve for good 1
a
( a + b )p 2 *
y=
x 2 Engel curve for good 2
b
Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences
y

y

( a + b )p1 *
y=
x1
a

Engel curve
for good 1

x1 *

( a + b )p 2 *
y=
x2
b
x2*

Engel curve
for good 2
Income Changes and PerfectlyComplementary Preferences
Another example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the
perfectly-complementary case.

U( x1 , x 2 ) = min{ x1 , x 2} .

The ordinary demand equations are
*
*
x1 = x 2 =

y
.
p1 + p 2
Income Changes and PerfectlyComplementary Preferences
*
*
x1 = x 2 =

y
.
p1 + p 2

Rearranged to isolate y, these are:
*
y = (p1 + p 2 )x1
*
y = (p1 + p 2 )x 2

Engel curve for good 1
Engel curve for good 2
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

x1
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x1
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x1
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’ < y’’ < y’’’

x2’’’
x2’’
x2’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y

x2’’’
x2’’
x2’

y’’’
y’’
y’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’
x1*
x1’’
Income Changes

y

Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’’’
y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2’’’
x2’’
x2’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

x2*
Income Changes

y

Fixed p1 and p2.
x2

y’’’
y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’
y

x2’’’
x2’’
x2’

y’’’
y’’
y’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’
x1*
x1’’
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.

*
y = (p1 + p 2 )x 2

y
y’’’
y’’
y’
y

*
y = (p1 + p 2 )x1

y’’’
y’’
y’

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’
x1*
x1’’
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
Another example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the
perfectly-substitution case.

U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 .

The ordinary demand equations are
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
0
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 > p 2

y / p1 , if p1 < p 2
, if p1 < p 2
0
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 
y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
0
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 > p 2

y / p1 , if p1 < p 2
, if p1 < p 2
0
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 
y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
Suppose p1 < p2. Then
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
0
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 > p 2

y / p1 , if p1 < p 2
, if p1 < p 2
0
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 
y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
y
*
*
Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1 =
and x 2 = 0
p1
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
0
*
x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 

, if p1 > p 2

y / p1 , if p1 < p 2
, if p1 < p 2
0
*
x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = 
y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
y
*
*
Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1 =
and x 2 = 0
p1

*
*
y = p1x1 and x 2 = 0.
Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences
y

y
*
y = p1x1

x1*
Engel curve
for good 1

x* = 0.
2

x2 *
0
Engel curve
for good 2
Income Changes
In every example so far the Engel
curves have all been straight lines?
Q: Is this true in general?
A: No. Engel curves are straight
lines if the consumer’s preferences
are homothetic.
Homotheticity
A consumer’s preferences are
homothetic if and only if
(x1,x2)  (y1,y2) ⇔ (kx1,kx2)



(ky1,ky2)

for every k > 0.
That is, the consumer’s MRS is the
same anywhere on a straight line
drawn from the origin.
Income Effects -- A
Nonhomothetic Example
Quasilinear preferences are not
homothetic.

U( x1 , x 2 ) = f ( x1 ) + x 2 .
For example,

U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 .
Quasi-linear Indifference Curves
x2

Each curve is a vertically shifted
copy of the others.
Each curve intersects
both axes.

x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility

x2

~
x1

x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility

x2

y

~
x1

x1

Engel
curve
for
good 1
x1*
~
x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
y

x2

~
x1

x1

Engel
curve
for
good 2
x2*
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
y

x2

y

~
x1

x1

Engel
curve
for
good 2
x2*
Engel
curve
for
good 1
x1*
~
x1
Income Effects
A good for which quantity demanded
rises with income is called normal.
Therefore a normal good’s Engel
curve is positively sloped.
Income Effects
A good for which quantity demanded
falls as income increases is called
income inferior.
Therefore an income inferior good’s
Engel curve is negatively sloped.
Income Changes; Goods
y
1 & 2 Normal
x2

Income
offer curve
x2’’’
x2’’
x2 ’

y’’’
y’’
y’
y
y’’’
y’’
y’

x1’ x1’’’
x1’’

x1

Engel
curve;
good 2

x2’ x2’’’
x2’’

x2*

Engel
curve;
good 1
x1’ x1’’’ x1*
x1’’
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2
Income
offer curve

x1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

y
Engel curve
for good 1
x1

x1*
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x2

y

Engel curve
for good 2
y

x2*
Engel curve
for good 1

x1

x1*
Ordinary Goods
A good is called ordinary if the
quantity demanded of it always
increases as its own price
decreases.
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

x1
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 price
offer
curve

x1
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.

Downward-sloping
p1 demand curve

x2

⇔

p1 price
offer
curve

Good 1 is
ordinary

x1*
x1
Giffen Goods
If, for some values of its own price,
the quantity demanded of a good
rises as its own-price increases then
the good is called Giffen.
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

x1
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2

p1 price offer
curve

x1
Ordinary Goods

Demand curve has
a positively
p1
sloped part

Fixed p2 and y.
x2

⇔

p1 price offer
curve

Good 1 is
Giffen
x1*
x1
Cross-Price Effects
If an increase in p2
– increases demand for commodity 1
then commodity 1 is a gross
substitute for commodity 2.
– reduces demand for commodity 1
then commodity 1 is a gross
complement for commodity 2.
Cross-Price Effects
A perfect-complements example:
y
*
x1 =
p1 + p 2
so
*
∂ x1
y
=−
< 0.
2
∂ p2
(p +p )
1

2

Therefore commodity 2 is a gross
complement for commodity 1.
Cross-Price Effects
p1
p1’’’

Increase the price of
good 2 from p2’ to p2’’
and

p1’’
p1’

y
p2
’

x1*
Cross-Price Effects
p1
p1’’’
p1’’
p1’

Increase the price of
good 2 from p2’ to p2’’
and the demand curve
for good 1 shifts inwards
-- good 2 is a
complement for good 1.
y
p2
’’

x1*
Cross-Price Effects
A Cobb- Douglas example:
by
*
x2 =
( a + b )p 2
so
Cross-Price Effects
A Cobb- Douglas example:
by
*
x2 =
( a + b )p 2
so
*
∂ x2
= 0.
∂ p1
Therefore commodity 1 is neither a gross
complement nor a gross substitute for
commodity 2.

More Related Content

More from Jan Novak (15)

Ch16
Ch16Ch16
Ch16
 
Ch15
Ch15Ch15
Ch15
 
Ch14
Ch14Ch14
Ch14
 
Ch13
Ch13Ch13
Ch13
 
Ch12
Ch12Ch12
Ch12
 
Ch11
Ch11Ch11
Ch11
 
Ch10
Ch10Ch10
Ch10
 
Ch9
Ch9Ch9
Ch9
 
Ch8
Ch8Ch8
Ch8
 
Ch7
Ch7Ch7
Ch7
 
Ch5
Ch5Ch5
Ch5
 
Ch4
Ch4Ch4
Ch4
 
Ch3
Ch3Ch3
Ch3
 
Ch2
Ch2Ch2
Ch2
 
Ch1
Ch1Ch1
Ch1
 

Recently uploaded

Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functionsSalient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
KarakKing
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds in the Classroom
Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds  in the ClassroomFostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds  in the Classroom
Fostering Friendships - Enhancing Social Bonds in the Classroom
 
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
Mehran University Newsletter Vol-X, Issue-I, 2024
 
How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptxHow to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
How to setup Pycharm environment for Odoo 17.pptx
 
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptxWellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
Wellbeing inclusion and digital dystopias.pptx
 
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptxHMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
HMCS Vancouver Pre-Deployment Brief - May 2024 (Web Version).pptx
 
How to Add New Custom Addons Path in Odoo 17
How to Add New Custom Addons Path in Odoo 17How to Add New Custom Addons Path in Odoo 17
How to Add New Custom Addons Path in Odoo 17
 
Basic Intentional Injuries Health Education
Basic Intentional Injuries Health EducationBasic Intentional Injuries Health Education
Basic Intentional Injuries Health Education
 
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptxInterdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
Interdisciplinary_Insights_Data_Collection_Methods.pptx
 
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
TỔNG ÔN TẬP THI VÀO LỚP 10 MÔN TIẾNG ANH NĂM HỌC 2023 - 2024 CÓ ĐÁP ÁN (NGỮ Â...
 
FSB Advising Checklist - Orientation 2024
FSB Advising Checklist - Orientation 2024FSB Advising Checklist - Orientation 2024
FSB Advising Checklist - Orientation 2024
 
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
ICT role in 21st century education and it's challenges.
 
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
Accessible Digital Futures project (20/03/2024)
 
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptxHMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
HMCS Max Bernays Pre-Deployment Brief (May 2024).pptx
 
Towards a code of practice for AI in AT.pptx
Towards a code of practice for AI in AT.pptxTowards a code of practice for AI in AT.pptx
Towards a code of practice for AI in AT.pptx
 
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning ExhibitSociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
Sociology 101 Demonstration of Learning Exhibit
 
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdfUGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
UGC NET Paper 1 Mathematical Reasoning & Aptitude.pdf
 
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
Sensory_Experience_and_Emotional_Resonance_in_Gabriel_Okaras_The_Piano_and_Th...
 
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptxExploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
Exploring_the_Narrative_Style_of_Amitav_Ghoshs_Gun_Island.pptx
 
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
NO1 Top Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
 
Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functionsSalient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
Salient Features of India constitution especially power and functions
 

Ch6

  • 2. Properties of Demand Functions Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x1*(p1,p2,y) and x2*(p1,p2,y) change as prices p1, p2 and income y change.
  • 3. Own-Price Changes How does x1*(p1,p2,y) change as p1 changes, holding p2 and y constant? Suppose only p1 increases, from p1’ to p1’’ and then to p1’’’.
  • 4. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1x1 + p2x2 = y p1 = p1’ x1
  • 5. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1x1 + p2x2 = y p1 = p1’ p1= p1’’ x1
  • 6. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1x1 + p2x2 = y p1 = p1’ p1= p1’’’ p1= p1’’ x1
  • 7. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’ x1
  • 8. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’ x1*(p1’) x1
  • 9. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’) x1 x1*
  • 10. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’) x1 x1*
  • 11. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 12. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 13. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 14. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Fixed p2 and y. p1 = p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 15. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 16. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 17. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 18. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. p1 price offer curve p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’) x1 x1*
  • 19. Own-Price Changes The curve containing all the utilitymaximizing bundles traced out as p 1 changes, with p2 and y constant, is the p1- price offer curve. The plot of the x1-coordinate of the p1price offer curve against p1 is the ordinary demand curve for commodity 1.
  • 20. Own-Price Changes What does a p1 price-offer curve look like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
  • 21. Own-Price Changes What does a p1 price-offer curve look like for Cobb-Douglas preferences? Take a b U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 x 2 . Then the ordinary demand functions for commodities 1 and 2 are
  • 22. Own-Price Changes a y × a + b p1 and b y * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = × . a + b p2 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the p1 price offer curve is
  • 23. Own-Price Changes a y × a + b p1 and b y * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = × . a + b p2 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the p1 price offer curve is flat
  • 24. Own-Price Changes a y × a + b p1 and b y * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = × . a + b p2 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the p1 price offer curve is flat and the ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 is a
  • 25. Own-Price Changes a y × a + b p1 and b y * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = × . a + b p2 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the p1 price offer curve is flat and the ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 is a rectangular hyperbola.
  • 26. Own-Price Changes x2 Fixed p2 and y. x* = 2 by ( a + b )p 2 x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) ay * x1 = x1*(p1’’) + b )p1 (a x1
  • 27. Own-Price Changes x2 p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 is ay * x1 = ( a + b )p1 Fixed p2 and y. x* = 2 by ( a + b )p 2 x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) ay * x1 = x1*(p1’’) + b )p1 (a x1* x1
  • 28. Own-Price Changes What does a p1 price-offer curve look like for a perfect-complements utility function?
  • 29. Own-Price Changes What does a p1 price-offer curve look like for a perfect-complements utility function? U( x1 , x 2 ) = min{ x1 , x 2} . Then the ordinary demand functions for commodities 1 and 2 are
  • 30. Own-Price Changes * * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = y . p1 + p 2
  • 31. Own-Price Changes * * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = y . p1 + p 2 With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes smaller x1* and x2*.
  • 32. Own-Price Changes * * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = y . p1 + p 2 With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes smaller x1* and x2*. As p1 → 0, y * * x1 = x 2 → . p2
  • 33. Own-Price Changes * * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) = x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) = y . p1 + p 2 With p2 and y fixed, higher p1 causes smaller x1* and x2*. y * * . As p1 → 0, x1 = x 2 → p2 * * As p1 → ∞ , x1 = x 2 → 0.
  • 35. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’ y/p2 x* = 2 p1’ y p1’+ p 2 x* = 1 x* = 1 y p1’+ p 2 x1 y p1 ’+ p 2 x1*
  • 36. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’’ y/p2 p1’’ p1’ x* = 2 y p1’’+ p 2 x* = 1 x* = 1 y p1’’+ p 2 x1 y p1’’+ p 2 x1*
  • 37. Own-Price Changes Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’’’ y/p2 p1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x* = 2 x* = 1 y p1’’’ + p 2 x* = 1 y p1’’’ + p 2 y p1’’’ + p 2 x1 x1*
  • 38. Own-Price Changes Fixed p2 and y. p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 is y * x1 = . p1 + p 2 p1’’’ x2 p1’’ y/p2 x* = 2 p1’ y p1 + p 2 y p2 x* = 1 y p1 + p 2 x1 x1*
  • 39. Own-Price Changes What does a p1 price-offer curve look like for a perfect-substitutes utility function? U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 . Then the ordinary demand functions for commodities 1 and 2 are
  • 40. Own-Price Changes 0 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 > p 2 0 * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 < p 2 and y / p1 , if p1 < p 2 y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
  • 41. Own-Price Changes Fixed p2 and y. x2 x* = 0 2 p1 = p1’ < p2 y * x1 = p1’ x1
  • 42. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’ < p2 p1’ y x* * 1 x1 = p1’ x* = 0 2 y * x1 = p1’ x1
  • 43. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’’ = p2 p1’ x1* x1
  • 44. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’’ = p2 p1’ x1* x1
  • 45. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 y * x2 = p2 p1 = p1’’ = p2       * x2 = 0      y * * x1 = x1 = 0 p1’’ p1’ x1* x1
  • 46. Own-Price Changes p1 Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 = p1’’ = p2 p2 = p1’’ y * x2 = p2       * x2 = 0      x* = 0 1 y * x1 = p2 p1’     y * 0 ≤ x1 ≤ p2 x1 x1*
  • 47. Own-Price Changes Fixed p2 and y. p1 p1’’’ x2 p2 = p1’’ y * x2 = p2 x* = 0 1 p1’ x* = 0 1 x1 x1*
  • 48. Own-Price Changes Fixed p2 and y. p1 Ordinary demand curve for commodity 1 p1’’’ y * x1 = p1 x2 p2 = p1’’ y p2 p1 price offer curve p1’     y * 0 ≤ x1 ≤ p2 x1 x1*
  • 49. Own-Price Changes Usually we ask “Given the price for commodity 1 what is the quantity demanded of commodity 1?” But we could also ask the inverse question “At what price for commodity 1 would a given quantity of commodity 1 be demanded?”
  • 50. Own-Price Changes p1 Given p1’, what quantity is demanded of commodity 1? p1’ x1*
  • 51. Own-Price Changes p1 Given p1’, what quantity is demanded of commodity 1? Answer: x1’ units. p1’ x1’ x1*
  • 52. Own-Price Changes p1 Given p1’, what quantity is demanded of commodity 1? Answer: x1’ units. The inverse question is: Given x1’ units are demanded, what is the price of x1* commodity 1? x1’
  • 53. Own-Price Changes p1 p1’ Given p1’, what quantity is demanded of commodity 1? Answer: x1’ units. The inverse question is: Given x1’ units are demanded, what is the price of x1* commodity 1? x1’ Answer: p1’
  • 54. Own-Price Changes Taking quantity demanded as given and then asking what must be price describes the inverse demand function of a commodity.
  • 55. Own-Price Changes A Cobb-Douglas example: ay * x1 = ( a + b )p1 is the ordinary demand function and p1 = ay * ( a + b ) x1 is the inverse demand function.
  • 56. Own-Price Changes A perfect-complements example: y * x1 = p1 + p 2 is the ordinary demand function and p1 = y − p2 * x1 is the inverse demand function.
  • 57. Income Changes How does the value of x1*(p1,p2,y) change as y changes, holding both p1 and p2 constant?
  • 58. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x1
  • 59. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x1
  • 60. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1
  • 61. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1
  • 62. Income Changes A plot of quantity demanded against income is called an Engel curve.
  • 63. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1
  • 64. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ y y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1*
  • 65. Income Changes x2 Fixed p1 and p2. y’ < y’’ < y’’’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ y y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 66. Income Changes x2 y Fixed p1 and p2. y’’’ y’’ y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2*
  • 67. Income Changes x2 y Fixed p1 and p2. y’’’ y’’ y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y’ Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2*
  • 68. Income Changes x2 y Fixed p1 and p2. y’’’ y’’ y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y’ Income offer curve y x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2* Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 69. Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences An example of computing the equations of Engel curves; the CobbDouglas case. a b U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 x 2 . The ordinary demand equations are * x1 = ay by * ; x2 = . ( a + b )p1 ( a + b )p 2
  • 70. Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences * x1 = ay by * ; x2 = . ( a + b )p1 ( a + b )p 2 Rearranged to isolate y, these are: ( a + b )p1 * y= x1 Engel curve for good 1 a ( a + b )p 2 * y= x 2 Engel curve for good 2 b
  • 71. Income Changes and CobbDouglas Preferences y y ( a + b )p1 * y= x1 a Engel curve for good 1 x1 * ( a + b )p 2 * y= x2 b x2* Engel curve for good 2
  • 72. Income Changes and PerfectlyComplementary Preferences Another example of computing the equations of Engel curves; the perfectly-complementary case. U( x1 , x 2 ) = min{ x1 , x 2} . The ordinary demand equations are * * x1 = x 2 = y . p1 + p 2
  • 73. Income Changes and PerfectlyComplementary Preferences * * x1 = x 2 = y . p1 + p 2 Rearranged to isolate y, these are: * y = (p1 + p 2 )x1 * y = (p1 + p 2 )x 2 Engel curve for good 1 Engel curve for good 2
  • 74. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. x2 x1
  • 75. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x1
  • 76. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x1
  • 77. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’ < y’’ < y’’’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1
  • 78. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y x2’’’ x2’’ x2’ y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 79. Income Changes y Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’’’ y’’ y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y’ Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 x2*
  • 80. Income Changes y Fixed p1 and p2. x2 y’’’ y’’ y’ < y’’ < y’’’ y’ y x2’’’ x2’’ x2’ y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2* Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 81. Income Changes Fixed p1 and p2. * y = (p1 + p 2 )x 2 y y’’’ y’’ y’ y * y = (p1 + p 2 )x1 y’’’ y’’ y’ Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2* Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 82. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences Another example of computing the equations of Engel curves; the perfectly-substitution case. U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 . The ordinary demand equations are
  • 83. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences 0 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 > p 2 y / p1 , if p1 < p 2 , if p1 < p 2 0 * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 .
  • 84. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences 0 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 > p 2 y / p1 , if p1 < p 2 , if p1 < p 2 0 * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 . Suppose p1 < p2. Then
  • 85. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences 0 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 > p 2 y / p1 , if p1 < p 2 , if p1 < p 2 0 * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 . y * * Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1 = and x 2 = 0 p1
  • 86. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences 0 * x1 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  , if p1 > p 2 y / p1 , if p1 < p 2 , if p1 < p 2 0 * x 2 (p1 , p 2 , y) =  y / p 2 , if p1 > p 2 . y * * Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1 = and x 2 = 0 p1 * * y = p1x1 and x 2 = 0.
  • 87. Income Changes and PerfectlySubstitutable Preferences y y * y = p1x1 x1* Engel curve for good 1 x* = 0. 2 x2 * 0 Engel curve for good 2
  • 88. Income Changes In every example so far the Engel curves have all been straight lines? Q: Is this true in general? A: No. Engel curves are straight lines if the consumer’s preferences are homothetic.
  • 89. Homotheticity A consumer’s preferences are homothetic if and only if (x1,x2)  (y1,y2) ⇔ (kx1,kx2)  (ky1,ky2) for every k > 0. That is, the consumer’s MRS is the same anywhere on a straight line drawn from the origin.
  • 90. Income Effects -- A Nonhomothetic Example Quasilinear preferences are not homothetic. U( x1 , x 2 ) = f ( x1 ) + x 2 . For example, U( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2 .
  • 91. Quasi-linear Indifference Curves x2 Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the others. Each curve intersects both axes. x1
  • 96. Income Effects A good for which quantity demanded rises with income is called normal. Therefore a normal good’s Engel curve is positively sloped.
  • 97. Income Effects A good for which quantity demanded falls as income increases is called income inferior. Therefore an income inferior good’s Engel curve is negatively sloped.
  • 98. Income Changes; Goods y 1 & 2 Normal x2 Income offer curve x2’’’ x2’’ x2 ’ y’’’ y’’ y’ y y’’’ y’’ y’ x1’ x1’’’ x1’’ x1 Engel curve; good 2 x2’ x2’’’ x2’’ x2* Engel curve; good 1 x1’ x1’’’ x1* x1’’
  • 99. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 x1
  • 100. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 x1
  • 101. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 x1
  • 102. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 x1
  • 103. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 x1
  • 104. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 Income offer curve x1
  • 105. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 y Engel curve for good 1 x1 x1*
  • 106. Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal, Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior x2 y Engel curve for good 2 y x2* Engel curve for good 1 x1 x1*
  • 107. Ordinary Goods A good is called ordinary if the quantity demanded of it always increases as its own price decreases.
  • 108. Ordinary Goods Fixed p2 and y. x2 x1
  • 109. Ordinary Goods Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 price offer curve x1
  • 110. Ordinary Goods Fixed p2 and y. Downward-sloping p1 demand curve x2 ⇔ p1 price offer curve Good 1 is ordinary x1* x1
  • 111. Giffen Goods If, for some values of its own price, the quantity demanded of a good rises as its own-price increases then the good is called Giffen.
  • 112. Ordinary Goods Fixed p2 and y. x2 x1
  • 113. Ordinary Goods Fixed p2 and y. x2 p1 price offer curve x1
  • 114. Ordinary Goods Demand curve has a positively p1 sloped part Fixed p2 and y. x2 ⇔ p1 price offer curve Good 1 is Giffen x1* x1
  • 115. Cross-Price Effects If an increase in p2 – increases demand for commodity 1 then commodity 1 is a gross substitute for commodity 2. – reduces demand for commodity 1 then commodity 1 is a gross complement for commodity 2.
  • 116. Cross-Price Effects A perfect-complements example: y * x1 = p1 + p 2 so * ∂ x1 y =− < 0. 2 ∂ p2 (p +p ) 1 2 Therefore commodity 2 is a gross complement for commodity 1.
  • 117. Cross-Price Effects p1 p1’’’ Increase the price of good 2 from p2’ to p2’’ and p1’’ p1’ y p2 ’ x1*
  • 118. Cross-Price Effects p1 p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ Increase the price of good 2 from p2’ to p2’’ and the demand curve for good 1 shifts inwards -- good 2 is a complement for good 1. y p2 ’’ x1*
  • 119. Cross-Price Effects A Cobb- Douglas example: by * x2 = ( a + b )p 2 so
  • 120. Cross-Price Effects A Cobb- Douglas example: by * x2 = ( a + b )p 2 so * ∂ x2 = 0. ∂ p1 Therefore commodity 1 is neither a gross complement nor a gross substitute for commodity 2.