SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA
             Decision Making
Part of a longer, forthcoming paper entitled:“He Got Game
                          Theory”


            Matt Goldman1 and Justin M. Rao2

                   1 Department of Economics

               University of California, San Diego
                    2 Yahoo!   Research Labs

                      March 5, 2005
           MIT Sloan Sports Analytics Conference



                Goldman and Rao    Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Introduction and Overview
Winning is All About Efficiency




        Teams have roughly equal possessions per game. The more efficient
        team will always win (Oliver (2002), James(1977)).

                                              Team’s problem: allocate scarce
                                              possessions between teammates
                                              and across the shot clock to
                                              maximize points.


        We attack this problem using game theory and optimal stopping.
        To do so, we need estimates of what would happen to a particular
        player’s efficiency if he chose to increase or decrease his usage.




                          Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
The Anatomy of a Possession
Optimal Stopping Under the Pressure of the Shot Clock




         At each shot clock interval the choice is between using and
         waiting for a better opportunity
         As shot clock goes to 0, the value of continuing the possession
         declines and players must shoot much more frequently.

                           Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Two Requirements of Optimal Shot Selection


  We model a half-court possession as a dynamic optimal stopping
  problem, this leads to two fundamental requirements:
    1   Dynamic efficiency : a shot is realized only if its expected value
        exceeds the continuation value of a possession
    2   Allocative efficiency : The frequency at which each player shoots
        generates equal marginal productivity
             Effective randomization over who shoots is a best-response to
             selective defensive pressure
             It ensures the team could not reallocate to more efficient
             players on the margin (which would increase output)




                          Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




            Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers


                            Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




            Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers


                            Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




            Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers


                            Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




            Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers


                            Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




         Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Power Forwards


                            Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




         Figure 1:   ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Small Forwards


                             Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




        Figure 1:   ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Shooting Guards


                           Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Intuition
Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage


        Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different
        periods of the shot clock.
        The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage
        combinations are possible for the given player.
        The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player
        must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage.




         Figure 1:   ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Point Guards


                          Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Model
Stochastic Shot Arrivals

         In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i
         observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ).
               We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of
               the shot clock.
         Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold).




   From such a player we should observe:
                            A+ci,t
         Efficiency: ei,t =     2
         Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession,
                                                   A−ci,t
         given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi
                                 dei       −(Ai −Bi )
         ’Usage Curve’ Slope:    dui   =      2

                            Goldman and Rao      Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Model
Stochastic Shot Arrivals

         In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i
         observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ).
               We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of
               the shot clock.
         Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold).




   From such a player we should observe:
                            A+ci,t
         Efficiency: ei,t =     2
         Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession,
                                                   A−ci,t
         given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi
                                 dei       −(Ai −Bi )
         ’Usage Curve’ Slope:    dui   =      2

                            Goldman and Rao      Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Model
Stochastic Shot Arrivals

         In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i
         observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ).
               We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of
               the shot clock.
         Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold).




   From such a player we should observe:
                            A+ci,t
         Efficiency: ei,t =     2
         Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession,
                                                   A−ci,t
         given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi
                                 dei       −(Ai −Bi )
         ’Usage Curve’ Slope:    dui   =      2

                            Goldman and Rao      Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Model
Stochastic Shot Arrivals

         In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i
         observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ).
               We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of
               the shot clock.
         Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold).




   From such a player we should observe:
                            A+ci,t
         Efficiency: ei,t =     2
         Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession,
                                                   A−ci,t
         given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi
                                 dei       −(Ai −Bi )
         ’Usage Curve’ Slope:    dui   =      2

                            Goldman and Rao      Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Dynamic Efficiency




     All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the
     possession.
     If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team.




                       Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Dynamic Efficiency



     All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the
     possession.
     If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team.




                        Figure 2: OVERSHOOTING!




                       Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Dynamic Efficiency



     All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the
     possession.
     If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team.




                       Figure 2: UNDERSHOOTING!




                       Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Dynamic Efficiency: Results
     Figure shows that, on average, this is nearly the case for ALL
     periods.




     NBA players understand Dynamic Efficiency very well.
                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Undershooting and Overshooting

     We preformed a t-test of every player’s adherence to Dynamic
     Efficiency (negative is overshooting; positive is undershooting)
     Overshooting is very rare, undershooting is more common.




                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Undershooting and Overshooting

     We preformed a t-test of every player’s adherence to Dynamic
     Efficiency (negative is overshooting; positive is undershooting)
     Overshooting is very rare, undershooting is more common.




                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Who Overshoots? Who Undershoots?


        Top 7 Overshooters and Undershooters (by t-statistic)
      Overshooter          t         Undershooter             t
    Russell Westbrook -2.97838        Chris Paul        5.341594
     Tyrus Thomas     -1.983194      Brandon Roy        5.127828
      Lamar Odom      -1.942873     LeBron James        4.931574
       Monta Ellis    -1.908993      Al Jefferson        4.623833
      Larry Hughes    -1.802382      Joe Johnson        4.437453
      Drew Gooden     -1.790609 Amare Stoudemire 4.061478
     Tracy McGrady    -1.770439      Vince Carter         4.0012


     Undershooters are primarily elite offensive players who may be
     sacrificing immediate preformance in order to conserve energy.
     High salary players are more likely to undershoot (t=2.75).



                       Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Allocative Efficiency
Our Statistical Test




         All teammates in a given line-up should choose a ’worst shot’ (ci,t )
         of the same value in each shot clock period.
         This ensures the team cannot reallocate to more productive players
         (on the margin) and increase output.
         Deviation from this standard is measured by Spread (defined in the
         paper).
         We use concept of 3-man (“most important 3 of 5-man line-up”)
         and 4-man cores to increase statistical power.




                           Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Allocative Efficiency
Results



          A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation.

                                                     The majority of line-ups
                                                     achieve Allocative Efficiency,
                                                     but it is very clear that some
                                                     core’s are
                                                     imperfect(t = 8.05).


                                                     Additionally less experienced
                                                     (t = 2.70) and higher salary
                                                     (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’
   Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread
   amongst all ’3 man cores’                         demonstrate larger deviations
                                                     from Allocative Efficiency.



                             Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Allocative Efficiency
Results



          A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation.

                                                     The majority of line-ups
                                                     achieve Allocative Efficiency,
                                                     but it is very clear that some
                                                     core’s are
                                                     imperfect(t = 8.05).


                                                     Additionally less experienced
                                                     (t = 2.70) and higher salary
                                                     (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’
   Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread
   amongst all ’3 man cores’                         demonstrate larger deviations
                                                     from Allocative Efficiency.



                             Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Allocative Efficiency
Results



          A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation.

                                                     The majority of line-ups
                                                     achieve Allocative Efficiency,
                                                     but it is very clear that some
                                                     core’s are
                                                     imperfect(t = 8.05).


                                                     Additionally less experienced
                                                     (t = 2.70) and higher salary
                                                     (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’
   Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread
   amongst all ’3 man cores’                         demonstrate larger deviations
                                                     from Allocative Efficiency.



                             Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Player Usage Curves

     The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each
     player’s abillity to create shots on the margin:
          ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi )
                                de

          What kinds of players have flatter usage curves?

         Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve
     LHS/RHS        PG      SG      SF      PF      C     Usage %
      ˆ ˆ
     A i −B i
         2         2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26*           -4.32*
     s.e.          0.26    0.30    0.29    0.31    0.33     0.97
                         R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01

     Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter
     usgae curves.
     A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court
     offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by
     .0025 − .006 points per possession.
          This estimate holds teammates constant.
                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Player Usage Curves

     The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each
     player’s abillity to create shots on the margin:
          ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi )
                                de

          What kinds of players have flatter usage curves?

         Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve
     LHS/RHS        PG      SG      SF      PF      C     Usage %
      ˆ ˆ
     A i −B i
         2         2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26*           -4.32*
     s.e.          0.26    0.30    0.29    0.31    0.33     0.97
                         R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01

     Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter
     usgae curves.
     A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court
     offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by
     .0025 − .006 points per possession.
          This estimate holds teammates constant.
                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Player Usage Curves

     The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each
     player’s abillity to create shots on the margin:
          ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi )
                                de

          What kinds of players have flatter usage curves?

         Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve
     LHS/RHS        PG      SG      SF      PF      C     Usage %
      ˆ ˆ
     A i −B i
         2         2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26*           -4.32*
     s.e.          0.26    0.30    0.29    0.31    0.33     0.97
                         R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01

     Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter
     usgae curves.
     A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court
     offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by
     .0025 − .006 points per possession.
          This estimate holds teammates constant.
                      Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
Conclusion




     Thanks for your time!
     If you liked our presentation, come check out our blog at
     www.hooptheory.com
     Our contact info:
          Matt Goldman: mrgoldman@ucsd.edu
          Justin M. Rao jmrao@yahoo-inc.com




                         Goldman and Rao   Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making

More Related Content

Similar to Allocation and Dynamic Efficiency in NBA Decision Making

Similar to Allocation and Dynamic Efficiency in NBA Decision Making (7)

Game theory
Game theoryGame theory
Game theory
 
Game theory
Game theoryGame theory
Game theory
 
Unit II A - Game Theory
Unit II A - Game TheoryUnit II A - Game Theory
Unit II A - Game Theory
 
Game theory and its applications
Game theory and its applicationsGame theory and its applications
Game theory and its applications
 
OR 14 15-unit_4
OR 14 15-unit_4OR 14 15-unit_4
OR 14 15-unit_4
 
Game model
Game modelGame model
Game model
 
Game theory.ppt for Micro Economics content
Game theory.ppt for Micro Economics contentGame theory.ppt for Micro Economics content
Game theory.ppt for Micro Economics content
 

More from Sloan Sports Conference

Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL Draft
Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL DraftFlipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL Draft
Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL DraftSloan Sports Conference
 
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...Sloan Sports Conference
 
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...Sloan Sports Conference
 
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...Sloan Sports Conference
 
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...Sloan Sports Conference
 
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...Sloan Sports Conference
 
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field Advantage
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field AdvantageThe Real Reasons Behind the Home Field Advantage
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field AdvantageSloan Sports Conference
 

More from Sloan Sports Conference (8)

Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL Draft
Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL DraftFlipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL Draft
Flipping Coins in the War Room: Skill and Chance in the NFL Draft
 
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...
DIGR: A Defense Independent Rating of NHL Goaltenders using Spatially Smoothe...
 
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...
Buying Tickets: Capturing the Dynamic Factors that Drive Consumer Purchase De...
 
How Much Trouble is Early Foul Trouble?
How Much Trouble is Early Foul Trouble?How Much Trouble is Early Foul Trouble?
How Much Trouble is Early Foul Trouble?
 
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...
Moral Hazard in Long-Term Guaranteed Contracts – Theory and Evidence from the...
 
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...
Scoring Strategies for the Underdog – Using Risk as an Ally in Determining Op...
 
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...
The Importance of Being Open: What Player Tracking Data Can Say About NBA Fie...
 
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field Advantage
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field AdvantageThe Real Reasons Behind the Home Field Advantage
The Real Reasons Behind the Home Field Advantage
 

Allocation and Dynamic Efficiency in NBA Decision Making

  • 1. Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making Part of a longer, forthcoming paper entitled:“He Got Game Theory” Matt Goldman1 and Justin M. Rao2 1 Department of Economics University of California, San Diego 2 Yahoo! Research Labs March 5, 2005 MIT Sloan Sports Analytics Conference Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 2. Introduction and Overview Winning is All About Efficiency Teams have roughly equal possessions per game. The more efficient team will always win (Oliver (2002), James(1977)). Team’s problem: allocate scarce possessions between teammates and across the shot clock to maximize points. We attack this problem using game theory and optimal stopping. To do so, we need estimates of what would happen to a particular player’s efficiency if he chose to increase or decrease his usage. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 3. The Anatomy of a Possession Optimal Stopping Under the Pressure of the Shot Clock At each shot clock interval the choice is between using and waiting for a better opportunity As shot clock goes to 0, the value of continuing the possession declines and players must shoot much more frequently. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 4. Two Requirements of Optimal Shot Selection We model a half-court possession as a dynamic optimal stopping problem, this leads to two fundamental requirements: 1 Dynamic efficiency : a shot is realized only if its expected value exceeds the continuation value of a possession 2 Allocative efficiency : The frequency at which each player shoots generates equal marginal productivity Effective randomization over who shoots is a best-response to selective defensive pressure It ensures the team could not reallocate to more efficient players on the margin (which would increase output) Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 5. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 6. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 7. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 8. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Centers Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 9. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Power Forwards Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 10. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Small Forwards Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 11. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Shooting Guards Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 12. Intuition Choosing From Feasible Combinations of Efficiency and Usage Intuition: We observe ei,t and ui,t for each player in 18 different periods of the shot clock. The fitted red line is an estimate of what efficiency-usage combinations are possible for the given player. The green line indicates the value of the marginal shot a player must be willing to take to reach any given level of usage. Figure 1: ’Usage Curve’ for the aggregate of all NBA Point Guards Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 13. Model Stochastic Shot Arrivals In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ). We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of the shot clock. Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold). From such a player we should observe: A+ci,t Efficiency: ei,t = 2 Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession, A−ci,t given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi dei −(Ai −Bi ) ’Usage Curve’ Slope: dui = 2 Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 14. Model Stochastic Shot Arrivals In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ). We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of the shot clock. Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold). From such a player we should observe: A+ci,t Efficiency: ei,t = 2 Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession, A−ci,t given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi dei −(Ai −Bi ) ’Usage Curve’ Slope: dui = 2 Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 15. Model Stochastic Shot Arrivals In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ). We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of the shot clock. Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold). From such a player we should observe: A+ci,t Efficiency: ei,t = 2 Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession, A−ci,t given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi dei −(Ai −Bi ) ’Usage Curve’ Slope: dui = 2 Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 16. Model Stochastic Shot Arrivals In each one-second period, with t seconds remaining, player i observes potential shot value: η ∼ Uniform(Bi , Ai ). We assume this distribution is constant across all periods of the shot clock. Player i shoots if and only if η > ci,t (the cut threshold). From such a player we should observe: A+ci,t Efficiency: ei,t = 2 Usage Hazard Rate (Probability that player i uses the possession, A−ci,t given that his team has the ball): ui,t = Ai −Bi dei −(Ai −Bi ) ’Usage Curve’ Slope: dui = 2 Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 17. Dynamic Efficiency All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the possession. If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 18. Dynamic Efficiency All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the possession. If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team. Figure 2: OVERSHOOTING! Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 19. Dynamic Efficiency All player’s should chose ci,t equal to the value of continuing the possession. If they don’t, they are throwing away points for their team. Figure 2: UNDERSHOOTING! Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 20. Dynamic Efficiency: Results Figure shows that, on average, this is nearly the case for ALL periods. NBA players understand Dynamic Efficiency very well. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 21. Undershooting and Overshooting We preformed a t-test of every player’s adherence to Dynamic Efficiency (negative is overshooting; positive is undershooting) Overshooting is very rare, undershooting is more common. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 22. Undershooting and Overshooting We preformed a t-test of every player’s adherence to Dynamic Efficiency (negative is overshooting; positive is undershooting) Overshooting is very rare, undershooting is more common. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 23. Who Overshoots? Who Undershoots? Top 7 Overshooters and Undershooters (by t-statistic) Overshooter t Undershooter t Russell Westbrook -2.97838 Chris Paul 5.341594 Tyrus Thomas -1.983194 Brandon Roy 5.127828 Lamar Odom -1.942873 LeBron James 4.931574 Monta Ellis -1.908993 Al Jefferson 4.623833 Larry Hughes -1.802382 Joe Johnson 4.437453 Drew Gooden -1.790609 Amare Stoudemire 4.061478 Tracy McGrady -1.770439 Vince Carter 4.0012 Undershooters are primarily elite offensive players who may be sacrificing immediate preformance in order to conserve energy. High salary players are more likely to undershoot (t=2.75). Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 24. Allocative Efficiency Our Statistical Test All teammates in a given line-up should choose a ’worst shot’ (ci,t ) of the same value in each shot clock period. This ensures the team cannot reallocate to more productive players (on the margin) and increase output. Deviation from this standard is measured by Spread (defined in the paper). We use concept of 3-man (“most important 3 of 5-man line-up”) and 4-man cores to increase statistical power. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 25. Allocative Efficiency Results A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation. The majority of line-ups achieve Allocative Efficiency, but it is very clear that some core’s are imperfect(t = 8.05). Additionally less experienced (t = 2.70) and higher salary (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’ Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread amongst all ’3 man cores’ demonstrate larger deviations from Allocative Efficiency. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 26. Allocative Efficiency Results A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation. The majority of line-ups achieve Allocative Efficiency, but it is very clear that some core’s are imperfect(t = 8.05). Additionally less experienced (t = 2.70) and higher salary (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’ Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread amongst all ’3 man cores’ demonstrate larger deviations from Allocative Efficiency. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 27. Allocative Efficiency Results A team that Allocates perfectly will have Spread = 0 in expectation. The majority of line-ups achieve Allocative Efficiency, but it is very clear that some core’s are imperfect(t = 8.05). Additionally less experienced (t = 2.70) and higher salary (t = 3.96) ’3-man cores’ Figure 3: Histogram of observed spread amongst all ’3 man cores’ demonstrate larger deviations from Allocative Efficiency. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 28. Player Usage Curves The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each player’s abillity to create shots on the margin: ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi ) de What kinds of players have flatter usage curves? Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve LHS/RHS PG SG SF PF C Usage % ˆ ˆ A i −B i 2 2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26* -4.32* s.e. 0.26 0.30 0.29 0.31 0.33 0.97 R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01 Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter usgae curves. A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by .0025 − .006 points per possession. This estimate holds teammates constant. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 29. Player Usage Curves The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each player’s abillity to create shots on the margin: ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi ) de What kinds of players have flatter usage curves? Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve LHS/RHS PG SG SF PF C Usage % ˆ ˆ A i −B i 2 2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26* -4.32* s.e. 0.26 0.30 0.29 0.31 0.33 0.97 R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01 Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter usgae curves. A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by .0025 − .006 points per possession. This estimate holds teammates constant. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 30. Player Usage Curves The results of our parametric procedure yield estimates of each player’s abillity to create shots on the margin: ’Usage Curve’ Slope: duii = −(Ai2−Bi ) de What kinds of players have flatter usage curves? Table: Robust OLS Regression Explaining the Usage Curve LHS/RHS PG SG SF PF C Usage % ˆ ˆ A i −B i 2 2.51* 2.87* 2.80* 3.15* 3.26* -4.32* s.e. 0.26 0.30 0.29 0.31 0.33 0.97 R 2 = 0.8465, ∗p <0.01 Perimeter players and high-usage players have significantly flatter usgae curves. A player who wants to use an additional 1% of his team’s half-court offense possessions, will see his overall efficiency drop by .0025 − .006 points per possession. This estimate holds teammates constant. Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making
  • 31. Conclusion Thanks for your time! If you liked our presentation, come check out our blog at www.hooptheory.com Our contact info: Matt Goldman: mrgoldman@ucsd.edu Justin M. Rao jmrao@yahoo-inc.com Goldman and Rao Dynamic and Allocative Efficiency in NBA Decision Making