SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 19
Download to read offline
1
BASIC OF PRICING 2.
Ilya Gikhman
6077 Ivy Woods Court
Mason OH 45040 USA
Ph. 513-573-9348
Email: ilyagikhman@mail.ru
Abstract. In this paper we develop a model of corporate bonds pricing. We begin with default definition
which is similar to one that is used in the standard reduced form of default model. The primary distinction
between our model and reduced form of default model is interpretation of the date-t price of the bond. In
reduced form model date-t corporate bond price is a single number which in practical applications is the
close price of the bond at date t. It could be a reasonable reduction when deviation between maximum and
minimum of the bond prices at date t is sufficiently small. Otherwise the reduction’s error could be
remarkable. In our interpretation date-t bond price is a random variable taking values between minimum -
maximum prices at the date t. In such setting random value of the bond is considered as the present value
of the recovery rate assuming that default occurs at maturity of the bond. Random format of the recovery
rate does not convenient to compare different risky bonds. It makes sense to assume that recovery rate is a
nonrandom constant. This reduction reduced default problem to finding unknown recovery rate and
correspondent default probability. This is the case of two unknowns and one can derive equations for the
first and second moments of the bond price to present a solution of the problem. This approach can be
extend to resolve default problem in more general cases.
JEL : G13.
Keywords: no arbitrage, mark-to-market, cash flow, market risk, credit risk, reduced form pricing, credit
risk, interest rate swap.
1. Risk Free Bond Pricing.
Introduction. The price notion is the basis of the finance theory and practice. In standard trading of the
risk free bond investors pay the bond price B ( t , T ) at date t ≥ 0 and receive bond which promises its
face value of $1 at bond’s expiration date T. In [1] we presented a formal definition of the no arbitrage
pricing. The no arbitrage pricing of a financial instrument is defined as pricing which starts with zero
value of the initial investment at initiation date. The zero value at initiation is formed by buying the
instrument and borrowing this amount at risk free interest rate from the bank. Conditioning on zero initial
value of the investor’s position investor should arrive at the 0 value at expiration date T. Such
2
interpretation of the no arbitrage pricing is an ideal scheme. It should be adjusted for a stochastic market.
Interest rates at the future dates are unknown which are interpreted as random variables. It can be higher
or lower than market implied forward rates estimated at initiation date. By using market implied forward
rates one can produce market implied forward estimate of the future coupon bond price, which does not
contain arbitrage opportunity with respect to the spot price. No arbitrage price of the risk free coupon
bond does not eliminate market risk. It stems from the fact that coupon payments received by bond buyer
at future dates should be invested at unknown at initiation real forward risk free rates while on no
arbitrage price set at initiation uses market implied forward rates. The difference between real market
forward rates and its market implied forward estimates defines market risk of the risk free bond during
lifetime of the bond prior to its expiration date.
We use cash flow as a formal definition of the financial instrument. Risk free coupon bond from the
buyer perspective can be defined by the cash flow
CF = – B c ( t 0 , T ) χ { t = t 0 } + 
n
1j
c χ { t = t j } + 1 χ { t = T } (1)
Here c > 0 is a coupon payment taking place at the dates t j , j = 1, 2, … n and t n = T Function
χ { t = T } denotes indicator of the event { t = T }. One usually interprets the CF’s portion

n
1j
c χ { t = t j } + 1 χ { t = T } (2)
as a portfolio of the risk free bonds with face values c at t j , j < n and 1 at T correspondingly. Portfolio
interpretation of the coupon bond price B c ( t 0 , T ) makes it possible reduce no arbitrage of the coupon
bond to a sum of no arbitrage prices of the zero coupon bonds in the portfolio. The equivalence of the
coupon bond and portfolio of the zero coupon bonds with different maturities takes place in the perfect
market. Indeed, in the perfect market buyer of the bond can go short at initiation with the portfolio of the
zero coupon bonds to compose the value B c ( t 0 , T ). More realistic setting of the bond pricing problem
implies borrowing funds equal to the bond price from the bank at risk free interest at date t 0 and then
return borrowing amount plus interest at the bond maturity T. In other words, we do not assume that
money borrowed from bank can be returned to the bank by parts. Cash flow (1.2) admits two types
representation of the date-t 0 price of the bond. One representation uses the real world market scenarios to
define B ( t j , T , ω ). It will be used to present stochastic market price at the date-t 0 . Other
representation uses market implied forward rates to present the current spot price of the bond. Here
B c ( t j , T ) , j > 0 denote future values of the bond at t j that are unknown at t 0 . One usually apply a
stochastic equation as a theoretical model representing future values of the bond B c ( t j , T , ω ). Using a
model of the B c ( t j , T , ω ) we can construct date-T future value FV of the CF

n
1j
c B – 1
( t j , T , ω ) + 1
Market risk of the coupon bond investment over [ t 0 , T ] period. Bond buyer loses money if
3
B c ( t 0 , T ) > B ( t 0 , T ) [ 
n
1j
c B – 1
( t j , T , ω ) + 1 ]
and he gets money otherwise. Nevertheless applying implied market forward estimate to valuation of the
PV of the cash flow (2) shows that B c ( t 0 , T ) is indeed no arbitrage price. Indeed one can easy verify
the equality
B c ( t 0 , T ) = B ( t 0 , T ) [ 
n
1j
c B – 1
( t j , T , t 0 ) + 1 ]
where date-t 0 market implied forward discount rate B ( t j , T , t 0 ) is defined as
B ( t 0 , T ) = B ( t 0 , t j ) B ( t j , T , t 0 )
j = 1, 2, … n. This equality confirms the fact that the value B c ( t 0 , T ) borrowed from the bank to buy
coupon bond at t 0 at risk free rate will be covered by the date-T value of the cash flow generated by the
bond.
In stochastic setting no arbitrage pricing does not eliminate market risk. In finance theory market risk
does not formally defined. Informally it can be associated with profit-loss diagram which represents profit
and loss of an investment based on a market scenario. Market scenario is associated with the future price
at a particular date or at a series of dates. The modern finance theory deals with modeling of the spot
price. Spot price of an instrument is interpreted as present value, PV of the future cash flow associated
with CF. For example, for the coupon bond defined by cash flow (0.1) we can write the formula
B c ( t 0 , T ) = PV CF
Market risk of the bond buyer or seller is associated with lower return than it is expected at the initial
moment. If risk free bond is used for financing of a business than going short and buying back bond
during lifetime of the bond is a market risky deal. On the other hand buying risk free bond and holding it
until expiration does not risky purchase.
Corporate bond pricing. Let { Ω , F , P }be a complete probability space. Elements of the set Ω
represent market scenarios which represent stochastic prices of the debt instruments, F is the sigma
algebra generated by the observed market scenarios, and P is a complete probabilistic measure. Consider
credit risk effect on bonds pricing. Credit risk is associated with bond default. Other risk that also effects
on pricing is counterparty risk. Counterparty risk is a risk when one of the participants could not fulfill its
obligations. In such a case, underlying financial instrument does not default. In case of a corporate bond
the credit risk is associated with the issuer of the bond that could not pay face value of the bond to bond
buyer at maturity. In this case counterparty risk coincides with the credit risk. For more complex financial
instruments credit and counterparty risks are different.
A corporate bond is a risky instrument in which only buyer of the bond is exposed to risk. This is credit
risk which implies that bond’s seller could not accomplish its obligations to pay notional value of the
bond at its expiration. In standard ’cash-and-carry’ trading buyer if the bond pays the spot price R ( t , T )
4
and gets the bond which promises say $1 at T. If default occurs prior to maturity buyer of the bond
receives bond’s recovery rate, RR = δ < $1.
Reduced form of default is probably the most popular model of the corporate bonds pricing theory. There
are two primary parameters such as recovery rate and probability of default that effect on corporate bond
price. Benchmark reduced form of default theory does not present simultaneously calculations of the
probability of default and recovery rate values. In practice, agencies heuristically assign 40% or other
popular percentage to the bond’s face value of the recovery rate. This assumption simplifies the reduced
form default model and makes it possible calculation of the probability of default that corresponds to a
chosen recovery rate. In contrast to the benchmark approach, we do not use known recovery rate
assumption. We considered more general approach to default problem in [2,3]. For example based on
pricing data at date t , t < T and assuming that default takes place only at maturity we present closed
form formulas for recovery rate and probability of default. Here we present more detailed study regarding
default.
Let briefly recall basic corporate coupon bond valuation formulas. Let corporate bond admits default
only at maturity. Then at maturity T the value of the bond can be defined by the formula
R ( T , T , ω ) = χ {  > T } + δ χ {  = T }
where the constant δ  [ 0 , 1 ) is assumed to be known depending on t. Functions χ {  > T } and
χ {  = T } denote indicators of the no default and default at T scenarios correspondingly. Probabilities
of the default and no default events are also depend on t. Value δ and ( 1 – δ ) are referred to as recovery
rate and loss given default . Stochastic value of the corporate bond at maturity T implies stochastic price
of the bond at date t
R ( t , T , ω ) = B ( t , T ) [ χ {  > T } + δ χ {  = T } ] (3)
= B ( t , T ) [ 1 – ( 1 – δ ) χ {  = T } ]
Formula (3) defines date-t ‘fair’ price for each market scenario ω. Denote R spot ( t , T ) the spot price of
the bond at date t. It is a statistics of the observed data during a period associated with date t. One can
interpret spot price of the day t as open, close, middle, or expected value of the random market price (1.3).
For given spot price probabilities
P { R ( t , T , ω ) > R spot ( t , T ) } , P { R ( t , T , ω ) < R spot ( t , T ) }
define seller’s and buyer’s market values of risk correspondingly. First probability represents the chance
that bond is underpriced at t while the second probability represents the chance that bond at t is overpriced
by the market. In practice the value of recovery rate is unknown and should be estimated by historical
data. Note that our interpretation of the notion price significantly broader than it is used in modern finance
theory. For example in the standard reduced form model of default the only spot price is defined, which is
expectation of the random price (3).
Formula (3) presents date-t bond price given value of the bond at maturity. There are two values of the
bond ( δ , 1 ) at T with known probability distribution. To each value of the bond corresponds a unique
value of the bond ( δ B ( t , T ) , B ( t , T ) ) at t and probability distribution does not changed. This
5
construction of the stochastic bond price does not be changed if we assume that value of the bond at T is a
discrete or continuous distributed random variable taking values on interval [ 0 , 1 ]. In practice we deal
with inverse problem. We observe distribution of the bond prices during a date t and our goal is to make a
conclusion regarding default distribution. Note that given price R ( t , T ; ω ) distribution at t we can
define market implied forward value δ ( ω ) = B – 1
( t , T ) R ( t , T ; ω ) to value of the bond at maturity
which represents market implied stochastic recovery rate at T assuming that default occurs at maturity. It
is not convenient to justify which bond is more reliable dealing with continuous distribution of recovery
rates.
In order to present valuation in more explicit form it is necessary to make a discrete reduction of the
recovery rates. We begin with theoretical model where values of the bond are assumed to be known at
maturity. Given that default can be only at maturity T we introduce a total set of scenarios Ω = 
m
1j 
ω j ,
where ω j = { ω : δ j – 1 ≤ R ( T , T ; ω ) < δ j } . Here 0 = δ 0 ≤ ≤ δ j < δ j + 1 , j = 1, 2, … m – 1
and δ m = 1. Thus a continuously distributed recovery rate δ ( ω ) can be approximated by a discrete
random variable δ λ ( ω ) = 
m
0j
δ j χ ( ω j ) where
P ( ω j ) = p j = P { R ( T , T ; ω )  [ δ j , δ j + 1 ) }
Let χ D (  ) denote indicator of the default. We can present price of the corporate bond as
R ( t , T ; ω ) = B ( t , T ) [ 1 – ( 1 –  ( ω ) ) χ D (  ) ]
This equation defines the price for each market scenario ω. We can approximate latter equality
1 –  λ ( t , T ;  ) = ( 1 –  λ ) χ (  ) = 
m
1j
( 1 – δ j ) χ ( ω j )
where
 λ ( t , T ;  ) =
)T,t(B
)ω;T,t(R
λ
λ
Therefore
E  k
λ ( t , T ;  ) = 
m
1j
( 1 – δ j ) k
p j
k = 1, 2, … m. This is a linear system of the m order with respect to unknown p j . It could be solved by
the standard methods of the Linear Algebra. The probability of the no default is equal to
p 0 = 1 – p 1 – p 2 – … – p m – 1
6
The solution of the system represents the approximation of the default distribution corresponding to the
stochastic recovery rate.
Corporate bond pricing.
Let us assume that recovery rate δ = δ ( ω ) is a continuously distributed random variables on [ 0 , 1 ).
Introduce a discrete approximation of the recovery rate given that default occurs only at maturity date T.
Denote
p j = P { R ( T , T , ω )  [ δ j – 1 , δ j ) }
(4)
ω j = { ω : R ( T , T , ω )  [ δ j – 1 , δ j ) } , Ω = 
m
1j 
ω j
where 0 ≤ δ j < δ j + 1 , j = 1, 2, … m – 1, δ 0 = 0 and δ m = 1 . In theory we suppose that distribution
of the random variable R ( T , T ; ω ) is known and therefore probabilities p j are known too. From (4) it
follows that market price of the bond that admits default at maturity with known recovery rate δ j is
defined as
R mkt ( t 0 , T ; Ω j ) = δ j B ( t 0 , T )
Hence a discrete approximation of the bond can be written as
R mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ) = 
m
1j
δ j B ( t 0 , T ) χ Ω j ( ω )
We have introduced theoretical valuation formulas of corporate bond. In practice we have only historical
data available. Recovery rate is unknown and should be estimated based on observed data. Hence the
problem is how using observed data present stochastic market price and recovery rate estimate.
Let us first introduce randomization of the bond’s price. Recall that market risk of the no arbitrage price
of the default free coupon bond is stipulated by the unknown at t 0 future values of the bond
B ( t j , T , ω ) [1] which are estimated by market implied forward rates. On the other hand later model of
the corporate zero coupon bond given possibility of default at maturity moment the date-t 0 uncertainty of
the PV reduction of the corporate bond comes with unknown recovery rate. In [1] we presented a
theoretical solution of the problem.
Remark. Benchmark reduced form model of default begins with the similar definition of default. Next
they introduce date-t spot price ignoring stochastic price at maturity of the bond. Recall that the price of
the risky bond is a random variable which takes two values 1 and δ with known probabilities. Difference
of these two approaches relates to the ways how one interprets date-t price of the bond. In theory asset
price is interpreted as a continuous time random process. In practice we usually use close price of asset as
the price at date-t. In such reduction of the price we can consider future price at T as close price at T. It
fallows from the fact that all data we use represent only close historical prices. In other interpretation of
the asset price close price of the date t can be interpreted as a good approximation of the whole trading
7
period which we associate with date-t. Good approximation can be justified by a low volatility of the
date-t asset prices. If volatility cannot by considered as sufficiently small then use deterministic statistics
like close, open admits additional risk leading to possible losses. Standard reduced form model deals with
one equation and two unknowns. It could not present a unique solution of the default problem in simplest
setting when default might occur only at maturity. That is why the primary financial institutions and
rating agencies need to make additional assumption that recovery rate is a known such as for example
30%, 40% or other pre-specified value of recovery rate. Using a heuristic recovery rate helps to produce
heuristic probability of default. It is clear that such simplification of the problem leads to distortion of the
estimates of the recovery rate as well as probability of default which are the primary quantitative rating
parameters.
Our approach to default is based on stochastic market price was introduced in [1]. Stochastic price at t is
defined for each market scenario which associated with a particular value of the bond during date-t
period. With the help of stochastic price one can present independent equations for higher moments of the
market price. The system of two equations for the first and the second moments is sufficient to calculate
nonrandom recovery rate along with correspondent default probability. Following [1] let us briefly recall
this construction. From equality (3) it follows that
1 –
)T,t(B
)ω,T,t(R
= ( 1 – δ ) χ {  = T } (5)
Then recovery rate can be written in the form
)T,t(B
)ω,T,t(R
, for ω  {  ( ω ) = T }
δ = δ ( t , T , ω ) = {
1 , for ω  {  ( ω ) > T }
The distribution of the random variable δ ( ω ) is the distribution of the stochastic recovery rate. One
choice of the statistical estimate Δ of the random recovery rate δ ( ω ) is its expectation Δ = E δ ( ω ).
Stochastic interpretation of the recovery rate implies that reduction Δ of the rate δ ( ω ) implies market
risk. This risk for the bond buyer is the higher value of the Δ than recovery rate which is specified by a
scenario at the default moment. Buyer and seller risks are measured by probabilities of undervalue or
overvalue of the recovery rate
P { δ ( ω ) < Δ } , P { δ ( ω ) > Δ }
correspondingly. Consider for example the estimate δ ( ω ) χ ( ω  D ), where D = { ω : δ ( ω ) < 1 }.
This estimate specifies credit risk when bond seller could not pay initially promised amount of $1 at
expiration date. At the same time this risk is appealing bond sellers. Define normalized spread function
θ ( t , T ; ω ) by the formula
)T,t(B
)ω,T,t(R
1)ω,T,t(θ 
8
Note that this random function associated with normalized estimate of the LGD. The random function
θ ( t , T ; ω ) is an observable function. Stochastic recovery rate is complete credit information of the
bond. Nevertheless it is difficult to compare two distribution functions. To present credit characteristics in
more comparable form we assume that observations on bond’s prices at t correspond to unknown
deterministic recovery rate in case of default. We use function θ ( t , T ; ω ) to calculate a nonrandom
market implied recovery rate < Δ > and its correspondent probability of default. From (5) it follows that
E θ ( t , T , ω ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) P ( D )
E θ ² ( t , T , ω ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) ² P ( D )
Solving the system for < Δ > and P ( D ) we arrive at the solution
< Δ > = 1 –
)ω,T,t(θE
)ω,T,t(θE 2
, P ( t , T , D ) =
)ω,T,t(θE
])ω,T,t(θE[
2
2
(6)
Value < Δ > is market implied estimate and it does not equal to expected value of the stochastic recovery
rate
δ ( t , T , ω ) =
)T,t(B
)ω,T,t(R
Value < Δ > depends on distribution of the random process R ( t , T ; ω ) which is an assumption of the
model. Note that recovery rate < Δ > and correspondent probability of default represents estimates of the
real credit risk. In general
E θ p
( t , T , ω ) ≠ ( 1 – < Δ > ) p
P ( D )
p = 3, 4, … . Hence the approach is good for price distribution which completely defined by its first and
second moments. More crude but more explicit estimate can be presented as following. Assume for
example that we fix a particular recovery rate < Δ > . Applying first moment equation we arrive at the
formula
P ( D ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) – 1
E θ ( t , T , ω )
Thus one can compare probabilities of default for different bonds given the same value of the recovery
rate. On the other hand one can fix probability of default and consider values of recovery rate of different
bonds. For example one can fix 45% recovery rate and determine bonds which probabilities of default
less than 0.2. Then fixing probability of default 0.3 one can find the bond which recovery rate is maximal
or a set of bonds which recovery rates exceed 80%.
Let us consider an implementation of randomization of the bond price. Let { t 0 } denote trading time
interval of the date t 0 . Value of { t 0 } can be either a day, week , or other appropriate period. Define
minimum and maximum values of the bond prices over the day period { t 0 }. Denote
9
D min
( t 0 , T ) =
}t{u 0
min

D spot ( u , T ) , D max
( t 0 , T ) =
}t{u 0
max

D spot ( u , T )
Symbol D spot is interpreted as spot price of the corporate bond. We interpret date-t 0 bond price as a
random variable taking values on the interval [ D min
( t 0 , T ) , D max
( t 0 , T ) ] . There are different ways
to assign distribution to random bond price D mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ). A simple distribution that can be used for
D mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ) is uniform distribution. This distribution actually does not have any advantages or
drawbacks with respect to other types of probability distributions that can be applied for randomization.
Discrete approximation of the uniform distribution can be introduced as following. Fix a number m and
denote δ j = j / m , j = 0, 1, … m Defined numbers k and q are defined by inequalities
δ k ≤ R min ( t 0 , T ) < δ k + 1 and δ k + q – 1 ≤ R max ( t 0 , T ) < δ k + q
Then putting Ω j = { u  { t 0 } : δ j ≤ R spot ( u , T ) < δ j + 1 } we put P { Ω j } = q – 1
,
j = k + 1, k + 2, … k + q – 1. Note that numbers k and q depends on t 0 . This is a heuristic distribution
that approximates real prices of the bond observed over the date t 0 .
Other more practical way of randomization of the date-t 0 pricing data is an assumption that distribution
P ( Ω j ) is proportional to the time when spot price
P ( Ω j ) ~ measure { u  { t 0 } : R spot ( u , T )  [ δ j , δ j + 1 ] }
We also can use other distributions that approximated prices of the bond. These randomizations are
assigned to a particular date. The benchmark pricing uses one close price to represent a date t 0 bond
price. Such approximation can be good if the value D max ( t 0 , T ) – D min ( t 0 , T ) is sufficiently small.
Otherwise a lot of real pricing information will be lost. Pricing in stochastic environment implies market
risk regardless the chance of default. For example buyer’s market risk is measured by the probability that
buyer pays a higher price for the bond than it is implied by the market. If spot price at t 0 is identified as
the close price of the date t 0 then market risk of the buyer is the probability
P { R close ( t 0 , T ) > R ( t 0 , T , ω ) } =
)T,t(R-)T,t(R
)T,t(R-)T,t(R
0min0max
0close0max
Let us define recovery rate and default distribution implied by the stochastic price of the corporate bond
R ( t 0 , T ; ω ). Assuming for example uniform distribution of the recovery rate at maturity we arrive at
the formula
R ( t 0 , T , ω ) = δ j B ( t 0 , T ) , ω  Ω j
P ( Ω j ) = q – 1
, j = k + 1, … k + q – 1
Hence given the date-t 0 pricing data of the risky bond δ j = δ j ( t 0 ) , k = k ( t 0 ) , q = q ( t 0 ) we can
calculate credit risk based on prior assumed uniform distribution.
Remark. Randomization of the date t spot price of the bond is a primary assumption of our approach to
credit risk valuation. In modern finance it is common rule to use historical data time series as independent
10
observation. It is not quite accurate interpretation of the statistical sample. Indeed consider for example
rate of return on an asset S
i ( t , T ) =
)t(S
)t(S)T(S 
and let t j < t j + 1 , j = 0 , 1, … n – 1 be a partition of the interval [ t , T ]. Then historical data
represented by time series i ( t j , t j + 1 ) is usually interpreted as independent observation over real rate of
return. Given historical data one should first to complete test of independence. Second unknown historical
data such as rate of return is assumed to present independent observation of the random variable. Hence
unknown parameters mean and variance are assumed to be constant. If not one should expect a large
deviation between model and real data. Also if parameters of the model could not be assume to be
constant one can observe other effects such as ‘fat’ tails. It can occur because variance depends on time
and fuzzifies data.
Consider corporate zero coupon bonds that admit default at any moment during its lifetime. Recall
approach that leads us to exponential distribution of the default moment. Introduce no default probability
distribution function P ( t ) = P {  > t } and let t 0 < t 1 <…< t n = T be a partition of the interval
[ t 0 , T ]. Function P ( t ) is monotonic decreasing function in variable t. Our problem is: given no default
up to the moment t j to calculate probability that there is no default up to the future moment t k , k > j. A
solution of the problem can be represented by the conditional probability
P ( t k , t j ) = P {  > t k |  > t j }
Bearing in mind that default time depends on initiation date t 0 all functions defined bellow are also
depend on t 0 . Bearing in mind that
P {  > t k   > t j } = P {  > t k } = P ( t k )
we note that
P ( t k , t j ) =
}tτ{P
}tτ{P
j
k


=
)t(P
)t(P
j
k
The probability of default on ( t j , t k ] is then equal to
Q ( t k , t j ) = 1 – P ( t k , t j ) = 1 –
)t(P
)t(P
j
k
=
)t(P
)t(P-)t(P
j
kj
Putting t j = t and t k = t + Δ t we arrive at the equality
Q ( t + Δ t , t ) = –
)t(P
)t('P
Δ t + o ( Δ t )
11
Denote λ ( t ) =
)t(P
)t('P
. Then
P ( t ) = exp – 
t
t 0
λ ( s ) d s
There are other types of distributions that can be applied for default time modeling. These types are
Weibull distribution, Lognormal, Power, Gamma distributions. These distributions have multiple
parameters that can be used for better than exponential approximations of the default time. Function
λ ( s ) in exponential distribution is known as a hazard rate.
A discrete time approximation of the continuously distributed default time can be represented in the form
 λ ( ω ) = 
n
1k
t k χ {  ( ω )  ( t k – 1 , t k ] } + T χ {  ( ω ) > T }
For simplicity we assumes that zero coupon bond admits default at the dates t j . There are a few pricing
settlements of the corporate bond at the time of default. Fractional recovery of the market value
δ j B ( t j , T ) that is paid at t j . Other types of default settlements are the contingent claim of value
defined as δ j B – 1
( t j , T ) paid at T and the fractional recovery of the Treasury value δ j at T. Given a
particular choice of the default settlement a discrete time approximation of the cash flows of the corporate
bond can be represented in one of the forms
CF A 1 ( ω ) = 
n
1j
χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) χ ( t = t j ) + χ (  λ > T ) χ ( t = T )
CF A 2 ( ω ) = 
n
1j
χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B – 1
( t j , T ) χ ( t = T ) + χ (  λ > T ) χ ( t = T )
CF A 3 ( ω ) = 
n
1j
χ (  λ = t j ) δ j χ ( t = t j ) + χ ( t > T ) χ ( t = T )
Here χ ( t = t j ) is indicator function in t which specifies value of transaction between buyer and seller
which takes place at t j . Cash flow CF A 1 defines recovery rates δ j of the corporate bond with respect to
the value of the risk free bond with equal maturity. Also note that as far as the bid and ask prices are
assumed in theory to be equal for a fixed maturity date T the bond price at a future date t j , t j < T does
not depend on time when bond was issued. In other words on the run risky or risk free bond issued at t j
and the similar bond issued prior to the date t j have the same price at the date t j . Note that theoretically
cash flows CF A k , k = 2, 3 can be rewritten in the CF A 1 form. Hence we assume that bond is
represented by the formula CF A 1 . The stochastic market price of the bond at t 0 can be represented as
the PV of the cash flow CF A 1 . Thus
12
PV { CF ( ω ) } = R ( t 0 , T , ω ) = 
n
1j
χ {  = t j } R ( t 0 , T , ω ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T ) =
= 
n
1j
χ {  = t j } B ( t 0 , t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T ) = (7)
= 
n
1j
χ {  = t j } R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T )
Next for writing simplicity we omit index λ and low index A 1 which specifies cash flow. For the fixed t 0
ratio δ j on the right hand side (7) depends on t j and does not depend on T . The recovery rate of the bond
at the date of default δ j B ( t j , T ) depends on T .
Risk factor that affects bond price (7) associated with default time distribution is referred to as credit risk.
Values B ( t j , T ) which are unknown at initiation date t 0 specify market risk of the recovery rate of the
corporate bond. Indeed replacing values B ( t j , T ) in formula (7) by market implied forward discounting
rate B ( t j , T , t 0 ) we use date-t 0 estimate of the real rate which arrives at the date of default. Future
value of the CF ( ω ) is equal to
FV { CF ( ω ) } = 
n
1j
χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) B – 1
( t j , T ) + χ (  λ > T ) =
= 
n
1j
χ (  = t j ) δ j ( ω ) + χ (  > T )
No arbitrage pricing on [ t 0 , T ] we defined in [1] by equality
B – 1
( t 0 , T ) PV { CF ( ω ) } = FV { CF ( ω ) }
where cash flow CF was associated with risk free bond. Spot price of the risk free bond is assumed here
to be a constant while risky bond spot price is a random variable. Therefore
B – 1
( t 0 , T ) PV { CF ( ω ) } = B – 1
( t 0 , T ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) =
= B – 1
( t 0 , T ) [ 
n
1j
χ (  = t j ) B ( t 0 , t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ (  > T ) B ( t 0 , T ) ] =
= 
n
1j
χ (  = t j ) B – 1
( t j , T , t 0 ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ (  > T ) =
= 
n
1j
χ (  = t j ) δ j ( ω ) + χ (  > T ) = FV { CF ( ω ) }
13
Therefore PV of the stochastic cash flow represents no arbitrage (stochastic) market price of the bond.
There is no market risk on [ t 0 , T ] as no arbitrage pricing excludes market risk. Nevertheless early
selling of the bond might represent market risk to counterparty. Indeed let us define market risk of the
corporate bond. We defined spot price as a random variable. By definition scenario ω is equal to a
particular price of the bond during trade time of the date t 0 . Note that prices of the bond at different
moments can be equal to each other. Investor buying bond at date t 0 does not know either exact moment
of default or recovery rate at this moment. Such uncertainty implies that counterparty could loss or makes
a profit based on realized market scenario. On the other hand price defined by (7) does not eliminate
credit risk which can be specified by a choice of default time distribution.
Remark. Recall that standard approaches to corporate bond pricing deal with expected value of the
market implied PV of the CF. This approach replace future rate by its market implied estimate. Such
reduction incorporates market risk. This risk is specified by the difference between real future rate and its
market implied estimate. For a small standard deviation it might be reasonable approximation of the
stochastic price R ( t 0 , T , ω ) to a single number R spot ( t 0 , T ). It can be open, close price, or for
example
R spot ( t 0 , T ) = E R ( t 0 , T , ω )
For each future date t j market risk is implied by the fact that B ( t j , T , t 0 ) ≠ B ( t j , T ). Applying a
stochastic model of the future rates [4] one can estimate a chance P { B ( t j , T , t 0 ) > B ( t j , T ) } or
P { B ( t j , T , t 0 ) < B ( t j , T ) } at the date t 0 . Such estimates can justify reduction of the stochastic
price to single number as a representation of the date-t 0 bond price.
Now let us consider a generalization of the method used for calculation recovery rate and probability of
default (6) to cover general discrete time pricing model. In formula (7) dates t j , j = 1,2 … n represent
possible dates of default. Suppose (in theory) that bonds with expiration dates at t j , j = 1, 2, … n are
available on the market. Applying (3) we arrive at the formula
( 1 – δ 1 ) χ {  = t 1 } = 1 –
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
10
10
From this equality it follows that
( 1 – δ 1 ) P {  = t 1 } = E [ 1 –
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
10
10
]
( 1 – δ 1 ) 2
P {  = t 1 } = E [ 1 –
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
10
10
] 2
Solving the system for recovery rate and default probability we arrive at the values
14
δ 1 = 1 –
]
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
1[E
]
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
1[E
10
10
2
10
10


,
P {  = t 1 } = ( 1 – δ 1 ) – 1
E [ 1 –
)t,t(B
)ω,t,t(R
10
10
] = (8)
= 2
1010
2
1010
])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E
}])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E{


,
P {  > t 1 } = 1 – P {  = t 1 }
Bearing in mind Jensen’s inequality it is easy to verify inequality
P {  = t 1 } = 2
1010
2
1010
])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E
}])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E{


≤ 1
Formulas (8) represent first term on the right hand side (7) which corresponds to a set of scenarios
D 1 = { ω :  = t 1 }. Next we note that value of probabilities P ( D j ) = P { ω :  = t j } and
correspondent recovery rates could be adjusted by taking into account that {  > t j – 1 }, j = 2, 3, … n .
Such adjustment implies on credit risk exposure and it can be realized by applying conditional probability
P {  λ = t j |  > t j – 1 }. Taking into account inclusion
{  > t j }  {  > t j – 1 }
we can conclude that
P {  λ = t j + 1 |  > t j , …  > t 1 } = P {  λ = t j + 1 |  > t j }
Given that {  ( ω ) > t j – 1 }, j = 2, 3, … n we use estimate of the price of the bond at the moment t j – 1
provided by market implied forward value. Definition of the market implied forward risky discount rate
which in contrast to the risk free discount rate should take into account default time distribution. It
follows from (7) that
R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } = R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T ) χ {  = t j } (9)
j = 1, 2, … n. Here B ( t j , T ) = B ( t j , T , ω ) is future rate known only at t j and it is unknown at t 0.
Let us apply market implied forward rate as an estimate of the real forward rate. Then we arrive at the
reduction which decompose bond price
R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } = [ δ j B ( t 0 , t j ) ] B ( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j } =
= R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j }
Solving latter equation for R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) brings us the formula
15
R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B – 1
( t j , T , t 0 ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } (9)
Note that transition from (9) to (9) implies market risk and the fact that bonds R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) , j = 1, 2,
… n – 1 might not exist on the market. On the other hand taking into account equality
R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) χ {  = t j }
we define market implied forward risky discount rate R ( t j – 1 , t j ; t 0 , ω ) , ω  {  = t j } by equality
R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j } =
= B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j }
Bearing in mind that
R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) χ {  > t j – 1 } = B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) χ {  > t j – 1 }
we conclude that
R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B – 1
( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = (10)
= B – 1
( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) B – 1
( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j }
Market implied forward discount rate R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) is represented by forward starting bond that
admits default only at its maturity t j . We can now apply estimates represented in formula (8).
Applying formulas (8) to the function R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) defined by (10) we arrive at the formulas
δ j ( t 0 ) = 1 –
]
)t,t,t(B
)t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B
1[E
]
)t,t,t(B
)t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B
1[E
0j1-j
0j
1
01-j0
1
R
2
0j1-j
0j
1
01-j0
1
R




(11)
with correspondent conditional probabilities of default
P {  = t j |  > t j – 1 } = ( 1 – δ j ( t 0 ) ) – 1
[ 1 – E
)t,t,t(B
)t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B
0j1-j
0j
1
01-j0
1 
]
No default conditional probability is then equal to
P {  > t j |  > t j – 1 } = 1 – P {  = t j |  > t j – 1 }
Unconditional probability of default at the date t j and no default over lifetime of the bond could be
defined by the formula
P {  = t j } = P (  = t j |  > t j – 1 ) 


1j
0k
[ 1 – P (  = t k |  > t k – 1 ) ]
16
(11)
P {  > T } = 1 – 
n
1j
P (  = t j |  > t j – 1 ) 


1j
0k
[ 1 – P (  = t k |  > t k – 1 ) ]
Formulas (1.11), (1.11) represent recovery rate and probability of default values of the zero coupon
corporate bond in discrete time setting.
Remark. Let us add some remarks on randomization. We generalized spot price notion of the bond.
Usually date-t price of the bond is associated with a particular price such as close price of the bond at the
date t. Our approach interprets bond price at date t as a random variable R ( t , T , ω ) taking values in the
interval
[
}t{u
min

R ( u , T ) ,
}t{u
max

R ( u , T ) ]
Therefore market scenario associated with a particular value of the bond, i.e. ω = R ( u , T ) for a some
moment u  { t }. The use of a fixed price such as close price at date t should be interpreted as an
approximation of the random variable implies market risk. If we consider random price at a future
moment t + Δ t then the probability space
[
}tt{u
min

R ( u , T ) ,
}tt{u
max

R ( u , T ) ]
does not coincide with the one that is defined at t. Therefore dealing with dynamic market we should
introduce a unique probability space. Next we associate probability space Ω R with the set of measurable
functions ω ( t ) such that
}t{u
min

R ( u , T ) ≤ ω ( t ) ≤
}t{u
max

R ( u , T ) }
t  [ t 0 , T ]. Prior to expiration date values of the corporate bond does not represent default event. Hence
time of default of the bond can be thought as an internal company factor and it can be interpreted as a
random variable. As far as values of the bond do not completely define time of default distribution the
probability space Ω ( R ) should not interpret default time  ( ω )  ( t 0 , +  ) , ω  Ω  . The term ‘
should not interpret default time’ suggests that in general  ( ω ) does not measurable function on Ω ( R ).
We introduce measurable space { Ω , B } where Ω = Ω ( R )  Ω  , B = B ( R )  B  . Here
symbol B denote σ-algebra of Borel sets on correspondent space. Probability measure P on measurable
space { Ω , B } is defined by equality
P ( A  Δ ) = P { R ( t , T , ω )  A ,  ( ω )  Δ }
A  B ( R ), Δ  B  . For a random variable ξ ( ω ) on { Ω , B , P } denote
expectation with respect to market scenarios generated by the values of the bond while default time
remains stochastic. Such construction implies that values of the bond and default time are mutually
17
independent random variables and symbol E R denotes conditional expectation with respect to -algebra
generated by the default time
E R ξ ( ω ) = E { ξ ( ω ) | B  }
Note that it is quite a strong assumption and it is very popular in credit risk valuations.
Corporate coupon bearing bond pricing. Zero coupon corporate bonds pricing scheme can be applied
to coupon bearing bond. Suppose for simplicity that default dates coincide with coupon payment dates
T 1 < T 2 < … < T m = T. Then cash flow of the coupon bearing bond from bond to bond buyer
perspective can be written in the form
CF ( ω ) = 
m
1j
χ (  = T j ) { 
1-j
1k
c χ ( t = T k ) + δ j [ c 
m
ji
B ( T j , T i ) +
+ B ( T j , T m ) ] χ ( t = T j ) + χ (  > T ) [ 
m
1j
c χ ( t = T k ) + χ ( t = T m ) ]
In this formula recovery rate is assigned to outstanding debt value defined at default moment. The PV
reduction at t of the cash flow CF ( ω ) defines market price of the corporate bond depending on market
scenario which incorporate unknown values of the risk free bonds B ( T j , T i ) at future moments T j , T i
and time of default. Assume that corporation simultaneously issued zero coupon and coupon bonds. In
this case investors can expect that loss-ratio due to default of the zero and nonzero coupon bonds are
equal. Otherwise there exists hypothetical arbitrage opportunity. The notion ‘equal loss-ratio’ in latter
statement should be refined. We interpret bond default as default of the corporation and therefore default
of the corporation affects on all corporate bonds issued by this corporation. One should assume that
probability distribution of default time for corporate zero and nonzero coupon bonds are the same. Recall
that recovery rate of the zero coupon bond conditional on default at T j can be represented in the form
c δ j ( t , ω ) B ( T j , T , ω ), which is unknown at t and can be estimated by deterministic value
δ j ( t ) B ( T j , T , t ) . Hence recovery rate of the zero coupon corporate bond is interpreted as a portion
δ j ( t ) of the date-T j PV of the face value of the bond. Following this idea we define recovery value of
the coupon bond at T j as a portion δ
c
j ( t ) of the outstanding balance of the coupon bond on [ T j , T ].
Hence, recovery rate of the coupon bond can be defined as
δc
j [ 1 + c 
m
1ji
B – 1
( T i , T ) + c B – 1
( T j , T ) ]
The value δc
j we call recovery ratio. For the zero coupon bond, c = 0 recovery rate notion coincides with
recovery ratio. Total losses due to default are equal to
( 1 – δ
c
j ) [ 1 + c 
m
1ji
B – 1
( T i , T ) + c B – 1
( T j , T ) ]
18
Theoretically the value of the losses at T of the zero and nonzero coupon bonds of the corporation that
defaults at T j should be equal for each scenario. In this case we eliminate arbitrage opportunity between
zero and non zero coupon bonds for each scenario. Hence
1
δ1
)T,T(Bc1
])T,T(Bc)T,T(Bc1[)δ1(
j
i
1
m
1ji
j
1
i
1
m
1ji
c
j










Solving latter equation for the recovery rate of the coupon bond rate we arrive at the formula
δc
j ( t , ω ) = 1 –
)T,T(B)T,T(Bc1
])T,T(Bc1[))ω,t(δ1(
j
1
i
1
m
1ji
i
1
m
1ji
j








Market implied estimate of the above stochastic recovery rate can be represented as
δc
j = 1 –
)t,T,T(B)T,T(Bc1
])t,T,T(Bc1[)δ1(
j
1
i
1
m
1ji
i
1
m
1ji
j








Recall that using market implied forward estimate δc
j implies market risk as far as δc
j ( t , ω ) ≠ δ c
j .
19
References.
1. I. Gikhman, BASIC OF PRICING 1, http://www.slideshare.net/list2do/basic-pricing ,
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2428024.
2. I. Gikhman, Corporate Debt Pricing, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1163195
3. Multiple Risky Securities Valuation I,
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1944171
4. Fixed Rates Modeling. 2013 p. 25,
http://www.slideshare.net/list2do/fixed-rates-modeling
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2287165

More Related Content

What's hot

Basic of pricing 2
Basic of pricing 2Basic of pricing 2
Basic of pricing 2Ilya Gikhman
 
BS concept of dynamic hedging
BS concept of dynamic hedgingBS concept of dynamic hedging
BS concept of dynamic hedgingIlya Gikhman
 
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)Fynn McKay
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptIlya Gikhman
 
Black scholes pricing consept
Black scholes pricing conseptBlack scholes pricing consept
Black scholes pricing conseptIlya Gikhman
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptIlya Gikhman
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptIlya Gikhman
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptIlya Gikhman
 
My pricing of american options
My pricing of american optionsMy pricing of american options
My pricing of american optionsIlya Gikhman
 
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. Ilya Gikhman
 
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilities
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilitiesLast my paper equity, implied, and local volatilities
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilitiesIlya Gikhman
 
Black-Scholes overview
Black-Scholes overviewBlack-Scholes overview
Black-Scholes overviewInon Sharony
 
Option pricing model
Option pricing modelOption pricing model
Option pricing modelVishal Jain
 

What's hot (18)

Basic of pricing 2
Basic of pricing 2Basic of pricing 2
Basic of pricing 2
 
Black schole
Black scholeBlack schole
Black schole
 
BS concept of dynamic hedging
BS concept of dynamic hedgingBS concept of dynamic hedging
BS concept of dynamic hedging
 
option pricing
option pricingoption pricing
option pricing
 
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)
Solution to Black-Scholes P.D.E. via Finite Difference Methods (MatLab)
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing concept
 
Black scholes pricing consept
Black scholes pricing conseptBlack scholes pricing consept
Black scholes pricing consept
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing concept
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing concept
 
Black scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing conceptBlack scholes pricing concept
Black scholes pricing concept
 
Black scholes model
Black scholes modelBlack scholes model
Black scholes model
 
Black Scholes
Black ScholesBlack Scholes
Black Scholes
 
My pricing of american options
My pricing of american optionsMy pricing of american options
My pricing of american options
 
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
 
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilities
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilitiesLast my paper equity, implied, and local volatilities
Last my paper equity, implied, and local volatilities
 
Black-Scholes overview
Black-Scholes overviewBlack-Scholes overview
Black-Scholes overview
 
Option pricing model
Option pricing modelOption pricing model
Option pricing model
 
Simulation methods finance_1
Simulation methods finance_1Simulation methods finance_1
Simulation methods finance_1
 

Viewers also liked

ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ Ilya Gikhman
 
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.Ilya Gikhman
 
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liq
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liqматематические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liq
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liqIlya Gikhman
 
Critical thoughts about modern option pricing
Critical thoughts about modern option pricingCritical thoughts about modern option pricing
Critical thoughts about modern option pricingIlya Gikhman
 
Remark on variance swaps pricing new
Remark on variance swaps pricing newRemark on variance swaps pricing new
Remark on variance swaps pricing newIlya Gikhman
 
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложения
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложенияисследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложения
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложенияIlya Gikhman
 
Comparison Theorems for SDEs
Comparison Theorems for SDEs Comparison Theorems for SDEs
Comparison Theorems for SDEs Ilya Gikhman
 
Fixed rates modeling
Fixed rates modelingFixed rates modeling
Fixed rates modelingIlya Gikhman
 
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014Ilya Gikhman
 
Stochastic Schrödinger equations
Stochastic Schrödinger equationsStochastic Schrödinger equations
Stochastic Schrödinger equationsIlya Gikhman
 
Black Scholes pricing consept
Black Scholes pricing conseptBlack Scholes pricing consept
Black Scholes pricing conseptIlya Gikhman
 

Viewers also liked (12)

ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
 
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
 
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liq
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liqматематические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liq
математические модели фиксированной ставк Bez corp liq
 
Critical thoughts about modern option pricing
Critical thoughts about modern option pricingCritical thoughts about modern option pricing
Critical thoughts about modern option pricing
 
Remark on variance swaps pricing new
Remark on variance swaps pricing newRemark on variance swaps pricing new
Remark on variance swaps pricing new
 
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложения
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложенияисследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложения
исследования по стохастическим уравнениям и их приложения
 
Comparison Theorems for SDEs
Comparison Theorems for SDEs Comparison Theorems for SDEs
Comparison Theorems for SDEs
 
Fixed rates modeling
Fixed rates modelingFixed rates modeling
Fixed rates modeling
 
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
 
American option
American optionAmerican option
American option
 
Stochastic Schrödinger equations
Stochastic Schrödinger equationsStochastic Schrödinger equations
Stochastic Schrödinger equations
 
Black Scholes pricing consept
Black Scholes pricing conseptBlack Scholes pricing consept
Black Scholes pricing consept
 

Similar to Basic of pricing 2

Cross currency swap
Cross currency swapCross currency swap
Cross currency swapIlya Gikhman
 
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricing
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricingNo arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricing
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricingIlya Gikhman
 
Derivatives ppt @ mab finance
Derivatives ppt @ mab financeDerivatives ppt @ mab finance
Derivatives ppt @ mab financeBabasab Patil
 
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rules
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate RulesMacrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rules
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rulespkconference
 
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?Rusman Mukhlis
 
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?Rusman Mukhlis
 
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)PrivateBanker.ro
 
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.pptMurat Öztürkmen
 
Risk mgmt and derinatives
Risk mgmt and derinativesRisk mgmt and derinatives
Risk mgmt and derinativesmahapurus
 
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset Prices
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset PricesOptimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset Prices
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset PricesSambit Mukherjee
 
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdf
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdfch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdf
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdfjgordon21
 
Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx
       Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx       Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx
Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docxhallettfaustina
 
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump risk
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump riskFair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump risk
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump riskAlex Kouam
 

Similar to Basic of pricing 2 (20)

Cross currency swap
Cross currency swapCross currency swap
Cross currency swap
 
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricing
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricingNo arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricing
No arbitrage and randomization of derivatives pricing
 
Derivatives ppt @ mab finance
Derivatives ppt @ mab financeDerivatives ppt @ mab finance
Derivatives ppt @ mab finance
 
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rules
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate RulesMacrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rules
Macrodynamics of Debt-Financed Investment-Led Growth with Interest Rate Rules
 
Credit risk models
Credit risk modelsCredit risk models
Credit risk models
 
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?
Chapter 05_How Do Risk and Term Structure Affect Interest Rate?
 
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?
Chapter 03_What Do Interest Rates Mean and What Is Their Role in Valuation?
 
Bonds
BondsBonds
Bonds
 
Bonds
BondsBonds
Bonds
 
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)
Presentare Obligatiuni (engleza)
 
L Pch13
L Pch13L Pch13
L Pch13
 
Formulas
FormulasFormulas
Formulas
 
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt
7_Analysing and Interpreting the Yield Curve.ppt
 
Risk mgmt and derinatives
Risk mgmt and derinativesRisk mgmt and derinatives
Risk mgmt and derinatives
 
Ross7e ch05
Ross7e ch05Ross7e ch05
Ross7e ch05
 
Ross7e ch05
Ross7e ch05Ross7e ch05
Ross7e ch05
 
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset Prices
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset PricesOptimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset Prices
Optimal Policy Response to Booms and Busts in Credit and Asset Prices
 
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdf
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdfch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdf
ch21 - Econ 442 - financial markets Par 1 of 2 (1).pdf
 
Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx
       Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx       Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx
Options Pricing The Black-Scholes ModelMore or .docx
 
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump risk
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump riskFair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump risk
Fair valuation of participating life insurance contracts with jump risk
 

More from Ilya Gikhman

CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. Ilya Gikhman
 
equity, implied, and local volatilities
equity, implied, and local volatilitiesequity, implied, and local volatilities
equity, implied, and local volatilitiesIlya Gikhman
 
о построении цены производных инструментов
о построении цены производных инструментово построении цены производных инструментов
о построении цены производных инструментовIlya Gikhman
 
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsr
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsrDiscrete space time option pricing forum fsr
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsrIlya Gikhman
 

More from Ilya Gikhman (6)

CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING. CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
 
equity, implied, and local volatilities
equity, implied, and local volatilitiesequity, implied, and local volatilities
equity, implied, and local volatilities
 
Cambridge
CambridgeCambridge
Cambridge
 
SPDE
SPDE SPDE
SPDE
 
о построении цены производных инструментов
о построении цены производных инструментово построении цены производных инструментов
о построении цены производных инструментов
 
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsr
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsrDiscrete space time option pricing forum fsr
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsr
 

Recently uploaded

Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot ModelsAndheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Modelshematsharma006
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam Smith
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam SmithClassical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam Smith
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam SmithAdamYassin2
 
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance Company
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance CompanyInterimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance Company
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance CompanyTyöeläkeyhtiö Elo
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spiritegoetzinger
 
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingHow Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingAggregage
 
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHouse of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHenry Tapper
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfAdnet Communications
 
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...Suhani Kapoor
 
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionChapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionMuhammadHusnain82237
 
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex
 
call girls in Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in  Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in  Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️9953056974 Low Rate Call Girls In Saket, Delhi NCR
 
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...yordanosyohannes2
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfMichael Silva
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot ModelsAndheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
Andheri Call Girls In 9825968104 Mumbai Hot Models
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
🔝+919953056974 🔝young Delhi Escort service Pusa Road
 
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam Smith
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam SmithClassical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam Smith
Classical Theory of Macroeconomics by Adam Smith
 
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance Company
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance CompanyInterimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance Company
Interimreport1 January–31 March2024 Elo Mutual Pension Insurance Company
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
 
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
 
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of ReportingHow Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
How Automation is Driving Efficiency Through the Last Mile of Reporting
 
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHouse of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
 
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdfLundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
Lundin Gold April 2024 Corporate Presentation v4.pdf
 
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
VIP High Class Call Girls Saharanpur Anushka 8250192130 Independent Escort Se...
 
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionChapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
 
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
Bladex Earnings Call Presentation 1Q2024
 
call girls in Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in  Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️call girls in  Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
call girls in Nand Nagri (DELHI) 🔝 >༒9953330565🔝 genuine Escort Service 🔝✔️✔️
 
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...
AfRESFullPaper22018EmpiricalPerformanceofRealEstateInvestmentTrustsandShareho...
 
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
 
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
Commercial Bank Economic Capsule - April 2024
 
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdfStock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck for 4/24/24 .pdf
 

Basic of pricing 2

  • 1. 1 BASIC OF PRICING 2. Ilya Gikhman 6077 Ivy Woods Court Mason OH 45040 USA Ph. 513-573-9348 Email: ilyagikhman@mail.ru Abstract. In this paper we develop a model of corporate bonds pricing. We begin with default definition which is similar to one that is used in the standard reduced form of default model. The primary distinction between our model and reduced form of default model is interpretation of the date-t price of the bond. In reduced form model date-t corporate bond price is a single number which in practical applications is the close price of the bond at date t. It could be a reasonable reduction when deviation between maximum and minimum of the bond prices at date t is sufficiently small. Otherwise the reduction’s error could be remarkable. In our interpretation date-t bond price is a random variable taking values between minimum - maximum prices at the date t. In such setting random value of the bond is considered as the present value of the recovery rate assuming that default occurs at maturity of the bond. Random format of the recovery rate does not convenient to compare different risky bonds. It makes sense to assume that recovery rate is a nonrandom constant. This reduction reduced default problem to finding unknown recovery rate and correspondent default probability. This is the case of two unknowns and one can derive equations for the first and second moments of the bond price to present a solution of the problem. This approach can be extend to resolve default problem in more general cases. JEL : G13. Keywords: no arbitrage, mark-to-market, cash flow, market risk, credit risk, reduced form pricing, credit risk, interest rate swap. 1. Risk Free Bond Pricing. Introduction. The price notion is the basis of the finance theory and practice. In standard trading of the risk free bond investors pay the bond price B ( t , T ) at date t ≥ 0 and receive bond which promises its face value of $1 at bond’s expiration date T. In [1] we presented a formal definition of the no arbitrage pricing. The no arbitrage pricing of a financial instrument is defined as pricing which starts with zero value of the initial investment at initiation date. The zero value at initiation is formed by buying the instrument and borrowing this amount at risk free interest rate from the bank. Conditioning on zero initial value of the investor’s position investor should arrive at the 0 value at expiration date T. Such
  • 2. 2 interpretation of the no arbitrage pricing is an ideal scheme. It should be adjusted for a stochastic market. Interest rates at the future dates are unknown which are interpreted as random variables. It can be higher or lower than market implied forward rates estimated at initiation date. By using market implied forward rates one can produce market implied forward estimate of the future coupon bond price, which does not contain arbitrage opportunity with respect to the spot price. No arbitrage price of the risk free coupon bond does not eliminate market risk. It stems from the fact that coupon payments received by bond buyer at future dates should be invested at unknown at initiation real forward risk free rates while on no arbitrage price set at initiation uses market implied forward rates. The difference between real market forward rates and its market implied forward estimates defines market risk of the risk free bond during lifetime of the bond prior to its expiration date. We use cash flow as a formal definition of the financial instrument. Risk free coupon bond from the buyer perspective can be defined by the cash flow CF = – B c ( t 0 , T ) χ { t = t 0 } +  n 1j c χ { t = t j } + 1 χ { t = T } (1) Here c > 0 is a coupon payment taking place at the dates t j , j = 1, 2, … n and t n = T Function χ { t = T } denotes indicator of the event { t = T }. One usually interprets the CF’s portion  n 1j c χ { t = t j } + 1 χ { t = T } (2) as a portfolio of the risk free bonds with face values c at t j , j < n and 1 at T correspondingly. Portfolio interpretation of the coupon bond price B c ( t 0 , T ) makes it possible reduce no arbitrage of the coupon bond to a sum of no arbitrage prices of the zero coupon bonds in the portfolio. The equivalence of the coupon bond and portfolio of the zero coupon bonds with different maturities takes place in the perfect market. Indeed, in the perfect market buyer of the bond can go short at initiation with the portfolio of the zero coupon bonds to compose the value B c ( t 0 , T ). More realistic setting of the bond pricing problem implies borrowing funds equal to the bond price from the bank at risk free interest at date t 0 and then return borrowing amount plus interest at the bond maturity T. In other words, we do not assume that money borrowed from bank can be returned to the bank by parts. Cash flow (1.2) admits two types representation of the date-t 0 price of the bond. One representation uses the real world market scenarios to define B ( t j , T , ω ). It will be used to present stochastic market price at the date-t 0 . Other representation uses market implied forward rates to present the current spot price of the bond. Here B c ( t j , T ) , j > 0 denote future values of the bond at t j that are unknown at t 0 . One usually apply a stochastic equation as a theoretical model representing future values of the bond B c ( t j , T , ω ). Using a model of the B c ( t j , T , ω ) we can construct date-T future value FV of the CF  n 1j c B – 1 ( t j , T , ω ) + 1 Market risk of the coupon bond investment over [ t 0 , T ] period. Bond buyer loses money if
  • 3. 3 B c ( t 0 , T ) > B ( t 0 , T ) [  n 1j c B – 1 ( t j , T , ω ) + 1 ] and he gets money otherwise. Nevertheless applying implied market forward estimate to valuation of the PV of the cash flow (2) shows that B c ( t 0 , T ) is indeed no arbitrage price. Indeed one can easy verify the equality B c ( t 0 , T ) = B ( t 0 , T ) [  n 1j c B – 1 ( t j , T , t 0 ) + 1 ] where date-t 0 market implied forward discount rate B ( t j , T , t 0 ) is defined as B ( t 0 , T ) = B ( t 0 , t j ) B ( t j , T , t 0 ) j = 1, 2, … n. This equality confirms the fact that the value B c ( t 0 , T ) borrowed from the bank to buy coupon bond at t 0 at risk free rate will be covered by the date-T value of the cash flow generated by the bond. In stochastic setting no arbitrage pricing does not eliminate market risk. In finance theory market risk does not formally defined. Informally it can be associated with profit-loss diagram which represents profit and loss of an investment based on a market scenario. Market scenario is associated with the future price at a particular date or at a series of dates. The modern finance theory deals with modeling of the spot price. Spot price of an instrument is interpreted as present value, PV of the future cash flow associated with CF. For example, for the coupon bond defined by cash flow (0.1) we can write the formula B c ( t 0 , T ) = PV CF Market risk of the bond buyer or seller is associated with lower return than it is expected at the initial moment. If risk free bond is used for financing of a business than going short and buying back bond during lifetime of the bond is a market risky deal. On the other hand buying risk free bond and holding it until expiration does not risky purchase. Corporate bond pricing. Let { Ω , F , P }be a complete probability space. Elements of the set Ω represent market scenarios which represent stochastic prices of the debt instruments, F is the sigma algebra generated by the observed market scenarios, and P is a complete probabilistic measure. Consider credit risk effect on bonds pricing. Credit risk is associated with bond default. Other risk that also effects on pricing is counterparty risk. Counterparty risk is a risk when one of the participants could not fulfill its obligations. In such a case, underlying financial instrument does not default. In case of a corporate bond the credit risk is associated with the issuer of the bond that could not pay face value of the bond to bond buyer at maturity. In this case counterparty risk coincides with the credit risk. For more complex financial instruments credit and counterparty risks are different. A corporate bond is a risky instrument in which only buyer of the bond is exposed to risk. This is credit risk which implies that bond’s seller could not accomplish its obligations to pay notional value of the bond at its expiration. In standard ’cash-and-carry’ trading buyer if the bond pays the spot price R ( t , T )
  • 4. 4 and gets the bond which promises say $1 at T. If default occurs prior to maturity buyer of the bond receives bond’s recovery rate, RR = δ < $1. Reduced form of default is probably the most popular model of the corporate bonds pricing theory. There are two primary parameters such as recovery rate and probability of default that effect on corporate bond price. Benchmark reduced form of default theory does not present simultaneously calculations of the probability of default and recovery rate values. In practice, agencies heuristically assign 40% or other popular percentage to the bond’s face value of the recovery rate. This assumption simplifies the reduced form default model and makes it possible calculation of the probability of default that corresponds to a chosen recovery rate. In contrast to the benchmark approach, we do not use known recovery rate assumption. We considered more general approach to default problem in [2,3]. For example based on pricing data at date t , t < T and assuming that default takes place only at maturity we present closed form formulas for recovery rate and probability of default. Here we present more detailed study regarding default. Let briefly recall basic corporate coupon bond valuation formulas. Let corporate bond admits default only at maturity. Then at maturity T the value of the bond can be defined by the formula R ( T , T , ω ) = χ {  > T } + δ χ {  = T } where the constant δ  [ 0 , 1 ) is assumed to be known depending on t. Functions χ {  > T } and χ {  = T } denote indicators of the no default and default at T scenarios correspondingly. Probabilities of the default and no default events are also depend on t. Value δ and ( 1 – δ ) are referred to as recovery rate and loss given default . Stochastic value of the corporate bond at maturity T implies stochastic price of the bond at date t R ( t , T , ω ) = B ( t , T ) [ χ {  > T } + δ χ {  = T } ] (3) = B ( t , T ) [ 1 – ( 1 – δ ) χ {  = T } ] Formula (3) defines date-t ‘fair’ price for each market scenario ω. Denote R spot ( t , T ) the spot price of the bond at date t. It is a statistics of the observed data during a period associated with date t. One can interpret spot price of the day t as open, close, middle, or expected value of the random market price (1.3). For given spot price probabilities P { R ( t , T , ω ) > R spot ( t , T ) } , P { R ( t , T , ω ) < R spot ( t , T ) } define seller’s and buyer’s market values of risk correspondingly. First probability represents the chance that bond is underpriced at t while the second probability represents the chance that bond at t is overpriced by the market. In practice the value of recovery rate is unknown and should be estimated by historical data. Note that our interpretation of the notion price significantly broader than it is used in modern finance theory. For example in the standard reduced form model of default the only spot price is defined, which is expectation of the random price (3). Formula (3) presents date-t bond price given value of the bond at maturity. There are two values of the bond ( δ , 1 ) at T with known probability distribution. To each value of the bond corresponds a unique value of the bond ( δ B ( t , T ) , B ( t , T ) ) at t and probability distribution does not changed. This
  • 5. 5 construction of the stochastic bond price does not be changed if we assume that value of the bond at T is a discrete or continuous distributed random variable taking values on interval [ 0 , 1 ]. In practice we deal with inverse problem. We observe distribution of the bond prices during a date t and our goal is to make a conclusion regarding default distribution. Note that given price R ( t , T ; ω ) distribution at t we can define market implied forward value δ ( ω ) = B – 1 ( t , T ) R ( t , T ; ω ) to value of the bond at maturity which represents market implied stochastic recovery rate at T assuming that default occurs at maturity. It is not convenient to justify which bond is more reliable dealing with continuous distribution of recovery rates. In order to present valuation in more explicit form it is necessary to make a discrete reduction of the recovery rates. We begin with theoretical model where values of the bond are assumed to be known at maturity. Given that default can be only at maturity T we introduce a total set of scenarios Ω =  m 1j  ω j , where ω j = { ω : δ j – 1 ≤ R ( T , T ; ω ) < δ j } . Here 0 = δ 0 ≤ ≤ δ j < δ j + 1 , j = 1, 2, … m – 1 and δ m = 1. Thus a continuously distributed recovery rate δ ( ω ) can be approximated by a discrete random variable δ λ ( ω ) =  m 0j δ j χ ( ω j ) where P ( ω j ) = p j = P { R ( T , T ; ω )  [ δ j , δ j + 1 ) } Let χ D (  ) denote indicator of the default. We can present price of the corporate bond as R ( t , T ; ω ) = B ( t , T ) [ 1 – ( 1 –  ( ω ) ) χ D (  ) ] This equation defines the price for each market scenario ω. We can approximate latter equality 1 –  λ ( t , T ;  ) = ( 1 –  λ ) χ (  ) =  m 1j ( 1 – δ j ) χ ( ω j ) where  λ ( t , T ;  ) = )T,t(B )ω;T,t(R λ λ Therefore E  k λ ( t , T ;  ) =  m 1j ( 1 – δ j ) k p j k = 1, 2, … m. This is a linear system of the m order with respect to unknown p j . It could be solved by the standard methods of the Linear Algebra. The probability of the no default is equal to p 0 = 1 – p 1 – p 2 – … – p m – 1
  • 6. 6 The solution of the system represents the approximation of the default distribution corresponding to the stochastic recovery rate. Corporate bond pricing. Let us assume that recovery rate δ = δ ( ω ) is a continuously distributed random variables on [ 0 , 1 ). Introduce a discrete approximation of the recovery rate given that default occurs only at maturity date T. Denote p j = P { R ( T , T , ω )  [ δ j – 1 , δ j ) } (4) ω j = { ω : R ( T , T , ω )  [ δ j – 1 , δ j ) } , Ω =  m 1j  ω j where 0 ≤ δ j < δ j + 1 , j = 1, 2, … m – 1, δ 0 = 0 and δ m = 1 . In theory we suppose that distribution of the random variable R ( T , T ; ω ) is known and therefore probabilities p j are known too. From (4) it follows that market price of the bond that admits default at maturity with known recovery rate δ j is defined as R mkt ( t 0 , T ; Ω j ) = δ j B ( t 0 , T ) Hence a discrete approximation of the bond can be written as R mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ) =  m 1j δ j B ( t 0 , T ) χ Ω j ( ω ) We have introduced theoretical valuation formulas of corporate bond. In practice we have only historical data available. Recovery rate is unknown and should be estimated based on observed data. Hence the problem is how using observed data present stochastic market price and recovery rate estimate. Let us first introduce randomization of the bond’s price. Recall that market risk of the no arbitrage price of the default free coupon bond is stipulated by the unknown at t 0 future values of the bond B ( t j , T , ω ) [1] which are estimated by market implied forward rates. On the other hand later model of the corporate zero coupon bond given possibility of default at maturity moment the date-t 0 uncertainty of the PV reduction of the corporate bond comes with unknown recovery rate. In [1] we presented a theoretical solution of the problem. Remark. Benchmark reduced form model of default begins with the similar definition of default. Next they introduce date-t spot price ignoring stochastic price at maturity of the bond. Recall that the price of the risky bond is a random variable which takes two values 1 and δ with known probabilities. Difference of these two approaches relates to the ways how one interprets date-t price of the bond. In theory asset price is interpreted as a continuous time random process. In practice we usually use close price of asset as the price at date-t. In such reduction of the price we can consider future price at T as close price at T. It fallows from the fact that all data we use represent only close historical prices. In other interpretation of the asset price close price of the date t can be interpreted as a good approximation of the whole trading
  • 7. 7 period which we associate with date-t. Good approximation can be justified by a low volatility of the date-t asset prices. If volatility cannot by considered as sufficiently small then use deterministic statistics like close, open admits additional risk leading to possible losses. Standard reduced form model deals with one equation and two unknowns. It could not present a unique solution of the default problem in simplest setting when default might occur only at maturity. That is why the primary financial institutions and rating agencies need to make additional assumption that recovery rate is a known such as for example 30%, 40% or other pre-specified value of recovery rate. Using a heuristic recovery rate helps to produce heuristic probability of default. It is clear that such simplification of the problem leads to distortion of the estimates of the recovery rate as well as probability of default which are the primary quantitative rating parameters. Our approach to default is based on stochastic market price was introduced in [1]. Stochastic price at t is defined for each market scenario which associated with a particular value of the bond during date-t period. With the help of stochastic price one can present independent equations for higher moments of the market price. The system of two equations for the first and the second moments is sufficient to calculate nonrandom recovery rate along with correspondent default probability. Following [1] let us briefly recall this construction. From equality (3) it follows that 1 – )T,t(B )ω,T,t(R = ( 1 – δ ) χ {  = T } (5) Then recovery rate can be written in the form )T,t(B )ω,T,t(R , for ω  {  ( ω ) = T } δ = δ ( t , T , ω ) = { 1 , for ω  {  ( ω ) > T } The distribution of the random variable δ ( ω ) is the distribution of the stochastic recovery rate. One choice of the statistical estimate Δ of the random recovery rate δ ( ω ) is its expectation Δ = E δ ( ω ). Stochastic interpretation of the recovery rate implies that reduction Δ of the rate δ ( ω ) implies market risk. This risk for the bond buyer is the higher value of the Δ than recovery rate which is specified by a scenario at the default moment. Buyer and seller risks are measured by probabilities of undervalue or overvalue of the recovery rate P { δ ( ω ) < Δ } , P { δ ( ω ) > Δ } correspondingly. Consider for example the estimate δ ( ω ) χ ( ω  D ), where D = { ω : δ ( ω ) < 1 }. This estimate specifies credit risk when bond seller could not pay initially promised amount of $1 at expiration date. At the same time this risk is appealing bond sellers. Define normalized spread function θ ( t , T ; ω ) by the formula )T,t(B )ω,T,t(R 1)ω,T,t(θ 
  • 8. 8 Note that this random function associated with normalized estimate of the LGD. The random function θ ( t , T ; ω ) is an observable function. Stochastic recovery rate is complete credit information of the bond. Nevertheless it is difficult to compare two distribution functions. To present credit characteristics in more comparable form we assume that observations on bond’s prices at t correspond to unknown deterministic recovery rate in case of default. We use function θ ( t , T ; ω ) to calculate a nonrandom market implied recovery rate < Δ > and its correspondent probability of default. From (5) it follows that E θ ( t , T , ω ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) P ( D ) E θ ² ( t , T , ω ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) ² P ( D ) Solving the system for < Δ > and P ( D ) we arrive at the solution < Δ > = 1 – )ω,T,t(θE )ω,T,t(θE 2 , P ( t , T , D ) = )ω,T,t(θE ])ω,T,t(θE[ 2 2 (6) Value < Δ > is market implied estimate and it does not equal to expected value of the stochastic recovery rate δ ( t , T , ω ) = )T,t(B )ω,T,t(R Value < Δ > depends on distribution of the random process R ( t , T ; ω ) which is an assumption of the model. Note that recovery rate < Δ > and correspondent probability of default represents estimates of the real credit risk. In general E θ p ( t , T , ω ) ≠ ( 1 – < Δ > ) p P ( D ) p = 3, 4, … . Hence the approach is good for price distribution which completely defined by its first and second moments. More crude but more explicit estimate can be presented as following. Assume for example that we fix a particular recovery rate < Δ > . Applying first moment equation we arrive at the formula P ( D ) = ( 1 – < Δ > ) – 1 E θ ( t , T , ω ) Thus one can compare probabilities of default for different bonds given the same value of the recovery rate. On the other hand one can fix probability of default and consider values of recovery rate of different bonds. For example one can fix 45% recovery rate and determine bonds which probabilities of default less than 0.2. Then fixing probability of default 0.3 one can find the bond which recovery rate is maximal or a set of bonds which recovery rates exceed 80%. Let us consider an implementation of randomization of the bond price. Let { t 0 } denote trading time interval of the date t 0 . Value of { t 0 } can be either a day, week , or other appropriate period. Define minimum and maximum values of the bond prices over the day period { t 0 }. Denote
  • 9. 9 D min ( t 0 , T ) = }t{u 0 min  D spot ( u , T ) , D max ( t 0 , T ) = }t{u 0 max  D spot ( u , T ) Symbol D spot is interpreted as spot price of the corporate bond. We interpret date-t 0 bond price as a random variable taking values on the interval [ D min ( t 0 , T ) , D max ( t 0 , T ) ] . There are different ways to assign distribution to random bond price D mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ). A simple distribution that can be used for D mkt ( t 0 , T , ω ) is uniform distribution. This distribution actually does not have any advantages or drawbacks with respect to other types of probability distributions that can be applied for randomization. Discrete approximation of the uniform distribution can be introduced as following. Fix a number m and denote δ j = j / m , j = 0, 1, … m Defined numbers k and q are defined by inequalities δ k ≤ R min ( t 0 , T ) < δ k + 1 and δ k + q – 1 ≤ R max ( t 0 , T ) < δ k + q Then putting Ω j = { u  { t 0 } : δ j ≤ R spot ( u , T ) < δ j + 1 } we put P { Ω j } = q – 1 , j = k + 1, k + 2, … k + q – 1. Note that numbers k and q depends on t 0 . This is a heuristic distribution that approximates real prices of the bond observed over the date t 0 . Other more practical way of randomization of the date-t 0 pricing data is an assumption that distribution P ( Ω j ) is proportional to the time when spot price P ( Ω j ) ~ measure { u  { t 0 } : R spot ( u , T )  [ δ j , δ j + 1 ] } We also can use other distributions that approximated prices of the bond. These randomizations are assigned to a particular date. The benchmark pricing uses one close price to represent a date t 0 bond price. Such approximation can be good if the value D max ( t 0 , T ) – D min ( t 0 , T ) is sufficiently small. Otherwise a lot of real pricing information will be lost. Pricing in stochastic environment implies market risk regardless the chance of default. For example buyer’s market risk is measured by the probability that buyer pays a higher price for the bond than it is implied by the market. If spot price at t 0 is identified as the close price of the date t 0 then market risk of the buyer is the probability P { R close ( t 0 , T ) > R ( t 0 , T , ω ) } = )T,t(R-)T,t(R )T,t(R-)T,t(R 0min0max 0close0max Let us define recovery rate and default distribution implied by the stochastic price of the corporate bond R ( t 0 , T ; ω ). Assuming for example uniform distribution of the recovery rate at maturity we arrive at the formula R ( t 0 , T , ω ) = δ j B ( t 0 , T ) , ω  Ω j P ( Ω j ) = q – 1 , j = k + 1, … k + q – 1 Hence given the date-t 0 pricing data of the risky bond δ j = δ j ( t 0 ) , k = k ( t 0 ) , q = q ( t 0 ) we can calculate credit risk based on prior assumed uniform distribution. Remark. Randomization of the date t spot price of the bond is a primary assumption of our approach to credit risk valuation. In modern finance it is common rule to use historical data time series as independent
  • 10. 10 observation. It is not quite accurate interpretation of the statistical sample. Indeed consider for example rate of return on an asset S i ( t , T ) = )t(S )t(S)T(S  and let t j < t j + 1 , j = 0 , 1, … n – 1 be a partition of the interval [ t , T ]. Then historical data represented by time series i ( t j , t j + 1 ) is usually interpreted as independent observation over real rate of return. Given historical data one should first to complete test of independence. Second unknown historical data such as rate of return is assumed to present independent observation of the random variable. Hence unknown parameters mean and variance are assumed to be constant. If not one should expect a large deviation between model and real data. Also if parameters of the model could not be assume to be constant one can observe other effects such as ‘fat’ tails. It can occur because variance depends on time and fuzzifies data. Consider corporate zero coupon bonds that admit default at any moment during its lifetime. Recall approach that leads us to exponential distribution of the default moment. Introduce no default probability distribution function P ( t ) = P {  > t } and let t 0 < t 1 <…< t n = T be a partition of the interval [ t 0 , T ]. Function P ( t ) is monotonic decreasing function in variable t. Our problem is: given no default up to the moment t j to calculate probability that there is no default up to the future moment t k , k > j. A solution of the problem can be represented by the conditional probability P ( t k , t j ) = P {  > t k |  > t j } Bearing in mind that default time depends on initiation date t 0 all functions defined bellow are also depend on t 0 . Bearing in mind that P {  > t k   > t j } = P {  > t k } = P ( t k ) we note that P ( t k , t j ) = }tτ{P }tτ{P j k   = )t(P )t(P j k The probability of default on ( t j , t k ] is then equal to Q ( t k , t j ) = 1 – P ( t k , t j ) = 1 – )t(P )t(P j k = )t(P )t(P-)t(P j kj Putting t j = t and t k = t + Δ t we arrive at the equality Q ( t + Δ t , t ) = – )t(P )t('P Δ t + o ( Δ t )
  • 11. 11 Denote λ ( t ) = )t(P )t('P . Then P ( t ) = exp –  t t 0 λ ( s ) d s There are other types of distributions that can be applied for default time modeling. These types are Weibull distribution, Lognormal, Power, Gamma distributions. These distributions have multiple parameters that can be used for better than exponential approximations of the default time. Function λ ( s ) in exponential distribution is known as a hazard rate. A discrete time approximation of the continuously distributed default time can be represented in the form  λ ( ω ) =  n 1k t k χ {  ( ω )  ( t k – 1 , t k ] } + T χ {  ( ω ) > T } For simplicity we assumes that zero coupon bond admits default at the dates t j . There are a few pricing settlements of the corporate bond at the time of default. Fractional recovery of the market value δ j B ( t j , T ) that is paid at t j . Other types of default settlements are the contingent claim of value defined as δ j B – 1 ( t j , T ) paid at T and the fractional recovery of the Treasury value δ j at T. Given a particular choice of the default settlement a discrete time approximation of the cash flows of the corporate bond can be represented in one of the forms CF A 1 ( ω ) =  n 1j χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) χ ( t = t j ) + χ (  λ > T ) χ ( t = T ) CF A 2 ( ω ) =  n 1j χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B – 1 ( t j , T ) χ ( t = T ) + χ (  λ > T ) χ ( t = T ) CF A 3 ( ω ) =  n 1j χ (  λ = t j ) δ j χ ( t = t j ) + χ ( t > T ) χ ( t = T ) Here χ ( t = t j ) is indicator function in t which specifies value of transaction between buyer and seller which takes place at t j . Cash flow CF A 1 defines recovery rates δ j of the corporate bond with respect to the value of the risk free bond with equal maturity. Also note that as far as the bid and ask prices are assumed in theory to be equal for a fixed maturity date T the bond price at a future date t j , t j < T does not depend on time when bond was issued. In other words on the run risky or risk free bond issued at t j and the similar bond issued prior to the date t j have the same price at the date t j . Note that theoretically cash flows CF A k , k = 2, 3 can be rewritten in the CF A 1 form. Hence we assume that bond is represented by the formula CF A 1 . The stochastic market price of the bond at t 0 can be represented as the PV of the cash flow CF A 1 . Thus
  • 12. 12 PV { CF ( ω ) } = R ( t 0 , T , ω ) =  n 1j χ {  = t j } R ( t 0 , T , ω ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T ) = =  n 1j χ {  = t j } B ( t 0 , t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T ) = (7) =  n 1j χ {  = t j } R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T ) + χ {  > T } B ( t 0 , T ) Next for writing simplicity we omit index λ and low index A 1 which specifies cash flow. For the fixed t 0 ratio δ j on the right hand side (7) depends on t j and does not depend on T . The recovery rate of the bond at the date of default δ j B ( t j , T ) depends on T . Risk factor that affects bond price (7) associated with default time distribution is referred to as credit risk. Values B ( t j , T ) which are unknown at initiation date t 0 specify market risk of the recovery rate of the corporate bond. Indeed replacing values B ( t j , T ) in formula (7) by market implied forward discounting rate B ( t j , T , t 0 ) we use date-t 0 estimate of the real rate which arrives at the date of default. Future value of the CF ( ω ) is equal to FV { CF ( ω ) } =  n 1j χ (  λ = t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) B – 1 ( t j , T ) + χ (  λ > T ) = =  n 1j χ (  = t j ) δ j ( ω ) + χ (  > T ) No arbitrage pricing on [ t 0 , T ] we defined in [1] by equality B – 1 ( t 0 , T ) PV { CF ( ω ) } = FV { CF ( ω ) } where cash flow CF was associated with risk free bond. Spot price of the risk free bond is assumed here to be a constant while risky bond spot price is a random variable. Therefore B – 1 ( t 0 , T ) PV { CF ( ω ) } = B – 1 ( t 0 , T ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) = = B – 1 ( t 0 , T ) [  n 1j χ (  = t j ) B ( t 0 , t j ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ (  > T ) B ( t 0 , T ) ] = =  n 1j χ (  = t j ) B – 1 ( t j , T , t 0 ) δ j B ( t j , T ) + χ (  > T ) = =  n 1j χ (  = t j ) δ j ( ω ) + χ (  > T ) = FV { CF ( ω ) }
  • 13. 13 Therefore PV of the stochastic cash flow represents no arbitrage (stochastic) market price of the bond. There is no market risk on [ t 0 , T ] as no arbitrage pricing excludes market risk. Nevertheless early selling of the bond might represent market risk to counterparty. Indeed let us define market risk of the corporate bond. We defined spot price as a random variable. By definition scenario ω is equal to a particular price of the bond during trade time of the date t 0 . Note that prices of the bond at different moments can be equal to each other. Investor buying bond at date t 0 does not know either exact moment of default or recovery rate at this moment. Such uncertainty implies that counterparty could loss or makes a profit based on realized market scenario. On the other hand price defined by (7) does not eliminate credit risk which can be specified by a choice of default time distribution. Remark. Recall that standard approaches to corporate bond pricing deal with expected value of the market implied PV of the CF. This approach replace future rate by its market implied estimate. Such reduction incorporates market risk. This risk is specified by the difference between real future rate and its market implied estimate. For a small standard deviation it might be reasonable approximation of the stochastic price R ( t 0 , T , ω ) to a single number R spot ( t 0 , T ). It can be open, close price, or for example R spot ( t 0 , T ) = E R ( t 0 , T , ω ) For each future date t j market risk is implied by the fact that B ( t j , T , t 0 ) ≠ B ( t j , T ). Applying a stochastic model of the future rates [4] one can estimate a chance P { B ( t j , T , t 0 ) > B ( t j , T ) } or P { B ( t j , T , t 0 ) < B ( t j , T ) } at the date t 0 . Such estimates can justify reduction of the stochastic price to single number as a representation of the date-t 0 bond price. Now let us consider a generalization of the method used for calculation recovery rate and probability of default (6) to cover general discrete time pricing model. In formula (7) dates t j , j = 1,2 … n represent possible dates of default. Suppose (in theory) that bonds with expiration dates at t j , j = 1, 2, … n are available on the market. Applying (3) we arrive at the formula ( 1 – δ 1 ) χ {  = t 1 } = 1 – )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 10 10 From this equality it follows that ( 1 – δ 1 ) P {  = t 1 } = E [ 1 – )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 10 10 ] ( 1 – δ 1 ) 2 P {  = t 1 } = E [ 1 – )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 10 10 ] 2 Solving the system for recovery rate and default probability we arrive at the values
  • 14. 14 δ 1 = 1 – ] )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 1[E ] )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 1[E 10 10 2 10 10   , P {  = t 1 } = ( 1 – δ 1 ) – 1 E [ 1 – )t,t(B )ω,t,t(R 10 10 ] = (8) = 2 1010 2 1010 ])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E }])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E{   , P {  > t 1 } = 1 – P {  = t 1 } Bearing in mind Jensen’s inequality it is easy to verify inequality P {  = t 1 } = 2 1010 2 1010 ])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E }])ω,t,t(R)t,t(B[E{   ≤ 1 Formulas (8) represent first term on the right hand side (7) which corresponds to a set of scenarios D 1 = { ω :  = t 1 }. Next we note that value of probabilities P ( D j ) = P { ω :  = t j } and correspondent recovery rates could be adjusted by taking into account that {  > t j – 1 }, j = 2, 3, … n . Such adjustment implies on credit risk exposure and it can be realized by applying conditional probability P {  λ = t j |  > t j – 1 }. Taking into account inclusion {  > t j }  {  > t j – 1 } we can conclude that P {  λ = t j + 1 |  > t j , …  > t 1 } = P {  λ = t j + 1 |  > t j } Given that {  ( ω ) > t j – 1 }, j = 2, 3, … n we use estimate of the price of the bond at the moment t j – 1 provided by market implied forward value. Definition of the market implied forward risky discount rate which in contrast to the risk free discount rate should take into account default time distribution. It follows from (7) that R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } = R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T ) χ {  = t j } (9) j = 1, 2, … n. Here B ( t j , T ) = B ( t j , T , ω ) is future rate known only at t j and it is unknown at t 0. Let us apply market implied forward rate as an estimate of the real forward rate. Then we arrive at the reduction which decompose bond price R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } = [ δ j B ( t 0 , t j ) ] B ( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j } = = R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) B ( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j } Solving latter equation for R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) brings us the formula
  • 15. 15 R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B – 1 ( t j , T , t 0 ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) χ {  = t j } (9) Note that transition from (9) to (9) implies market risk and the fact that bonds R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) , j = 1, 2, … n – 1 might not exist on the market. On the other hand taking into account equality R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) χ {  = t j } we define market implied forward risky discount rate R ( t j – 1 , t j ; t 0 , ω ) , ω  {  = t j } by equality R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j } = = B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j } Bearing in mind that R ( t 0 , t j – 1 , ω ) χ {  > t j – 1 } = B ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) χ {  > t j – 1 } we conclude that R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) χ {  = t j } = B – 1 ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t 0 , t j , ω ) χ {  = t j } = (10) = B – 1 ( t 0 , t j – 1 ) R ( t 0 , T , ω ) B – 1 ( t j , T , t 0 ) χ {  = t j } Market implied forward discount rate R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) is represented by forward starting bond that admits default only at its maturity t j . We can now apply estimates represented in formula (8). Applying formulas (8) to the function R ( t j – 1 , t j , t 0 , ω ) defined by (10) we arrive at the formulas δ j ( t 0 ) = 1 – ] )t,t,t(B )t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B 1[E ] )t,t,t(B )t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B 1[E 0j1-j 0j 1 01-j0 1 R 2 0j1-j 0j 1 01-j0 1 R     (11) with correspondent conditional probabilities of default P {  = t j |  > t j – 1 } = ( 1 – δ j ( t 0 ) ) – 1 [ 1 – E )t,t,t(B )t,T,t(B)ω,T,t(R)t,t(B 0j1-j 0j 1 01-j0 1  ] No default conditional probability is then equal to P {  > t j |  > t j – 1 } = 1 – P {  = t j |  > t j – 1 } Unconditional probability of default at the date t j and no default over lifetime of the bond could be defined by the formula P {  = t j } = P (  = t j |  > t j – 1 )    1j 0k [ 1 – P (  = t k |  > t k – 1 ) ]
  • 16. 16 (11) P {  > T } = 1 –  n 1j P (  = t j |  > t j – 1 )    1j 0k [ 1 – P (  = t k |  > t k – 1 ) ] Formulas (1.11), (1.11) represent recovery rate and probability of default values of the zero coupon corporate bond in discrete time setting. Remark. Let us add some remarks on randomization. We generalized spot price notion of the bond. Usually date-t price of the bond is associated with a particular price such as close price of the bond at the date t. Our approach interprets bond price at date t as a random variable R ( t , T , ω ) taking values in the interval [ }t{u min  R ( u , T ) , }t{u max  R ( u , T ) ] Therefore market scenario associated with a particular value of the bond, i.e. ω = R ( u , T ) for a some moment u  { t }. The use of a fixed price such as close price at date t should be interpreted as an approximation of the random variable implies market risk. If we consider random price at a future moment t + Δ t then the probability space [ }tt{u min  R ( u , T ) , }tt{u max  R ( u , T ) ] does not coincide with the one that is defined at t. Therefore dealing with dynamic market we should introduce a unique probability space. Next we associate probability space Ω R with the set of measurable functions ω ( t ) such that }t{u min  R ( u , T ) ≤ ω ( t ) ≤ }t{u max  R ( u , T ) } t  [ t 0 , T ]. Prior to expiration date values of the corporate bond does not represent default event. Hence time of default of the bond can be thought as an internal company factor and it can be interpreted as a random variable. As far as values of the bond do not completely define time of default distribution the probability space Ω ( R ) should not interpret default time  ( ω )  ( t 0 , +  ) , ω  Ω  . The term ‘ should not interpret default time’ suggests that in general  ( ω ) does not measurable function on Ω ( R ). We introduce measurable space { Ω , B } where Ω = Ω ( R )  Ω  , B = B ( R )  B  . Here symbol B denote σ-algebra of Borel sets on correspondent space. Probability measure P on measurable space { Ω , B } is defined by equality P ( A  Δ ) = P { R ( t , T , ω )  A ,  ( ω )  Δ } A  B ( R ), Δ  B  . For a random variable ξ ( ω ) on { Ω , B , P } denote expectation with respect to market scenarios generated by the values of the bond while default time remains stochastic. Such construction implies that values of the bond and default time are mutually
  • 17. 17 independent random variables and symbol E R denotes conditional expectation with respect to -algebra generated by the default time E R ξ ( ω ) = E { ξ ( ω ) | B  } Note that it is quite a strong assumption and it is very popular in credit risk valuations. Corporate coupon bearing bond pricing. Zero coupon corporate bonds pricing scheme can be applied to coupon bearing bond. Suppose for simplicity that default dates coincide with coupon payment dates T 1 < T 2 < … < T m = T. Then cash flow of the coupon bearing bond from bond to bond buyer perspective can be written in the form CF ( ω ) =  m 1j χ (  = T j ) {  1-j 1k c χ ( t = T k ) + δ j [ c  m ji B ( T j , T i ) + + B ( T j , T m ) ] χ ( t = T j ) + χ (  > T ) [  m 1j c χ ( t = T k ) + χ ( t = T m ) ] In this formula recovery rate is assigned to outstanding debt value defined at default moment. The PV reduction at t of the cash flow CF ( ω ) defines market price of the corporate bond depending on market scenario which incorporate unknown values of the risk free bonds B ( T j , T i ) at future moments T j , T i and time of default. Assume that corporation simultaneously issued zero coupon and coupon bonds. In this case investors can expect that loss-ratio due to default of the zero and nonzero coupon bonds are equal. Otherwise there exists hypothetical arbitrage opportunity. The notion ‘equal loss-ratio’ in latter statement should be refined. We interpret bond default as default of the corporation and therefore default of the corporation affects on all corporate bonds issued by this corporation. One should assume that probability distribution of default time for corporate zero and nonzero coupon bonds are the same. Recall that recovery rate of the zero coupon bond conditional on default at T j can be represented in the form c δ j ( t , ω ) B ( T j , T , ω ), which is unknown at t and can be estimated by deterministic value δ j ( t ) B ( T j , T , t ) . Hence recovery rate of the zero coupon corporate bond is interpreted as a portion δ j ( t ) of the date-T j PV of the face value of the bond. Following this idea we define recovery value of the coupon bond at T j as a portion δ c j ( t ) of the outstanding balance of the coupon bond on [ T j , T ]. Hence, recovery rate of the coupon bond can be defined as δc j [ 1 + c  m 1ji B – 1 ( T i , T ) + c B – 1 ( T j , T ) ] The value δc j we call recovery ratio. For the zero coupon bond, c = 0 recovery rate notion coincides with recovery ratio. Total losses due to default are equal to ( 1 – δ c j ) [ 1 + c  m 1ji B – 1 ( T i , T ) + c B – 1 ( T j , T ) ]
  • 18. 18 Theoretically the value of the losses at T of the zero and nonzero coupon bonds of the corporation that defaults at T j should be equal for each scenario. In this case we eliminate arbitrage opportunity between zero and non zero coupon bonds for each scenario. Hence 1 δ1 )T,T(Bc1 ])T,T(Bc)T,T(Bc1[)δ1( j i 1 m 1ji j 1 i 1 m 1ji c j           Solving latter equation for the recovery rate of the coupon bond rate we arrive at the formula δc j ( t , ω ) = 1 – )T,T(B)T,T(Bc1 ])T,T(Bc1[))ω,t(δ1( j 1 i 1 m 1ji i 1 m 1ji j         Market implied estimate of the above stochastic recovery rate can be represented as δc j = 1 – )t,T,T(B)T,T(Bc1 ])t,T,T(Bc1[)δ1( j 1 i 1 m 1ji i 1 m 1ji j         Recall that using market implied forward estimate δc j implies market risk as far as δc j ( t , ω ) ≠ δ c j .
  • 19. 19 References. 1. I. Gikhman, BASIC OF PRICING 1, http://www.slideshare.net/list2do/basic-pricing , http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2428024. 2. I. Gikhman, Corporate Debt Pricing, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1163195 3. Multiple Risky Securities Valuation I, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1944171 4. Fixed Rates Modeling. 2013 p. 25, http://www.slideshare.net/list2do/fixed-rates-modeling http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2287165