SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 5
Devon Bull
ECON 765
Professor Rosenbloom
Examining Economic Growth between the Great Depression and WWII
The Great Depression is considered to be the worst period in U.S. economic history.
Consequently, it is commonly thought that little scientific progress and with it technological
developments were made in this period. However, using Solo’s model and other historical data
researcher Alexander Field hypothesizes that the period from 1929-1941 was the most
technologically progressive period in U.S. history. Despite huge economic setbacks Field
believes much of the economic boom during the Second World War has its roots in the Great
Depression. Field examines the roles increased technological and organizational advances,
critical infrastructure creation, and the role of R&D spending in this period. Field tests his
assumption by comparing two radically different periods of extraordinary economic growth in
the twentieth century to determine what was responsible for these advances.
To start Field examines multifactor productivity growth which appears to have peaked in
the second quarter of the twentieth century (pg. 1399). This growth seems to start in 1929 and
work by a variety of researchers such as Gordon suggest it slowed after the Second World War.
Field then argues that this growth is mainly due to technological advancement and uses Solow’s
work to explain the TFP growth rates of other time periods relative to the Great Depression.
Specifically Field believes the period from 1929-1941 is critical to understanding long-term
technical change in the U.S. up to the present day (pg. 1400). Primarily he is concerned with
whether these “extraordinarily high rates of MFP” are attributable to the war or prior technical
advances (pg. 1400).
In order to answer these question of what caused this jump in MFP growth he must
separate these timeframes into roughly comparable periods. To do this he must select years in
which the economy is at similar stages of the business cycle (pg. 1402). This is not a simple task
and we will examine Field’s decisions in depth later on. Field relies on Kendrick’s data for his
examination of the periods. Field analyzes and explains his decisions as he makes slight
modifications to Kendrick’s data to get what he believes is a “more accurate representation” of
the period (pg. 1403). He then arrives at the two periods of 1929-1941 and 1941-1948. The
endpoint of 1941 is chosen over Kendrick’s 1937 because Field argues unemployment was
relatively more similar to 1929 than 1937 was. Field also states notes that in 1941 military
spending and production hadn’t increased enough to make a large difference in our analysis, a
point we will revisit later. Using these timeframes Field finds multifactor productivity growth of
the private domestic economy to be 2.27% from 1929-1941 and 1.51%, using Kendrick’s data.
Clearly then there appears to be critical differences between the periods and Field then goes on
to compare and contrast them for further analysis.
During the Great Depression period of 1929-1941 Field finds evidence of rapid
technological and organizational advances in the United States. Breakthroughs and new
products/technologies occurred in a wide variety of fields. Field lists breakthroughs in fields
such as: aeronautics, transportation, communication, chemical engineering and many others.
All these breakthroughs took place before the war (pg. 1401). Field also notes that “during the
1930’s, industry R&D expenditures more than doubled” (pg. 1406). The amount of employed
research scientists grew by 72.9% from 1929-1933 and almost tripled during 1933-1940 (pg.
1406). Furthermore, this time period saw large amounts of critical infrastructure development
creation such as highways, roads, residential housing, and wholesale/retail distribution
facilities. The combined effects of technological innovations and government infrastructure
development (which literally paved the way for long-term growth) arguably led to the
incredible growth of this period.
The alternative period of 1941-1948 saw a significant increase in total output,
specifically the war period of 1942-1945. There were also a number of advances in things like
radar, atomic energy, metal working, etc. Certain sectors saw increases in labor productivity of
160% during the war (pg. 1402). This explosive growth isn’t the average across all industries,
other sectors saw more modest increases of 25% (pg. 1401). Field also states that these
increases in productivity could be explained by the movement of workers from fields with
relatively low labor productivity to ones with significantly higher labor productivity such as
airframe construction. Thus, this shift could account for the increased output during the war
but this growth is unfeasible after the war as military demand for these products dropped
substantially. Field also notes: “there is relatively limited evidence of beneficial feedback from
wartime production to civilian activity post WW2” (pg. 1402). Ultimately he finds the war hurt
productivity growth by draining skilled workers and even the increased labor productivity there
was little net economic gain during the war. In sum, Field argues the war was detrimental the
high growth rate the U.S. experienced from 1929-1941.
There are several notable things to point out in Field’s work. Firstly, his choice of the
year 1941 as the endpoint instead of Kendrick’s choice of 1937. As Field notes, U.S. military
spending had increased by a total of 5% of the U.S. GDP in 1941. We could use this to argue
that this increase in military spending is responsible for the fall in unemployment that makes
1941 a “better comparison” to 1929. However, this is a spurious comparison in my mind since
we want to analyze the economy before the economic impact of the war and then compare the
two. If we already accept that military spending artificially lowered unemployment then we
won’t have an accurate representation of what actually occurred. I will admit I’m not sure what
the correct year to use is, that would require multiple calculations, but I would argue that it is
most likely to be found between Kendrick’s choice of 1937 and Field’s choice of 1941. While
you may not have the most comparable business cycles (at least I’massuming that without
actually knowing the data) it could theoretically still be a more accurate representation than
either choice.
In addition to the data interpretation we also have to consider how Field contrasts the
two periods in his individual analyses. He uses arguments to explain the growth of the 1929-
1941 period such as the increase in R&D researchers and their employment numbers. How
much of an impact did hiring more R&D researchers have on the number of scientific
breakthroughs? I would argue that the sheer amount of R&D researchers has a limited
correlation with the actual number of technological breakthroughs.
Field’s work introduced a number of ideas and facts that occurred during a time that I
had formerly associated with little growth and development. His findings raise a number of
questions related to the role of technological advances in fueling economic growth. His work
also highlights the role of the private and public sectors in driving this growth. While the
findings are arguable imperfect due to his data choices, I believe it does give us great insights
into this historical period. We can all learn something from his research.

More Related Content

Similar to Examining Economic Growth between the Great Depression and WWII

WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docx
WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docxWWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docx
WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docxshericehewat
 
FinalProject
FinalProjectFinalProject
FinalProjectKarl Fink
 
Lattice Energy LLC- Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...
Lattice Energy LLC-  Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...Lattice Energy LLC-  Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...
Lattice Energy LLC- Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...Lewis Larsen
 
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold War
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold WarAn Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold War
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold WarJessica Navarro
 

Similar to Examining Economic Growth between the Great Depression and WWII (9)

Field powerpoint
Field powerpointField powerpoint
Field powerpoint
 
WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docx
WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docxWWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docx
WWII CLASSShort and constructive response to classmates.docx
 
Dissertation
DissertationDissertation
Dissertation
 
FinalProject
FinalProjectFinalProject
FinalProject
 
Powerpoint
PowerpointPowerpoint
Powerpoint
 
Lattice Energy LLC- Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...
Lattice Energy LLC-  Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...Lattice Energy LLC-  Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...
Lattice Energy LLC- Macroeconomics Technology and Long Sweep of History-Apri...
 
krav paper
krav paperkrav paper
krav paper
 
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold War
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold WarAn Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold War
An Historian S Perspective On Technology And The Cold War
 
MilDisEcon4
MilDisEcon4MilDisEcon4
MilDisEcon4
 

Examining Economic Growth between the Great Depression and WWII

  • 1. Devon Bull ECON 765 Professor Rosenbloom Examining Economic Growth between the Great Depression and WWII The Great Depression is considered to be the worst period in U.S. economic history. Consequently, it is commonly thought that little scientific progress and with it technological developments were made in this period. However, using Solo’s model and other historical data researcher Alexander Field hypothesizes that the period from 1929-1941 was the most technologically progressive period in U.S. history. Despite huge economic setbacks Field believes much of the economic boom during the Second World War has its roots in the Great Depression. Field examines the roles increased technological and organizational advances, critical infrastructure creation, and the role of R&D spending in this period. Field tests his assumption by comparing two radically different periods of extraordinary economic growth in the twentieth century to determine what was responsible for these advances. To start Field examines multifactor productivity growth which appears to have peaked in the second quarter of the twentieth century (pg. 1399). This growth seems to start in 1929 and work by a variety of researchers such as Gordon suggest it slowed after the Second World War. Field then argues that this growth is mainly due to technological advancement and uses Solow’s work to explain the TFP growth rates of other time periods relative to the Great Depression. Specifically Field believes the period from 1929-1941 is critical to understanding long-term technical change in the U.S. up to the present day (pg. 1400). Primarily he is concerned with
  • 2. whether these “extraordinarily high rates of MFP” are attributable to the war or prior technical advances (pg. 1400). In order to answer these question of what caused this jump in MFP growth he must separate these timeframes into roughly comparable periods. To do this he must select years in which the economy is at similar stages of the business cycle (pg. 1402). This is not a simple task and we will examine Field’s decisions in depth later on. Field relies on Kendrick’s data for his examination of the periods. Field analyzes and explains his decisions as he makes slight modifications to Kendrick’s data to get what he believes is a “more accurate representation” of the period (pg. 1403). He then arrives at the two periods of 1929-1941 and 1941-1948. The endpoint of 1941 is chosen over Kendrick’s 1937 because Field argues unemployment was relatively more similar to 1929 than 1937 was. Field also states notes that in 1941 military spending and production hadn’t increased enough to make a large difference in our analysis, a point we will revisit later. Using these timeframes Field finds multifactor productivity growth of the private domestic economy to be 2.27% from 1929-1941 and 1.51%, using Kendrick’s data. Clearly then there appears to be critical differences between the periods and Field then goes on to compare and contrast them for further analysis. During the Great Depression period of 1929-1941 Field finds evidence of rapid technological and organizational advances in the United States. Breakthroughs and new products/technologies occurred in a wide variety of fields. Field lists breakthroughs in fields such as: aeronautics, transportation, communication, chemical engineering and many others. All these breakthroughs took place before the war (pg. 1401). Field also notes that “during the 1930’s, industry R&D expenditures more than doubled” (pg. 1406). The amount of employed
  • 3. research scientists grew by 72.9% from 1929-1933 and almost tripled during 1933-1940 (pg. 1406). Furthermore, this time period saw large amounts of critical infrastructure development creation such as highways, roads, residential housing, and wholesale/retail distribution facilities. The combined effects of technological innovations and government infrastructure development (which literally paved the way for long-term growth) arguably led to the incredible growth of this period. The alternative period of 1941-1948 saw a significant increase in total output, specifically the war period of 1942-1945. There were also a number of advances in things like radar, atomic energy, metal working, etc. Certain sectors saw increases in labor productivity of 160% during the war (pg. 1402). This explosive growth isn’t the average across all industries, other sectors saw more modest increases of 25% (pg. 1401). Field also states that these increases in productivity could be explained by the movement of workers from fields with relatively low labor productivity to ones with significantly higher labor productivity such as airframe construction. Thus, this shift could account for the increased output during the war but this growth is unfeasible after the war as military demand for these products dropped substantially. Field also notes: “there is relatively limited evidence of beneficial feedback from wartime production to civilian activity post WW2” (pg. 1402). Ultimately he finds the war hurt productivity growth by draining skilled workers and even the increased labor productivity there was little net economic gain during the war. In sum, Field argues the war was detrimental the high growth rate the U.S. experienced from 1929-1941. There are several notable things to point out in Field’s work. Firstly, his choice of the year 1941 as the endpoint instead of Kendrick’s choice of 1937. As Field notes, U.S. military
  • 4. spending had increased by a total of 5% of the U.S. GDP in 1941. We could use this to argue that this increase in military spending is responsible for the fall in unemployment that makes 1941 a “better comparison” to 1929. However, this is a spurious comparison in my mind since we want to analyze the economy before the economic impact of the war and then compare the two. If we already accept that military spending artificially lowered unemployment then we won’t have an accurate representation of what actually occurred. I will admit I’m not sure what the correct year to use is, that would require multiple calculations, but I would argue that it is most likely to be found between Kendrick’s choice of 1937 and Field’s choice of 1941. While you may not have the most comparable business cycles (at least I’massuming that without actually knowing the data) it could theoretically still be a more accurate representation than either choice. In addition to the data interpretation we also have to consider how Field contrasts the two periods in his individual analyses. He uses arguments to explain the growth of the 1929- 1941 period such as the increase in R&D researchers and their employment numbers. How much of an impact did hiring more R&D researchers have on the number of scientific breakthroughs? I would argue that the sheer amount of R&D researchers has a limited correlation with the actual number of technological breakthroughs. Field’s work introduced a number of ideas and facts that occurred during a time that I had formerly associated with little growth and development. His findings raise a number of questions related to the role of technological advances in fueling economic growth. His work also highlights the role of the private and public sectors in driving this growth. While the
  • 5. findings are arguable imperfect due to his data choices, I believe it does give us great insights into this historical period. We can all learn something from his research.