SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 38
Download to read offline
Would Implementation of the
Gold Dinar Affect Trade Among
OIC Countries?
M. Luthfi Hamidi
Abstract: This study attempts to analyze whether the implementation of the gold
dinar proposal would affect trade among OIC members, since gold is considered a
more stable currency, as it is less risky than fiat money. Empirical results produced by
thisstudyprovethatfiatmoney,particularlyrealexchangerateof theUSdollaragainst
gold, has an absolutely negative impact on developing countries’ exports. Although
its direct effect on trade is very low, the variable itself is statistically significant at 5%
level of significance. In contrast, those involved in the gold dinar trade bloc will likely
increase their respective intra-trade by more than 2 units. In other words, the gold
dinar bloc offers to those members a trade-creating effect. This effect is more robust
than the benefit generated by the outstanding economic bloc within OIC including
AMU and CEAU. Furthermore, gold dinar also generates considerable efficiency in
terms of trade payment. If six leading OIC exporting countries join in the gold dinar
bloc, trade efficiency in terms of payment will be around 76.68%.
JEL Classification: F02, F10, F36, E42, P45.
I.  Introduction
The gold dinar has been a controversial issue among OIC member states
ever since the former Prime Minister of Malaysia, Mahathir Mohammad,
M. Luthfi Hamidi, Bank Muamalat Indonesia (BMI), and Lecturer in Islamic Business at
the University of Paramadina, Jakarta, Indonesia.
This paper is a shorter version of the author’s master dissertation submitted to Markfield
Institute of Higher Education, Leicester, UK. The author would like to thank to Dr. Mehmet
Asutay for his supervision and insightful comments during completing this work. The
author wishes to extend his thanks to Dr. Mustafa Edwin Nasution for his suggestion on the
econometric estimation procedure.
© 2009, international association for islamic economics
Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009, pp. 31–68.
32 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
initiated public discussion of the proposal in 2001, arguing that the gold
dinar would boost inter-OIC trade.
That trade is certainly extremely low. One of the striking factors
inhibiting such trade is high exchange rate volatility of the member states’
domestic currencies so that, in order to reduce that risk, most of them use
‘hard’ currency such as the US dollar in international trade. But that does
not altogether remove the risk since the dollar, like other fiat money, also
tends to fluctuate in value: the notion of gold dinar is therefore seen as an
attractive alternative since its value is expected to be more stable than fiat
money.
The important question that needs to be asked and properly answered
is whether the gold dinar really would affect trade among the member states
of the OIC. Unless there is a positive answer, the gold dinar will remain a
wish or fantasy and not become a reality. This paper attempts to evaluate
and examine the gold dinar issue from several standpoints. Firstly, it seeks
to assess whether the gold dinar would be a stable currency and whether
it would (or not) have a significant impact on trade. For this reason, the
performance of gold is contrasted with that of the dollar and other hard
currencies such as the DM and Yen. Secondly, the paper tries to evaluate
whether a gold dinar trade bloc is likely (or not) to trigger a trade-creating
effect1
which can increase trade among its members. Finally, if the first two
questions are answered positively, the further task is to calculate how much
gold is required to support the trade and then to determine whether the
member states own sufficient gold reserves.
II. Literature Review
2.1. Trade in the Islamic world
In the Islamic tradition, trade has not only been the way to obtain reciprocal
benefits for the parties involved, but also a primary means to spread Islamic
teachings to different parts of the world. It has also played an important
role in unifying the Islamic world.2
Thus, the failure of trading among
Islamic countries implies disunity among them and is a signal of the
weakened bargaining power they have at their disposal in relation with other
countries.
The establishment in 1972 of the Organization of Islamic Conference
(OIC) prompted a hope that Muslim countries that share similar political
and economic interests would cooperate. The OIC was also intended to
33Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
serve as a forum where the problems faced by Muslim countries could be
tackled by them together. Among other concerns, the issue of trade gained
priority in OIC as trade volume among Muslim countries was and remains
very low, even though most of the Muslim countries are blessed with
abundant natural resources. In 2003, the trade amongst Muslim countries
was only around 13% of the total trade. This is the highest record during the
last five years (see Table 1).
Table 1: Trade among OIC Member Countries (US million dollar)
Trade 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999
Total intra-trade 151,272 123,972 115,793 109,376 83,402
Total trade 1,153,847 947,629 907,947 919,203 751,098
Percentage 13.11 13.08 12.75 11.89 11.1
Source: SESRTCIC statistics
In general there is an incremental trade growth of OIC members, but
most of it is dominated by oil and relies on primary commodity exports
(Table 2a and Table 2b) while being heavily dependent on industrialized
countries for the import of manufactured products (Table 3). That, in turn,
makes the Muslim countries dependent on and enormously affected by the
world economy, and they are, in consequence, subordinate to the economy
of the industrialized world (Shalaby, 1988:90).
Table 2a: Share of Oil to the Total Export for the OIC Leading Exporters (%)
No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999
1 Saudi Arabia 89 90 92 85
2 UAE 92 - - -
3 Malaysia 9 9.7 9.6 7
4 Indonesia 24 25.3 25 23
5 Turkey 1.9 1.4 1 1
6 Pakistan 1.9 2 1 1
7 Nigeria 100 99.6 98.9 99
8 Iran 86 84 91.2 75.7
9 Kuwait - 79 79 90.2
10 Syria 72 76 76.3 68
Source: SESRTCIC Statistics
34 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 2b: Share of Primary Commodity to the Total Export of the OIC
Leading Exporters (%)
No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999
1 Saudi Arabia 90 91 93 87
2 UAE 96 - - -
3 Malaysia 21 20 19.6 20
4 Indonesia 46 44 43 46
5 Turkey 14.5 15.1 15 16
6 Pakistan 53 50 47 53
7 Nigeria 97 97.2 98 98
8 Iran 91 90 93 -
9 Kuwait - 80 80 91.5
10 Syria 93 92 92.2 92.6
Source: SESRTCIC Statistics
Table 3: Share of Manufactures to the Total Imports of the OIC Top Ten
Exporters (%)
No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999
1 Saudi Arabia 79 79 76 78
2 UAE 86 - - -
3 Malaysia 83 83 83.9 85
4 Indonesia 59 61 61 69
5 Turkey 68 67 70 73
6 Pakistan 53 50 47 53
7 Nigeria 76 76 76 67
8 Iran 82 76 73 -
9 Kuwait - 79 79 79
10 Syria 64 65 65 59
Source: SESRTCIC statistics
2.2. Economic cooperation among OIC countries
Economic cooperation among OIC member countries is believed to be a
way forward to overcome the obstacles inhibiting trade flow. A significant
achievement in 1978 was the establishment of The Islamic Chamber of
Commerce, Industry and Commodity Exchange (ICCICE)3
in Karachi.
Furthermore, the focus on economic cooperation has improved consistently
since the founding of The Islamic Centre for Development of Trade (ICDT)4
in Casablanca in 1981.
35Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Full economic cooperation gained momentum once there has been a
proposal to establish an Islamic Common Market (ICM). The ICM will be
a kind of vehicle based on ideological unity to bridge the gap among Muslim
countries with the main target to facilitate optimal intra-Islamic utilization
of their resources (Sadeq, 1996: 39). The ICM is considerably more complex
than a Free Trade Area (FTA)5
or Customs Union (CU),6
since it encourages
cooperation not only in the trading of goods, but also in regard to mobility
of factors of production. Thus, the ICM is to be characterized by free
movement of capital, labour, service, as well as entrepreneurship (Satiroglu,
1996: 6; Nienhaus, 1996; 91; Sadeq, 1996: 44; Alatas, 1987: 32).
Some scholars hold that the establishment of the ICM will overcome
trade barriers and enhance effective economic cooperation. On the other
hand, few of those scholars have taken care to point out that the low level
of intra-trade among OIC members is a result of the low level of their
development (Bhuyan, 1996:26). According to Bhuyan, the establishment of
economic cooperation among the members should be a catalyst to accelerate
their industrialization rather than directly to improve the level of trade.
Another concern in light of the establishment of the ICM is its
applicability. It is believed that the ICM is a long-term target that needs
to be consistently adhered to. Regrettably, however, the future of the ICM
is unclear since there is barely even a definite timetable agreed, among the
members, to formalize the work of ICM.7
Instead of planning to move
together gradually as a step closer towards ICM goals, some of OIC members
have been reluctant to remove the barriers to free movement of capital and
labour which protect their national interest (Nienhaus, 1996:101).
2.3. The impact of currency volatility on trade
Currency volatility is considered to be one of the barriers to increase
trade. Many of the developed countries adopted a floating rate regime
on their national currency in 1973. Since the inception of that regime, the
industrialized countries have experienced a significant decline in their
economic growth. Between 1960 and 1973, their average yearly growth rate
was 4.4%, while, during 1973–1990, it dropped to 1.3% (Grauwe, 1998:240).
The decline in economic growth can be traced to the change that has
taken place in international trade since the floating exchange regime.Because
the variability of exchange rate increases uncertainty, it leads investors to
reduce risk by shifting a part of their international trade into domestic trade.
This in turn hits the international trade and results in slowdown in growth.
36 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
One may argue that the agents are free to utilize hedging facilities to protect
themselves against loss. However, since this facility is not without cost, it
means that any resulting gains or benefits are set off against the losses or
drawbacks (Grauwe, 1998:241).
Recent studies provide more robust evidence with respect to the effect
on trade of the currency volatility. A study on G-38
exchange rate volatility
suggests that one percentage increase in that rate decreases real exports of
developing countries by, on average, about 2 percent (Esquivel and Larrain,
2002). Vergil (2002) examines trade flows between Turkey and its trade
partners and finds that exchange rate volatility has a significant negative
effect on trade. Arize et al. (2004) came up with the same result. They
investigated exchange rate volatility in eight Latin American countries and
report that the exchange rate has a significant negative impact on export
demand both in the short and long run.
III. Methodology
3.1. Measuring exchange rate volatility and modelling its impact on trade
One of the most common measures to capture time-varying volatility on
exchange rates is Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity,
known as the GARCH model, developed by Bollerslev (as cited by Verbeek,
2000:266). This model has been employed in previous studies such as
McKenzie (1998) and Vergil (2002).
Another way to measure exchange rate volatility is coefficient of
variation (CV) of exchange rate. Esquivel and Larrain (2002) define
exchange rate volatility as the time-varying twelve-month coefficient of
variation (CV) of the real exchange rate. This method is actually used to
indicate a dispersion of the real exchange rate. The formula to calculate CV
can be written as follows:
�
CVt +m =
1
m
(εt +i−1 −ε)2
i=1
m
∑






1
2
ε
				
(1)
where m is the order of moving average and ε is the mean of the bilateral
exchange rate between month t and t+m-1. In this study, CV will be used to
measure the level of volatility of exchange rate, which can then be utilized
to predict its impact on trade. Since in this study annual data is used, the
−
37Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
moving average method is perhaps no longer relevant. Instead of using
the formula given above, this study proposes to calculate CV based on the
following formula:
				 
(2)
where, x is an individual value, n is the number of observations (test values)
and x is the mean of n values. In other words, CV is calculated by dividing
standard deviation by mean value (Chou, 1965:107; see also Kane, 1969:78).
Esquivel and Larrain (2002) investigate the impact of the volatility of G-3
currencies on developing countries trade. They propose a model to estimate
the exports of developing countries as a function in the following form:
X = f (world demand, bilateral dollar real exchange rate, G-3 currency),
which can be expressed as follows:
(3)
where Xt
denotes exports of country t, GDPw
represents the real World GDP,
RERUS
is bilateral real exchange rate in terms of the dollar and the variables
VOL are the coefficients of variation (CV) of the G-3 real exchange rates. In
this study, the model will be utilized with subtle modification by introducing
variable Ddollar/gold
in the model. Besides, a model based on pure exchange rate
will also be assessed.
Model 1:
(4)
Model 2:
(5)
Model 3:
(6)
where VG represents volatility values based on the GARCH technique, VC
is volatility values based on the coefficient of variance (CV) method, and
RER represents the absolute values of real exchange rate of the respective
38 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
countries. Xt
is total export of developing countries, in dollar millions.
GDPw
is World’s Gross Domestic Product in dollar millions. Ddollar/gold
is real
exchange rate of dollar in terms of gold, while DMDM/dollar
and Yyen/dollar
are real
exchange rate of DM and yen with respect to the dollar.
GDPw
represents the scale economy of the world. It is expected to be
positive since the larger the value of GDPw
, the larger the value of exports
will be. Ddollar/gold
, DMDM/dollar
and Yyen/dollar
represent risk which may occur as a
result of exchange rate variability in international trade. These are expected
to be inversely correlated with the exports. Increase in the exchange rate
volatility will likely decrease the volume of exports.
3.2. The gravity model to capture trade-creating effect
One of the famous econometric models to assess trade between countries is
the gravity model, developed by Tinbergen (1962) and Poyhonen (1963). The
simple gravity model introduces trade between two countries as a function
of their gross national product (GNP) or gross domestic product (GDP),
and the distance between them, usually calculated as the distance between
their respective capital cities. The volume of trade should positively correlate
with their respective GDP and income per capita, since a country with
considerably large GDP will tend to trade more than the one with a small
GDP. Greater distance between them should reduce trade volume, since it
incurs transportation and information costs.
Employing the gravity model, many researchers have observed the
effect of common currency on trade. Recent research by Glick and Rose
(2002) suggest that participation in a currency union has doubled trade
and is statistically significant. However, Glick and Rose’s work is challenged
by other researchers. Pakko and Wall (2001), for instance, also use the
gravity model but find that the trade-creating effect of common currency is
definitely lower then the findings of Glick and Rose.
As for OIC member countries, Bendjilali (2000) suggests an empirical
gravity model for these countries by adding a variable of IDB’s import trade
financing operations to country i, while Hassan and Islam (2001) employ
the basic gravity model to assess whether there is (or not) a significant
trade-creating effect from implementing a trade bloc among OIC members.
In this study, that model is modified by introducing a gold dinar trade bloc.
The model can be written as follows:
log(TRADEijt
) = α ± β1
log(GDPit*
GDPjt
) ± β2
log(PCIit*
PCIjt
) ± β3
log(DISTANCEij
) (7)
	 ± β4(BORDERij
) ± β5
(BLOCij
) ± εij
39Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
For simplicity, the above equation is rewritten as follows:
	 (8)
Trade is expected to increase with the size of domestic economy G (GDP),per
capita income Y (PCI), common border B (BORDER), joining in the same
trade bloc (BLOC) and to decline with distance D (DISTANCE). Coefficient
of β1
, β2
, β4
, and β5
should be positive, while β3
should be negative.
3.3. Measuring the amount of gold to serve trade and its generated
efficiency
Once the gold dinar is implemented, one may ask: How much gold is
required to support the trade? How much efficiency can be generated?
Yakcop (2002a and 2002b) introduces the Bilateral Payment Agreement
(BPA) model, which can be extended into a Multilateral Payment Agreement
(MPA) to illustrate how trade will be facilitated by gold dinar. Furthermore,
Meera and Larbani (2004) develop an efficient trade matrix to indicate the
detail of trade conducted by gold dinar.
In this study, the MPA scheme is utilized. It is essential to introduce
the BPA scheme first before turning to further steps. Let us say Malaysia and
Indonesia sign a BPA scheme whereby trade balances will be settled up in
quarterly periods. Both countries agree that trade will be denominated in
gold dinars, one unit being defined as one troy ounce of gold. Bank Negara
will pay Malaysian exporters in ringgit, based on the ringgit/gold dinar
exchange rate prevailing at the date of export. Likewise, Malaysian importers
have to pay ringgit to Bank Negara to the same amount of their import
value. Meanwhile, Bank Indonesia will also do the same for Indonesia’s
exporters and importers. At the end of the first quarter, the trade cycle is
ended, the total export from Malaysia to Indonesia, say, is 3 million gold
dinar and the total export from Indonesia to Malaysia is worth 2.5 million
gold dinar (Table 4).
Table 4: Gold Dinar Settlement by BPA Scheme
Gold Dinar (million)
Export to Malaysia Indonesia Total Export Net Payment
Malaysia   2.5 2.5 -0.5
Indonesia 3   3 0.5
Total Import 3 2.5 5.5  
40 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 4 shows that at the end of the quarter, Malaysia has a trade deficit
of 0.5 million gold dinar, while Indonesia has a surplus of 0.5 million gold
dinar. Accordingly, Bank Negara as central bank will pay Bank Indonesia
0.5 million gold dinar. Initially, it is agreed that both of them have a gold
custodian account in Bank of England, for instance. Then the actual
payment can be transferred into the account of Bank Indonesia in Bank of
England. It is interesting to note that only a small amount of 0.5 million gold
dinar is able to support the total trade value of 5.5 million gold dinar.
This scheme will be more efficient, if other participants join and
therefore the mechanism of payment will use the MPA scheme which in
essentials is the same as the BPA, but involves more members. From the
above sample we can calculate the amount of gold dinar to support trade by
simple equation as follows:
(1)	 Gold required to last trade:
				 (9)
where, Xi
and Ii
represent the total export and import of country i to its
trading partners, in millions of gold dinar. n is number of countries involved
in the transaction (the economic bloc).
(2)	 The efficiency generated from gold can be written as:
					(10)
where TVT stands for total value of trade and Np is the net payment.
3.4. Data source and definition
The statistical data in this study is mainly obtained from three sources: (i)
Statistical, Economic and Social Research and Training Centre for Islamic
Countries (SESRTCIC) for all data pertaining to OIC member countries;
(ii) Direction of Trade Statistics, which is prepared quarterly by IMF for
data particularly related to detail intra-trade (export and import) among
members; (iii) United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
(UNCTAD) for data particularly related to export volume of developing
countries.
41Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
In addition, some data is retrieved from other sources, such as the distance
between capital cities among OIC member countries,which is easily accessed
in (http://www.wcrl.ars.usda.gov/cec/java/capitals.htm). Data relating to the
exchange rates of DM and Yen against dollar and dollar in terms of gold are
obtained from www.econstats.com and Global Financial Data, respectively.
The definition of each of the selected variables in the models is as
follows:
Exports (X): Data show the f.o.b. (free on board) value of goods provided to
the rest of the world valued in US dollars. Export of Developing Countries (X)
is total export generated from developing countries.
GDP (G): GDP is defined as the sum of the gross value-added by all resident
and non-resident producers in the economy plus indirect taxes and minus
any subsidies not included in the value of the products, in US dollars. GDP
World (GDPw
) is the sum of total GDP generated from all countries in the
world. GDP Per Capita Income (Y) is calculated by dividing GDP by the
mid-year population. The following charts represent GDP of OIC Countries
(GDP OIC), exports of developing countries (X), and GDPw
.
Real Exchange Rate (RER): It is the exchange rate of one particular country
compared with another at a particular point in time, taking into account
their respective inflation. One of the common measures to calculate RER
is by adjusting nominal exchange rate by the ratio of the foreign price level
to the domestic. Due to availability of data, in this study RER is computed
by indexing, that is, creating an index. The first year of observation, namely
1972, is taken as the base value, with the first exchange rate value for that
year, say x, equated to 100. Mathematically this can be simply written as
follows:
						 (11)
where, xt
is real exchange rate at time t, and x0
is real exchange rate at the
base year which is 100. Yyen/dollar
and DMDM/dollar
represent the bilateral real
exchange rate of yen and DM with respect to the dollar, while Ddollar/gold
illustrates the real exchange rate of dollar in terms of gold price. These are
displayed in Figures 1, 2, and 3.
42 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Figure 1: Real Exchange Rate Yen/USD
Figure 2: Real Exchange Rate DM/USD
Figure 3: Real Exchange Rate USD/Gold
Source: www.econstats.com and Global Financial Data
TRADEijt
(T): the bilateral trade comprising total exports and imports
between countries i and j at time t in dollar.
43Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
DISTANCEij
(D): The distance in kilometres between two countries (i.e.
between the capital cities i and j).
BORDERij
(B): A dummy variable, which takes a value of 1 if two countries
have a common border and zero otherwise.
BLOCKij
: A dummy variable, which takes a value of 1 if one country joins in
the trade bloc, and zero otherwise. The trade blocs to be evaluated are those
within OIC countries. A new trade bloc, namely the gold dinar trade bloc,
will be introduced.
IV. Empirical Result
4.1. Exchange rate volatility and its impact on trade
As discussed in the previous section, volatility of exchange rate is evaluated
by computing coefficient of variance (CV). The results are depicted in
Figures 4, 5, and 6.
Figure 4: Volatility Dollar/Gold (Coefficient of Variance Method)
Figure 5: Volatility DM/Dollar (Coefficient of Variance Method)
44 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Figure 6: Volatility Yen/Dollar (Coefficient of Variance Method)
Recalling the model described in the previous section, there are three
models presented which refer to equation 4, 5, and 6. By conducting unit
root test, we found the variable(s) in Model 1 (see Table 5) and Model 3 (see
Table 7) to indicate a non-stationary feature.
Table 5: Unit Root Test for Model 1
Variables Test Statistics & Critical Values Adjusted
  Levels 1st differences Regression
  ADF CV(5%) ADF CV(5%) Variable
LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796 - - -
L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943 - - -
VG(D) -3.7158(0) -2.9665 - - -
VG(DM) -3.3137(1) -2.9706 - - -
VG(Y) -1.9079(3) -2.9798 -6.365 -2.9706 DVG(Y)
Table 6: Unit Root Test for Model 2
Variables
Test Statistics &
Critical Values
  Levels
  ADF CV(5%)
LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796
L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943
VC(D) -4.1887(1) -2.9706
VC(DM) -4.1713(0) -2.9665
VC(Y) -3.2690(3) -2.9798
45Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 7: Unit Root test for Model 3
Test Statistics & Critical Values Adjusted
 Variables Levels 1st differences Regression
  ADF CV(5%) ADF CV(5%) Variable
LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796 - - -
L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943 - - -
RER(D) -8.3549(0) -2.9665 - - -
RER(DM) -2.6850(0) -2.9665 -4.0074 -2.9706 DRER(DM)
RER(Y) -2.0152(0) -2.9798 -3.5134 -2.9800 DRER(Y)
Given this condition, the regression results may be misleading and
incorrect (Koop, 2000:152). Thus, while the regression for Model 2 remains
the same, Model 1 and 3 need to be adjusted as follows:
Model 1:
(11)
Model 3
  (12)
The OLS results for all models are set out in Tables 8, 9, 10 and 11.
Table 8: Regression Result for Model 1
No. Variables
Expected
Results
Actual
Results
Coefficient t-stat
Significant
level
1 Intercept - - -25.5887 -10.6263 0.000 *
2 LogGDPw + + 2.3057 16.6202 0.000 *
3 VG(D) - - -.6627E-4 -3.3867 0.002 *
4 VG(DM) - - -.3940E-4 -1.7939 0.085 **
5
∆ VG(Y)
- + .4733E-4 1.9730 0.060 **
Notes: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (two-tailed); ‘**’ indicates significance at α=10% (2 tailed)
Table 9: Regression Result for Model 2
No. Variables
Expected
Results
Actual
Results
Coefficient t-stat
Significant
level
1 Intercept - - -27.2689 -9.4127 0.000 *
2 LogGDPw + + 2.4022 14.1914 0.000 *
3 VC(D) - - -0.018090 -3.4178 0.002 *
4 VC(DM) - - -0.007324 -0.39427 0.697
5 VC(Y) - - -0.008019 -0.5504 0.584
Note: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (two-tailed)
46 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 10: Regression Result for Model 3
No Variables
Expected
Results
Actual
Results
Coefficient t-stat
Significant
level
1 Intercept - - -26.9085 -12.2342 0.000 *
2 LogGDPw + + 2.3827 18.6695 0.000 *
3 RER(D) - - -0.009723 -3.2855 0.003 *
4
∆ RER(DM)
- + -0.010074 2.5180 0.019 **
5
∆ RER (Y)
- + 0.001525 .36465 0.719
Notes: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (2 tailed); ‘**’ indicates significance at α=10%
(2 tailed)
Table 11: Overall results Models 1, 2, and 3
No. Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
1 2
R 0.96230 0.95033 0.96163
2 2
R 0.95602 0.94238 0.95523
3 F statistics 153.1557 119.5711 150.3674
4 DW statistics 0.80718 0.91669 1.1093
As can be seen from Tables 11, 12 and 13, the individual variable performs
well. The coefficient of determination of each model ( 2
R ) also indicates
that the explanatory variables in each model are able to explain more than
95 percent of variation taking place in the dependent variable. Besides,
the models also demonstrate overall significance as indicated by high
F-statistics. The overall coefficient of variables is statistically significant even
with one percent level of significance. However, the models may encounter
severe serial autocorrelation since their DW statistics are terribly low (Table
11). Some remedies are taken to completely remove the problem from the
equation by transforming the variables into first differences form. Thus, the
above model is revised as follows:
Model 1
(13)
Model 2
(14)
Model 3
	   (15)
The regression results of the above models are presented in Table 12.
47Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 12: Regression Results of the Revised Models
No.
Model 1
GARCH
Estimated
Values
Model 2
Coef. of
Variance
Estimated
Values
Model 3
RER
Estimated
Values
1
Dependent
Variable
∆log Xt
Dependent
Variable
∆log Xt
Dependent
Variable
∆log Xt
2 Intercept
-.004693
(-.06248)
Intercept
0.071721
(1.0246)
Intercept
0.093767
(1.6045)
3 ∆log GDPW
3.7468
(1.6984)
∆log GDPW
0.66625
(0.31141)
∆log GDPW
0.11494
(0.06396)
4 ∆VG (D)
-0.3111E-4
(-1.5566)
∆VC (D)
-0.011259
(-2.5102)
∆RER (D)
-0.0099251
(-3.1461)
5 ∆VG (DM)
-0.9410E-5
(-0.33142)
∆VC(DM)
-0.009850
(-0.66785)
∆RER
(DM)
-0.0028690
(-0.71586)
6 ∆VG (Y)
0.1647E-4
(0.54677)
∆VC (Y)
0.018811
(1.3252)
∆RER (Y)
0.0072179
(1.9074)
7 2
R 0.19624 0.29622 0.48737
8 2
R 0.062277 0.17893 0.40193
9 F-statistics 1.4649 2.5254 5.7044
10
DW-
statistics
1.2342 1.6194 2.0846
Note: Figures in parentheses are t-statistics
The revised models are able impressively to increase DW statistics,
which is a signal of improvement in dealing with problem of serial
autocorrelation. However, 2
R and F-statistics decrease sharply. The low of
2
R indicates that the explanatory variables no longer have strong power
to explain the independent variable, which was not the case in the original
model. Meanwhile, the low F-statistics (except for Model 3) illustrate
that the coefficient of variables as a whole are likely having no statistical
significance. Accordingly, Model 3 is chosen as the final model and will be
analysed subsequently.
The equation for the revised model (Model 3) can be written as follows:
∆logXt
= 0.093767 + 0.11494∆logGDPw
– 0.0099251∆RERDollar/Gold	
(16)
	 – 0.002869∆RERDM/Dollar
+ 0.0072179∆RERYen/Dollar
Two of the most noteworthy outcomes from equation 13 are that,
if world GDP increases by one unit, holding other variables constant,
48 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
the exports of developing countries also increase slightly by 0.114 units.
Inversely, if the dollar real exchange rate in terms of gold rises by one point,
the exports of developing countries decrease by 0.009 units. The variable
of RERdollar/gold
is statistically significant at 5% level of significance. However,
its impact on trade as indicated by the coefficient (0.009) is considered
low. Similarly, a one point increase in the real exchange rate of DM against
dollar (RERDM/dollar
) has an inverse effect on developing countries’ exports by
a mere 0.002 units (ceteris paribus). In addition, the variable is statistically
insignificant.
These low effects on trade are definitely interesting since other previous
researchers – Esquivel and Larrain (2002) for instance – reported a significant
impact. They reported that each one-unit increase in the volatility of DM
against dollar reduces developing countries’ exports by around 2 percent.
The difference may be caused by the data for developing countries. In this
study, aggregate data of developing countries’ exports, which is time series
data, is used whereas Esquivel and Larrain used panel data (individual data)
of developing countries’ exports. Moreover, in this study the regression
model chosen is based on the differenced form, while their study was based
on logarithmic form. The latter, as presented in the previous section, did not
work well, since it contains severe serial correlation problems.
Surprisingly, the variable of real exchange rate of yen against dollar
(RERyen/dollar
) in this study has positive effect on trade. A one point increase
in RERyen/dollar
tends to increase developing countries’ exports by 0.007 units.
Even though the impact is considerably low, the variable itself is statistically
significant at 10% level of significance. The positive sign on this variable
is the same as in Esquivel and Larrain’s results. However, they did not give
any special attention to why the sign of this variable is not as expected. This
anomaly might emerge because the yen actually is a less influential currency
for developing countries. The share of yen in the global currency in 2002
and 2003 is only 5.2 and 4.8 percent respectively (Table 13), while the share
of DM, which has merged into the euro, is 19.3 and 19.7 percent respectively
in the same year. Perhaps, most of the developing countries in Africa tend to
use European currency including DM (euro) rather than yen. It is reasonable
to argue that they tend to maintain their trade partnership with European
countries rather than with Japan for reasons of geographical proximity.
49Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 13: Official Foreign Exchange Reserve: Currency Share (%)
Currency 2000 2001 2002 2003
US dollar 66.6 66.9 63.5 63.8
Euro 16.3 16.7 19.3 19.7
Japanese yen 6.2 5.5 5.2 4.8
Pound sterling 3.8 4 4.4 4.4
Swiss franc 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.4
Unspecified currency 6.6 6.4 7.1 6.8
Source: European Central Bank (2005)
In general, the model has no strong explanatory power as indicated
by its low 2
R . That is a mere 48%, implying that the selected explanatory
variables within the model can only explain 48% of the variation taking
place in the dependent variable. However, this is still acceptable since, in the
financial field, 2
R is rarely impressive. Furthermore, the model as a whole
is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, as illustrated by its high
F-statistics. In addition the model is also free of the serial autocorrelation
problem. However, the model contains heteroscedasticity problem. This
does not destroy the unbiasedness and consistency of the estimations, but
these are no longer efficient (Gujarati, 1995:381).
4.2. Gold dinar’s trade creating effect: empirical result from gravity model
The gravity model utilized in this study contains eight explanatory variables,
namely GDP (the product of GDP’s country i and country j), Y (the product
of their per capita income), D (DISTANCE between their capital cities), and
dummy variables B (BORDER), GOLD9
(Gold Dinar Trade Bloc), CAEU10
,
AMU11
, and D-812
.
log(T) = a ± b1
log GDP ± b2logY ± b3
logD ± b4
B ± b5
GOLD ± b6
CARU (17)
	 ± b7
D8 ± b8
AMU
The complete set of regression results is presented in Table 14.
50 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 14: Regression Results of Gravity Model
No.
Original model
Estimated
Values
Observation 31
1 Dependent Variable Log(T)
2 Intercept
-4.0686
(-.44709)
3 LogGDP
.4001
(1.2348)
4 LogY
.12409
(.33743)
5 LogD
-.5176
(-.9495)
6 B
2.3309
(2.1959)
7 GOLD
1.6537
(1.9665)
8 CAEU
.4534
(.6658)
9 D-8
1.9810
(1.9943)
10 AMU
.16978
(.1684)
11 2
R .82133
12 F-statistics 12.6415
13 DW-statistics 1.8634
Note: Figure in parentheses are t-statistics
The model can be expressed in the equation as follows:
log(T) = –4.0686 + 0.4001logGDP + 0.12409logY – 0.51762logD + 2.3309B
	 +1.6537GOLD + 1.45349CAEU + 1.9810D8 + 0.16978AMU
The estimation of equation 17 suggests that an increase in one unit of
GDP and per capita income will tend to increase trade by 2.5 and 1.33 units
respectively.13
On the other hand, a one point additional distance between
countries will likely decrease trade by 3.23 units.14
However these variables are
statistically insignificant. Thus within a 5% level of significance, only variable
B (BORDER) is statistically significant. If we extend the level of significance
to 10%, variable GOLD and D8 are also statistically significant (Table 15).
51Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 15: The Property of t-test for the Equation 17
Variables tcal
ttab
(α=5%) Decision ttab
α=10% Decision
LogGDP 1.2348 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant
LogY 0.33743 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant
LogD -0.9495 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant
B 2.1959 2.079 Significant 1.7207 Significant
GOLD 1.9665 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Significant
CAEU 0.6658 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant
D-8 1.9943 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Significant
AMU 0.1684 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant
Note: n=30, k=9, n-k=21, for α=5% or 0.025(two tails) ttab
value = 2.079; α=10% or 0.05(two
tails) ttab
value =1.7207
Another point from the model is that having the same border and
participation in a trade bloc supports greater volume of trade. In the case
of sharing the same border, trade is increased by 2.3 units, whereas those
involved in gold dinar trade bloc will likely enjoy an increase in their trade
by 1.65 units.A similar result prevails for those in CAEU, D8, and AMU trade
blocs with an increase in trade of 1.45, 1.9, and 0.16 units, respectively. These
positive impacts on trade as a result of joining trade blocs is similar with
Hassan and Islam’s (2001) study. It also proves that joining in a trade bloc
will open a trade-creating effect. One interesting result here is conformity
of each sign. The actual sign for all of the variables does confirm with those
expected. It is a bit different with Hassan and Islam’s (2001) study, which
finds per capita income is negatively correlated with bilateral trade.
The 2
R value is 82% which means that the model has a high
explanatory power, and indicates that it has high goodness of fit. The
explanatory variables selected in the model can simultaneously explain 82%
of the variation taking place in the model. However, the model contains
heteroscedasticity problem. Multicollinearity may also arise since some
of its variables are statistically insignificant with low t-statistics including
variable per capita income (Y) and two trade blocs namely CAEU and AMU.
Perhaps, this is not surprising as variable Y is gained from the GDP value
divided by the respective population of each country. Similarly, few of the
members of CAEU are involved in the D8 group. In this respect, it is sensible
to omit these three variables from the equation presented in the revised
model, and the new results can be seen in Table 16.
52 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 16: Regression results of the revised model
No.
Revised model
Estimated
values
Observation 31
1 Dependent variable log(T)
2 Intercept
-9.5117
(-1.3793)
3 logGDP
.80253
(4.0997)
4 logD
-.60904
(-1.2415)
5 B
1.9587
(2.1096)
6 GOLD
2.1136
(2.7355)
7 2
R .78287
8 F-statistics 23.4353
9 DW-statistics 2.1948
Note: figure in parentheses are t-statistics
The equation of the model can be written as follows:
	 (18)
It can be seen that the reduced model performs better, as illustrated
by improving statistically significant variables (see Table 16). Another
interesting finding is the effect of gold if it were implemented as the
international currency for trade. Recalling equation 18 and its statistical
summary, it can be seen that only the distance variable (D) is statistically
insignificant. However, the sign of the variable is as predicted before. The
insignificant variable is a bit surprising since other researchers (Bendjilali,
2000, and Hassan and Islam, 2001) reported that distance is statistically
significant. Other variables such as GDP and border (B) are statistically
significant too. These results strengthen the previous studies.
The distinction of this study stems from the introduction of the gold
dinar trade bloc variable, something not witnessed in other studies. Those
involved in this bloc would enjoy an increase of their respective intra-trade
of more than 2 units. Moreover, this variable is statistically significant at 5%
level of significance, which is further convincing evidence.
53Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
In general, the model also demonstrates a highly desirable explanatory
efficiency, as the selected explanatory variables are indeed able to explain
more than 78% of variation taking place in the dependent variable. The high
F-statistics illustrate that the overall model is statistically significant even at
1% level of significance. In addition, the model is also free from serious error
derived from the serial correlation error and multicollinearity problem. It
may be deduced that the model used here is quite impressive.
4.3. The amount of gold dinars needed to support trade
As mentioned earlier, it is possible to calculate the quantity of gold dinars
needed to support trade simply by calculating the volume of trade, whether
it produces surplus or deficit. In presenting the gravity model, we said that
the gold dinar trade bloc is assumed to consist of six leading OIC exporting
countries. They are Saudi Arabia, UAE, Malaysia, Indonesia, Turkey, and
Pakistan. Table 17 shows their respective trade (export and import).
Table 17: The Trade among Six Leading OIC Exporting Countries in 2002
(Million Dollar)
Export to
Saudi
Arabia
UAE Malaysia Indonesia Turkey Pakistan
Total
Export
Saudi A   1695 343 1003 716 1196 4953
UAE 490   3827 105 92 1198 5712
Malaysia 370 835   1586 221 486 3498
Indonesia 475 720 2030   238 265 3728
Turkey 535 440 113 28   52 1168
Pakistan 390 837 64 81 110   1482
Total
Import
2260 4527 6377 2803 1377 3197 20541
Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003
In 2002, total trade among these six countries was more than 20.5
billion dollars. UAE is at the top rank of exporting countries with total
exports of around 5.7 billion dollars, while Malaysia is in the top rank of
importing countries with total imports of more than 6.3 billion dollars. It is
noteworthy that Turkey holds the lowest position both in terms of import
and export, perhaps because it tends to trade with its European partners
rather than Muslim countries.
54 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
From Table 17, the amount of gold dinars required to facilitate the
respective trade of these countries can be estimated. The first thing needing
to be taken into account is the gold price in the prevailing year which is in
2002. According to Global Financial Data, the price of one troy ounce of
gold in 2002 was 346.7 dollar. Hence, for instance, the total imports and
exports of Saudi Arabia are equivalent to 14.28 and 6.51 million gold dinars,
respectively. (This is worked out by dividing column (1) and (2) by 346.7
(see Table 18). The net payment for Saudi Arabia is thus equal to 7.76 million
gold dinars which is obtained by subtracting the figure in column (4) from
that in column (3). The amount of gold needed to support the trade is then
equal to 59.2 million gold dinars. This amount is equal to 13.4 million troy
ounces of gold or around 4.292 tons of gold (see Table 19).
4.4. The efficiency of the gold dinar
The last stage of the calculation is to calculate the efficiency that would be
generated if the gold dinar were to be implemented. Recall equation 10:
Efficiency = 				 (10)
From Table 18 the amount of net payment (Np) is the same with the
amount of gold dinar payable (or receivable),which is 13.8 million gold dinar.
Total value of trade (TVT) is the total amount of trade in the conventional
sense (if gold dinar would not be implemented), which is 20,541 million
dollars or equal to 59.2 million gold dinars. Hence the efficiency generated
from implementing the gold dinar is:
Efficiency = x 100 = 76.68 %
This figure 76.68% implies that the six leading exporting countries
enjoy the trade by only paying the remaining (around 23.31%) at the end
of the year. In other words, if the gold dinar were implemented, they could
save almost 4/5 of their budget for other economic allocations. It is indeed
a giant step forward that should encourage prosperity among the member
countries in the gold dinar trade bloc.
55Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 18:	Total Trade of Six Leading Exporting Countries, 2002
							 (million gold dinar)
Countries
Million Dollar Million Gold Dinar
ApproximationExport Import Export Import
Net
Payment
(1) (2) (3) (4) (3)-(4)
Saudi A 4953 2260 14.286 6.5186 7.767522 7.7
UAE 5712 4527 16.475 13.0574 3.417941 3.4
Malaysia 3498 6377 10.089 18.3934 -8.30401 -8.3
Indonesia 3728 2803 10.752 8.0848 2.6680125 2.7
Turkey 1168 1377 3.3689 3.97173 -0.6028267 -0.6
Pakistan 1482 3197 4.2745 9.22123 -4.9466397 -4.9
 Total     59.247 59.247 0 0
Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003
Table 19:	 Gold Required to Support Trade (million gold dinar, troy ounce, 	
							 and ton units)
Deficit by
Countries
Gold
Dinar
Surplus
Gold
Dinar Gold
Dinar
Total
Trade
Gold Required
Payable Countries Receivable Troy ounce Ton
Malaysia -8.3 Saudi A 7.7
59.215
13,800,000 4,29216
    UAE 3.4
Turkey -0.6 Indonesia 2.7
Pakistan -4.9    
Total -13.8   13.8
56 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
V. Discussion
The first question, whether the variability of exchange rate – particularly
dollars in terms of gold – has significant impact on trade, has already
been answered. As can be seen from equation 13, the model shows that
an additional one point on the exchange rate variability of the dollar in
respect of gold (RERdollar/gold
) tends to decrease the value of developing
countries’ exports by 0.009 units (holding other explanatory variables as
constant). The variable of RERdollar/gold
is statistically significant at 5% level
of significance. This is further proof that exchange rate variability tends to
decrease trade. However, its impact on trade as indicated by the coefficient
(0.009) is considered low and inconsistent with what the relevant literature
leads one to expect.
The establishment of a Gold Dinar Trade Bloc (GDTB), proposed for
the first time in this study, indicates a new hope for OIC members since
members of this bloc would enjoy an increase of their respective intra-trade
by more than 2 units. It is an initial indicator that a GDTB would be more
fruitful than other existing trade blocs among OIC countries. Moreover, this
variable is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, which is further
convincing evidence.
The model also promises the hope for OIC member countries of
making enormous budget savings. Assuming that the six leading countries
of OIC are to be GDTB members, the value of their intra-trade in 2002
stands at 20.5 billion dollars or almost 60 million gold dinars. However,
those taking part would not need to supply gold dinars in the same amount
as the total value of their trade, but only the amount of the net difference,
namely 13.8 million gold dinars. In other words, they would only pay for
around 23.31% of the total amount payable if paid in the conventional
way using dollars. Thus, the efficiency generated by using the gold dinar is
around 76.68%.
That figure would be even higher if the trade between the mentioned
member countries were to become larger. If, for instance, ten leading
exporting countries within the OIC agreed to settle their trade in gold
dinars (i.e. if four additional countries join to the bloc17
), the efficiency
will increase. In 2002, for the total trade among the 10 leading exporting
countries of 32.2 billion dollars (equivalent to 92.98 million gold dinar, see
Table 20), the net payment would be only 18.51 million gold dinars. In other
words, the efficiency generated would be 80.09%.18
57Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Table 20: Total Intra-Trade of Ten Leading Exporting Countries, 2002
(Million Dollar and Gold Dinar)
Countries
Million Dollar Million Gold Dinar
Approxi-
mation
Export Import Export Import Netpayment
(1) (2) (3) (4) (3)-(4)
Saudi A. 5593 2560.11 16.1321 7.384223 8.74788001 8.74
UAE 8202 6606.31 23.65734 19.05483 4.60250937 4.6
Malaysia 3895 6547.77 11.2345 18.88598 -7.6514854 -7.65
Indonesia 4284 4521.08 12.3565 13.04032 -0.6838189 -0.68
Turkey 1922 2835.27 5.543698 8.177877 -2.6341794 -2.63
Pakistan 1637 4087.42 4.721661 11.7895 -7.0678396 -7.06
Nigeria 1200 541 3.461206 1.560427 1.90077877 1.9
Iran 3056 2356.08 8.814537 6.795731 2.01880588 2.02
Kuwait 1608 1173.67 4.638016 3.385261 1.25275454 1.25
Syria 840.71 1009 2.424892 2.910297 -0.4854052 -0.48
Total 32237.71 32237.71 92.98445 92.98445   0
Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003
This figure implies that the ten leading exporting countries only need
one fifth of their current budget to support their trade. They can allocate
another 80% of the budget to other economic purposes. Hence, using the
gold dinar would be a breakthrough that could enhance prosperity among
the countries involved in the gold dinar trade bloc.
5.1. Transmission how gold dinar would increase trade
The following strategies are available to OIC members which trade among
themselves (see Figure 7):
Firstly, exporters/importers can use their domestic currency. This
is possible for those who enjoy relatively low volatility of their respective
national currency, which is the case only for a few countries, perhaps only
some of the oil-exporting ones. Hence, it is assumed that these few countries
may enjoy more trade than other OIC member countries.
The second strategy is that a hard currency such as the dollar takes
the place of the national currencies. Although hard currencies mostly have
a stable exchange rate, it does not necessarily follow that they are free from
risk. To remove risk completely from the business, there is no choice but
to hedge, for which additional costs are entailed. The trade would still be a
58 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
normal trade in the sense that although they have to pay an additional cost
for hedging, still they can predict their costs and benefits.
Finally, some exporters/importers have no opportunity to use hedging
facilities since these are not available in many developing countries (Meera
and Larbani, 2004). Thus, there is no choice in these countries except to use
the dollar, without hedging. This can worsen the uncertainty of business,
which in turn restrains exporters/importers from doing business, thus
leading to less trade.
Figure 7: Domestic Currency vs Hard Currency and Its Impact on Trade
59Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Once the gold dinar is established as the common currency for payment
for trade, some advantages could arise for participants. Joining in a common
currency, according to Grauwe (2000:58), will remove the uncertainty risk
due to volatility of the exchange rate. In the case of gold dinar, Meera (2004)
contends that gold dinar payment will totally eliminate exchange rate risk.
There is no need for a trader to hedge currency to minimize risk, because
hedging cost is fixed against the gold dinar itself. Furthermore, transaction
cost will be minimized since it can be affected electronically (see Figure 8).
Figure 8: The Mechanism of How Gold is Estimated to Increase Trade
Along with the benefits just mentioned, the gold dinar would improve
trade in three ways:
Firstly, the relative stability of gold may influence in two fronts (Izhar
and Asutay, 2005): the fluctuation of general prices is relatively controllable,
thus inflation should be relatively low; there is no opportunity to create
60 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
unlimited money, since this will be subject to availability of gold. Hence,
there will be harmonization between the real sector and the monetary
sector. As a result, the phenomenon of appreciation or depreciation will be
relatively manageable.
Secondly, as discussed earlier, implementing the gold dinar based
on MPA will provide massive efficiency in term of the amount of gold to
sustain the trade. In addition, since the members of the gold dinar bloc will
support each other, the trade-creating effect is expected to take place. Given
this situation, the gold dinar may serve as an optimum currency if more
countries are expected to join.On his famous optimum currency area (OCA)
theory, Mundell (1977a; 1977b) states that implementation of OCA would
also reduce transaction costs in trade. He affirms that “the more countries
join a currency area, the more efficient it will be”. The more OIC members
are involved, the more efficient it will be. From the empirical results, we
have already demonstrated that the efficiency of the GDTB increases from
76.68% to 80.09% after four other countries joining in the bloc.
Finally, aside from economic factors, the success of international trade
is basically also determined by political bargaining. The success of the gold
dinar will constitute an immense capital with which to negotiate with
developed countries, especially in respect of unfair trade practices. It is no
secret that the industrialized countries use their position in the World Trade
Organization (WTO) to protect their interests. Stiglitz (2002:244) points
out that some of them demonstrate a hypocritical attitude by advocating
the opening up of markets in developing countries while keeping their
own markets closed to the produce and products of developing countries,
such as textiles and agriculture. Hence, successful implementation of the
gold dinar will be the source of a new energy and confidence among OIC
countries so that they have a better bargaining position to deal with their
trade partners, particularly developed counties. This will produce incentives
which encourage not just intra-trade but also inter-trade.
5.2. Why does the idea not get off the ground?
The trade-creating effect and efficiency generated by GDTB so far are
convincing. Why then does the idea not move towards becoming a reality?
It may be argued that implementation is difficult due to inadequate gold
reserves in the countries concerned. As we just calculated for the year 2002,
the net payment was around 13.8 million gold dinars or the equivalent of
4,292 tons of gold. This entails vast reserves, beyond the capacity of the OIC
61Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
member countries (see Table 24). In 2002, total gold reserves held by the
deficit countries in the trade bloc was a mere 314.5 tons of gold.
Table 21: Gold Dinar Required for Intra-Trade and Gold Reserve
Kept by Central Bank in 2002
Countries Gold Required (Ton)20
Gold Reserve (Ton)21
Malaysia 2,581 36.4
Turkey 186.6 116.5
Pakistan 1,525 65.1
Total 4,293 218.0
At first glance, looking at Table 21, those countries could not effect their
trade based on the gold dinar on account of a lack of gold reserves. However,
this is not the case in fact since all of those countries do hold adequate
reserves in dollars. Malaysia, for example, in 2002 held over 34 billion dollars
in its reserve account. That amount is equal to 3,070 tons of gold. Other
countries also recorded large amounts of total reserves in dollars (see Table
22). In other words, basically, these countries are able to implement the gold
dinar by converting a part of their dollar reserves into gold, the potential of
which depicted in Table 23.
Table 22: Countries’ Total Reserve in 2002 and Its Value in Gold
Countries
Reserve Minus Gold22
(Million Dollar)
Reserve Value
(Million Gold Dinar)
Reserve Value
(Ton Gold)
Malaysia 34,221 98.7 30,699
Turkey 27,068 78.07 24,282
Pakistan 8,078 23.29 7,244
Total 69,367 200.06 62,225
Table 23: Potential Gold Reserve (Ton) and Gold Needed
to Settle Transaction (%)
Countries
Gold Required
(Ton)
Actual Gold
Reserve (Ton)
Potential
Gold Reserve
Gold Needed
to Serve %
Malaysia 2,581 98.7 30,699 8.4
Turkey 186.6 78.07 24,282 0.76
Pakistan 1,525 23.29 7,244 21.0
Total 4,293 200.06 62,225
62 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
As an illustration, Malaysia in 2002 had a reserve 34,221 million dollar. If
Malaysia would convert this reserve totally to gold, then they would have
potential gold reserve equal to 30,699 ton gold. Theoretically, although
Malaysia has had to pay 2,581 ton gold because of its suffer trade deficit with
its trade partners, still this deficit can be easily settled since it was only 8.4%
of its giant potential gold reserve (see Table 22 and 23).
5.3. Conclusion
This study has attempted to find whether and how the implementation of the
gold dinar proposal would affect trade among OIC members. The findings
from the empirical analysis and available evidence from the literature help
to answer this challenging question. The following remarks can be made in
light of the available evidence and the findings:
(i)	 The gold dinar is considered to be more stable than fiat money, i.e.,
the US dollar. The term ‘stable’ here has the practical sense of ‘low
volatility’, whereas the dollar is considerably more volatile. Empirical
results produced by this study prove that in terms of gold, dollar
tends to depreciate and its real exchange rate (RER) volatility has
an absolutely negative impact on developing countries’ exports.
The variable is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, as
explained previously. However, its direct impact on trade is very low as
illustrated by its coefficient (0.009), as shown earlier. Thus, the findings
are inconsistent with the hypothesis explored in this study.
(ii)	 Establishing a gold dinar trade bloc will likely encourage intra-trade
among OIC members. Empirical results in this study suggests that
those involved in the bloc will enjoy an increase of more than 2 units
of their respective intra-trade. This is indeed a very convincing result,
since the variable is also consistently statistically significant in various
models tested at 5% level of significance. In other words, the gold dinar
bloc is an economic bloc which offers to its members a trade-creating
effect. This effect is more robust than those generated by currently
existing economic blocs within the OIC, including AMU and CEAU.
(iii)	 Another interesting finding for those joining the gold dinar bloc is the
efficiency generated by it. Empirical results in this study demonstrate
that if six countries selected would join in the gold dinar bloc, trade
efficiency in terms of payments will be around 76.68%. which implies
that they only need to pay the remaining 23.32% at the end of the trade
63Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
period. This figure becomes larger if the number of member countries
is increased. A simulation by adding another four countries (making
the total number of countries involved 10) showed that the efficiency
increases to almost 80%. Such an improvement is perhaps because the
selected countries are the top ten leading exporting countries within
the OIC. Perhaps, this efficiency will tend to diminish slightly if the
additional joining countries do not have any significant intra-trade.
(iv)	From these three basic explanations, it may be deduced that the
implementation of the gold dinar proposal will be a move forward
for Muslim countries, in the sense that it will bring many economic
advantages. Their respective trade tends to increase. Unfortunately, the
project is likely not feasible since there are insufficient gold reserves held
by the members. If this can be tackled, perhaps the gold dinar would
become the main tool, not just to unite Muslim countries but also to
disseminate economic cooperation and foster prosperity among them.
5.4. Recommendation
Insufficient gold reserves held by most of Islamic countries will be the most
serious critical problem to be handled. To confront this shortage, former
Malaysian Prime Minister Mahathir suggested that those taking part in gold
dinar trade should help each other by purchasing some materials from the
poorest gold reserve countries thus enabling them to participate in the trade
(Mahathir, 2002). This probably would render a little help.
Alternatively, this study recommends two points:
(i)	 At the starting stage, use of the gold dinar can be restricted to facilitate
trade between member governments excluding private trade. There
are two advantages in this strategy: firstly, the amount of trade will be
reduced, that is, each member may hold sufficient gold stocks to sustain
their respective government’s trade; secondly, the administration
is likely to be less complex since the trade is fully backed by the
government.
(ii)	 The level of gold reserves can be improved by converting a significant
part of the country’s dollar reserves into gold. Almost all of the
countries assumed to be in the gold dinar have massive reserves in
dollars. Thus, by converting up to half of the dollar reserve into gold,
the insufficiency of gold stock to sustain trade can be met.
64 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Notes
1.	 That trade-creating effect (as opposed to trade-diverting effect) occurs when some
domestic production in a member state of the trade bloc is replaced by lower cost
imports from other members. See Salvatore (2001:328-329).
2.	 Trade was the main vehicle for the spread of Islamic teaching from Andalusia (Spain)
to the Cape of Good Hope in Africa and to the Malay Peninsula. See, for example,
Yakcop (2002a).
3.	 ICCICE is intended to promote trade, commerce and industrial cooperation.
4.	 At the official level this idea was first launched by Bangladesh in the Second Summit
Meeting of OIC Heads of States, held in Taif in 1981. A year later, the issue has gained
more attention once Morocco again sounded the need to shape ICM in the Third
General Assembly of the Islamic Chamber of Commerce (ICC) held in Casablanca.
Finally, the Fourth General Assembly of the ICC held in Jakarta in 1983, repeated the
importance of establishing an ICM (Harjono as cited in Sadeq, 1996:49). ICDT is
intended to encourage regular commercial contacts and promote the harmonization
of commercial and investment policies among member countries.
5.	 The most striking feature of an FTA is the removal of existing restrictions on trade
among the regional members (Satiroglu, 1986:5).
6.	 It is the next step after FTA has been established. Custom Union entails, as well as
removal of trade barriers, a common external trade policy to both members and non-
members (Satiroglu, 2000).
7.	One of the successful aspects of the implementation of the euro was the establishment
of a definite time table, which had to be adhered to by EU members. Ratification of
the Maastricht Treaty was meant to signal the beginning of the EU’s integration. See,
for example, Jovanovic (1997:18) and Keis (1997:42).
8.	 G-3 refers to the three major economic powers, namely USA, Japan, and Germany.
9.	 The six leading exporting countries are assumed to join this bloc. They are Saudi
Arabia, UAE, Malaysia, Indonesia, Turkey, and Pakistan.
10.	 The Council of Arab Economic Unity was established in 1957. It consists of Egypt, Iraq,
Libya, Jordan, Kuwait, Mauritania, Somalia, Sudan, Syria, UAE, and Yemen. In this
study four countries, namely Iraq, Mauritania, Somalia, and Sudan, were excluded due
to unavailability of data.
11.	 The Arab Maghrib Union (AMU) was established in 1987, comprising five countries:
Algeria, Libya, Mauritania, Morocco, and Tunisia. Again, due to incomplete data,
Mauritania and Morocco were excluded.
12.	 The D-8 was founded in 1997. It unites the eight countries of Bangladesh, Egypt,
Indonesia, Iran, Malaysia, Nigeria, Pakistan, and Turkey. All these countries are
included in the study.
13.	Since it is a double log model, the antilog value is employed. The antilogs of 0.4 and
0.12 are 2.51 and 1.33, respectively.
14.	 Antilog of 0.5176 is 3.293
15.	 Total trade	 =  20541 million dollar
			  
16.	 1 		 troy ounce	 = 0.311035 kilogram
	 13,800,000	 troy ounce	 = 4292283 kilogram
					 = 4,292 ton
17.	 It is assumed that Nigeria, Iran, Kuwait, and Syria are involved in the bloc.
65Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
18.	 The complete calculation is as follows:
		Net payment	  = Np	 = (8.74+4.6+1.9+2.02+1.25) million gold dinars
							 = 18.51 million gold dinars
		 Total value of Trade  =TVT	 = 92.98 million gold dinars
		 		 (TVT-Np)x100	 (92.98-18.51) x 100
		 Efficiency = 			 =
					 TVT			  92.98
							 = 80.09%
References
Alatas, Syed Farid (1987).“An Islamic Common Market and Economic Development”, Islamic
Culture, 61 (1), pp.28-38.
Arize, Agustine C.; Osang, Thomas, and Slottje, Daniel J. (2004). Exchange Rate Volatility in
Latin America and Its Impact on Foreign Trade. Available at <URL: http://faculty.smu.edu/
tosang/pdf/latin2.pdf >, Access Date: 8th August 2005.
Bendjilali, Boualem (2000). An Intra-Trade Econometric Model for OIC Member Countries: A
Cross Country Analysis. Jeddah: IRTI
Bernstein, Peter L. (2000). The Power of Gold. The History of an Obsession. New York: John
Wiley & Sons.
Bhuyan, Ayubur Rahman (1996). “Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries: Issues
and Prospectives”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards an Islamic Common
Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau.
Chou, Ya-lun (1965). Applied Business and Economic Statistics. New York: Holt, Rinehart and
Winston.
Dorn, James A. (1989).“Alternatives to Government Fiat Money”, Cato Journal, 9 (2), pp.277-
294.
Esquivel, Gerardo and Larrain B., Felipe (2002). The Impact of G-3 Exchange Rate Volatility on
Developing Countries. Harvard University Working Paper No. 86.
European Central Bank (2005). Review of the International Role of the Euro. Available at:
<URL: http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/ euro-international-role2005en.pdf >, Access Date:
1st August 2005.
Glick, Reuven and Rose, Andrew K. (2002).“Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The Time-
Series Evidence”, European Economic Review, 46 (6), pp. 1125-1151
Grauwe, Paul De (1989). International Money. Second Edition. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Grauwe, Paul De (2000). Economics of Monetary Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Greenspan, Alan (1966). Gold and Economic Freedom. Available at: <URL: http://shoemaker
consulting.com/GoldisFreedom/greenspan.htm>, Access Date: 19th December 2004.
Gujarati, Damodar (1995). Basic Econometrics. Third Edition. New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc.
Haberler, Gottfried (1983).“A Comment on ‘The Importance of Stable Money’”. Cato Journal,
3 (1) Spring, pp. 83-91.
66 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Hamidi, M. Luthfi (2005). The Implementation of Gold Dinar Proposal among OIC Member
Countries: Would It Affect Trade? Dissertation for MA Islamic Banking, Finance, and
Management at Markfield Institute of Higher Education, UK.
Hamidi, M. Luthfi (2007). Gold Dinar: Sistem Moneter Global yang Stabil dan Berkeadilan.
Jakarta: Senayan Abadi Publishing
Hassan, M. Kabir and Islam, Faridul (2001). “Prospect and Problem of a Common Market:
An Empirical Examination of the OIC Countries”, American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences,
18 (4), pp.19-45.
IMF (2004). World Out Look. Advance Structural Reforms. Washington DC: IMF
Izhar, Hylmun and Asutay, Mehmet (2005). Relative Stability of Gold Standard: A Theoretical
Study. Paper presented at the Global Finance Conference 2005, 27-29 June 2005, Trinity
College Dublin, Ireland.
Jovanovic, Miroslav N. (1997). European Economic Integration: Limits and Prospects. London:
Routledge.
Kane, Edward J (1969). Economic Statistics and Econometrics: An Introduction to Quantitative
Economics. London: Harper & Row Ltd.
Keis, Nikolaus (1997).“The Costs and Benefits of the Euro: a Case Study for Germany”, in Paul
Temperton (ed.). The Euro. Second Edition. Chicester: John Wiley & Sons.
Koop, Gary (2000). Analysis of Economic Data. West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Mahathir, Mohammad (2002). The Seriousness of the Gold Dinar. Keynote address presented
at International Seminar, Gold Dinar in Multilateral Trade, 22-23 October 2002, Organised
by IKIM, Malaysia.
McKenzie, M. (1998). “The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on Australian Trade Flows”,
Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 8, pp. 21-38
Meera, Ahamed Kameel Mydin (2004). “Hedging Foreign Exchange Risk with Forward,
Futures, Options and the Gold Dinar: a Comparison Note”, in The Theft of Nations. Selangor:
Pelanduk Publications.
Meera, Ahmad Kameel Mydin and Larbani, Moussa (2004). “The Gold Dinar: The Next
Component in Islamic Economics Banking and Finance”, Review of Islamic Economic, 8 (1),
pp.5-34.
Meier, Gerald M. (1998). The International Environment of Business. Competition and
Governance in the Global Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Miller, Joseph M. (n.d.). Monetary Gold Mismanagement in the Twentieth Century. Available
at:<URL: http://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials/ jmiller121497.html>, Access Date: 29 March
2005
Mishkin, Frederick S. (2001). The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Market. Sixth
Edition. London: Addison Wesley.
Mohd Dali, Nuradli Ridzwan Shah bin (n.d.). Investment from Islamic Perspective and
Mitigating Currency Risk with the Implementation of Gold Dinar.Available at:<URL:http: www.
67Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
microfinancenetwork.org/images/ndMitigatingCurrencyRiskwiththeImplementationof
GoldDinar.pdf>, Access Date: 4th April 2005.
MohdYusuf,Abu Bakar bin;Mohd Dali,Nuradli Ridzwan Shah bin;and Mat Husin,Norhayati
(2002). “Implementation of The Gold Dinar: Is It the End of Speculative Measures?”, Journal
of Economic Cooperation, 23 (3), pp.71-84.
Mundell, Robert A. (1997a). Could Gold Make a Comeback? Paper delivered at St. Vincent
College, Letrobe, Pennsylvania, March 12, 1997.
Mundell, Robert A. (1997b). Optimum Currency Areas. Paper presented at the conference on
Optimum Currency Areas, organized by Tel-Aviv University, December 5, 1997.
Nienhaus, Volker (1996).“Trade Relations, Factor Movements and Islamic Common Market”,
in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds). Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic
Economic Research Bureau.
Nort,Garry (2003).Gold is a Political Metal.Available at: <URL: <http://shoemakerconsulting.
com/GoldisFreedom/political-metal.htm>, Access Date: 1 February 2005
Pakko, Michael R. and Wall, Howard J. (2001).“Reconsidering the Trade-Creating Effects of a
Currency Union”, Review - Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 83 (5) Sep/Oct., pp. 37-45.
Poyhonen, P. (1963), “A Tentative Model of Trade between Countries”, Weltwirtschaftliches
Archiv, 90, pp. 91-113.
Reynolds, Alan (1983). “Why Gold?”, Cato Journal, 3 (1), Spring, pp.211-232.
Sadeq, Abul Hasan M. (1996).“Intra-Islamic Economic Integration: Regionalism to Ummatic
Globalism”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds), Towards an Islamic Common Market.
Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau.
Salvatore, Dominick (2001). International Economics. Seventh Edition. New York: John Wiley
& Sons.
Samuelson, P.A. (1969). “The Gains from International Trade Once Again”, in Jagdish
Bhagwati (ed.), International Trade. Middlesex: Penguin Books.
Satiroglu, A. Kadir D. (2000).“The Theory of Economic Integration and Its Relevance to OIC
Member Countries”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards an Islamic Common
Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau.
SESRTCIC (1980). Areas of Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries. Ankara:
Organisation of the Islamic Conference.
Shakweer, Farooq (1996). “Prospects for the Establishment of the Islamic Common Market
and the Role of Islamic Development Bank”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards
an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau.
Shalaby, Ismail (1988). “The Islamic Common Market”, Journal of Islamic Banking and
Finance, 5 (1), pp.83-111.
Sprinkel, Beryl W. (1983). “Can The Fed Control Money?”, Cato Journal, 3 (1) Spring, pp.
155-162.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2002). Globalization and Its Discontent. London: Allen Lane, The Penguin
Press.
68 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009
Tinbergen, Jan (1962). Shaping the World Economy: Suggestion for an International Economic
Policy. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund
Vadillo, Umar Ibrahim (1996). The Return of The Gold Dinar. Cape Town: Madinah Press.
Verbeek, Marno (2000). A Guide to Modern Econometrics. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.
Vergil, Hasan (2002). “Exchange Rate Volatility in Turkey and Its Effect on Trade Flows”,
Journal of Economic and Social Research, 4 (1), pp. 83-99.
White, Lawrence H. (1983). “Competitive Money, Inside and Out”, Cato Journal, 3(1), Spring,
pp. 281-299.
Yackop, Tan Sri Nor Mohamed (2002a). Trade and The Gold Dinar: The Next Component in
the International Islamic Financial System. Paper presented at the International Conference
on Stable and Just Global Monetary System, 19-20 August 2002, organised by International
Islamic University Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.
Yackop, Tan Sri Nor Mohamed (2002b). The Role of Central Banks in the Implementation
of the Gold Dinar Proposal. Paper presented at the international seminar on Gold Dinar in
Multilateral Trades, 22-23 October 2002, Organized by IKIM, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.

More Related Content

What's hot

11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...
11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...
11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...Alexander Decker
 
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securities
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives SecuritiesThe Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securities
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securitiesiosrjce
 
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...The Business Council of Mongolia
 
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010Dr Lendy Spires
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1AaryanAJirde
 
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual Framework
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual FrameworkFinancial Sector Performance and Conceptual Framework
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual FrameworkAtif Ahmed
 
Islamic Banking Int Fin Mkts
Islamic Banking Int Fin MktsIslamic Banking Int Fin Mkts
Islamic Banking Int Fin MktsISEConsult
 
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)PwC France
 
Templeton Global Bond Update1009
Templeton Global Bond Update1009Templeton Global Bond Update1009
Templeton Global Bond Update1009mwkarstrom
 
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent Economic Research Forum
 
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09Revised Chapter3 Jan 09
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09727ai765
 
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. Rutledge
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. RutledgeGCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. Rutledge
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. RutledgeEconomic Research Forum
 
agencies that facilitate international flows
agencies that facilitate international flowsagencies that facilitate international flows
agencies that facilitate international flowsmuniswamy Paluru
 
Nature and scope of international finance
Nature and scope of international financeNature and scope of international finance
Nature and scope of international financeDr. Mital Bhayani
 
Global economic crisis
Global economic crisisGlobal economic crisis
Global economic crisisAdarsh Simmy
 

What's hot (19)

11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...
11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...
11.the theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case o...
 
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securities
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives SecuritiesThe Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securities
The Need for Financial Stability in Zimbabwe: Use of Derivatives Securities
 
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...
23.11.2010 Investment opportunities across asset classes in Mongolia, Mr. Ali...
 
A maze-sixth edition
A maze-sixth editionA maze-sixth edition
A maze-sixth edition
 
Islamic Finance 7e
Islamic Finance 7eIslamic Finance 7e
Islamic Finance 7e
 
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010
All Eyes on Asset Quality Microfinance Global Valuation Survey 2010
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1
 
Transformation, not diversification?
Transformation, not diversification?Transformation, not diversification?
Transformation, not diversification?
 
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual Framework
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual FrameworkFinancial Sector Performance and Conceptual Framework
Financial Sector Performance and Conceptual Framework
 
Islamic Banking Int Fin Mkts
Islamic Banking Int Fin MktsIslamic Banking Int Fin Mkts
Islamic Banking Int Fin Mkts
 
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)
Etude PwC sur le BFR (2013)
 
Templeton Global Bond Update1009
Templeton Global Bond Update1009Templeton Global Bond Update1009
Templeton Global Bond Update1009
 
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent
Oil production, entrepreneurship, and the allocation of talent
 
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09Revised Chapter3 Jan 09
Revised Chapter3 Jan 09
 
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. Rutledge
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. RutledgeGCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. Rutledge
GCC Currency Union: Necessary Precursors and Prospects - Emilie J. Rutledge
 
agencies that facilitate international flows
agencies that facilitate international flowsagencies that facilitate international flows
agencies that facilitate international flows
 
Nature and scope of international finance
Nature and scope of international financeNature and scope of international finance
Nature and scope of international finance
 
Global economic crisis
Global economic crisisGlobal economic crisis
Global economic crisis
 
Wolf
WolfWolf
Wolf
 

Similar to would the implementation of the gold dinar affect trade among oic countries

Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRs
Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRsEnhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRs
Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRsMahmoud Sami Nabi
 
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integration
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integrationBashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integration
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integrationBashar H Malkawi
 
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets report
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets reportPulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets report
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets reportDinarStandard
 
Intra-OIC Trade: Special Report
Intra-OIC Trade: Special ReportIntra-OIC Trade: Special Report
Intra-OIC Trade: Special ReportDinarStandard
 
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...Mahmoud Sami Nabi
 
Overview, FDI in the Arab world
Overview, FDI in the Arab worldOverview, FDI in the Arab world
Overview, FDI in the Arab worldAbed El-Azez Safi
 
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...Alexander Decker
 
The Impact Of Economic Globalization
The Impact Of Economic GlobalizationThe Impact Of Economic Globalization
The Impact Of Economic GlobalizationJamie Boyd
 
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...Alexander Decker
 
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...Alexander Decker
 

Similar to would the implementation of the gold dinar affect trade among oic countries (20)

Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRs
Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRsEnhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRs
Enhancing Intra-Trade in OIC Member Countries Through T-SDRs
 
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integration
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integrationBashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integration
Bashar H. Malkawi, legal architecture and design for gcc economic integration
 
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets report
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets reportPulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets report
Pulse of the OIC Islamic Capital Markets report
 
Intra-OIC Trade: Special Report
Intra-OIC Trade: Special ReportIntra-OIC Trade: Special Report
Intra-OIC Trade: Special Report
 
Gcc report
Gcc reportGcc report
Gcc report
 
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...
Facilitating Intra-OIC trade through T-SDRs: A catalyst for SMEs development ...
 
Ecn mifc
Ecn mifcEcn mifc
Ecn mifc
 
MR. TAJ 2007
MR. TAJ 2007MR. TAJ 2007
MR. TAJ 2007
 
191
191191
191
 
Gcc
GccGcc
Gcc
 
Overview, FDI in the Arab world
Overview, FDI in the Arab worldOverview, FDI in the Arab world
Overview, FDI in the Arab world
 
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...
An empirical analysis of the impact of globalisation on performance of nigeri...
 
The Impact Of Economic Globalization
The Impact Of Economic GlobalizationThe Impact Of Economic Globalization
The Impact Of Economic Globalization
 
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...
The theoretical considerations of financial markets integration the case of a...
 
Paradox of Plenty
Paradox of PlentyParadox of Plenty
Paradox of Plenty
 
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...
Financial development, trade openness and economic growth evidence from sulta...
 
Structuring Alternative Investment in Public Private Partnership Projects Usi...
Structuring Alternative Investment in Public Private Partnership Projects Usi...Structuring Alternative Investment in Public Private Partnership Projects Usi...
Structuring Alternative Investment in Public Private Partnership Projects Usi...
 
RIDE long paper
RIDE long paperRIDE long paper
RIDE long paper
 
Important institution
Important institutionImportant institution
Important institution
 
An evolution of IMF
An evolution of IMFAn evolution of IMF
An evolution of IMF
 

More from Luthfi Hamidi

Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!
Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!
Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!Luthfi Hamidi
 
theory and practice of islamic management style
theory and practice of islamic management styletheory and practice of islamic management style
theory and practice of islamic management styleLuthfi Hamidi
 
Cara riset sederhana quranomics
Cara riset sederhana quranomicsCara riset sederhana quranomics
Cara riset sederhana quranomicsLuthfi Hamidi
 
Mencintai yang melelahkan
Mencintai yang melelahkanMencintai yang melelahkan
Mencintai yang melelahkanLuthfi Hamidi
 
Pesan kennedy untuk capres
Pesan kennedy untuk capresPesan kennedy untuk capres
Pesan kennedy untuk capresLuthfi Hamidi
 
MengemBALIkan Kemerdekaan
MengemBALIkan KemerdekaanMengemBALIkan Kemerdekaan
MengemBALIkan KemerdekaanLuthfi Hamidi
 

More from Luthfi Hamidi (9)

Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!
Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!
Terimakasih, Pak Rachmat!
 
theory and practice of islamic management style
theory and practice of islamic management styletheory and practice of islamic management style
theory and practice of islamic management style
 
Cara riset sederhana quranomics
Cara riset sederhana quranomicsCara riset sederhana quranomics
Cara riset sederhana quranomics
 
Mencintai yang melelahkan
Mencintai yang melelahkanMencintai yang melelahkan
Mencintai yang melelahkan
 
Syukur
SyukurSyukur
Syukur
 
Pesan kennedy untuk capres
Pesan kennedy untuk capresPesan kennedy untuk capres
Pesan kennedy untuk capres
 
MengemBALIkan Kemerdekaan
MengemBALIkan KemerdekaanMengemBALIkan Kemerdekaan
MengemBALIkan Kemerdekaan
 
Barakah Ramadhan
Barakah RamadhanBarakah Ramadhan
Barakah Ramadhan
 
Rokok barakah
Rokok barakahRokok barakah
Rokok barakah
 

Recently uploaded

VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Roomdivyansh0kumar0
 
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHouse of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHenry Tapper
 
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一S SDS
 
SBP-Market-Operations and market managment
SBP-Market-Operations and market managmentSBP-Market-Operations and market managment
SBP-Market-Operations and market managmentfactical
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesMarketing847413
 
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdf
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdfgovernment_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdf
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdfshaunmashale756
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryPooja Nehwal
 
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办fqiuho152
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikCall Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Commonwealth
 
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionChapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionMuhammadHusnain82237
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdf
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdfBPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdf
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdfHenry Tapper
 
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Sapana Sha
 
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...Henry Tapper
 
Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................AmanBajaj36
 

Recently uploaded (20)

VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With RoomVIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130  Available With Room
VIP Kolkata Call Girl Serampore 👉 8250192130 Available With Room
 
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview documentHouse of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
House of Commons ; CDC schemes overview document
 
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一
(办理学位证)加拿大萨省大学毕业证成绩单原版一比一
 
SBP-Market-Operations and market managment
SBP-Market-Operations and market managmentSBP-Market-Operations and market managment
SBP-Market-Operations and market managment
 
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast SlidesQ3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
Q3 2024 Earnings Conference Call and Webcast Slides
 
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdf
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdfgovernment_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdf
government_intervention_in_business_ownership[1].pdf
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
 
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
(办理原版一样)QUT毕业证昆士兰科技大学毕业证学位证留信学历认证成绩单补办
 
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service NashikHigh Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
High Class Call Girls Nashik Maya 7001305949 Independent Escort Service Nashik
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
Monthly Market Risk Update: April 2024 [SlideShare]
 
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
🔝9953056974 🔝Call Girls In Dwarka Escort Service Delhi NCR
 
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th editionChapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
Chapter 2.ppt of macroeconomics by mankiw 9th edition
 
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Dilsukhnagar Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdf
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdfBPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdf
BPPG response - Options for Defined Benefit schemes - 19Apr24.pdf
 
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
Call Girls In Yusuf Sarai Women Seeking Men 9654467111
 
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
Monthly Economic Monitoring of Ukraine No 231, April 2024
 
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Begumpet Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
letter-from-the-chair-to-the-fca-relating-to-british-steel-pensions-scheme-15...
 
Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................Attachment Of Assets......................
Attachment Of Assets......................
 

would the implementation of the gold dinar affect trade among oic countries

  • 1. Would Implementation of the Gold Dinar Affect Trade Among OIC Countries? M. Luthfi Hamidi Abstract: This study attempts to analyze whether the implementation of the gold dinar proposal would affect trade among OIC members, since gold is considered a more stable currency, as it is less risky than fiat money. Empirical results produced by thisstudyprovethatfiatmoney,particularlyrealexchangerateof theUSdollaragainst gold, has an absolutely negative impact on developing countries’ exports. Although its direct effect on trade is very low, the variable itself is statistically significant at 5% level of significance. In contrast, those involved in the gold dinar trade bloc will likely increase their respective intra-trade by more than 2 units. In other words, the gold dinar bloc offers to those members a trade-creating effect. This effect is more robust than the benefit generated by the outstanding economic bloc within OIC including AMU and CEAU. Furthermore, gold dinar also generates considerable efficiency in terms of trade payment. If six leading OIC exporting countries join in the gold dinar bloc, trade efficiency in terms of payment will be around 76.68%. JEL Classification: F02, F10, F36, E42, P45. I.  Introduction The gold dinar has been a controversial issue among OIC member states ever since the former Prime Minister of Malaysia, Mahathir Mohammad, M. Luthfi Hamidi, Bank Muamalat Indonesia (BMI), and Lecturer in Islamic Business at the University of Paramadina, Jakarta, Indonesia. This paper is a shorter version of the author’s master dissertation submitted to Markfield Institute of Higher Education, Leicester, UK. The author would like to thank to Dr. Mehmet Asutay for his supervision and insightful comments during completing this work. The author wishes to extend his thanks to Dr. Mustafa Edwin Nasution for his suggestion on the econometric estimation procedure. © 2009, international association for islamic economics Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009, pp. 31–68.
  • 2. 32 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 initiated public discussion of the proposal in 2001, arguing that the gold dinar would boost inter-OIC trade. That trade is certainly extremely low. One of the striking factors inhibiting such trade is high exchange rate volatility of the member states’ domestic currencies so that, in order to reduce that risk, most of them use ‘hard’ currency such as the US dollar in international trade. But that does not altogether remove the risk since the dollar, like other fiat money, also tends to fluctuate in value: the notion of gold dinar is therefore seen as an attractive alternative since its value is expected to be more stable than fiat money. The important question that needs to be asked and properly answered is whether the gold dinar really would affect trade among the member states of the OIC. Unless there is a positive answer, the gold dinar will remain a wish or fantasy and not become a reality. This paper attempts to evaluate and examine the gold dinar issue from several standpoints. Firstly, it seeks to assess whether the gold dinar would be a stable currency and whether it would (or not) have a significant impact on trade. For this reason, the performance of gold is contrasted with that of the dollar and other hard currencies such as the DM and Yen. Secondly, the paper tries to evaluate whether a gold dinar trade bloc is likely (or not) to trigger a trade-creating effect1 which can increase trade among its members. Finally, if the first two questions are answered positively, the further task is to calculate how much gold is required to support the trade and then to determine whether the member states own sufficient gold reserves. II. Literature Review 2.1. Trade in the Islamic world In the Islamic tradition, trade has not only been the way to obtain reciprocal benefits for the parties involved, but also a primary means to spread Islamic teachings to different parts of the world. It has also played an important role in unifying the Islamic world.2 Thus, the failure of trading among Islamic countries implies disunity among them and is a signal of the weakened bargaining power they have at their disposal in relation with other countries. The establishment in 1972 of the Organization of Islamic Conference (OIC) prompted a hope that Muslim countries that share similar political and economic interests would cooperate. The OIC was also intended to
  • 3. 33Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 serve as a forum where the problems faced by Muslim countries could be tackled by them together. Among other concerns, the issue of trade gained priority in OIC as trade volume among Muslim countries was and remains very low, even though most of the Muslim countries are blessed with abundant natural resources. In 2003, the trade amongst Muslim countries was only around 13% of the total trade. This is the highest record during the last five years (see Table 1). Table 1: Trade among OIC Member Countries (US million dollar) Trade 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 Total intra-trade 151,272 123,972 115,793 109,376 83,402 Total trade 1,153,847 947,629 907,947 919,203 751,098 Percentage 13.11 13.08 12.75 11.89 11.1 Source: SESRTCIC statistics In general there is an incremental trade growth of OIC members, but most of it is dominated by oil and relies on primary commodity exports (Table 2a and Table 2b) while being heavily dependent on industrialized countries for the import of manufactured products (Table 3). That, in turn, makes the Muslim countries dependent on and enormously affected by the world economy, and they are, in consequence, subordinate to the economy of the industrialized world (Shalaby, 1988:90). Table 2a: Share of Oil to the Total Export for the OIC Leading Exporters (%) No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999 1 Saudi Arabia 89 90 92 85 2 UAE 92 - - - 3 Malaysia 9 9.7 9.6 7 4 Indonesia 24 25.3 25 23 5 Turkey 1.9 1.4 1 1 6 Pakistan 1.9 2 1 1 7 Nigeria 100 99.6 98.9 99 8 Iran 86 84 91.2 75.7 9 Kuwait - 79 79 90.2 10 Syria 72 76 76.3 68 Source: SESRTCIC Statistics
  • 4. 34 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 2b: Share of Primary Commodity to the Total Export of the OIC Leading Exporters (%) No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999 1 Saudi Arabia 90 91 93 87 2 UAE 96 - - - 3 Malaysia 21 20 19.6 20 4 Indonesia 46 44 43 46 5 Turkey 14.5 15.1 15 16 6 Pakistan 53 50 47 53 7 Nigeria 97 97.2 98 98 8 Iran 91 90 93 - 9 Kuwait - 80 80 91.5 10 Syria 93 92 92.2 92.6 Source: SESRTCIC Statistics Table 3: Share of Manufactures to the Total Imports of the OIC Top Ten Exporters (%) No. Countries 2002 2001 2000 1999 1 Saudi Arabia 79 79 76 78 2 UAE 86 - - - 3 Malaysia 83 83 83.9 85 4 Indonesia 59 61 61 69 5 Turkey 68 67 70 73 6 Pakistan 53 50 47 53 7 Nigeria 76 76 76 67 8 Iran 82 76 73 - 9 Kuwait - 79 79 79 10 Syria 64 65 65 59 Source: SESRTCIC statistics 2.2. Economic cooperation among OIC countries Economic cooperation among OIC member countries is believed to be a way forward to overcome the obstacles inhibiting trade flow. A significant achievement in 1978 was the establishment of The Islamic Chamber of Commerce, Industry and Commodity Exchange (ICCICE)3 in Karachi. Furthermore, the focus on economic cooperation has improved consistently since the founding of The Islamic Centre for Development of Trade (ICDT)4 in Casablanca in 1981.
  • 5. 35Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Full economic cooperation gained momentum once there has been a proposal to establish an Islamic Common Market (ICM). The ICM will be a kind of vehicle based on ideological unity to bridge the gap among Muslim countries with the main target to facilitate optimal intra-Islamic utilization of their resources (Sadeq, 1996: 39). The ICM is considerably more complex than a Free Trade Area (FTA)5 or Customs Union (CU),6 since it encourages cooperation not only in the trading of goods, but also in regard to mobility of factors of production. Thus, the ICM is to be characterized by free movement of capital, labour, service, as well as entrepreneurship (Satiroglu, 1996: 6; Nienhaus, 1996; 91; Sadeq, 1996: 44; Alatas, 1987: 32). Some scholars hold that the establishment of the ICM will overcome trade barriers and enhance effective economic cooperation. On the other hand, few of those scholars have taken care to point out that the low level of intra-trade among OIC members is a result of the low level of their development (Bhuyan, 1996:26). According to Bhuyan, the establishment of economic cooperation among the members should be a catalyst to accelerate their industrialization rather than directly to improve the level of trade. Another concern in light of the establishment of the ICM is its applicability. It is believed that the ICM is a long-term target that needs to be consistently adhered to. Regrettably, however, the future of the ICM is unclear since there is barely even a definite timetable agreed, among the members, to formalize the work of ICM.7 Instead of planning to move together gradually as a step closer towards ICM goals, some of OIC members have been reluctant to remove the barriers to free movement of capital and labour which protect their national interest (Nienhaus, 1996:101). 2.3. The impact of currency volatility on trade Currency volatility is considered to be one of the barriers to increase trade. Many of the developed countries adopted a floating rate regime on their national currency in 1973. Since the inception of that regime, the industrialized countries have experienced a significant decline in their economic growth. Between 1960 and 1973, their average yearly growth rate was 4.4%, while, during 1973–1990, it dropped to 1.3% (Grauwe, 1998:240). The decline in economic growth can be traced to the change that has taken place in international trade since the floating exchange regime.Because the variability of exchange rate increases uncertainty, it leads investors to reduce risk by shifting a part of their international trade into domestic trade. This in turn hits the international trade and results in slowdown in growth.
  • 6. 36 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 One may argue that the agents are free to utilize hedging facilities to protect themselves against loss. However, since this facility is not without cost, it means that any resulting gains or benefits are set off against the losses or drawbacks (Grauwe, 1998:241). Recent studies provide more robust evidence with respect to the effect on trade of the currency volatility. A study on G-38 exchange rate volatility suggests that one percentage increase in that rate decreases real exports of developing countries by, on average, about 2 percent (Esquivel and Larrain, 2002). Vergil (2002) examines trade flows between Turkey and its trade partners and finds that exchange rate volatility has a significant negative effect on trade. Arize et al. (2004) came up with the same result. They investigated exchange rate volatility in eight Latin American countries and report that the exchange rate has a significant negative impact on export demand both in the short and long run. III. Methodology 3.1. Measuring exchange rate volatility and modelling its impact on trade One of the most common measures to capture time-varying volatility on exchange rates is Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity, known as the GARCH model, developed by Bollerslev (as cited by Verbeek, 2000:266). This model has been employed in previous studies such as McKenzie (1998) and Vergil (2002). Another way to measure exchange rate volatility is coefficient of variation (CV) of exchange rate. Esquivel and Larrain (2002) define exchange rate volatility as the time-varying twelve-month coefficient of variation (CV) of the real exchange rate. This method is actually used to indicate a dispersion of the real exchange rate. The formula to calculate CV can be written as follows: � CVt +m = 1 m (εt +i−1 −ε)2 i=1 m ∑       1 2 ε (1) where m is the order of moving average and ε is the mean of the bilateral exchange rate between month t and t+m-1. In this study, CV will be used to measure the level of volatility of exchange rate, which can then be utilized to predict its impact on trade. Since in this study annual data is used, the −
  • 7. 37Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 moving average method is perhaps no longer relevant. Instead of using the formula given above, this study proposes to calculate CV based on the following formula:   (2) where, x is an individual value, n is the number of observations (test values) and x is the mean of n values. In other words, CV is calculated by dividing standard deviation by mean value (Chou, 1965:107; see also Kane, 1969:78). Esquivel and Larrain (2002) investigate the impact of the volatility of G-3 currencies on developing countries trade. They propose a model to estimate the exports of developing countries as a function in the following form: X = f (world demand, bilateral dollar real exchange rate, G-3 currency), which can be expressed as follows: (3) where Xt denotes exports of country t, GDPw represents the real World GDP, RERUS is bilateral real exchange rate in terms of the dollar and the variables VOL are the coefficients of variation (CV) of the G-3 real exchange rates. In this study, the model will be utilized with subtle modification by introducing variable Ddollar/gold in the model. Besides, a model based on pure exchange rate will also be assessed. Model 1: (4) Model 2: (5) Model 3: (6) where VG represents volatility values based on the GARCH technique, VC is volatility values based on the coefficient of variance (CV) method, and RER represents the absolute values of real exchange rate of the respective
  • 8. 38 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 countries. Xt is total export of developing countries, in dollar millions. GDPw is World’s Gross Domestic Product in dollar millions. Ddollar/gold is real exchange rate of dollar in terms of gold, while DMDM/dollar and Yyen/dollar are real exchange rate of DM and yen with respect to the dollar. GDPw represents the scale economy of the world. It is expected to be positive since the larger the value of GDPw , the larger the value of exports will be. Ddollar/gold , DMDM/dollar and Yyen/dollar represent risk which may occur as a result of exchange rate variability in international trade. These are expected to be inversely correlated with the exports. Increase in the exchange rate volatility will likely decrease the volume of exports. 3.2. The gravity model to capture trade-creating effect One of the famous econometric models to assess trade between countries is the gravity model, developed by Tinbergen (1962) and Poyhonen (1963). The simple gravity model introduces trade between two countries as a function of their gross national product (GNP) or gross domestic product (GDP), and the distance between them, usually calculated as the distance between their respective capital cities. The volume of trade should positively correlate with their respective GDP and income per capita, since a country with considerably large GDP will tend to trade more than the one with a small GDP. Greater distance between them should reduce trade volume, since it incurs transportation and information costs. Employing the gravity model, many researchers have observed the effect of common currency on trade. Recent research by Glick and Rose (2002) suggest that participation in a currency union has doubled trade and is statistically significant. However, Glick and Rose’s work is challenged by other researchers. Pakko and Wall (2001), for instance, also use the gravity model but find that the trade-creating effect of common currency is definitely lower then the findings of Glick and Rose. As for OIC member countries, Bendjilali (2000) suggests an empirical gravity model for these countries by adding a variable of IDB’s import trade financing operations to country i, while Hassan and Islam (2001) employ the basic gravity model to assess whether there is (or not) a significant trade-creating effect from implementing a trade bloc among OIC members. In this study, that model is modified by introducing a gold dinar trade bloc. The model can be written as follows: log(TRADEijt ) = α ± β1 log(GDPit* GDPjt ) ± β2 log(PCIit* PCIjt ) ± β3 log(DISTANCEij ) (7) ± β4(BORDERij ) ± β5 (BLOCij ) ± εij
  • 9. 39Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 For simplicity, the above equation is rewritten as follows: (8) Trade is expected to increase with the size of domestic economy G (GDP),per capita income Y (PCI), common border B (BORDER), joining in the same trade bloc (BLOC) and to decline with distance D (DISTANCE). Coefficient of β1 , β2 , β4 , and β5 should be positive, while β3 should be negative. 3.3. Measuring the amount of gold to serve trade and its generated efficiency Once the gold dinar is implemented, one may ask: How much gold is required to support the trade? How much efficiency can be generated? Yakcop (2002a and 2002b) introduces the Bilateral Payment Agreement (BPA) model, which can be extended into a Multilateral Payment Agreement (MPA) to illustrate how trade will be facilitated by gold dinar. Furthermore, Meera and Larbani (2004) develop an efficient trade matrix to indicate the detail of trade conducted by gold dinar. In this study, the MPA scheme is utilized. It is essential to introduce the BPA scheme first before turning to further steps. Let us say Malaysia and Indonesia sign a BPA scheme whereby trade balances will be settled up in quarterly periods. Both countries agree that trade will be denominated in gold dinars, one unit being defined as one troy ounce of gold. Bank Negara will pay Malaysian exporters in ringgit, based on the ringgit/gold dinar exchange rate prevailing at the date of export. Likewise, Malaysian importers have to pay ringgit to Bank Negara to the same amount of their import value. Meanwhile, Bank Indonesia will also do the same for Indonesia’s exporters and importers. At the end of the first quarter, the trade cycle is ended, the total export from Malaysia to Indonesia, say, is 3 million gold dinar and the total export from Indonesia to Malaysia is worth 2.5 million gold dinar (Table 4). Table 4: Gold Dinar Settlement by BPA Scheme Gold Dinar (million) Export to Malaysia Indonesia Total Export Net Payment Malaysia   2.5 2.5 -0.5 Indonesia 3   3 0.5 Total Import 3 2.5 5.5  
  • 10. 40 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 4 shows that at the end of the quarter, Malaysia has a trade deficit of 0.5 million gold dinar, while Indonesia has a surplus of 0.5 million gold dinar. Accordingly, Bank Negara as central bank will pay Bank Indonesia 0.5 million gold dinar. Initially, it is agreed that both of them have a gold custodian account in Bank of England, for instance. Then the actual payment can be transferred into the account of Bank Indonesia in Bank of England. It is interesting to note that only a small amount of 0.5 million gold dinar is able to support the total trade value of 5.5 million gold dinar. This scheme will be more efficient, if other participants join and therefore the mechanism of payment will use the MPA scheme which in essentials is the same as the BPA, but involves more members. From the above sample we can calculate the amount of gold dinar to support trade by simple equation as follows: (1) Gold required to last trade: (9) where, Xi and Ii represent the total export and import of country i to its trading partners, in millions of gold dinar. n is number of countries involved in the transaction (the economic bloc). (2) The efficiency generated from gold can be written as: (10) where TVT stands for total value of trade and Np is the net payment. 3.4. Data source and definition The statistical data in this study is mainly obtained from three sources: (i) Statistical, Economic and Social Research and Training Centre for Islamic Countries (SESRTCIC) for all data pertaining to OIC member countries; (ii) Direction of Trade Statistics, which is prepared quarterly by IMF for data particularly related to detail intra-trade (export and import) among members; (iii) United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) for data particularly related to export volume of developing countries.
  • 11. 41Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 In addition, some data is retrieved from other sources, such as the distance between capital cities among OIC member countries,which is easily accessed in (http://www.wcrl.ars.usda.gov/cec/java/capitals.htm). Data relating to the exchange rates of DM and Yen against dollar and dollar in terms of gold are obtained from www.econstats.com and Global Financial Data, respectively. The definition of each of the selected variables in the models is as follows: Exports (X): Data show the f.o.b. (free on board) value of goods provided to the rest of the world valued in US dollars. Export of Developing Countries (X) is total export generated from developing countries. GDP (G): GDP is defined as the sum of the gross value-added by all resident and non-resident producers in the economy plus indirect taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products, in US dollars. GDP World (GDPw ) is the sum of total GDP generated from all countries in the world. GDP Per Capita Income (Y) is calculated by dividing GDP by the mid-year population. The following charts represent GDP of OIC Countries (GDP OIC), exports of developing countries (X), and GDPw . Real Exchange Rate (RER): It is the exchange rate of one particular country compared with another at a particular point in time, taking into account their respective inflation. One of the common measures to calculate RER is by adjusting nominal exchange rate by the ratio of the foreign price level to the domestic. Due to availability of data, in this study RER is computed by indexing, that is, creating an index. The first year of observation, namely 1972, is taken as the base value, with the first exchange rate value for that year, say x, equated to 100. Mathematically this can be simply written as follows: (11) where, xt is real exchange rate at time t, and x0 is real exchange rate at the base year which is 100. Yyen/dollar and DMDM/dollar represent the bilateral real exchange rate of yen and DM with respect to the dollar, while Ddollar/gold illustrates the real exchange rate of dollar in terms of gold price. These are displayed in Figures 1, 2, and 3.
  • 12. 42 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Figure 1: Real Exchange Rate Yen/USD Figure 2: Real Exchange Rate DM/USD Figure 3: Real Exchange Rate USD/Gold Source: www.econstats.com and Global Financial Data TRADEijt (T): the bilateral trade comprising total exports and imports between countries i and j at time t in dollar.
  • 13. 43Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 DISTANCEij (D): The distance in kilometres between two countries (i.e. between the capital cities i and j). BORDERij (B): A dummy variable, which takes a value of 1 if two countries have a common border and zero otherwise. BLOCKij : A dummy variable, which takes a value of 1 if one country joins in the trade bloc, and zero otherwise. The trade blocs to be evaluated are those within OIC countries. A new trade bloc, namely the gold dinar trade bloc, will be introduced. IV. Empirical Result 4.1. Exchange rate volatility and its impact on trade As discussed in the previous section, volatility of exchange rate is evaluated by computing coefficient of variance (CV). The results are depicted in Figures 4, 5, and 6. Figure 4: Volatility Dollar/Gold (Coefficient of Variance Method) Figure 5: Volatility DM/Dollar (Coefficient of Variance Method)
  • 14. 44 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Figure 6: Volatility Yen/Dollar (Coefficient of Variance Method) Recalling the model described in the previous section, there are three models presented which refer to equation 4, 5, and 6. By conducting unit root test, we found the variable(s) in Model 1 (see Table 5) and Model 3 (see Table 7) to indicate a non-stationary feature. Table 5: Unit Root Test for Model 1 Variables Test Statistics & Critical Values Adjusted   Levels 1st differences Regression   ADF CV(5%) ADF CV(5%) Variable LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796 - - - L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943 - - - VG(D) -3.7158(0) -2.9665 - - - VG(DM) -3.3137(1) -2.9706 - - - VG(Y) -1.9079(3) -2.9798 -6.365 -2.9706 DVG(Y) Table 6: Unit Root Test for Model 2 Variables Test Statistics & Critical Values   Levels   ADF CV(5%) LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796 L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943 VC(D) -4.1887(1) -2.9706 VC(DM) -4.1713(0) -2.9665 VC(Y) -3.2690(3) -2.9798
  • 15. 45Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 7: Unit Root test for Model 3 Test Statistics & Critical Values Adjusted  Variables Levels 1st differences Regression   ADF CV(5%) ADF CV(5%) Variable LX -4.0662(0) -3.5796 - - - L(GDPw) -4.0121(1) -3.5943 - - - RER(D) -8.3549(0) -2.9665 - - - RER(DM) -2.6850(0) -2.9665 -4.0074 -2.9706 DRER(DM) RER(Y) -2.0152(0) -2.9798 -3.5134 -2.9800 DRER(Y) Given this condition, the regression results may be misleading and incorrect (Koop, 2000:152). Thus, while the regression for Model 2 remains the same, Model 1 and 3 need to be adjusted as follows: Model 1: (11) Model 3   (12) The OLS results for all models are set out in Tables 8, 9, 10 and 11. Table 8: Regression Result for Model 1 No. Variables Expected Results Actual Results Coefficient t-stat Significant level 1 Intercept - - -25.5887 -10.6263 0.000 * 2 LogGDPw + + 2.3057 16.6202 0.000 * 3 VG(D) - - -.6627E-4 -3.3867 0.002 * 4 VG(DM) - - -.3940E-4 -1.7939 0.085 ** 5 ∆ VG(Y) - + .4733E-4 1.9730 0.060 ** Notes: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (two-tailed); ‘**’ indicates significance at α=10% (2 tailed) Table 9: Regression Result for Model 2 No. Variables Expected Results Actual Results Coefficient t-stat Significant level 1 Intercept - - -27.2689 -9.4127 0.000 * 2 LogGDPw + + 2.4022 14.1914 0.000 * 3 VC(D) - - -0.018090 -3.4178 0.002 * 4 VC(DM) - - -0.007324 -0.39427 0.697 5 VC(Y) - - -0.008019 -0.5504 0.584 Note: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (two-tailed)
  • 16. 46 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 10: Regression Result for Model 3 No Variables Expected Results Actual Results Coefficient t-stat Significant level 1 Intercept - - -26.9085 -12.2342 0.000 * 2 LogGDPw + + 2.3827 18.6695 0.000 * 3 RER(D) - - -0.009723 -3.2855 0.003 * 4 ∆ RER(DM) - + -0.010074 2.5180 0.019 ** 5 ∆ RER (Y) - + 0.001525 .36465 0.719 Notes: ‘*’ indicates significance at α=5% (2 tailed); ‘**’ indicates significance at α=10% (2 tailed) Table 11: Overall results Models 1, 2, and 3 No. Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 1 2 R 0.96230 0.95033 0.96163 2 2 R 0.95602 0.94238 0.95523 3 F statistics 153.1557 119.5711 150.3674 4 DW statistics 0.80718 0.91669 1.1093 As can be seen from Tables 11, 12 and 13, the individual variable performs well. The coefficient of determination of each model ( 2 R ) also indicates that the explanatory variables in each model are able to explain more than 95 percent of variation taking place in the dependent variable. Besides, the models also demonstrate overall significance as indicated by high F-statistics. The overall coefficient of variables is statistically significant even with one percent level of significance. However, the models may encounter severe serial autocorrelation since their DW statistics are terribly low (Table 11). Some remedies are taken to completely remove the problem from the equation by transforming the variables into first differences form. Thus, the above model is revised as follows: Model 1 (13) Model 2 (14) Model 3    (15) The regression results of the above models are presented in Table 12.
  • 17. 47Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 12: Regression Results of the Revised Models No. Model 1 GARCH Estimated Values Model 2 Coef. of Variance Estimated Values Model 3 RER Estimated Values 1 Dependent Variable ∆log Xt Dependent Variable ∆log Xt Dependent Variable ∆log Xt 2 Intercept -.004693 (-.06248) Intercept 0.071721 (1.0246) Intercept 0.093767 (1.6045) 3 ∆log GDPW 3.7468 (1.6984) ∆log GDPW 0.66625 (0.31141) ∆log GDPW 0.11494 (0.06396) 4 ∆VG (D) -0.3111E-4 (-1.5566) ∆VC (D) -0.011259 (-2.5102) ∆RER (D) -0.0099251 (-3.1461) 5 ∆VG (DM) -0.9410E-5 (-0.33142) ∆VC(DM) -0.009850 (-0.66785) ∆RER (DM) -0.0028690 (-0.71586) 6 ∆VG (Y) 0.1647E-4 (0.54677) ∆VC (Y) 0.018811 (1.3252) ∆RER (Y) 0.0072179 (1.9074) 7 2 R 0.19624 0.29622 0.48737 8 2 R 0.062277 0.17893 0.40193 9 F-statistics 1.4649 2.5254 5.7044 10 DW- statistics 1.2342 1.6194 2.0846 Note: Figures in parentheses are t-statistics The revised models are able impressively to increase DW statistics, which is a signal of improvement in dealing with problem of serial autocorrelation. However, 2 R and F-statistics decrease sharply. The low of 2 R indicates that the explanatory variables no longer have strong power to explain the independent variable, which was not the case in the original model. Meanwhile, the low F-statistics (except for Model 3) illustrate that the coefficient of variables as a whole are likely having no statistical significance. Accordingly, Model 3 is chosen as the final model and will be analysed subsequently. The equation for the revised model (Model 3) can be written as follows: ∆logXt = 0.093767 + 0.11494∆logGDPw – 0.0099251∆RERDollar/Gold (16) – 0.002869∆RERDM/Dollar + 0.0072179∆RERYen/Dollar Two of the most noteworthy outcomes from equation 13 are that, if world GDP increases by one unit, holding other variables constant,
  • 18. 48 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 the exports of developing countries also increase slightly by 0.114 units. Inversely, if the dollar real exchange rate in terms of gold rises by one point, the exports of developing countries decrease by 0.009 units. The variable of RERdollar/gold is statistically significant at 5% level of significance. However, its impact on trade as indicated by the coefficient (0.009) is considered low. Similarly, a one point increase in the real exchange rate of DM against dollar (RERDM/dollar ) has an inverse effect on developing countries’ exports by a mere 0.002 units (ceteris paribus). In addition, the variable is statistically insignificant. These low effects on trade are definitely interesting since other previous researchers – Esquivel and Larrain (2002) for instance – reported a significant impact. They reported that each one-unit increase in the volatility of DM against dollar reduces developing countries’ exports by around 2 percent. The difference may be caused by the data for developing countries. In this study, aggregate data of developing countries’ exports, which is time series data, is used whereas Esquivel and Larrain used panel data (individual data) of developing countries’ exports. Moreover, in this study the regression model chosen is based on the differenced form, while their study was based on logarithmic form. The latter, as presented in the previous section, did not work well, since it contains severe serial correlation problems. Surprisingly, the variable of real exchange rate of yen against dollar (RERyen/dollar ) in this study has positive effect on trade. A one point increase in RERyen/dollar tends to increase developing countries’ exports by 0.007 units. Even though the impact is considerably low, the variable itself is statistically significant at 10% level of significance. The positive sign on this variable is the same as in Esquivel and Larrain’s results. However, they did not give any special attention to why the sign of this variable is not as expected. This anomaly might emerge because the yen actually is a less influential currency for developing countries. The share of yen in the global currency in 2002 and 2003 is only 5.2 and 4.8 percent respectively (Table 13), while the share of DM, which has merged into the euro, is 19.3 and 19.7 percent respectively in the same year. Perhaps, most of the developing countries in Africa tend to use European currency including DM (euro) rather than yen. It is reasonable to argue that they tend to maintain their trade partnership with European countries rather than with Japan for reasons of geographical proximity.
  • 19. 49Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 13: Official Foreign Exchange Reserve: Currency Share (%) Currency 2000 2001 2002 2003 US dollar 66.6 66.9 63.5 63.8 Euro 16.3 16.7 19.3 19.7 Japanese yen 6.2 5.5 5.2 4.8 Pound sterling 3.8 4 4.4 4.4 Swiss franc 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.4 Unspecified currency 6.6 6.4 7.1 6.8 Source: European Central Bank (2005) In general, the model has no strong explanatory power as indicated by its low 2 R . That is a mere 48%, implying that the selected explanatory variables within the model can only explain 48% of the variation taking place in the dependent variable. However, this is still acceptable since, in the financial field, 2 R is rarely impressive. Furthermore, the model as a whole is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, as illustrated by its high F-statistics. In addition the model is also free of the serial autocorrelation problem. However, the model contains heteroscedasticity problem. This does not destroy the unbiasedness and consistency of the estimations, but these are no longer efficient (Gujarati, 1995:381). 4.2. Gold dinar’s trade creating effect: empirical result from gravity model The gravity model utilized in this study contains eight explanatory variables, namely GDP (the product of GDP’s country i and country j), Y (the product of their per capita income), D (DISTANCE between their capital cities), and dummy variables B (BORDER), GOLD9 (Gold Dinar Trade Bloc), CAEU10 , AMU11 , and D-812 . log(T) = a ± b1 log GDP ± b2logY ± b3 logD ± b4 B ± b5 GOLD ± b6 CARU (17) ± b7 D8 ± b8 AMU The complete set of regression results is presented in Table 14.
  • 20. 50 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 14: Regression Results of Gravity Model No. Original model Estimated Values Observation 31 1 Dependent Variable Log(T) 2 Intercept -4.0686 (-.44709) 3 LogGDP .4001 (1.2348) 4 LogY .12409 (.33743) 5 LogD -.5176 (-.9495) 6 B 2.3309 (2.1959) 7 GOLD 1.6537 (1.9665) 8 CAEU .4534 (.6658) 9 D-8 1.9810 (1.9943) 10 AMU .16978 (.1684) 11 2 R .82133 12 F-statistics 12.6415 13 DW-statistics 1.8634 Note: Figure in parentheses are t-statistics The model can be expressed in the equation as follows: log(T) = –4.0686 + 0.4001logGDP + 0.12409logY – 0.51762logD + 2.3309B +1.6537GOLD + 1.45349CAEU + 1.9810D8 + 0.16978AMU The estimation of equation 17 suggests that an increase in one unit of GDP and per capita income will tend to increase trade by 2.5 and 1.33 units respectively.13 On the other hand, a one point additional distance between countries will likely decrease trade by 3.23 units.14 However these variables are statistically insignificant. Thus within a 5% level of significance, only variable B (BORDER) is statistically significant. If we extend the level of significance to 10%, variable GOLD and D8 are also statistically significant (Table 15).
  • 21. 51Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 15: The Property of t-test for the Equation 17 Variables tcal ttab (α=5%) Decision ttab α=10% Decision LogGDP 1.2348 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant LogY 0.33743 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant LogD -0.9495 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant B 2.1959 2.079 Significant 1.7207 Significant GOLD 1.9665 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Significant CAEU 0.6658 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant D-8 1.9943 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Significant AMU 0.1684 2.079 Insignificant 1.7207 Insignificant Note: n=30, k=9, n-k=21, for α=5% or 0.025(two tails) ttab value = 2.079; α=10% or 0.05(two tails) ttab value =1.7207 Another point from the model is that having the same border and participation in a trade bloc supports greater volume of trade. In the case of sharing the same border, trade is increased by 2.3 units, whereas those involved in gold dinar trade bloc will likely enjoy an increase in their trade by 1.65 units.A similar result prevails for those in CAEU, D8, and AMU trade blocs with an increase in trade of 1.45, 1.9, and 0.16 units, respectively. These positive impacts on trade as a result of joining trade blocs is similar with Hassan and Islam’s (2001) study. It also proves that joining in a trade bloc will open a trade-creating effect. One interesting result here is conformity of each sign. The actual sign for all of the variables does confirm with those expected. It is a bit different with Hassan and Islam’s (2001) study, which finds per capita income is negatively correlated with bilateral trade. The 2 R value is 82% which means that the model has a high explanatory power, and indicates that it has high goodness of fit. The explanatory variables selected in the model can simultaneously explain 82% of the variation taking place in the model. However, the model contains heteroscedasticity problem. Multicollinearity may also arise since some of its variables are statistically insignificant with low t-statistics including variable per capita income (Y) and two trade blocs namely CAEU and AMU. Perhaps, this is not surprising as variable Y is gained from the GDP value divided by the respective population of each country. Similarly, few of the members of CAEU are involved in the D8 group. In this respect, it is sensible to omit these three variables from the equation presented in the revised model, and the new results can be seen in Table 16.
  • 22. 52 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 16: Regression results of the revised model No. Revised model Estimated values Observation 31 1 Dependent variable log(T) 2 Intercept -9.5117 (-1.3793) 3 logGDP .80253 (4.0997) 4 logD -.60904 (-1.2415) 5 B 1.9587 (2.1096) 6 GOLD 2.1136 (2.7355) 7 2 R .78287 8 F-statistics 23.4353 9 DW-statistics 2.1948 Note: figure in parentheses are t-statistics The equation of the model can be written as follows: (18) It can be seen that the reduced model performs better, as illustrated by improving statistically significant variables (see Table 16). Another interesting finding is the effect of gold if it were implemented as the international currency for trade. Recalling equation 18 and its statistical summary, it can be seen that only the distance variable (D) is statistically insignificant. However, the sign of the variable is as predicted before. The insignificant variable is a bit surprising since other researchers (Bendjilali, 2000, and Hassan and Islam, 2001) reported that distance is statistically significant. Other variables such as GDP and border (B) are statistically significant too. These results strengthen the previous studies. The distinction of this study stems from the introduction of the gold dinar trade bloc variable, something not witnessed in other studies. Those involved in this bloc would enjoy an increase of their respective intra-trade of more than 2 units. Moreover, this variable is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, which is further convincing evidence.
  • 23. 53Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 In general, the model also demonstrates a highly desirable explanatory efficiency, as the selected explanatory variables are indeed able to explain more than 78% of variation taking place in the dependent variable. The high F-statistics illustrate that the overall model is statistically significant even at 1% level of significance. In addition, the model is also free from serious error derived from the serial correlation error and multicollinearity problem. It may be deduced that the model used here is quite impressive. 4.3. The amount of gold dinars needed to support trade As mentioned earlier, it is possible to calculate the quantity of gold dinars needed to support trade simply by calculating the volume of trade, whether it produces surplus or deficit. In presenting the gravity model, we said that the gold dinar trade bloc is assumed to consist of six leading OIC exporting countries. They are Saudi Arabia, UAE, Malaysia, Indonesia, Turkey, and Pakistan. Table 17 shows their respective trade (export and import). Table 17: The Trade among Six Leading OIC Exporting Countries in 2002 (Million Dollar) Export to Saudi Arabia UAE Malaysia Indonesia Turkey Pakistan Total Export Saudi A   1695 343 1003 716 1196 4953 UAE 490   3827 105 92 1198 5712 Malaysia 370 835   1586 221 486 3498 Indonesia 475 720 2030   238 265 3728 Turkey 535 440 113 28   52 1168 Pakistan 390 837 64 81 110   1482 Total Import 2260 4527 6377 2803 1377 3197 20541 Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003 In 2002, total trade among these six countries was more than 20.5 billion dollars. UAE is at the top rank of exporting countries with total exports of around 5.7 billion dollars, while Malaysia is in the top rank of importing countries with total imports of more than 6.3 billion dollars. It is noteworthy that Turkey holds the lowest position both in terms of import and export, perhaps because it tends to trade with its European partners rather than Muslim countries.
  • 24. 54 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 From Table 17, the amount of gold dinars required to facilitate the respective trade of these countries can be estimated. The first thing needing to be taken into account is the gold price in the prevailing year which is in 2002. According to Global Financial Data, the price of one troy ounce of gold in 2002 was 346.7 dollar. Hence, for instance, the total imports and exports of Saudi Arabia are equivalent to 14.28 and 6.51 million gold dinars, respectively. (This is worked out by dividing column (1) and (2) by 346.7 (see Table 18). The net payment for Saudi Arabia is thus equal to 7.76 million gold dinars which is obtained by subtracting the figure in column (4) from that in column (3). The amount of gold needed to support the trade is then equal to 59.2 million gold dinars. This amount is equal to 13.4 million troy ounces of gold or around 4.292 tons of gold (see Table 19). 4.4. The efficiency of the gold dinar The last stage of the calculation is to calculate the efficiency that would be generated if the gold dinar were to be implemented. Recall equation 10: Efficiency = (10) From Table 18 the amount of net payment (Np) is the same with the amount of gold dinar payable (or receivable),which is 13.8 million gold dinar. Total value of trade (TVT) is the total amount of trade in the conventional sense (if gold dinar would not be implemented), which is 20,541 million dollars or equal to 59.2 million gold dinars. Hence the efficiency generated from implementing the gold dinar is: Efficiency = x 100 = 76.68 % This figure 76.68% implies that the six leading exporting countries enjoy the trade by only paying the remaining (around 23.31%) at the end of the year. In other words, if the gold dinar were implemented, they could save almost 4/5 of their budget for other economic allocations. It is indeed a giant step forward that should encourage prosperity among the member countries in the gold dinar trade bloc.
  • 25. 55Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 18: Total Trade of Six Leading Exporting Countries, 2002 (million gold dinar) Countries Million Dollar Million Gold Dinar ApproximationExport Import Export Import Net Payment (1) (2) (3) (4) (3)-(4) Saudi A 4953 2260 14.286 6.5186 7.767522 7.7 UAE 5712 4527 16.475 13.0574 3.417941 3.4 Malaysia 3498 6377 10.089 18.3934 -8.30401 -8.3 Indonesia 3728 2803 10.752 8.0848 2.6680125 2.7 Turkey 1168 1377 3.3689 3.97173 -0.6028267 -0.6 Pakistan 1482 3197 4.2745 9.22123 -4.9466397 -4.9  Total     59.247 59.247 0 0 Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003 Table 19: Gold Required to Support Trade (million gold dinar, troy ounce, and ton units) Deficit by Countries Gold Dinar Surplus Gold Dinar Gold Dinar Total Trade Gold Required Payable Countries Receivable Troy ounce Ton Malaysia -8.3 Saudi A 7.7 59.215 13,800,000 4,29216     UAE 3.4 Turkey -0.6 Indonesia 2.7 Pakistan -4.9     Total -13.8   13.8
  • 26. 56 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 V. Discussion The first question, whether the variability of exchange rate – particularly dollars in terms of gold – has significant impact on trade, has already been answered. As can be seen from equation 13, the model shows that an additional one point on the exchange rate variability of the dollar in respect of gold (RERdollar/gold ) tends to decrease the value of developing countries’ exports by 0.009 units (holding other explanatory variables as constant). The variable of RERdollar/gold is statistically significant at 5% level of significance. This is further proof that exchange rate variability tends to decrease trade. However, its impact on trade as indicated by the coefficient (0.009) is considered low and inconsistent with what the relevant literature leads one to expect. The establishment of a Gold Dinar Trade Bloc (GDTB), proposed for the first time in this study, indicates a new hope for OIC members since members of this bloc would enjoy an increase of their respective intra-trade by more than 2 units. It is an initial indicator that a GDTB would be more fruitful than other existing trade blocs among OIC countries. Moreover, this variable is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, which is further convincing evidence. The model also promises the hope for OIC member countries of making enormous budget savings. Assuming that the six leading countries of OIC are to be GDTB members, the value of their intra-trade in 2002 stands at 20.5 billion dollars or almost 60 million gold dinars. However, those taking part would not need to supply gold dinars in the same amount as the total value of their trade, but only the amount of the net difference, namely 13.8 million gold dinars. In other words, they would only pay for around 23.31% of the total amount payable if paid in the conventional way using dollars. Thus, the efficiency generated by using the gold dinar is around 76.68%. That figure would be even higher if the trade between the mentioned member countries were to become larger. If, for instance, ten leading exporting countries within the OIC agreed to settle their trade in gold dinars (i.e. if four additional countries join to the bloc17 ), the efficiency will increase. In 2002, for the total trade among the 10 leading exporting countries of 32.2 billion dollars (equivalent to 92.98 million gold dinar, see Table 20), the net payment would be only 18.51 million gold dinars. In other words, the efficiency generated would be 80.09%.18
  • 27. 57Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Table 20: Total Intra-Trade of Ten Leading Exporting Countries, 2002 (Million Dollar and Gold Dinar) Countries Million Dollar Million Gold Dinar Approxi- mation Export Import Export Import Netpayment (1) (2) (3) (4) (3)-(4) Saudi A. 5593 2560.11 16.1321 7.384223 8.74788001 8.74 UAE 8202 6606.31 23.65734 19.05483 4.60250937 4.6 Malaysia 3895 6547.77 11.2345 18.88598 -7.6514854 -7.65 Indonesia 4284 4521.08 12.3565 13.04032 -0.6838189 -0.68 Turkey 1922 2835.27 5.543698 8.177877 -2.6341794 -2.63 Pakistan 1637 4087.42 4.721661 11.7895 -7.0678396 -7.06 Nigeria 1200 541 3.461206 1.560427 1.90077877 1.9 Iran 3056 2356.08 8.814537 6.795731 2.01880588 2.02 Kuwait 1608 1173.67 4.638016 3.385261 1.25275454 1.25 Syria 840.71 1009 2.424892 2.910297 -0.4854052 -0.48 Total 32237.71 32237.71 92.98445 92.98445   0 Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2003 This figure implies that the ten leading exporting countries only need one fifth of their current budget to support their trade. They can allocate another 80% of the budget to other economic purposes. Hence, using the gold dinar would be a breakthrough that could enhance prosperity among the countries involved in the gold dinar trade bloc. 5.1. Transmission how gold dinar would increase trade The following strategies are available to OIC members which trade among themselves (see Figure 7): Firstly, exporters/importers can use their domestic currency. This is possible for those who enjoy relatively low volatility of their respective national currency, which is the case only for a few countries, perhaps only some of the oil-exporting ones. Hence, it is assumed that these few countries may enjoy more trade than other OIC member countries. The second strategy is that a hard currency such as the dollar takes the place of the national currencies. Although hard currencies mostly have a stable exchange rate, it does not necessarily follow that they are free from risk. To remove risk completely from the business, there is no choice but to hedge, for which additional costs are entailed. The trade would still be a
  • 28. 58 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 normal trade in the sense that although they have to pay an additional cost for hedging, still they can predict their costs and benefits. Finally, some exporters/importers have no opportunity to use hedging facilities since these are not available in many developing countries (Meera and Larbani, 2004). Thus, there is no choice in these countries except to use the dollar, without hedging. This can worsen the uncertainty of business, which in turn restrains exporters/importers from doing business, thus leading to less trade. Figure 7: Domestic Currency vs Hard Currency and Its Impact on Trade
  • 29. 59Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Once the gold dinar is established as the common currency for payment for trade, some advantages could arise for participants. Joining in a common currency, according to Grauwe (2000:58), will remove the uncertainty risk due to volatility of the exchange rate. In the case of gold dinar, Meera (2004) contends that gold dinar payment will totally eliminate exchange rate risk. There is no need for a trader to hedge currency to minimize risk, because hedging cost is fixed against the gold dinar itself. Furthermore, transaction cost will be minimized since it can be affected electronically (see Figure 8). Figure 8: The Mechanism of How Gold is Estimated to Increase Trade Along with the benefits just mentioned, the gold dinar would improve trade in three ways: Firstly, the relative stability of gold may influence in two fronts (Izhar and Asutay, 2005): the fluctuation of general prices is relatively controllable, thus inflation should be relatively low; there is no opportunity to create
  • 30. 60 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 unlimited money, since this will be subject to availability of gold. Hence, there will be harmonization between the real sector and the monetary sector. As a result, the phenomenon of appreciation or depreciation will be relatively manageable. Secondly, as discussed earlier, implementing the gold dinar based on MPA will provide massive efficiency in term of the amount of gold to sustain the trade. In addition, since the members of the gold dinar bloc will support each other, the trade-creating effect is expected to take place. Given this situation, the gold dinar may serve as an optimum currency if more countries are expected to join.On his famous optimum currency area (OCA) theory, Mundell (1977a; 1977b) states that implementation of OCA would also reduce transaction costs in trade. He affirms that “the more countries join a currency area, the more efficient it will be”. The more OIC members are involved, the more efficient it will be. From the empirical results, we have already demonstrated that the efficiency of the GDTB increases from 76.68% to 80.09% after four other countries joining in the bloc. Finally, aside from economic factors, the success of international trade is basically also determined by political bargaining. The success of the gold dinar will constitute an immense capital with which to negotiate with developed countries, especially in respect of unfair trade practices. It is no secret that the industrialized countries use their position in the World Trade Organization (WTO) to protect their interests. Stiglitz (2002:244) points out that some of them demonstrate a hypocritical attitude by advocating the opening up of markets in developing countries while keeping their own markets closed to the produce and products of developing countries, such as textiles and agriculture. Hence, successful implementation of the gold dinar will be the source of a new energy and confidence among OIC countries so that they have a better bargaining position to deal with their trade partners, particularly developed counties. This will produce incentives which encourage not just intra-trade but also inter-trade. 5.2. Why does the idea not get off the ground? The trade-creating effect and efficiency generated by GDTB so far are convincing. Why then does the idea not move towards becoming a reality? It may be argued that implementation is difficult due to inadequate gold reserves in the countries concerned. As we just calculated for the year 2002, the net payment was around 13.8 million gold dinars or the equivalent of 4,292 tons of gold. This entails vast reserves, beyond the capacity of the OIC
  • 31. 61Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 member countries (see Table 24). In 2002, total gold reserves held by the deficit countries in the trade bloc was a mere 314.5 tons of gold. Table 21: Gold Dinar Required for Intra-Trade and Gold Reserve Kept by Central Bank in 2002 Countries Gold Required (Ton)20 Gold Reserve (Ton)21 Malaysia 2,581 36.4 Turkey 186.6 116.5 Pakistan 1,525 65.1 Total 4,293 218.0 At first glance, looking at Table 21, those countries could not effect their trade based on the gold dinar on account of a lack of gold reserves. However, this is not the case in fact since all of those countries do hold adequate reserves in dollars. Malaysia, for example, in 2002 held over 34 billion dollars in its reserve account. That amount is equal to 3,070 tons of gold. Other countries also recorded large amounts of total reserves in dollars (see Table 22). In other words, basically, these countries are able to implement the gold dinar by converting a part of their dollar reserves into gold, the potential of which depicted in Table 23. Table 22: Countries’ Total Reserve in 2002 and Its Value in Gold Countries Reserve Minus Gold22 (Million Dollar) Reserve Value (Million Gold Dinar) Reserve Value (Ton Gold) Malaysia 34,221 98.7 30,699 Turkey 27,068 78.07 24,282 Pakistan 8,078 23.29 7,244 Total 69,367 200.06 62,225 Table 23: Potential Gold Reserve (Ton) and Gold Needed to Settle Transaction (%) Countries Gold Required (Ton) Actual Gold Reserve (Ton) Potential Gold Reserve Gold Needed to Serve % Malaysia 2,581 98.7 30,699 8.4 Turkey 186.6 78.07 24,282 0.76 Pakistan 1,525 23.29 7,244 21.0 Total 4,293 200.06 62,225
  • 32. 62 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 As an illustration, Malaysia in 2002 had a reserve 34,221 million dollar. If Malaysia would convert this reserve totally to gold, then they would have potential gold reserve equal to 30,699 ton gold. Theoretically, although Malaysia has had to pay 2,581 ton gold because of its suffer trade deficit with its trade partners, still this deficit can be easily settled since it was only 8.4% of its giant potential gold reserve (see Table 22 and 23). 5.3. Conclusion This study has attempted to find whether and how the implementation of the gold dinar proposal would affect trade among OIC members. The findings from the empirical analysis and available evidence from the literature help to answer this challenging question. The following remarks can be made in light of the available evidence and the findings: (i) The gold dinar is considered to be more stable than fiat money, i.e., the US dollar. The term ‘stable’ here has the practical sense of ‘low volatility’, whereas the dollar is considerably more volatile. Empirical results produced by this study prove that in terms of gold, dollar tends to depreciate and its real exchange rate (RER) volatility has an absolutely negative impact on developing countries’ exports. The variable is statistically significant at 5% level of significance, as explained previously. However, its direct impact on trade is very low as illustrated by its coefficient (0.009), as shown earlier. Thus, the findings are inconsistent with the hypothesis explored in this study. (ii) Establishing a gold dinar trade bloc will likely encourage intra-trade among OIC members. Empirical results in this study suggests that those involved in the bloc will enjoy an increase of more than 2 units of their respective intra-trade. This is indeed a very convincing result, since the variable is also consistently statistically significant in various models tested at 5% level of significance. In other words, the gold dinar bloc is an economic bloc which offers to its members a trade-creating effect. This effect is more robust than those generated by currently existing economic blocs within the OIC, including AMU and CEAU. (iii) Another interesting finding for those joining the gold dinar bloc is the efficiency generated by it. Empirical results in this study demonstrate that if six countries selected would join in the gold dinar bloc, trade efficiency in terms of payments will be around 76.68%. which implies that they only need to pay the remaining 23.32% at the end of the trade
  • 33. 63Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 period. This figure becomes larger if the number of member countries is increased. A simulation by adding another four countries (making the total number of countries involved 10) showed that the efficiency increases to almost 80%. Such an improvement is perhaps because the selected countries are the top ten leading exporting countries within the OIC. Perhaps, this efficiency will tend to diminish slightly if the additional joining countries do not have any significant intra-trade. (iv) From these three basic explanations, it may be deduced that the implementation of the gold dinar proposal will be a move forward for Muslim countries, in the sense that it will bring many economic advantages. Their respective trade tends to increase. Unfortunately, the project is likely not feasible since there are insufficient gold reserves held by the members. If this can be tackled, perhaps the gold dinar would become the main tool, not just to unite Muslim countries but also to disseminate economic cooperation and foster prosperity among them. 5.4. Recommendation Insufficient gold reserves held by most of Islamic countries will be the most serious critical problem to be handled. To confront this shortage, former Malaysian Prime Minister Mahathir suggested that those taking part in gold dinar trade should help each other by purchasing some materials from the poorest gold reserve countries thus enabling them to participate in the trade (Mahathir, 2002). This probably would render a little help. Alternatively, this study recommends two points: (i) At the starting stage, use of the gold dinar can be restricted to facilitate trade between member governments excluding private trade. There are two advantages in this strategy: firstly, the amount of trade will be reduced, that is, each member may hold sufficient gold stocks to sustain their respective government’s trade; secondly, the administration is likely to be less complex since the trade is fully backed by the government. (ii) The level of gold reserves can be improved by converting a significant part of the country’s dollar reserves into gold. Almost all of the countries assumed to be in the gold dinar have massive reserves in dollars. Thus, by converting up to half of the dollar reserve into gold, the insufficiency of gold stock to sustain trade can be met.
  • 34. 64 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Notes 1. That trade-creating effect (as opposed to trade-diverting effect) occurs when some domestic production in a member state of the trade bloc is replaced by lower cost imports from other members. See Salvatore (2001:328-329). 2. Trade was the main vehicle for the spread of Islamic teaching from Andalusia (Spain) to the Cape of Good Hope in Africa and to the Malay Peninsula. See, for example, Yakcop (2002a). 3. ICCICE is intended to promote trade, commerce and industrial cooperation. 4. At the official level this idea was first launched by Bangladesh in the Second Summit Meeting of OIC Heads of States, held in Taif in 1981. A year later, the issue has gained more attention once Morocco again sounded the need to shape ICM in the Third General Assembly of the Islamic Chamber of Commerce (ICC) held in Casablanca. Finally, the Fourth General Assembly of the ICC held in Jakarta in 1983, repeated the importance of establishing an ICM (Harjono as cited in Sadeq, 1996:49). ICDT is intended to encourage regular commercial contacts and promote the harmonization of commercial and investment policies among member countries. 5. The most striking feature of an FTA is the removal of existing restrictions on trade among the regional members (Satiroglu, 1986:5). 6. It is the next step after FTA has been established. Custom Union entails, as well as removal of trade barriers, a common external trade policy to both members and non- members (Satiroglu, 2000). 7. One of the successful aspects of the implementation of the euro was the establishment of a definite time table, which had to be adhered to by EU members. Ratification of the Maastricht Treaty was meant to signal the beginning of the EU’s integration. See, for example, Jovanovic (1997:18) and Keis (1997:42). 8. G-3 refers to the three major economic powers, namely USA, Japan, and Germany. 9. The six leading exporting countries are assumed to join this bloc. They are Saudi Arabia, UAE, Malaysia, Indonesia, Turkey, and Pakistan. 10. The Council of Arab Economic Unity was established in 1957. It consists of Egypt, Iraq, Libya, Jordan, Kuwait, Mauritania, Somalia, Sudan, Syria, UAE, and Yemen. In this study four countries, namely Iraq, Mauritania, Somalia, and Sudan, were excluded due to unavailability of data. 11. The Arab Maghrib Union (AMU) was established in 1987, comprising five countries: Algeria, Libya, Mauritania, Morocco, and Tunisia. Again, due to incomplete data, Mauritania and Morocco were excluded. 12. The D-8 was founded in 1997. It unites the eight countries of Bangladesh, Egypt, Indonesia, Iran, Malaysia, Nigeria, Pakistan, and Turkey. All these countries are included in the study. 13. Since it is a double log model, the antilog value is employed. The antilogs of 0.4 and 0.12 are 2.51 and 1.33, respectively. 14. Antilog of 0.5176 is 3.293 15. Total trade =  20541 million dollar    16. 1 troy ounce = 0.311035 kilogram 13,800,000 troy ounce = 4292283 kilogram = 4,292 ton 17. It is assumed that Nigeria, Iran, Kuwait, and Syria are involved in the bloc.
  • 35. 65Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 18. The complete calculation is as follows: Net payment   = Np = (8.74+4.6+1.9+2.02+1.25) million gold dinars = 18.51 million gold dinars Total value of Trade  =TVT = 92.98 million gold dinars (TVT-Np)x100 (92.98-18.51) x 100 Efficiency = = TVT   92.98 = 80.09% References Alatas, Syed Farid (1987).“An Islamic Common Market and Economic Development”, Islamic Culture, 61 (1), pp.28-38. Arize, Agustine C.; Osang, Thomas, and Slottje, Daniel J. (2004). Exchange Rate Volatility in Latin America and Its Impact on Foreign Trade. Available at <URL: http://faculty.smu.edu/ tosang/pdf/latin2.pdf >, Access Date: 8th August 2005. Bendjilali, Boualem (2000). An Intra-Trade Econometric Model for OIC Member Countries: A Cross Country Analysis. Jeddah: IRTI Bernstein, Peter L. (2000). The Power of Gold. The History of an Obsession. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Bhuyan, Ayubur Rahman (1996). “Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries: Issues and Prospectives”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau. Chou, Ya-lun (1965). Applied Business and Economic Statistics. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. Dorn, James A. (1989).“Alternatives to Government Fiat Money”, Cato Journal, 9 (2), pp.277- 294. Esquivel, Gerardo and Larrain B., Felipe (2002). The Impact of G-3 Exchange Rate Volatility on Developing Countries. Harvard University Working Paper No. 86. European Central Bank (2005). Review of the International Role of the Euro. Available at: <URL: http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/ euro-international-role2005en.pdf >, Access Date: 1st August 2005. Glick, Reuven and Rose, Andrew K. (2002).“Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The Time- Series Evidence”, European Economic Review, 46 (6), pp. 1125-1151 Grauwe, Paul De (1989). International Money. Second Edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Grauwe, Paul De (2000). Economics of Monetary Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Greenspan, Alan (1966). Gold and Economic Freedom. Available at: <URL: http://shoemaker consulting.com/GoldisFreedom/greenspan.htm>, Access Date: 19th December 2004. Gujarati, Damodar (1995). Basic Econometrics. Third Edition. New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc. Haberler, Gottfried (1983).“A Comment on ‘The Importance of Stable Money’”. Cato Journal, 3 (1) Spring, pp. 83-91.
  • 36. 66 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Hamidi, M. Luthfi (2005). The Implementation of Gold Dinar Proposal among OIC Member Countries: Would It Affect Trade? Dissertation for MA Islamic Banking, Finance, and Management at Markfield Institute of Higher Education, UK. Hamidi, M. Luthfi (2007). Gold Dinar: Sistem Moneter Global yang Stabil dan Berkeadilan. Jakarta: Senayan Abadi Publishing Hassan, M. Kabir and Islam, Faridul (2001). “Prospect and Problem of a Common Market: An Empirical Examination of the OIC Countries”, American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, 18 (4), pp.19-45. IMF (2004). World Out Look. Advance Structural Reforms. Washington DC: IMF Izhar, Hylmun and Asutay, Mehmet (2005). Relative Stability of Gold Standard: A Theoretical Study. Paper presented at the Global Finance Conference 2005, 27-29 June 2005, Trinity College Dublin, Ireland. Jovanovic, Miroslav N. (1997). European Economic Integration: Limits and Prospects. London: Routledge. Kane, Edward J (1969). Economic Statistics and Econometrics: An Introduction to Quantitative Economics. London: Harper & Row Ltd. Keis, Nikolaus (1997).“The Costs and Benefits of the Euro: a Case Study for Germany”, in Paul Temperton (ed.). The Euro. Second Edition. Chicester: John Wiley & Sons. Koop, Gary (2000). Analysis of Economic Data. West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Mahathir, Mohammad (2002). The Seriousness of the Gold Dinar. Keynote address presented at International Seminar, Gold Dinar in Multilateral Trade, 22-23 October 2002, Organised by IKIM, Malaysia. McKenzie, M. (1998). “The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on Australian Trade Flows”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 8, pp. 21-38 Meera, Ahamed Kameel Mydin (2004). “Hedging Foreign Exchange Risk with Forward, Futures, Options and the Gold Dinar: a Comparison Note”, in The Theft of Nations. Selangor: Pelanduk Publications. Meera, Ahmad Kameel Mydin and Larbani, Moussa (2004). “The Gold Dinar: The Next Component in Islamic Economics Banking and Finance”, Review of Islamic Economic, 8 (1), pp.5-34. Meier, Gerald M. (1998). The International Environment of Business. Competition and Governance in the Global Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Miller, Joseph M. (n.d.). Monetary Gold Mismanagement in the Twentieth Century. Available at:<URL: http://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials/ jmiller121497.html>, Access Date: 29 March 2005 Mishkin, Frederick S. (2001). The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Market. Sixth Edition. London: Addison Wesley. Mohd Dali, Nuradli Ridzwan Shah bin (n.d.). Investment from Islamic Perspective and Mitigating Currency Risk with the Implementation of Gold Dinar.Available at:<URL:http: www.
  • 37. 67Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 microfinancenetwork.org/images/ndMitigatingCurrencyRiskwiththeImplementationof GoldDinar.pdf>, Access Date: 4th April 2005. MohdYusuf,Abu Bakar bin;Mohd Dali,Nuradli Ridzwan Shah bin;and Mat Husin,Norhayati (2002). “Implementation of The Gold Dinar: Is It the End of Speculative Measures?”, Journal of Economic Cooperation, 23 (3), pp.71-84. Mundell, Robert A. (1997a). Could Gold Make a Comeback? Paper delivered at St. Vincent College, Letrobe, Pennsylvania, March 12, 1997. Mundell, Robert A. (1997b). Optimum Currency Areas. Paper presented at the conference on Optimum Currency Areas, organized by Tel-Aviv University, December 5, 1997. Nienhaus, Volker (1996).“Trade Relations, Factor Movements and Islamic Common Market”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds). Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau. Nort,Garry (2003).Gold is a Political Metal.Available at: <URL: <http://shoemakerconsulting. com/GoldisFreedom/political-metal.htm>, Access Date: 1 February 2005 Pakko, Michael R. and Wall, Howard J. (2001).“Reconsidering the Trade-Creating Effects of a Currency Union”, Review - Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 83 (5) Sep/Oct., pp. 37-45. Poyhonen, P. (1963), “A Tentative Model of Trade between Countries”, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 90, pp. 91-113. Reynolds, Alan (1983). “Why Gold?”, Cato Journal, 3 (1), Spring, pp.211-232. Sadeq, Abul Hasan M. (1996).“Intra-Islamic Economic Integration: Regionalism to Ummatic Globalism”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds), Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau. Salvatore, Dominick (2001). International Economics. Seventh Edition. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Samuelson, P.A. (1969). “The Gains from International Trade Once Again”, in Jagdish Bhagwati (ed.), International Trade. Middlesex: Penguin Books. Satiroglu, A. Kadir D. (2000).“The Theory of Economic Integration and Its Relevance to OIC Member Countries”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau. SESRTCIC (1980). Areas of Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries. Ankara: Organisation of the Islamic Conference. Shakweer, Farooq (1996). “Prospects for the Establishment of the Islamic Common Market and the Role of Islamic Development Bank”, in Ayubur Rahman Bhuyan et al. (eds.), Towards an Islamic Common Market. Dhaka: Islamic Economic Research Bureau. Shalaby, Ismail (1988). “The Islamic Common Market”, Journal of Islamic Banking and Finance, 5 (1), pp.83-111. Sprinkel, Beryl W. (1983). “Can The Fed Control Money?”, Cato Journal, 3 (1) Spring, pp. 155-162. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2002). Globalization and Its Discontent. London: Allen Lane, The Penguin Press.
  • 38. 68 Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, 2009 Tinbergen, Jan (1962). Shaping the World Economy: Suggestion for an International Economic Policy. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund Vadillo, Umar Ibrahim (1996). The Return of The Gold Dinar. Cape Town: Madinah Press. Verbeek, Marno (2000). A Guide to Modern Econometrics. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons. Vergil, Hasan (2002). “Exchange Rate Volatility in Turkey and Its Effect on Trade Flows”, Journal of Economic and Social Research, 4 (1), pp. 83-99. White, Lawrence H. (1983). “Competitive Money, Inside and Out”, Cato Journal, 3(1), Spring, pp. 281-299. Yackop, Tan Sri Nor Mohamed (2002a). Trade and The Gold Dinar: The Next Component in the International Islamic Financial System. Paper presented at the International Conference on Stable and Just Global Monetary System, 19-20 August 2002, organised by International Islamic University Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia. Yackop, Tan Sri Nor Mohamed (2002b). The Role of Central Banks in the Implementation of the Gold Dinar Proposal. Paper presented at the international seminar on Gold Dinar in Multilateral Trades, 22-23 October 2002, Organized by IKIM, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.