SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 11
Entrepreneurship and Path Creation in
the Saudi Arabian Energy Transition
By Tatjana     de Kerros
Posted on April 9, 2012 on The Entrepreneurialist




                                                            A nation’s transition from
one technological path to another is the underlying feature to understanding the
transformation to an innovation-led system. The process of change and factors that
favour the adoption of certain types of technologies over others enables to examine the
role of different innovation mechanisms and actors that drive an economic and
industrial transformation.

Within the last two years, three combined challenges have emerged in the Kingdom of
Saudi Arabia; sustainability, competitiveness and energy security. These challenges are
coupled with other pressing macro-economic issues such as job creation, workforce
nationalization and diversification of the economic structure. In the coming years, these
factors will be drivers of the third energy revolution in Saudi Arabia.

The first energy revolution started in 1938, with the discovery of oil fields in Al
Hasa and the formation of the most powerful oil company in the world, Saudi Aramco.
The second energy revolution in 1973, led by the OPEC crisis and the oil embargo, saw
the price of the barrel double and led to one of the fastest economic and infrastructural
transformations ever seen globally. Saudi Arabia transformed from oil exporter to one
of the most powerful and affluent nations in the world, having a widespread effect on its
organizational and industrial evolution, whose impact remains visible to this day. The
third energy revolution is shaping, its backbone remaining Saudi Arabia’s vast natural
resource wealth, but this time, sustainable resources are the central feature of this
transition.

In 2011, Saudi Arabia saw a US$ 40.3 billion loss in oil revenues due to domestic
electricity consumption, which is encountering a 5% growth annually, and has risen by
27% in the last four years alone. Oil revenue losses are expected to rise to US$ 54.9
billion by 2015, equivalent to one third of Saudi Arabia’s 2012 national budget and 18
times the expected government surplus. According to the Electricity and Co-Generation
Regulatory Authority (ECRA), the number of new electricity consumers rose by 57.4%
from the period 2000-2009, 52% of which is compromised by residential growth
alone[1]. By 2016, the number of customers connected to the power grid is expected to
grow by 116%, and the impetus given by the Saudi government to increase private
sector actors has seen an increase of 93.7% in sold energy by the SEC to the
commercial sector[2].

However, Saudi Arabia is far from blind from these issues. Rather, the unfolding of its
domestic energy security has given rise to the opportunity to invest in new technological
paths that will transform an energy crisis into an energy revolution. Approximately US$
100 billion has been set aside to invest in alternative energy sources, which will see the
large-scale deployment of nuclear and solar power, aimed to compromise up to 15% of
the total energy mix by 2020[3]. The return on investment of alternative energies is also
significant- a US$ 1 billion investment in solar energy could lead to a revenue potential
of $2 billion by 2013, equivalent to a 72% return[4].

This leads us to explore who will be the drivers and actors of this new technological
path, which could lead Saudi Arabia to become the global hub for alternative energy
production and exports. How will Saudi Arabia be able to balance the integration
of alternative energy to its energy mix without disrupting other sources of
competiveness? The Kingdom is engaging into a process of economic
irreversibility which will lay the foundations for all future resource allocation; not just
by government institutions, but by the set of actors that are incremental to achieving
these goals and form part of the current system of equilibrium. Intentions can only be
transformed into a reality if Saudi Arabia manages to break its technological ‘lock-in’ to
enable the launch and adaptation of a renewable energy path away from oil dependence.
And at the very heart of the creation of a new technological trajectory, lays
entrepreneurship.

Oil dependency, technological ‘lock-in’ and path dependence in Saudi Arabia

To understand how entrepreneurship can reconfigure Saudi Arabia’s energy system,
understanding the mechanisms that has led to the dominance of a particular
technology- in this case hydrocarbons- over a sustainable energy source, such as solar
energy, is crucial. To this effect, evolutionary economics and path dependence plays a
huge part in explaining why the transition to alternative energy is only being pursued
now, rather than in the late 1970’s, as would initially have been possible. This also
enables to project the role of entrepreneurship in the development of new energy
systems, and subsequently, develop inducing regulations for all actors involved.

Path dependence implies that the evolution of an industry is governed by the
consequence of past events and decisions that create self-reinforcing mechanisms and
positive feedback loops enabling a predictable outcome for prices and market shares.
From an economic standpoint, it has been argued that technological path dependence
stems from a minor or inconsequential event that provides the impetus for a technology,
product or standard to lead, having irreversible influences on the market allocation of
resources[5]. In its most negative connotation, it means a system, once having adopted a
dominant path, finds itself unable to ‘shake free’ of this technology on the premise that
it will destabilize the whole of the system’s equilibrium.

Path dependence is a concept that also easily applies to regional disparities in economic
development, as economic landscapes inherit the legacies of pat developments which
can influence its future development. Regions become ‘locked in’ to particular
economic specialization, becoming over reliant on a particular technological resource,
leading to rigid and inflexible structures and restricting its ability to adapt to
competitive forces. Regions that suffer from path dependence become more vulnerable
to external shocks, which in turn, can bring about the decline of an industry as whole[6].

We can argue that at one stage, a state of multiple equilibrium existed in Saudi Arabia,
where both oil and solar power had the opportunity to compete successfully, but
investing resources in oil was favoured beyond investing in the stock of alternative
energy. A mechanism of selection took place where actors ‘branched out’ and decided
to extend the chosen path.

Oil already detained a selectional advantage as it was more technologically advanced,
detained wide-spread user experience, and brought about ‘increasing returns’ for actors
involved. This meant that although oil-based energy industries had an inferior long-run
potential, the actors involved in the industry had gained an early lead, gained experience
on how to increase production and reduced costs, directly raising the benefits for the
wider market. Added to this were the large fixed and sunk costs associated with oil
extraction and production, as compared to the cost of non-modular technologies, whose
costs tend to decrease at much slower rate that wind or photovoltaic modules[7].
Among other investment assets that cannot be ignored include the reputation
of individuals, firms and organizations, as well as heavy investments into the creation
of knowledge assets through education and training. At the time, the credibility,
feasibility and commitment to enabling policy was not substantial enough for these
actors to engage in competitive behaviour. This was aggravated by the government’s
tendency to detain large stakes in energy actors, and to partake in the practice of
selecting ‘winners and losers’, hence creating an artificial competitive environment.

From research in the field of path dependence, it has emerged that there exist various
degrees of this type of system behaviour. Path dependence at its most engrained is based
on decisions to use a particular system (or technology) that may have a controlling
influence for decades, and by which the long-term effects are fully appreciated by
decision-makers. All other actors become ‘locked-in’ to this technology despite its
inferiority due to its profit-making abilities, or in the case of Saudi Arabia, revenue
which contributes to 47.6% of GDP[8].

From an organizational perspective however, decisions to prolong the usage of oil rather
than develop alternative energy technologies resides primarily in asymmetric or
imperfect information. Without a clear market outlook and the ability to project the
return potential and demand, the associated risks are deemed too excessive by
incumbent firms and investors. In addition, the failure to deploy past alternative energy
projects such as SOLERAS resulted in the widespread belief that the initial conditions
and selection of an alternative path didn’t lead to the anticipated outcome. ‘Failure to
launch’ tends to include what is coined as ‘technologies of unknown merit’. Economic
momentum is lost as either the market place for such technologies do not yet exist,
affected parties are not yet born and actors cannot successfully coordinate or pool their
resources. Past events demonstrate that these factors heavily influenced the slow uptake
of alternative energy in Saudi Arabia, with key energy incumbents preferring to balance
between meeting external pressures whilst conforming to their undeniable competitive
advantage in hydrocarbons and sunk costs in infrastructure.

Above any other technological field, path dependence in energy systems is concerned
not only with technology, but the ideas and practices that are imbedded within the
organizational behaviour of actors, and consumer demand and behaviour by end-users.
Ideas and practices in the energy field subsequently shape innovation capabilities,
government policy, the environment and competition- all of whom are interlinked
within the reigning energy paradigm. Experience acquired with the usage of
hydrocarbons as the primary energy source generates knowledge derived from
experience. As technological knowledge is gained, this creates coordination effects;
whereas the benefits derived by one user increases when others use it. This creates a
domino effect, simultaneously increasing the positive expectations of its benefits by all
actors within the system, and generating increasing returns in the form of profit,
sustaining the ‘technological lock-in’ and influencing macro-level inputs and micro-
level behaviour.

The end of industry, innovation and creative destruction




                                     When examining the impacts of path dependence,
policy-makers and practitioners often neglect how closely related it is to industry
lifecycles, therefore how easily it can be disrupted. As path dependence is linked to the
evolution of an industry, it will follow the same industrial lifecycle of formation,
development, maturity and eventually, discontinuity.

At the formative stage, a breakthrough discovery will enable firms to enter a new
industry, with those that are successful able to expand their production and generate
economies of scale, leading to the exit of firms that are not able to compete. As the
industry develops, firms compete with alternative products, technologies and designs,
whereas by the rules of the industry, one technology will have dominance above all
others. This creates ‘lock-in’ as new products become uncompetitive and innovation
occurs only in processes, aggravating barriers to entry. When industry maturity has been
reached, new entrants are unable to compete with incumbents, and can only operate
within niche markets which do not allow for economies of scope.

However, incumbents cannot dominate niche markets, making it the ideal ecosystem for
new entrants to gain resilience and sustainability. Niche environments such as
specialized clusters, preferential policy or even incubators create a ‘protected’ space
whereas collaboration, rather than competition with incumbents is favoured, and
enables new entrants to differentiate their products from the dominant path. These
spaces allow for innovative activity, experimentation and growth, building on the
existing resource base and competencies of large firms. In this niche, technologies can
develop and mature whilst remaining sheltered from market forces.

However, a dominant energy system cannot be rendered discontinuous without the
technologies developed in niche markets being commercialized and diffused. This
requires the mobilization of skills and resources, as well as the transfer of knowledge.
Schumpeter clearly distinguishes the difference between an invention and an
innovation; an invention being a product or process conceived for the first time, as
opposed to an innovation which is the commercialization of that invention, involving a
transition from what is technologically possible to what is economically viable[9]. Only
once a critical mass of innovations have occurred within a protected niche it is then
possible to commercialize them via new investors, entrepreneurs, policy-makers,
incumbents and ultimately, the end-users.

To achieve this process, supporting new ventures and entrepreneurial activity is critical.
It is a well-known fact that entrepreneurial firms are more likely to adopt disruptive
innovation. Entrepreneurs seek solutions to problems that cannot be solved by old
technologies, and without radical innovation within the energy space, the dominant
market for fossil fuels cannot be destabilized.

Entrepreneurs have two strategic options: create new ventures based on incremental
innovation- thus prolonging the dominant path, or pursuing innovations that aims to
break the mould and create a new technological path. This differs from incumbents who
are more likely to invest in R&D based on technologies that balance between emerging
external pressures but retain their competitive advantage. However, these types of R&D
investments only contribute to creating discontinuous improvements in the dominant
technology. If an alternative technology manages to break the mould, the old system on
which the firms are dependent becomes obsolete, as will eventually be the incumbent.
Other forces such as organizational inertia, hierarchical rigidity and risk aversion are
additional features which destabilize incumbent firms and create a loss of vitality and
power to develop.

Nowhere is the battle between old and new more pronounced than in the energy field, as
it is the means of production that changes, not the end-product. A new system will not
emerge on the side-lines, but amidst the old structure. It will build on the existing
competency base and recombine existing resources with new players. To this effect, it is
important to realize that no single energy technology will be the ‘be-end and end-all’,
but that several technologies shall have to compete in parallel. During this stage of
discontinuity, one or more firms may have a competitive advantage or superior position,
but this will only be temporary. It will take a mass scale of innovations within the sector
and inducing policy to generate the momentum to transition from one technology to
another.

Goodbye the ‘Heroic Entrepreneur’

As was argued above, new entrants are incremental to the process of creative
destruction that garners change and unproductive economic growth. As has been the
case in many economies which today have radically shifted their energy systems to
alternative energy, entrepreneurship was one of the root enablers to this transition.

Entrepreneurs are known as ‘path creators’. They set in motion the process that shape
emerging social practices and technologies, and deviate from existing structures.
Entrepreneurs understand the factors that have create path dependency, and choose to
deviate from its structure. This means entrepreneurs do not conceive new technologies
as neutral, but mindfully know they are socially embedded. They understand that to
generate increasing returns and profit, they must not only create new solutions to
existing problems but new contexts in which the solutions can survive[10].

However, the concept that a single entrepreneur can change a technological path is
incoherent. To deviate from the existing path necessitates collective action, momentum
and a combination of inputs that harnesses the gradual involvement of all actors who
form part of the old system. It requires the ability to mobilize resources, networks and
know-how. The technology has to eliminate boundaries among actors so that it makes
economic sense and generates positive expectations that reduce uncertainty and
eliminate information asymmetries attributed to ‘technologies of unknown merit’.

The central challenge found in all entrepreneurial pursuits’ remains access to resources,
legitimacy and knowledge asymmetries. Whilst new entrants may be the proponents of
disruptive innovation, and are incremental at the early stages of market formation, new
contexts for these innovations cannot be created without the support of incumbents
firms, policy and finally, consumers. The role of networks and institutions cannot be set
aside when seeking to create emerging social practices, as entrepreneurs are least likely
to influence policy processes. In the case the change is actively sought due to the
inedibility of the future exhaustion of raw materials, the role of the state becomes
emphasized as market mechanisms are less effective to support energy
entrepreneurship. Upon this realization, the actions of large incumbent firms and actions
taken by the state represents change that is managed, centralized and coordinated.

Whilst centralized government and quasi-monopolistic market structures are usually
associated with a reduction of entrepreneurial activity, such is not the case in the
creation of new energy systems. Rather, this type of structure can facilitate new market
entrants by having the advantage of being able to pool and manages resources and
decision-making structures. They can clarify the nature of the value chain, and reduce
uncertainties on whether entrepreneurs can ‘fill the gap’ by combining their efforts with
large incumbents. In addition, many of the skills required within alternative
technologies are closely aligned with those existing in oil & gas, enabling the
knowledge-transfer required and increasing experience with a new technology. To this
extent, entrepreneurship is not a “random act of genius, but a disciplined effort of
many[11]”. Technological developments and the adoption of new energy systems may
be initiated by a limited number of actors, but needs to be backed by a social movement
to garner the required momentum.

Policy-induced energy innovation

Energy entrepreneurship finds itself at the intersection of science, technology and
innovation. Increasing the scope of innovative activity within energy systems and
creating an enabling environment demands a careful balance between supply-push and
demand-pull mechanisms. In the past and as many international examples have
demonstrated, technology-push policies in the form of public R&D, tax levies and
support to basic science have been the preferred regulatory instruments to induce
innovation within new energy technologies. However, it has been well documented a
balance between demand-pull regulations is the most favourable option. In turn, policies
that affect that the system distribution of new entrants and incumbents will impact not
only the energy system, but the innovation ecosystem as a whole, as this remains
embedded in a variety of socio-economic contexts.

Institutional players are critical in generating and steering various types of learning.
Their role should focus on steering the technological development process and
developing the complimentary assets necessary to create new paths. Energy systems are
unique in the sense that they require institutional intervention for a new path to emerge,
and cannot rely upon market forces alone to transition. A ‘level playing field’ has to be
created, which from its on-start must include the creation of niche environments, as well
as shared spaces among players. This can only be achieved through the implementation
of multiple policy instruments that encourages the participation of new entrants and
creates favourable market conditions. Institutional players must realize that new energy
technologies cannot compete on equal terms with the dominant energy path, and this
must be translated into policy.

Learning and coordination effects have been identified as prime elements of path
dependence- policies that focus on these features can steer new paths. This includes
supporting the creation of inter-industry alliances and creating shared industry
standards. In addition, policies that foster the availability of financing and generates
networks within education, institutions and associations induces the social movements
necessary to garner technological momentum.

Rather than banking on steering policies to induce breakthrough innovations, at the
stage of market formation and development, institutional players should favour
bricolage. Bricolage is an approach that harnesses the co-evolution of an industry sector
through a series of inputs from all actors, aiming to make smaller but steady gains with
a particular technology- hence mutually shaping a new technological trajectory. It is at
the opposite scale of actors attempting to achieve quick and dramatic changes within the
system, running into the risk of reducing learning and coordination effects. Most
importantly, if the attempt to achieve a dramatic technological transition fails, it
becomes much more difficult for firms to recover or correct deficiencies[12].
Bricolage induces experimentation, particularly among new entrants, and enables to
build the competency structures, networks and knowledge-sharing which are critical to
entrepreneurs and spillovers.
Factors that enable the rapid creation of new energy paths among institutional players
include a long-term alternative energy adoption plan, and broad political consensus.
Signalling years in advance the future requirements and objectives provides an incentive
for private sector participation, as well as the creation of a future market-space. If
incumbents and new entrants believe that a market will exist for their products, they are
more likely to invest resources, enhance their competencies and experiment in
innovative activity. Understanding how the future market will be shaped enables
entrepreneurs to secure key assets and assess how collaboration with incumbents will
affect them.

Institutional players must realize that policy-induced mechanisms for path creation
typically favour large incumbents rather than new entrants. Large firms detain the
legitimacy, know-how, resources and competencies to influence the shaping, or failure
of a market. Strong incentives have to be developed to garner their commitment,
investment and collaboration with new entrants in order to transfer resources and
knowledge. Critically, during the transition from one technological path to another, the
objective is to ensure the survival of large incumbents alongside new entrants.

Lastly, the role of civil society cannot be ignored when shaping the transition. It is
lead users and active consumers who create the new market for companies, and
influence the political climate. As the end-product will remain the same, consumers will
be influenced by price rather than by product. Therefore policies which enable
competitive pricing alongside fossil fuels are indispensable. To harness learning effects,
a large-scale demonstration provides experience to the user, having a domino effect that
will lead to the belief that the use of the technology will increase with every new user
and augment its benefits. Again, building networks, education, incentives and providing
regulatory plans well in advance increases the build-up of momentum which enables
widespread adoption.

Whilst new entrants set in motion the processes of change and new path creation, the
possibility of failure remains very much inherent. Rather than compete, entrepreneurial
firms should seek to collaborate with incumbents to secure legitimacy, increase
capacity, access complimentary assets and facilitate the selective development of new
markets. The ability to orchestrate efforts with all players within the system enables to
overcome the challenges that are associated to current path dependence. There needs to
be a concerted effort for entrepreneurs to understand the current and future market in
which they are born, and not limit themselves solely on their growth and technology. To
this end, an understanding of the nature and structure of the value-chain, their intended
positioning and stakeholder networks are key.

As being possessors of knowledge that can deviate from the dominating path,
entrepreneurs are required to be able to translate their ideas into an interaction. The
manner in which the entrepreneurial venture is communicated and presented enables to
test the preferences of actors within the system, and co-mutually shape them through
experimentation. This creates the positive feedback loops that set a path in motion.
Through practice, new entrants can re-combine existing and under-utilized resources to
their advantage, and partake in the creation of a context for their innovation.

The deviation from an existing energy system to a new path involves a multiplicity
of players and their careful orchestration. First and foremost, recognizing the
characteristics that signal the destabilization of the dominant system is crucial in order
to enact alternative solutions that enable diversification. To this process,
entrepreneurship is focal as they are able to develop a process of mindful deviation that
generates collective action in coordination with all actors that form part of the system.
They are not exogenous to the system, but have to set new foundations within the old
structure that can break the technological ‘lock-in’.

In the case of Saudi Arabia, the transition is already well underway. Incumbents and
champions are aware of the future transition, and have started allocating their resources
and enhancing their competencies to ensure that this equates to increased market
opportunity, rather than failure. The centralized nature of resources is enabling
leadership and swift decision-making from institutional players, steering the investment
of resources from incumbents.

It could be argued that within the current climate, an environment for bricolage rather
than breakthrough innovation will result in a better coordinated and competitive
environment for alternative technologies. Solar technology for example has been at the
centre of R&D in the Kingdom for the past three decades- breakthrough innovations are
not as much required as the collective development of incremental innovations for its
widespread growth, price-competitiveness and diffusion.

Despite the huge market potential, the crucial gap remains the inclusion of new entrants
and entrepreneurs to the equation. For Saudi Arabia to manoeuvre its energy transition,
a level playing field for entrepreneurial activity within the energy system must be
prioritized above all.

© Tatjana de Kerros 2012


[1] Electricity & Cogeneration Regulatory Authority. (2009). Activities and
Achievements of the Authority. Riyadh: Activities and Achievements of the Authority.

[2] Saudi Electricity Company. (2010). Annual Report 2010. Riyadh: Saudi Electricity
Company.

[3] King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable Energy. (2011). Towards a
Sustainable Energy Mix for Saudi Arabia. Third Saudi Solar Energy Forum (pp. 1-41).
Riyadh: King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable Energy

[4] Lovato, W. (2011). Six Solar Market Myths: An Investor Perspective. Third Saudi
Solar Energy Forum (pp. 1-28). Riyadh: King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable
Energy.

[5] Liebowitz, (1995). Path Dependence, Lock-in and History p.1

[6] (Martin & Sunley, 2006)

[7] (Lovio, Mickwitz, & Heiskanen, 2011, p. 277)

[8] 2010, Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency.
[9] (Carpenter, Simmie, Conti, Povinelli, & Kishagen, 2011, p. 8)

[10] (Lovio, Mickwitz, & Heiskanen, 2011, pp. 274,279)

[11] (Garud & Karnoe, Path Creation as a Process of Mindful Deviation, 2011, p. 26)

[12] (Garud & Karnoe, Bricolage versus breakthrough: distributed and embedded
agency in technology entrepreneurship, 2003, p. 296)


Bibliography
Altman, M. (2000). A Behavioural Model of Path Dependency: The Economics of
profitable inefficiency and market Failure. Journal of Socio-Economics, 29, 127-145.

Arrow, K. J. (2011). Path Dependence and Competitive Equilibrium. The European
Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 7(2), 171-180.

Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by
Historical Events. The Economic Journal, 99(394), 116-131.

Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev, Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. M. (1994). Positive Feedbacks in the
 Economy. In W. B. Arthur, Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the
Economy (pp. 1-12). University of Michigan.

Carpenter, J., Simmie, J., Conti, E., Povinelli, F., & Kishagen, M. (2011). Innovation
and New Path Creation: Insights into the Wind Power Industry for Europe’s
Competitiveness. Knowledge for Growth-Industrial Research ans Innovation (pp.
1-24). Sevilla: Directorate General for Research and Innovation.

cogent. (2011). Power People: The Civiol Nuclear Workforce 2009-2025. London:
cogent.

Cooke, P. (2010). Regional Innovation Systems, Clusters and the Knowledge
Economy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4), 945-974.

DDavid, P. A. (2007). Path Dependence-A Foundational Concept for Historical Social
Science. The Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History, 1(2), 1-23.

Electricity & Co-Generation Regulatory Authority. (2010). Annual Statistical Booklet
on Electricity Industry. Riyadh: Electricity & Co-Generation Regulatory Authority.

Fagerberg, J., Mowery, D. C., & Verspagen, B. (2008). Innovation-systems, path-
dependency and policy: The co-evolution of science, technology and innovation policy
and industrial structure

Garud, R., & Karnoe, P. (2003). Bricolage versus breakthrough: distributed and
embedded agency in technology entrepreneurship. Research Policy, 32, 277-300.
Garud, R., & Karnoe, P. (2011). Path Creation as a Process of Mindful Deviation. In
R. Garud, & P. Karnoe, Path Dependence and Creation (pp. 1-38). New Jersey:
Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

Liebowitz, S. J. (1995). Path Dependence, Lock-In, and History. Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization, 205-226.

Lovio, R., Mickwitz, P., & Heiskanen, E. (2011). Path dependence, path creation and
creative destruction in the evolution of energy systems. In R. Wustenhagen, & R.
Wuebker, Handbook of Research on Energy Entrepreneurship (pp. 274-301). Edward
Elgar.

Martin, R., & Sunley, P. (2006). The Place of Path Dependence in an Evolutionary
Perspective on the Economic Landscape. In R. Boschma, & R. Martin, Handbook of
Evolutionay Economic Geography (pp. 1-49). Chichester: Edward Elgar.

Saudi Electricity Company. (2010). Annual Report 2010. Riyadh: Saudi Electricity
Company.



............................................................................................................................................

More Related Content

What's hot

EEI Future of Distribution 2012
EEI Future of Distribution 2012EEI Future of Distribution 2012
EEI Future of Distribution 2012Paul De Martini
 
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS H Janardan Prabhu
 
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading Markets
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading MarketsDisruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading Markets
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading MarketsCTRM Center
 
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008Dmitry Tseitlin
 
DOE Solar Energy Industry Forecast
DOE Solar Energy Industry ForecastDOE Solar Energy Industry Forecast
DOE Solar Energy Industry Forecastkiakaha
 
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformation
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformationKS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformation
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformationNicholas Howarth
 
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy Competitiveness
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy CompetitivenessMcKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy Competitiveness
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy CompetitivenessMarcellus Drilling News
 
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014Scott Clausen
 
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio Serrano
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio SerranoWEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio Serrano
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio SerranoEcologistas en Accion
 
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014WNS Global Services
 
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014ScottMadden, Inc.
 
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity Christoph Forstner
 
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...ReportsnReports
 
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)Grant Thornton International Ltd
 
Challenge For Utilities And Regulators
Challenge For Utilities And RegulatorsChallenge For Utilities And Regulators
Challenge For Utilities And Regulatorsbinny_prabhakar
 
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & Publications
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & PublicationsRenewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & Publications
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & PublicationsAranca
 
P16100_strategybrief
P16100_strategybriefP16100_strategybrief
P16100_strategybriefScott Martin
 
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015Energy for One World
 

What's hot (20)

EEI Future of Distribution 2012
EEI Future of Distribution 2012EEI Future of Distribution 2012
EEI Future of Distribution 2012
 
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS
INDIA SOLAR PHTOVOLTAIC EXPECTATIONS
 
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading Markets
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading MarketsDisruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading Markets
Disruptive Technologies in Commodity Trading Markets
 
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008
Solar Energy Industry Forecast DOE 2008
 
DOE Solar Energy Industry Forecast
DOE Solar Energy Industry ForecastDOE Solar Energy Industry Forecast
DOE Solar Energy Industry Forecast
 
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformation
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformationKS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformation
KS-1517-WB15A-Global-shift_The-energy-productivity-transformation
 
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy Competitiveness
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy CompetitivenessMcKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy Competitiveness
McKinsey & Co. Report: Ohio Energy Competitiveness
 
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014
ACORE_USEPA_111(d)_Comments_12-1-2014
 
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio Serrano
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio SerranoWEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio Serrano
WEF global energy architecture (2015). Lecturas recomendadas. Antonio Serrano
 
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014
The Future of Utilities Special Report 2014
 
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014
The ScottMadden Energy Industry Update – Winter 2013-2014
 
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity
Christoph Forstner: Market Entry Concept of Solarcity
 
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...
Power Markets in Emerging Economies - Market Outlook, Capacity and Generation...
 
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)
Sustainability: changing the debate in emerging markets (IBR 2014)
 
Challenge For Utilities And Regulators
Challenge For Utilities And RegulatorsChallenge For Utilities And Regulators
Challenge For Utilities And Regulators
 
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & Publications
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & PublicationsRenewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & Publications
Renewable Energy: Growing sources of Investment | Aranca Article & Publications
 
G.E.T. Smart - Smart Renewables: Dept. of Commerce Policy Presentation
G.E.T. Smart - Smart Renewables: Dept. of Commerce Policy PresentationG.E.T. Smart - Smart Renewables: Dept. of Commerce Policy Presentation
G.E.T. Smart - Smart Renewables: Dept. of Commerce Policy Presentation
 
Emerging wind energy markets europe
Emerging wind energy markets europeEmerging wind energy markets europe
Emerging wind energy markets europe
 
P16100_strategybrief
P16100_strategybriefP16100_strategybrief
P16100_strategybrief
 
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015
Energy Transition and The State of US Utility 2015
 

Similar to Entrepreneurship in the Middle East energy sector

Digital Future of Oil & Gas
Digital Future of Oil & GasDigital Future of Oil & Gas
Digital Future of Oil & GasHarjit Birdi
 
UAE Renewable Energy transition Pathways
UAE Renewable Energy transition PathwaysUAE Renewable Energy transition Pathways
UAE Renewable Energy transition PathwaysJagannathan P.R
 
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy Sources
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy SourcesThe Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy Sources
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy SourcesChristo Ananth
 
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015PwC
 
Financing slide _India.docx
Financing slide _India.docxFinancing slide _India.docx
Financing slide _India.docxamitMishra732469
 
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Scott Clausen
 
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-Countries
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-CountriesKS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-Countries
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-CountriesNicholas Howarth
 
Rauluk Testimony Final no pics
Rauluk Testimony Final no picsRauluk Testimony Final no pics
Rauluk Testimony Final no picsValerie Rauluk
 
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.Energy for One World
 
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 Paper
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 PaperSteve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 Paper
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 PaperSteven Avary
 
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...Power System Operation
 
Leading In Green 11 30 09 Final
Leading In Green 11 30 09 FinalLeading In Green 11 30 09 Final
Leading In Green 11 30 09 Finalinterplaydave
 
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy Projects
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy ProjectsZero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy Projects
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy ProjectsStavros Thomas
 
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM Capabilities
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM CapabilitiesGlobal Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM Capabilities
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM CapabilitiesCTRM Center
 
NewBase August 22-2022 Energy News issue - 1540 by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...
NewBase August 22-2022  Energy News issue - 1540  by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...NewBase August 22-2022  Energy News issue - 1540  by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...
NewBase August 22-2022 Energy News issue - 1540 by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...Khaled Al Awadi
 
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...PwC France
 
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy Innovation
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy InnovationVenture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy Innovation
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy InnovationTBJ Investments, LLC
 

Similar to Entrepreneurship in the Middle East energy sector (20)

Digital Future of Oil & Gas
Digital Future of Oil & GasDigital Future of Oil & Gas
Digital Future of Oil & Gas
 
Aligning Global Agendas
Aligning Global AgendasAligning Global Agendas
Aligning Global Agendas
 
UAE Renewable Energy transition Pathways
UAE Renewable Energy transition PathwaysUAE Renewable Energy transition Pathways
UAE Renewable Energy transition Pathways
 
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy Sources
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy SourcesThe Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy Sources
The Economics of Transitioning to Renewable Energy Sources
 
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015
PwC Global Power & Utilities Survey 2015
 
Financing slide _India.docx
Financing slide _India.docxFinancing slide _India.docx
Financing slide _India.docx
 
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
Senate Finance Committee Tax Reform Comments 4-15-15
 
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-Countries
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-CountriesKS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-Countries
KS-1646-DP041A-Energy-Productivity-as-a-New-Growth-Model-for-GCC-Countries
 
Solar Tech- HR Final Project
Solar Tech- HR Final Project Solar Tech- HR Final Project
Solar Tech- HR Final Project
 
Rauluk Testimony Final no pics
Rauluk Testimony Final no picsRauluk Testimony Final no pics
Rauluk Testimony Final no pics
 
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.
CEeraWeek 2024, Daniel Yergins View on Road map for Energy Transition.
 
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 Paper
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 PaperSteve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 Paper
Steve Avary - Electricity Utility 2 point 0 Paper
 
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...
INTERNATIONAL GRID INTEGRATION Efficiencies, Vulnerabilities, and Strategic I...
 
Leading In Green 11 30 09 Final
Leading In Green 11 30 09 FinalLeading In Green 11 30 09 Final
Leading In Green 11 30 09 Final
 
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy Projects
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy ProjectsZero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy Projects
Zero-subsidy Onshore Wind Energy Projects
 
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM Capabilities
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM CapabilitiesGlobal Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM Capabilities
Global Renewables Transition Requires Dedicated ETRM Capabilities
 
Clareo jaouiche utility
Clareo jaouiche utilityClareo jaouiche utility
Clareo jaouiche utility
 
NewBase August 22-2022 Energy News issue - 1540 by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...
NewBase August 22-2022  Energy News issue - 1540  by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...NewBase August 22-2022  Energy News issue - 1540  by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...
NewBase August 22-2022 Energy News issue - 1540 by Khaled Al Awadi (AutoRec...
 
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...
Etude PwC/Strategy& sur les fusions-acquisitions dans le secteur de l'énergie...
 
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy Innovation
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy InnovationVenture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy Innovation
Venture Capital and Cleantech: The Wrong Model for Energy Innovation
 

Entrepreneurship in the Middle East energy sector

  • 1. Entrepreneurship and Path Creation in the Saudi Arabian Energy Transition By Tatjana de Kerros Posted on April 9, 2012 on The Entrepreneurialist A nation’s transition from one technological path to another is the underlying feature to understanding the transformation to an innovation-led system. The process of change and factors that favour the adoption of certain types of technologies over others enables to examine the role of different innovation mechanisms and actors that drive an economic and industrial transformation. Within the last two years, three combined challenges have emerged in the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia; sustainability, competitiveness and energy security. These challenges are coupled with other pressing macro-economic issues such as job creation, workforce nationalization and diversification of the economic structure. In the coming years, these factors will be drivers of the third energy revolution in Saudi Arabia. The first energy revolution started in 1938, with the discovery of oil fields in Al Hasa and the formation of the most powerful oil company in the world, Saudi Aramco. The second energy revolution in 1973, led by the OPEC crisis and the oil embargo, saw the price of the barrel double and led to one of the fastest economic and infrastructural transformations ever seen globally. Saudi Arabia transformed from oil exporter to one of the most powerful and affluent nations in the world, having a widespread effect on its organizational and industrial evolution, whose impact remains visible to this day. The third energy revolution is shaping, its backbone remaining Saudi Arabia’s vast natural
  • 2. resource wealth, but this time, sustainable resources are the central feature of this transition. In 2011, Saudi Arabia saw a US$ 40.3 billion loss in oil revenues due to domestic electricity consumption, which is encountering a 5% growth annually, and has risen by 27% in the last four years alone. Oil revenue losses are expected to rise to US$ 54.9 billion by 2015, equivalent to one third of Saudi Arabia’s 2012 national budget and 18 times the expected government surplus. According to the Electricity and Co-Generation Regulatory Authority (ECRA), the number of new electricity consumers rose by 57.4% from the period 2000-2009, 52% of which is compromised by residential growth alone[1]. By 2016, the number of customers connected to the power grid is expected to grow by 116%, and the impetus given by the Saudi government to increase private sector actors has seen an increase of 93.7% in sold energy by the SEC to the commercial sector[2]. However, Saudi Arabia is far from blind from these issues. Rather, the unfolding of its domestic energy security has given rise to the opportunity to invest in new technological paths that will transform an energy crisis into an energy revolution. Approximately US$ 100 billion has been set aside to invest in alternative energy sources, which will see the large-scale deployment of nuclear and solar power, aimed to compromise up to 15% of the total energy mix by 2020[3]. The return on investment of alternative energies is also significant- a US$ 1 billion investment in solar energy could lead to a revenue potential of $2 billion by 2013, equivalent to a 72% return[4]. This leads us to explore who will be the drivers and actors of this new technological path, which could lead Saudi Arabia to become the global hub for alternative energy production and exports. How will Saudi Arabia be able to balance the integration of alternative energy to its energy mix without disrupting other sources of competiveness? The Kingdom is engaging into a process of economic irreversibility which will lay the foundations for all future resource allocation; not just by government institutions, but by the set of actors that are incremental to achieving these goals and form part of the current system of equilibrium. Intentions can only be transformed into a reality if Saudi Arabia manages to break its technological ‘lock-in’ to enable the launch and adaptation of a renewable energy path away from oil dependence. And at the very heart of the creation of a new technological trajectory, lays entrepreneurship. Oil dependency, technological ‘lock-in’ and path dependence in Saudi Arabia To understand how entrepreneurship can reconfigure Saudi Arabia’s energy system, understanding the mechanisms that has led to the dominance of a particular technology- in this case hydrocarbons- over a sustainable energy source, such as solar energy, is crucial. To this effect, evolutionary economics and path dependence plays a huge part in explaining why the transition to alternative energy is only being pursued now, rather than in the late 1970’s, as would initially have been possible. This also enables to project the role of entrepreneurship in the development of new energy systems, and subsequently, develop inducing regulations for all actors involved. Path dependence implies that the evolution of an industry is governed by the consequence of past events and decisions that create self-reinforcing mechanisms and
  • 3. positive feedback loops enabling a predictable outcome for prices and market shares. From an economic standpoint, it has been argued that technological path dependence stems from a minor or inconsequential event that provides the impetus for a technology, product or standard to lead, having irreversible influences on the market allocation of resources[5]. In its most negative connotation, it means a system, once having adopted a dominant path, finds itself unable to ‘shake free’ of this technology on the premise that it will destabilize the whole of the system’s equilibrium. Path dependence is a concept that also easily applies to regional disparities in economic development, as economic landscapes inherit the legacies of pat developments which can influence its future development. Regions become ‘locked in’ to particular economic specialization, becoming over reliant on a particular technological resource, leading to rigid and inflexible structures and restricting its ability to adapt to competitive forces. Regions that suffer from path dependence become more vulnerable to external shocks, which in turn, can bring about the decline of an industry as whole[6]. We can argue that at one stage, a state of multiple equilibrium existed in Saudi Arabia, where both oil and solar power had the opportunity to compete successfully, but investing resources in oil was favoured beyond investing in the stock of alternative energy. A mechanism of selection took place where actors ‘branched out’ and decided to extend the chosen path. Oil already detained a selectional advantage as it was more technologically advanced, detained wide-spread user experience, and brought about ‘increasing returns’ for actors involved. This meant that although oil-based energy industries had an inferior long-run potential, the actors involved in the industry had gained an early lead, gained experience on how to increase production and reduced costs, directly raising the benefits for the wider market. Added to this were the large fixed and sunk costs associated with oil extraction and production, as compared to the cost of non-modular technologies, whose costs tend to decrease at much slower rate that wind or photovoltaic modules[7]. Among other investment assets that cannot be ignored include the reputation of individuals, firms and organizations, as well as heavy investments into the creation of knowledge assets through education and training. At the time, the credibility, feasibility and commitment to enabling policy was not substantial enough for these actors to engage in competitive behaviour. This was aggravated by the government’s tendency to detain large stakes in energy actors, and to partake in the practice of selecting ‘winners and losers’, hence creating an artificial competitive environment. From research in the field of path dependence, it has emerged that there exist various degrees of this type of system behaviour. Path dependence at its most engrained is based on decisions to use a particular system (or technology) that may have a controlling influence for decades, and by which the long-term effects are fully appreciated by decision-makers. All other actors become ‘locked-in’ to this technology despite its inferiority due to its profit-making abilities, or in the case of Saudi Arabia, revenue which contributes to 47.6% of GDP[8]. From an organizational perspective however, decisions to prolong the usage of oil rather than develop alternative energy technologies resides primarily in asymmetric or imperfect information. Without a clear market outlook and the ability to project the return potential and demand, the associated risks are deemed too excessive by
  • 4. incumbent firms and investors. In addition, the failure to deploy past alternative energy projects such as SOLERAS resulted in the widespread belief that the initial conditions and selection of an alternative path didn’t lead to the anticipated outcome. ‘Failure to launch’ tends to include what is coined as ‘technologies of unknown merit’. Economic momentum is lost as either the market place for such technologies do not yet exist, affected parties are not yet born and actors cannot successfully coordinate or pool their resources. Past events demonstrate that these factors heavily influenced the slow uptake of alternative energy in Saudi Arabia, with key energy incumbents preferring to balance between meeting external pressures whilst conforming to their undeniable competitive advantage in hydrocarbons and sunk costs in infrastructure. Above any other technological field, path dependence in energy systems is concerned not only with technology, but the ideas and practices that are imbedded within the organizational behaviour of actors, and consumer demand and behaviour by end-users. Ideas and practices in the energy field subsequently shape innovation capabilities, government policy, the environment and competition- all of whom are interlinked within the reigning energy paradigm. Experience acquired with the usage of hydrocarbons as the primary energy source generates knowledge derived from experience. As technological knowledge is gained, this creates coordination effects; whereas the benefits derived by one user increases when others use it. This creates a domino effect, simultaneously increasing the positive expectations of its benefits by all actors within the system, and generating increasing returns in the form of profit, sustaining the ‘technological lock-in’ and influencing macro-level inputs and micro- level behaviour. The end of industry, innovation and creative destruction When examining the impacts of path dependence, policy-makers and practitioners often neglect how closely related it is to industry lifecycles, therefore how easily it can be disrupted. As path dependence is linked to the evolution of an industry, it will follow the same industrial lifecycle of formation, development, maturity and eventually, discontinuity. At the formative stage, a breakthrough discovery will enable firms to enter a new industry, with those that are successful able to expand their production and generate economies of scale, leading to the exit of firms that are not able to compete. As the industry develops, firms compete with alternative products, technologies and designs, whereas by the rules of the industry, one technology will have dominance above all others. This creates ‘lock-in’ as new products become uncompetitive and innovation
  • 5. occurs only in processes, aggravating barriers to entry. When industry maturity has been reached, new entrants are unable to compete with incumbents, and can only operate within niche markets which do not allow for economies of scope. However, incumbents cannot dominate niche markets, making it the ideal ecosystem for new entrants to gain resilience and sustainability. Niche environments such as specialized clusters, preferential policy or even incubators create a ‘protected’ space whereas collaboration, rather than competition with incumbents is favoured, and enables new entrants to differentiate their products from the dominant path. These spaces allow for innovative activity, experimentation and growth, building on the existing resource base and competencies of large firms. In this niche, technologies can develop and mature whilst remaining sheltered from market forces. However, a dominant energy system cannot be rendered discontinuous without the technologies developed in niche markets being commercialized and diffused. This requires the mobilization of skills and resources, as well as the transfer of knowledge. Schumpeter clearly distinguishes the difference between an invention and an innovation; an invention being a product or process conceived for the first time, as opposed to an innovation which is the commercialization of that invention, involving a transition from what is technologically possible to what is economically viable[9]. Only once a critical mass of innovations have occurred within a protected niche it is then possible to commercialize them via new investors, entrepreneurs, policy-makers, incumbents and ultimately, the end-users. To achieve this process, supporting new ventures and entrepreneurial activity is critical. It is a well-known fact that entrepreneurial firms are more likely to adopt disruptive innovation. Entrepreneurs seek solutions to problems that cannot be solved by old technologies, and without radical innovation within the energy space, the dominant market for fossil fuels cannot be destabilized. Entrepreneurs have two strategic options: create new ventures based on incremental innovation- thus prolonging the dominant path, or pursuing innovations that aims to break the mould and create a new technological path. This differs from incumbents who are more likely to invest in R&D based on technologies that balance between emerging external pressures but retain their competitive advantage. However, these types of R&D investments only contribute to creating discontinuous improvements in the dominant technology. If an alternative technology manages to break the mould, the old system on which the firms are dependent becomes obsolete, as will eventually be the incumbent. Other forces such as organizational inertia, hierarchical rigidity and risk aversion are additional features which destabilize incumbent firms and create a loss of vitality and power to develop. Nowhere is the battle between old and new more pronounced than in the energy field, as it is the means of production that changes, not the end-product. A new system will not emerge on the side-lines, but amidst the old structure. It will build on the existing competency base and recombine existing resources with new players. To this effect, it is important to realize that no single energy technology will be the ‘be-end and end-all’, but that several technologies shall have to compete in parallel. During this stage of discontinuity, one or more firms may have a competitive advantage or superior position, but this will only be temporary. It will take a mass scale of innovations within the sector
  • 6. and inducing policy to generate the momentum to transition from one technology to another. Goodbye the ‘Heroic Entrepreneur’ As was argued above, new entrants are incremental to the process of creative destruction that garners change and unproductive economic growth. As has been the case in many economies which today have radically shifted their energy systems to alternative energy, entrepreneurship was one of the root enablers to this transition. Entrepreneurs are known as ‘path creators’. They set in motion the process that shape emerging social practices and technologies, and deviate from existing structures. Entrepreneurs understand the factors that have create path dependency, and choose to deviate from its structure. This means entrepreneurs do not conceive new technologies as neutral, but mindfully know they are socially embedded. They understand that to generate increasing returns and profit, they must not only create new solutions to existing problems but new contexts in which the solutions can survive[10]. However, the concept that a single entrepreneur can change a technological path is incoherent. To deviate from the existing path necessitates collective action, momentum and a combination of inputs that harnesses the gradual involvement of all actors who form part of the old system. It requires the ability to mobilize resources, networks and know-how. The technology has to eliminate boundaries among actors so that it makes economic sense and generates positive expectations that reduce uncertainty and eliminate information asymmetries attributed to ‘technologies of unknown merit’. The central challenge found in all entrepreneurial pursuits’ remains access to resources, legitimacy and knowledge asymmetries. Whilst new entrants may be the proponents of disruptive innovation, and are incremental at the early stages of market formation, new contexts for these innovations cannot be created without the support of incumbents firms, policy and finally, consumers. The role of networks and institutions cannot be set aside when seeking to create emerging social practices, as entrepreneurs are least likely to influence policy processes. In the case the change is actively sought due to the inedibility of the future exhaustion of raw materials, the role of the state becomes emphasized as market mechanisms are less effective to support energy entrepreneurship. Upon this realization, the actions of large incumbent firms and actions taken by the state represents change that is managed, centralized and coordinated. Whilst centralized government and quasi-monopolistic market structures are usually associated with a reduction of entrepreneurial activity, such is not the case in the creation of new energy systems. Rather, this type of structure can facilitate new market entrants by having the advantage of being able to pool and manages resources and decision-making structures. They can clarify the nature of the value chain, and reduce uncertainties on whether entrepreneurs can ‘fill the gap’ by combining their efforts with large incumbents. In addition, many of the skills required within alternative technologies are closely aligned with those existing in oil & gas, enabling the knowledge-transfer required and increasing experience with a new technology. To this extent, entrepreneurship is not a “random act of genius, but a disciplined effort of many[11]”. Technological developments and the adoption of new energy systems may
  • 7. be initiated by a limited number of actors, but needs to be backed by a social movement to garner the required momentum. Policy-induced energy innovation Energy entrepreneurship finds itself at the intersection of science, technology and innovation. Increasing the scope of innovative activity within energy systems and creating an enabling environment demands a careful balance between supply-push and demand-pull mechanisms. In the past and as many international examples have demonstrated, technology-push policies in the form of public R&D, tax levies and support to basic science have been the preferred regulatory instruments to induce innovation within new energy technologies. However, it has been well documented a balance between demand-pull regulations is the most favourable option. In turn, policies that affect that the system distribution of new entrants and incumbents will impact not only the energy system, but the innovation ecosystem as a whole, as this remains embedded in a variety of socio-economic contexts. Institutional players are critical in generating and steering various types of learning. Their role should focus on steering the technological development process and developing the complimentary assets necessary to create new paths. Energy systems are unique in the sense that they require institutional intervention for a new path to emerge, and cannot rely upon market forces alone to transition. A ‘level playing field’ has to be created, which from its on-start must include the creation of niche environments, as well as shared spaces among players. This can only be achieved through the implementation of multiple policy instruments that encourages the participation of new entrants and creates favourable market conditions. Institutional players must realize that new energy technologies cannot compete on equal terms with the dominant energy path, and this must be translated into policy. Learning and coordination effects have been identified as prime elements of path dependence- policies that focus on these features can steer new paths. This includes supporting the creation of inter-industry alliances and creating shared industry standards. In addition, policies that foster the availability of financing and generates networks within education, institutions and associations induces the social movements necessary to garner technological momentum. Rather than banking on steering policies to induce breakthrough innovations, at the stage of market formation and development, institutional players should favour bricolage. Bricolage is an approach that harnesses the co-evolution of an industry sector through a series of inputs from all actors, aiming to make smaller but steady gains with a particular technology- hence mutually shaping a new technological trajectory. It is at the opposite scale of actors attempting to achieve quick and dramatic changes within the system, running into the risk of reducing learning and coordination effects. Most importantly, if the attempt to achieve a dramatic technological transition fails, it becomes much more difficult for firms to recover or correct deficiencies[12]. Bricolage induces experimentation, particularly among new entrants, and enables to build the competency structures, networks and knowledge-sharing which are critical to entrepreneurs and spillovers.
  • 8. Factors that enable the rapid creation of new energy paths among institutional players include a long-term alternative energy adoption plan, and broad political consensus. Signalling years in advance the future requirements and objectives provides an incentive for private sector participation, as well as the creation of a future market-space. If incumbents and new entrants believe that a market will exist for their products, they are more likely to invest resources, enhance their competencies and experiment in innovative activity. Understanding how the future market will be shaped enables entrepreneurs to secure key assets and assess how collaboration with incumbents will affect them. Institutional players must realize that policy-induced mechanisms for path creation typically favour large incumbents rather than new entrants. Large firms detain the legitimacy, know-how, resources and competencies to influence the shaping, or failure of a market. Strong incentives have to be developed to garner their commitment, investment and collaboration with new entrants in order to transfer resources and knowledge. Critically, during the transition from one technological path to another, the objective is to ensure the survival of large incumbents alongside new entrants. Lastly, the role of civil society cannot be ignored when shaping the transition. It is lead users and active consumers who create the new market for companies, and influence the political climate. As the end-product will remain the same, consumers will be influenced by price rather than by product. Therefore policies which enable competitive pricing alongside fossil fuels are indispensable. To harness learning effects, a large-scale demonstration provides experience to the user, having a domino effect that will lead to the belief that the use of the technology will increase with every new user and augment its benefits. Again, building networks, education, incentives and providing regulatory plans well in advance increases the build-up of momentum which enables widespread adoption. Whilst new entrants set in motion the processes of change and new path creation, the possibility of failure remains very much inherent. Rather than compete, entrepreneurial firms should seek to collaborate with incumbents to secure legitimacy, increase capacity, access complimentary assets and facilitate the selective development of new markets. The ability to orchestrate efforts with all players within the system enables to overcome the challenges that are associated to current path dependence. There needs to be a concerted effort for entrepreneurs to understand the current and future market in which they are born, and not limit themselves solely on their growth and technology. To this end, an understanding of the nature and structure of the value-chain, their intended positioning and stakeholder networks are key. As being possessors of knowledge that can deviate from the dominating path, entrepreneurs are required to be able to translate their ideas into an interaction. The manner in which the entrepreneurial venture is communicated and presented enables to test the preferences of actors within the system, and co-mutually shape them through experimentation. This creates the positive feedback loops that set a path in motion. Through practice, new entrants can re-combine existing and under-utilized resources to their advantage, and partake in the creation of a context for their innovation. The deviation from an existing energy system to a new path involves a multiplicity of players and their careful orchestration. First and foremost, recognizing the
  • 9. characteristics that signal the destabilization of the dominant system is crucial in order to enact alternative solutions that enable diversification. To this process, entrepreneurship is focal as they are able to develop a process of mindful deviation that generates collective action in coordination with all actors that form part of the system. They are not exogenous to the system, but have to set new foundations within the old structure that can break the technological ‘lock-in’. In the case of Saudi Arabia, the transition is already well underway. Incumbents and champions are aware of the future transition, and have started allocating their resources and enhancing their competencies to ensure that this equates to increased market opportunity, rather than failure. The centralized nature of resources is enabling leadership and swift decision-making from institutional players, steering the investment of resources from incumbents. It could be argued that within the current climate, an environment for bricolage rather than breakthrough innovation will result in a better coordinated and competitive environment for alternative technologies. Solar technology for example has been at the centre of R&D in the Kingdom for the past three decades- breakthrough innovations are not as much required as the collective development of incremental innovations for its widespread growth, price-competitiveness and diffusion. Despite the huge market potential, the crucial gap remains the inclusion of new entrants and entrepreneurs to the equation. For Saudi Arabia to manoeuvre its energy transition, a level playing field for entrepreneurial activity within the energy system must be prioritized above all. © Tatjana de Kerros 2012 [1] Electricity & Cogeneration Regulatory Authority. (2009). Activities and Achievements of the Authority. Riyadh: Activities and Achievements of the Authority. [2] Saudi Electricity Company. (2010). Annual Report 2010. Riyadh: Saudi Electricity Company. [3] King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable Energy. (2011). Towards a Sustainable Energy Mix for Saudi Arabia. Third Saudi Solar Energy Forum (pp. 1-41). Riyadh: King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable Energy [4] Lovato, W. (2011). Six Solar Market Myths: An Investor Perspective. Third Saudi Solar Energy Forum (pp. 1-28). Riyadh: King Abdullah City for Atomic and Renewable Energy. [5] Liebowitz, (1995). Path Dependence, Lock-in and History p.1 [6] (Martin & Sunley, 2006) [7] (Lovio, Mickwitz, & Heiskanen, 2011, p. 277) [8] 2010, Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency.
  • 10. [9] (Carpenter, Simmie, Conti, Povinelli, & Kishagen, 2011, p. 8) [10] (Lovio, Mickwitz, & Heiskanen, 2011, pp. 274,279) [11] (Garud & Karnoe, Path Creation as a Process of Mindful Deviation, 2011, p. 26) [12] (Garud & Karnoe, Bricolage versus breakthrough: distributed and embedded agency in technology entrepreneurship, 2003, p. 296) Bibliography Altman, M. (2000). A Behavioural Model of Path Dependency: The Economics of profitable inefficiency and market Failure. Journal of Socio-Economics, 29, 127-145. Arrow, K. J. (2011). Path Dependence and Competitive Equilibrium. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 7(2), 171-180. Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events. The Economic Journal, 99(394), 116-131. Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev, Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. M. (1994). Positive Feedbacks in the Economy. In W. B. Arthur, Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy (pp. 1-12). University of Michigan. Carpenter, J., Simmie, J., Conti, E., Povinelli, F., & Kishagen, M. (2011). Innovation and New Path Creation: Insights into the Wind Power Industry for Europe’s Competitiveness. Knowledge for Growth-Industrial Research ans Innovation (pp. 1-24). Sevilla: Directorate General for Research and Innovation. cogent. (2011). Power People: The Civiol Nuclear Workforce 2009-2025. London: cogent. Cooke, P. (2010). Regional Innovation Systems, Clusters and the Knowledge Economy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4), 945-974. DDavid, P. A. (2007). Path Dependence-A Foundational Concept for Historical Social Science. The Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History, 1(2), 1-23. Electricity & Co-Generation Regulatory Authority. (2010). Annual Statistical Booklet on Electricity Industry. Riyadh: Electricity & Co-Generation Regulatory Authority. Fagerberg, J., Mowery, D. C., & Verspagen, B. (2008). Innovation-systems, path- dependency and policy: The co-evolution of science, technology and innovation policy and industrial structure Garud, R., & Karnoe, P. (2003). Bricolage versus breakthrough: distributed and embedded agency in technology entrepreneurship. Research Policy, 32, 277-300.
  • 11. Garud, R., & Karnoe, P. (2011). Path Creation as a Process of Mindful Deviation. In R. Garud, & P. Karnoe, Path Dependence and Creation (pp. 1-38). New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Liebowitz, S. J. (1995). Path Dependence, Lock-In, and History. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 205-226. Lovio, R., Mickwitz, P., & Heiskanen, E. (2011). Path dependence, path creation and creative destruction in the evolution of energy systems. In R. Wustenhagen, & R. Wuebker, Handbook of Research on Energy Entrepreneurship (pp. 274-301). Edward Elgar. Martin, R., & Sunley, P. (2006). The Place of Path Dependence in an Evolutionary Perspective on the Economic Landscape. In R. Boschma, & R. Martin, Handbook of Evolutionay Economic Geography (pp. 1-49). Chichester: Edward Elgar. Saudi Electricity Company. (2010). Annual Report 2010. Riyadh: Saudi Electricity Company. ............................................................................................................................................