SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 22
Download to read offline
Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget
Balance for Spain
GUIDO ZACK*
Alcalá University
PILAR POnCELA**
Universidad Autónoma de Madrid
EvA SEnRA
Alcalá University
DAnIEL SOTELSEK***
Alcalá University
Received: April, 2014
Accepted: July, 2014
Summary
The recession that started in 2008 caused a sharp deterioration of the budget balance of Spain. This de-
cline was not fully anticipated by the structural budget balance due to some methodology limitations.
In this article, we calculate an alternative structural balance for Spain in the years prior to the subprime
crisis that includes residential investment as an explanatory variable. This estimate shows that by 2004
the Spanish fiscal situation was not as strong as presumed. This fragility was hidden by the extraordi-
nary revenue from the real estate bubble and the construction boom.
Keywords: Crisis, structural budget balance, real estate bubble, construction boom, Spain.
JEL Classification: C20, E32, E63, H62.
1. Introduction
Until 2006 Spain seemed to have one of the most countercyclical fiscal policies in Eu-
rope. In fact, the observed budget balance (OBB) improved from a deficit of 6.5% of GDP in
1995 to a surplus of 2% in 2006. nevertheless, the crisis revealed the fragility of this improve-
ment, since between 2007 and 2009 the OBB fell by 13 percentage points (p.p.) of GDP.
* Guido Zack acknowledges the support of the Institute of Latin American Studies (IELAT), Alcalá Universtity.
** Pilar Poncela acknowledges financial support from the Spanish government, Ministerio de Economía y Compet-
itividad, contract grant ECO2012–32854.
*** Daniel Sotelsek acknowledges the support of SIPA-ILAS (Columbia University), during his 2013–2014 visit-
ing scholar.
Hacienda Pública Española / Review of Public Economics, 210-(3/2014): 11-31
© 2014, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales
DOI: 10.7866/HPE-RPE.14.3.1
This strong fall is also shown in the structural budget balance (SBB), however neither
the consolidation until 2006 nor the deterioration between 2007 and 2009 can be explained
only by discretionary measures. Situations like that not only happened in Spain, but they
have been occurring in several countries (Larch and Turrini, 2009). Thus, since 2000 there
are several proposals to improve the SBB.
The main objective of this paper is to adapt some of these proposals to the Spanish case
in the years prior to the subprime crisis. In particular, the fiscal impact of the real estate bub-
ble and the boom in the construction industry are incorporated, showing that the SBB is not
capable to identify completely the cycle effect on the budget balance. The improvement of
the SBB methodology is essential in Spain, given that its new budgetary stability law is
based on this indicator.
The article is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the evolution of the Spanish
budget within the European context, identifying a particularly volatile observed and struc-
tural budget balanced trend. This would have been a reflection of the volatile evolution of
residential investment. The SBB was not able to identify the transitory component of the rev-
enue and expenditure. Consequently, in the third section, several improvements of the SBB
traditional methodology proposed by the literature are reviewed. The fourth section adapts
some of these improvements to the particular case of Spain and shows the results obtained.
Finally, conclusions and policy recommendations are presented in section 5.
2. Descriptive analysis of the case of Spain within the European context
2.1. Evolution of public accounts
During the 90s, the budgetary policy in Eurozone countries was dominated by compli-
ance with the Stability and Growth Pact, which established limits on both government deficit
and public debt (3% and 60% of GDP, respectively). In this context, Spain seemed to pio-
neer a counter-cyclical policy. As shown in figure 1, the country progressed from a chroni-
cally high fiscal deficit in the first half of the 90s to a moderate deficit by the end of the
decade, and finally achieved a surplus of 2% of GDP in the years leading up to the reces-
sion. nevertheless, Spanish apparent solvency disappeared with the subprime crisis. Al-
though the recession punished the budgets of all European countries, Spain was particularly
affected. Indeed, between 2007 and 2009 the balance fell from a surplus of 1.9% of GDP to
a deficit of 11.1%, a decline of 13 p.p. in just two years, when the European Union average
(15 countries) fell only by 6 p.p.
Spanish fiscal decline was the result of the evolution of both expenditure and revenue.
The weight of expenditure in the GDP increased by 7 p.p. due to the combined effect of dis-
cretionary policies aimed at maintaining aggregate demand and automatic stabilisers in the
form of unemployment benefits. Revenue, meanwhile, fell by 6 p.p. of GDP, from slightly
more than 41% in 2007 to less than 35% in 2009, the lowest of all Eurozone countries. As
12 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
13Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
Figure 1. Observed and structural budget balance
(as a % of GDP and potential GDP)
Source: European Commission.
shown figure 2, the main reason for this was the loss of revenue from corporate tax (2.4 p.p.),
added value tax (2.3 p.p.), personal income tax (0.9 p.p.) and capital transfer tax and stamp
duty (0.9 p.p.).
The evolution of Spanish SBB in these years did not differ substantially from the OBB.
Indeed, from the mid-90s the SBB also showed a process of fiscal consolidation, reaching a
surplus of 1% of potential GDP in 2006 1. When the subprime crisis hit the market, the SBB
returned to negative figures, with a deficit of 8.6% of potential GDP in 2009 (figure 1).
This shortfall in the Spanish SBB was not seen in other European countries. Thus, it is
essential to ascertain what was different in Spain, moreover considering that its new budg-
etary stability law included in the Spanish Constitution is based on this indicator 2. The an-
swer can be found in the collapse of residential investment, since most revenues were direct-
ly and indirectly linked to the construction industry, while this sector was mainly responsible
for the loss of employment and, therefore, the increase in related expenditure (REAF, 2007).
2.2. Evolution of residential investment
In the years leading up to the 2007 crisis, housing prices rose sharply across most Euro-
pean countries, particularly in the UK and Spain, where they increased threefold, and to a
lesser extent in other countries such as France, Italy and Portugal (figure 3). Although price
variations in Spain were among the greatest, this would not seem enough to explain the no-
table difference in public accounts.
The greatest difference is found in the number of units built: while the GDP share of res-
idential investment remained either steady or even declined in most EU countries, in Spain
it rose sharply until 2006 (figure 4). This is because the increase in housing prices, instead
of discouraging buyers fearful of a reversal of the trend, had the opposite effect based on the
belief that prices would continue to raise, a clear indication of the creation of a bubble 3 (Gar-
cía Montalvo, 2003).
14 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Figure 2. Spanish government revenue and expenditure
(as a % of GDP)
Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations.
Accordingly, residential investment in Spain grew at an average rate of 8% per year
in real terms over the 1998-2007 period, twice the rate of the economy as a whole and
accounting for one fifth of the rise in GDP. Thus, by 2006 it accounted for 12.5% of
nominal GDP in Spain, when historically it had stood between 5% and 8%. In the
labour market, the construction sector accounted for 13.5% of all jobs in Spain, and
nearly a quarter of the growth in employment over the same period. When the bubble
burst, residential investment shrank to 4.4% of nominal GDP in 2013, while the con-
struction sector was directly responsible for the loss of 60% of the jobs between 2007
and 2011.
To sum up, the evolution of the construction sector and the housing market, not only in
terms of prices but also in the number of units built, could be responsible for the volatility
of Spanish public accounts.
15Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
Figure 3. Housing prices in Europe
(1996=100)
Source: European Central Bank.
3. SBB traditional methodology limitations
The SBB is estimated by the European Commission (EC) and the International Mone-
tary Fund (IMF). Both organisations base their calculation on the cyclical position of the
economy, i.e., the output gap (OG), and on the relationship between the cycle and the differ-
ent balance components (revenue and expenditure) 4. The cycle is linked to the budget
through the elasticities between the main revenue items (direct taxation of individuals and
companies, indirect taxes and social security contributions) and the OG, while in terms of
expenditure, only unemployment expenditures are considered cyclical. Then, the structural
components are calculated by multiplying the observed revenue or expenditure net of one-
off and temporary measures (Mourre et al., 2013) by the OG to the corresponding elasticity
power. In the case of expenditure, the IMF approach differs from the EC in that instead of
basing their calculations on the OG and the elasticity, they use a simple proportional rule be-
tween observed unemployment expenditures, the rate of unemployment and the non-Accel-
erating Wage Rate of Unemployment (nAWRU). Finally, the structural revenue and expen-
16 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Figure 4. Residential investment in Europe
(as a % of GDP, 2005 prices)
Source: European Commission.
diture are subtracted and the result is divided by the potential GDP (Girouard and André,
2005; Hagemann, 1999).
The objective of estimating the SBB is twofold: first, to assess the cyclical behaviour of
discretionary fiscal policies; and second, to attempt to measure the sustainability of such
policies by showing whether a fiscal balance is the result of the cyclical components of rev-
enue and expenditure, or whether it is based on a more stable trend (Blanchard, 1990). nev-
ertheless, in several cases, this indicator failed to explain both, the cyclicality and the sus-
tainability of fiscal policy. The reasons that led to these problems are the following.
First of all, SBB real-time estimation could be biased not because an error in its method-
ology, but because a bias in the OG real-time estimation. Kempkes (2012) shows that the OG
real-time estimation is biased. This bias points towards a more negative OG between 0.5%
and 0.6% of potential output. Thus, if a fiscal rule is based on this indicator, the real-time
admissible deficit will exceed the final value by about 0.5 percentage points per year 5.
Assuming an unbiased OG, SBB could still be biased because of the decoupling between
the tax base and GDP (Kremer et al., 2006; European Commission, 2013, Part III). This can
be partially corrected by taking into account the effects of the composition of demand
through more disaggregated indicators than the OG, such as the tax bases (European Com-
mission, 2007, Part II). But, each tax has sometimes several bases and it is not always pos-
sible to consider all of them. Thus, it is desirable to take into consideration at least the most
important ones and the assets that can be affected by a bubble. If not, a significant bias in
elasticity estimations could be generated 6.
In fact, de Castro et al. (2008) show that output elasticities of revenues and expenditures
are not constant across the cycle, but rather pro-cyclical. This could cause the cyclical pat-
tern in the revenues windfalls and shortfalls (Morris et al., 2009). That is why, in times of
economic growth, part of the cyclical revenue is usually considered structural (Girouard and
Price, 2004; Joumard and André, 2008). Therefore, based on real time data, fiscal policies
seem to be counter-cyclical, while after-the-event input suggests pro-cyclicality (Cimadomo,
2008; Golinelli and Momigliano, 2007; Forni and Momigliano, 2004).
Taking into account the SBB limitations to measure the fiscal policy cyclicality, the Eu-
ropean Commission (2013, part III) has developed a new indicator to measure the discre-
tionary fiscal effort (DFE). It consists of a narrative (bottom-up) approach on the revenue
side and a traditional (top-down) approach on the expenditure side. A comparison of both in-
dicators shows that, during booms, DFE indicates a more pro-cyclical policy than real time
estimation of SBB, in line with the evidence presented in the previous paragraph.
However, the DFE does not aim at measuring the sustainability of the fiscal policy. To
do so, and taking into account the SBB limitations reviewed in this section, the impact of
bubbles and booms in the cyclical components needs to be considered. In fact, de Castro et
al. (2008) and Morris et al. (2009) recognize that the housing boom could be responsible for
17Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
the notable revenues windfalls presented in Spain between 1999 and 2007. So, this paper
main objective is to include the real estate asset in the Spanish SBB estimation during the
years prior to the subprime crisis at the aim of improving the fiscal policy sustainability
measure.
4. Estimated structural budget balance for Spain
4.1. Methodology
First of all, tax collection must be disaggregated into revenue categories. As we are deal-
ing specifically with Spain, we can achieve a more accurate disaggregation instead of rely-
ing on the EC general categories. Revenue is therefore disaggregated into: social security
contributions (SSC), personal income tax (PIT), corporate tax (CT), property tax (PT; in-
cludes inheritance and gift tax and the discontinued wealth tax), value added tax (vAT), cap-
ital transfer tax and stamp duty (CTT-SD) and regional governments revenue (RG) 7.
Tax base proxies are used instead of the OG as explanatory variables. Thus composition
effects are considered. The tax base proxies used for each revenue item are as follows: for
the SSC, the average wage (W), the number of people employed (EM), and unemployment
benefits (UB); for PIT, the gross disposable household income (GDHI) and the average tax
rate (RatePIT); for CT, the gross disposable corporate income (GDCI) and the average tax
rate (RateCT) 8; for vAT, private consumption (PRC). Finally, for the PT, the CTT-SD and
the RG the residential investment (RI) is the only explanatory variable. RI is also included
in all the equations as an additional tax base because it takes into accounts not only prices,
but also quantities. Therefore, it can be considered as a proxy of economy-wide effects, since
the number of units built may affect employment in the construction sector, wage increases
and consumption rises, among others.
Annual data from 1986 to 2010 are used and the sources can be found at the annex A.
Following Girouard and Price (2004), Kremer et al. (2006), Morris and Schuknecht
(2007), and Price and Dang (2011), an error correction model was estimated for each tax rev-
enue category to capture both, short- and long-term relationships. Accordingly, we have es-
timated a long-term equation (1) linking the levels of the variables (in logarithms) for each
revenue category. Equation (2) shows the short-term dynamics between the revenue varia-
tion rate, due to long-term deviations from equilibrium, the variation rate of the respective
tax base proxies and (nominal) residential investment.
(1)
(2)
ln ln ln, , , ,T B RIi t i i j
j
N
i j t i tlt lt
i
lt
= + + +
=
∑α β γ
1
εεi t,
∆ = + ∆ + ∆
=
∑ln ln ln, , , ,T B Ri t i i j
j
N
i j t ist st
i
st
α β γ
1
II et i i t i t+ +−δ ε , ,1
18 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
where Ti is the observed revenue of the “i” revenue category; Bi,j is the “j” tax base proxy of
the “i” revenue category; Rl is the nominal residential investment; bi,j is the elasticity 9 of “i”
revenue to the “j” tax base; gi is the elasticity of the “i” revenue items to nominal residential
investment; subscripts “lt” and “st” stand for the long-term and short-term equations respec-
tively; di is the error correction factor; ∆ is the first difference operator; and ln is the natural
logarithm.
Once the coefficients have been obtained, the equation yields the structural value of each
revenue item based on the long-term values of the tax bases and residential investment prox-
ies. In the former case, following Kremer et al. (2006), tax bases proxies were smoothed
using a Hodrick – Prescott filter (λ=30) 10. In the latter case, the long-term value is taken to
be a fixed percentage of nominal GDP. various scenarios are developed based on the evo-
lution over time in Spain, ranging from 5% to 8% 11. Therefore, the structural value of each
revenue item is obtained from the following equation, adapted from the EC and IMF
methodology based on the OG (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999):
(3)
where the superscript “*” indicates structural value.
Adding up all structural revenue and tax revenue not included in the quantitative calcu-
lation (basically excise tax, foreign trade and gambling tax, that represent less than 10% of
total revenue and are taken to be unrelated to the evolution of the construction industry), we
obtain the total structural revenue.
(4)
where the superscript “*” indicates structural value; T is the total revenue; Ti is the revenue
stemming from residential investment; and NIT are the revenue items not related to residen-
tial investment.
According to the EC and IMF approaches, the only cyclical item of expenditure is un-
employment benefits (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999). The nAWRU, estimat-
ed by the EC, is used as the structural unemployed rate. However, the methodology of this
indicator (Mc Morrow and Roeger, 2000) affirms that it cannot be considered structural,
since it estimates the unemployment rate that stabilises the inflation rate, while the long-term
rate should stabilise both inflation and unemployment. Consequently our methodology does
not use the annual nAWRU value, but rather its 20-year moving average 12. This increases
the unemployment expenditure that is considered cyclical because it allows a greater differ-
ence between the long-term and observed unemployment rate. For the sake of simplicity, we
have followed the IMF method of calculating cyclical expenditure, i.e., a proportional rule
considering the monetary value of unemployment benefits, divided by the unemployment
rate and multiplied by the nAWRU moving average.
T T
B
B
RI
RI
i i
i j
i jj
Ni
i jlt
* ,
*
,
*,
=









=
∏
1
β



γilt
T T NITi
* *
= +∑
19Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
(5)
where the superscript “*” indicates the structural value; E is the total public expenditure; Ec
is the cyclical public expenditure; Eu is the unemployment expenditure; and UR is the unem-
ployment rate.
Finally, SBB is obtained by subtracting revenue from structural expenditures.
SBB* = T* – E* (6)
4.4. Results
First of all, we perform Dickey-Fuller (1981) unit roots tests to identify the order of in-
tegration of all variables. As shown in table B.1 in the annex B, we did not reject the unit
root hypothesis for the levels of the variables (in logarithms) in any case.
Table 1 shows short- and long-term coefficients obtained from the error correction
model estimated on each tax revenue using as covariates their tax base and nominal residen-
tial investment proxies, together with the error correction term. The annex B shows evidence
that confirms the suitability of the models used. Specifically, table B.2 shows the statistics
of the unit root test on the residuals of the long-term equations and MacKinnon’s (1991) crit-
ical values. It can be seen that, with the exception of the RG variable, the unit root null hy-
potheses is rejected for the residuals of all long-term equations (1), and as such they can be
considered stationary. In the case of RG, we concluded that there is no cointegration rela-
tionship between this variable and residential investment. Table B.3 shows the autocorrela-
tion value of the first two lags of the residuals from the long-term equations (1) and the error
correction models (2). The Ljung-Box (1978) statistic shows that the residuals in all short-
term equations are white noise, which confirms the suitability of the models. The residuals
of the long-term equations or cointegration relationships can be considered white noise for
all variables, except for IS. In this case, the efficiency of the cointegration vector estimation
can be improved using Stock and Watson’s (1993) dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS)
technique, that shows very similar results 13.
Going back to table 1, it can be seen that residential investment turned out to be a very
significant variable to explain the evolution of all the revenue items considered, and that the
coefficients signs are as expected. Likewise, the remaining variables are also significant, and
their signs as expected too 14. Error correction terms, which show the percentage of devia-
tion corrected for each period, are significant, being in all cases between 39% and 87%, ex-
cept for SSC, which seems to over-correct the deviation by 9%.
It can also be seen that there are no RG values in either the long-term equation or the
error correction term. This is because, as discussed previously, the residuals from its long-
E E E E E E E E E
UR
UR
E Ec u u u u u
* *
*
( )= − = − − = − −





 = − 1−−






UR
UR
*
20 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
term equation were not stationary. Therefore, in this case, we supposed that there is no coin-
tegration relationship between variables, meaning that the coefficient used to estimate
structural revenue is taken from the short-term equation in which no error correction was
included.
Table 1
TAX REVENUE ELASTICITIES
Error
RI W EM UB GDHI RatePIT GDCI RateCT PRC C correction R2
term
Short-term
SSC 0.15** 0.82*** 0.59** 0.07** 0 –1.09*** 0,90
–0,06 –0,1 –0,22 –0,03 –0,01 –0,26
PIT 0.20*** 0.43*** 0.18*** 0.03*** –0.69*** 0,98
–0,03 –0,14 –0,01 –0,01 –0,2
CT 0.39*** 0.42** 0.33*** 0 –0.39** 0,92
–0,08 –0,12 –0,03 –0,01 –0,15
PT 0.99*** 0 –0.87*** 0,58
–0,25 –0,04 –0,21
vAT 0.73*** 1.58*** –0.11*** –0.89*** 0,99
–0,13 –0,45 –0,02 –0,16
CTT–SD 1.39*** 0 –0.82*** 0,66
–0,19 –0,03 –0,21
RG 0.29*** 0.06*** – 0,47
–0,06 –0,02 –
Long–term
SSC 0.13*** 0.87*** 0.61*** 0.08*** 0,16 0,99
–0,04 –0,04 –0,16 –0,02 –0,85
PIT 0.14*** 0.90*** 0.14*** –3.62*** 0,99
–0,02 –0,04 –0,01 –0,32
CT 0.28** 0.65*** 0.38*** –1,30 0,98
–0,12 –0,15 –0,05 –1,00
PT 0.85*** –0,38 0,93
–0,05 –0,86
vAT 0.46*** 0.33*** 0,00 0,99
–0,04 –0,04 –3,95
CTT–SD 1.05*** –2.98*** 0,97
–0,04 –0,65
note: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%.
Figures 5 and 6 show the evolution of total revenue and unemployment expenditure, re-
spectively, both in terms of observed and structural values. In the case of revenue, different
long-term residential investment scenarios are presented. It can be seen that up to 2002 the
observed revenue did not differ significantly from the structural revenue as expected. How-
ever, from 2002 to 2008 the observed revenue exceeded all long-term residential investment
scenarios, peaking in 2007 with a difference of 3.3% of GDP compared with the average sce-
nario (6.5%). Since 2009, after the bubble burst, the observed value has returned to the struc-
tural one.
21Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
Regarding unemployment expenditures, the observed and the traditional structural ones
are very close to each other, given the small difference between the unemployment rate and
the nAWRU. On the contrary, our structural estimation presents lower values until 1998 and
higher values from that year on. The highest difference in comparison with the observed
value is 1.1% of GDP in 2006 and 2007. Since 2009, our estimation is lower again, given
that it does not take into account completely the extremely high unemployment rate of these
years and due to the reduction in the unitary benefits.
Finally, figure 7 shows the OBB, the SBB estimated by the EC and IMF, our own esti-
mate of the SBB for the average scenario (where the nominal GDP share of residential in-
vestment is 6.5%) and other estimates from earlier papers (Price and Dang, 2011; Morris and
Schuknetch, 2007). First, it can be seen that all the SBB are relatively similar until 1998.
From this year onwards, our own estimate starts to show a downward trend that dips more
sharply after 2001, while the remaining estimations maintain their upward trend for several
more years.
22 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Figure 5. Observed and structural revenue
(as a % of GDP and potential GDP)
Source: Own estimations and Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations.
With regard to the SBB estimated by the EC and IMF, it is interesting to note how sim-
ilar they are to the OBB, particularly in the case of EC estimates. IMF estimates differ to a
certain extent due to subsequent corrections, but the unrevised estimates are very similar to
those of the EC and the OBB. As discussed above, it is obvious that these indicators need to
be adjusted, since the advantage of a long-term indicator lies in its capacity to differ from
observed data in order to present an overview of the economy that is unaffected by circum-
stantial factors.
This is the aim of the articles written by Price and Dang (2011) and Morris and
Schuknetch (2007). To achieve this, both incorporated the price of financial and property as-
sets in their balance estimates. As indicated above, the methodology used is similar to that
used in this article. Total revenue is divided in different categories, for each category an error
correction model is developed that includes the tax base of the different taxes and the asset
price as explanatory variables. Price and Dang (2011) obtain the structural value of the fore-
going prices in two ways: one based on fundamentals, and the other by means of a Hodrick
23Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
Figure 6. Observed and structural unemployment expenditure
(as a % of GDP and potential GDP)
Source: Own estimations, Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations and European Commission.
and Prescott filter. Morris and Schuknetch (2007) only use the filter. Despite these changes,
it is interesting to note that their structural estimates do not differ to any great extent; at least
they are not capable of identifying fiscal difficulties in advance of observed balances.
The main advantage of the approach suggested here, therefore, is that it shows that long-
term public accounts had started to deteriorate in 1999, with a 3% potential GDP deficit by
2002, and below 4% from 2004 onwards. This would have identified Spanish potential fis-
cal troubles several years in advance, and measures could have been taken to correct them
in real time. The estimation is improved because the general methodology for all countries
is adapted to a particular case. The main feature of Spain over the period studied, as dis-
cussed above, is that the real estate bubble was accompanied by a construction boom, which
means that the process not only affected prices but also the number of units built, a factor
that was not taken into consideration in earlier papers. In other words, instead of discourag-
ing buyers, the rise in housing prices had the opposite effect due to the belief that the upward
trend would continue. This is why it was decided to include nominal residential investment
in our SBB calculation in order to capture the effect of both the prices and units built.
24 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Figure 7. Observed and structural budget balance
(as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively)
Source: Own estimations, Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations, EC, IMF and referred papers.
As a robustness check, we have estimated our model with data up to 2004 and 2007. We
obtain similar results and none of our conclusions are altered 15. The scenario after the crisis
may have changed. We were able to estimate a model with data up to 2004 and 2007 because
we had enough data. Unfortunately, we only have few observations after the crisis and it is
not possible to estimate a model with these few data. But, in any case, the current SBB esti-
mation is not the final word on the future outlook for public finances in Spain. In fact, the
lower growth rates that are foreseen for Spain in the next years should be taken into account
in future research.
5. Conclusions
This article attempts to make a contribution to understand the extremely deterioration in
the Spanish budget balance. This situation could not be anticipated by the SBB estimated by
the EC and the IMF, given that they showed a structural surplus until 2007. Based on these
figures, the Spanish authorities took a series of decisions to fight against the recession of
2008 on the assumption that public accounts were structurally sound and had a large enough
buffer to allow counter-cyclical policies to be implemented. However, it later became evi-
dent that the buffer was nowhere near as robust as expected, forcing them to withdraw tax
incentives before the private sector was ready to spearhead the aggregate demand.
Such situations might arise due to the failure to include the effect of bubbles in SBB cal-
culations. nevertheless, estimates carried out by other authors who did include such vari-
ables in their calculations were not capable of improved significantly Spanish SBB either, at
least not enough to identify the deterioration of the fiscal situation in time. The main reason
for this is that the studies were carried out for a group of countries or a particular region, and
as such the particular characteristics of each country are not factored in.
In this regard, Spain was in a unique situation because the real estate bubble affected not
only prices but also the number of units built, which means that including property prices as
the sole explanatory variable of tax revenue was not enough. In this article we have used
nominal residential investment as a way of including the number of units built too. It is in-
teresting to note that this type of investment has, historically, represented around 6.5% of
nominal GDP, but it reached 12.5% in the years leading up to the crisis.
The results obtained confirm how important residential investment was in Spanish tax
revenue, at least, until the bubble burst. Indeed, it can be seen that including this variable in
the equation, and assuming different scenarios concerning its long-term share in GDP, re-
veals that Spanish SBB started to show a strong deficit as far back as 2004. Taken this data
into consideration, different fiscal policy decisions would probably have been taken not only
from 2008 onwards, since the start of the crisis, but also in preceding years.
To conclude, it is essential to include bubbles and booms in SBB estimates. This is es-
pecially important in Spain, given that its fiscal rule is based on this indicator.
25Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
26 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Annex A
Serie Source
Observed budget balance
Total revenues
Social security contributions
Total expenditures
Unemployment benefits
Gross domestic product
Gross disposable corporate income
Gross disposable household income
Private consumption
Employment
Unemployment
Wages
Personal income tax
Corporate tax
Inheritance and gift tax
Wealth tax
value added tax
Capital transfer tax
Stamp duty
Real Property Tax
Motor vehicle Tax
Urban Land value Increase Tax
Tax on Economic Activities
Tax on Building, Installations and
other Work
Local rates
Structural budget balance
Potential GDP
Structural revenues
Structural expenditures
nAWRU
Residential investment
Housing prices
Average personal income tax rate
Average corporate tax rate
Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas
de España
http://www.sepg.pap.minhap.gob.es/sitios/sepg/es-ES/Presu-
puestos/Documentacion/paginas/bdmacro.aspx
Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas
de España
http://www.minhap.gob.es/es-ES/Estadistica%20e%20Infor-
mes/Impuestos/Paginas/Impuestos.aspx
Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas
de España
http://serviciosweb.meh.es/apps/EntidadesLocales/
European Commission
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/Se-
lectSerie.cfm
International Monetary Fund
http://www.imf.org/external/ns/cs.aspx?id=28
European Commission
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/Se-
lectSerie.cfm
European Commission
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/s
earch_database
European Central Bank
http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/browse.do?node=2120781
OECD
http://stats.oecd.org/
27Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
AnnexB
TableB.1
UNITROOTTESTS(Dickey-Fullercriticalvalues,1981)
LevelsFirstDifferencesSeconddifferences
Variable
Nointercept,Withintercept,Withintercept,Nointercept,Withintercept,Nointercept,
notrendnotrendandtrendnotrendnotrendnotrend
“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value
Socialsecuritycontributions0,2770,757–0,7770,807–2,5250,314–1,1570,218–1,8260,359–4,6650,000
Personalincometax3,7771,0002,1441,000–0,9670,9250,5130,817–4,2660,003––
Corporatetax–0,3180,560–1,3990,566–1,7320,697–3,5340,001–2,0340,271––
Propertytax–0,2400,589–1,4840,524–2,8840,185–4,6110,000–4,5700,002––
valueaddedtax0,9580,905–1,0110,732–2,8500,197–4,0010,000–4,0080,007––
Capitaltransfertaxand
stampduty–0,8680,329–1,8810,335–0,7340,956–2,6240,011–3,1880,035––
Regionalgovernmentrevenue3,9401,0003,6221,0001,3661,000–0,6840,408–2,0410,268–5,2650,000
Residentialinvestment3,3400,9991,9421,000–0,5740,971–1,3450,160–4,2650,003––
Wage1,1650,932–1,0450,718–3,2090,114–0,7010,401–3,4930,018––
Employed1,5800,968–1,3800,574–2,8690,190–1,7940,070–2,7210,087––
Unemploymentbenefits3,1200,9992,0781,0000,7550,999–2,4700,016–2,7980,074––
Consumption2,7070,9972,0581,000–2,0310,555–1,4190,141–3,2460,030––
Householdincome21,1201,0006,4911,0002,6591,000–0,9220,306–1,0520,713–5,9630,000
Corporateincome3,3390,9990,6270,987–2,0000,566–2,1640,032–3,9220,008––
PITrate0,5340,824–1,6940,421–2,1580,489–6,2630,000–6,0740,000––
CTrate–0,4220,520–1,7720,385–2,7600,225–4,0050,000–3,9030,007––
28 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Table B.2
UNIT ROOT TESTS OF THE RESIDUALS OF LONG-TERM EQUATIONS
(MacKinnon critical values, 1991)
“t” statistic
Critical values
a = 0,05 a = 0,1
Social security contributions –4,759 –4,998 –4,567
Personal income tax –4,980 –4,564 –4,152
Corporate tax –4,562 –4,564 –4,152
Property tax –4,218 –3,591 –3,218
value added tax –5,357 –4,098 –3,706
Capital transfer tax and stamp duty –3,363 –3,591 –3,218
Regional government revenue –1,920 –3,591 –3,218
Table B.3
AUTOCORRELATIONS OF THE FIRST TWO LAGS AND p-values
ASSOCIATED TO THE LJUNG-BOX STATISTICS (1978) FOR THE RESIDUAL
OF THE LONG- AND SHORT- TERM EQUATIONS
Equation Lags
Long term Short term
Auto
P-value
Auto
P-value
correlations correlations
Social security contributions 1 –0,021 0,913 –0,042 0,827
2 –0,062 0,939 –0,082 0,887
Personal income tax 1 –0,036 0,847 0,223 0,245
2 –0,007 0,981 0,087 0,457
Corporate tax 1 0,401 0,040 –0,022 0,911
2 –0,228 0,060 –0,147 0,747
Property tax 1 0,126 0,504 –0,029 0,879
2 0,266 0,284 0,245 0,422
value added tax 1 0,070 0,709 0,107 0,577
2 –0,231 0,426 –0,076 0,788
Capital transfer tax and stamp duty 1 0,355 0,060 0,073 0,704
2 –0,142 0,126 –0,282 0,301
Regional government revenue 1 – – 0,137 0,476
2 – – –0,095 0,682
Notes
1. Alternative SBB estimations, which are analyzed afterwards (Price and Dang, 2011; Morris and Schuknetch,
2007), also showed a surplus in the years prior to the crisis (see figure 7).
2. For an analysis of the changes introduced, the rationale and shortcomings of the new budgetary stability law
see Hernández de Cos and Pérez (2013).
3. According to Stiglitz (1990) a bubble exists when the price of an asset grows only because investors believe
it will continue to increase in the future, although fundamental factors do not justify this belief.
4. While the OG is an essential driver of the SBB, its estimation remains outside the scope of this paper. For the
OG estimation, see Denis et al. (2006) and D’Auria et al. (2010).
5. This real-time bias in the admissible deficit would be added to another bias identified by de Castro et al.
(2013), related to political issues such as unfavorable economic conditions or elections.
6. For example, if a financial or real estate bubble raises the price of assets, it would affect certain tax bases, but
not the OG, affecting the elasticities (Joumard and André, 2008).
7. This category is the sum of Real Property Tax (Impuesto sobre bienes inmuebles, or “IBI”), Motor vehicle
Tax (Impuesto sobre vehículos tracción mecánica, or “IvTM”), Urban Land value Increase Tax (Impuesto
sobre incremento valor terrenos naturaleza urbana, or “IIvTnU”), Tax on Economic Activities (Impuesto
sobre actividades económicas, or “IAE”), Tax on Building, Installations and other Work (Impuesto sobre con-
strucciones, instalaciones y obras, or “ICIO”), and local rates.
8. RatePIT and RateCT are calculated by the OECD as the ratio between the personal income tax and the corpo-
rate tax revenues, respectably, and the GDP. Therefore, these are not statutory rates.
9. Equations (1) and (2) should take on board legislation changes in order for β and γ to be interpreted as proper
tax elasticities in the sense in which the literature uses them. As we focus on the fit of the equations, we use
these coefficients as proxies of the real elasticities.
10. The choice of the value of the parameter is discussed in Bouthevillain et al. (2001).
11. In the pre-bubble two decades (between 1980 and 2000), residential investment had never been less than 5%
or more than 8% of GDP.
12. Results are not significantly modified when different moving averages are used.
13. Results are available upon request.
14. We attempted to include lagged variables in short-term equations, but none were significant. This was expect-
ed since annual data are used. Thus, only contemporary dynamics are shown.
15. We thank both anonymous referees for suggesting this robustness check.
References
Blanchard, O. J. (1990), “Suggestions for a new set of fiscal indicators”, OECD Department of Eco-
nomics and Statistics Working Papers, 79.
Bouthevillain, C.; Cour-Thimann, P.; van den Dool, G.; Hernández de Cos, P.; Langenus, G.; Mohr,
M.; Momigliano, S. and Tujula, M. (2001), “Cyclically adjusted budget balances: an alternative ap-
proach”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 77.
Cimadomo, J. (2008), “Fiscal policy in real time”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 919.
D’Auria, F.; Denis, C.; Havik, K.; Mc Morrow, K.; Planas, C.; Raciborski, R.; Röger, W. and Rossi,
A. (2010), “The production function methodology for calculating potential growth rates and output
gaps”, European Commission Economic Papers, 420.
de Castro Fernández, F.; Estrada García, A.; Hernández de Cos, P. and Martí Esteve, F. (2008), “Una
aproximación al componente transitorio del saldo público en España”, Boletín Económico del Banco
de España, 6: 71-81.
29Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
de Castro, F.; Pérez, J. and Rodríguez-vives, M. (2013), “Fiscal Data Revisions in Europe”, Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, 45 (6): 1187-1209.
Denis, C.; Grenouilleau, D.; Mc Morrow, K. and Röger, W. (2006), “Calculating potential growth rates
and output gaps – A revised production function approach”, European Commission Economic Pa-
pers, 247.
Dickey, D. A. and Fuller, W. A. (1981), “Likehood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with
a unit root”, Econometrica, 49 (4): 1057-1072.
European Commission (2007), “Public finances in EMU 2007”, European Economy, 3.
European Commission (2013), “Report on Public finances in EMU 2013”, European Economy, 4.
Forni, L. and Momigliano, S. (2004), “Cyclical sensitivity of fiscal policies based on real-time data”,
MPRA Paper, 4315.
García Montalvo, J. (2003), “La vivienda en España: desgravaciones, burbujas y otras historias”, Fun-
dación de las Cajas de Ahorro (FUNCAS), Perspectivas del Sistema Financiero, 78.
Girouard, n. and André, C. (2005), “Measuring Cyclically-adjusted Budget Balances for OECD Coun-
tries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 434.
Girouard, n. and Price, R. (2004), “Asset Price Cycles, ´One-Off´ Factors and Structural Budget Bal-
ances”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 391.
Golinelli, R. and Momigliano, S. (2007), “The Cyclical Response of Fiscal Policies in the Euro Area -
Why Do Results of Empirical Research Differ so Strongly?”, Banca d`Italia Working Papers, 654.
Hagemann, R. (1999), “The Structural Budget Balance. The IMF´s Methodology”, IMF Working
Paper, 95.
Hernández de Cos, P. and Pérez, J. (2013), “The new budgetary stability law”, Bank of Spain Econom-
ic bulletin, April: 13-25.
Joumard, I. and André, C. (2008), “Revenue Buoyancy and its Fiscal Policy Implications”, OECD Eco-
nomics Department Working Papers, 598.
Kempkes, G. (2012), “Cyclical adjustment in fiscal rules: some evidence on real-time bias for EU-15
countries”, Discussion Paper Deutsche Bundesbank, 15.
Kremer, J.; Rodrigues Braz, C.; Brosens, T.; Langenus, G.; Momigliano, S. and Spolander, M. (2006),
“A Disaggregated Framework for the Analysis of Structural Developments in Public Finances”, Eu-
ropean Central Bank Working Paper Series, 579.
Larch, M. and Turrini, A. (2009), “The cyclically-adjusted budget balance in EU fiscal policy making:
A love at first sight turned into a mature relationship”, European Commission Economic Papers, 374.
Ljung, G. M. and Box, G. E. P. (1978), “On a Measure of a Lack of Fit in Time Series Models”, Bio-
metrika, 65(2): 297-303.
MacKinnon, J. G. (1991), “Critical values for Cointegration Tests”, in R. F. Engel and C. W. I.
Granger (eds.), Long Run Economic Relationship, Oxford University Press, 267-76.
Mc Morrow, K. and Roeger, W. (2000), “Time –varying nairu / nawru Estimates for the EU’s Mem-
ber States”, Economic and Financial Affairs (ECFIN) of the European Commission, 145.
30 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
Morris, R. and Schuknecht, L. (2007), “Structural balances and revenue windfalls. The role of asset
prices revisited”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 737.
Morris, R.; Rodrigues Braz, C.; de Castro, F.; Jonk, S.; Kremer, J.; Linehan, S.; Marino, M.; Schalck,
C. and Tkacevs, O (2009), “Explaining government revenue windfalls and shortfalls: an analysis for
selected EU countries”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 1114.
Mourre, G.; Isbasoiu, G.; Paternoster, D. and Salto, M. (2013), “The cyclically-adjusted budget bal-
ance used in the EU fiscal framework: an update”, European Economy Economic Papers, 478.
Price, R. and Dang, T. (2011), “Adjusting fiscal balances for asset prices cycles”, OECD Economics
Department Working Paper, 868.
REAF (Registro de Economistas Asesores Fiscales) (2007), “Costes asociados a la adquisición, uso y
alquiler de viviendas”. http://www.unionprofesional.com/index.php/unionprofesional/sala_prensa/noti-
cias_colegiales/economia_sociedad/costes_fiscales_asociados_a_la_adquisicion_uso_y_alquiler_de_vi
viendas_segun_un_estudio_del_reaf
Stiglitz, J. (1990), “Symposium on Bubbles”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2): 13-18.
Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (1993), “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating vectors in Higher Order
Integrated Systems”, Econometrica, 61(4): 783-820.
Resumen
La recesión iniciada en 2008 generó un fuerte deterioro del resultado fiscal de España. Este deterioro
no fue completamente anticipado por el resultado fiscal estructural debido a ciertas limitaciones meto-
dológicas. En este artículo se calcula un resultado estructural alternativo para España durante los años
previos a la crisis subprime, que incluye la inversión en vivienda como variable explicativa. Esta esti-
mación muestra que desde 2004 la situación fiscal española no era tan sólida como se creía y que la
fragilidad estuvo oculta gracias a los recursos extraordinarios resultantes de la burbuja inmobiliaria y
del boom en la construcción.
Palabras clave: crisis, resultado fiscal estructural, burbuja inmobiliaria, boom de la construcción, Es-
paña.
Clasificación JEL: C20, E32, E63, H62.
31Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
"Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain"; Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra, Daniel Sotelsek

More Related Content

What's hot

Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approach
Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approachSpain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approach
Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approachwiljohanne
 
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016 REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016 ESADE
 
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...Massimo Resce
 
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013Frank Ragol
 
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazil
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazilPec 241 threatening the development of brazil
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazilFernando Alcoforado
 
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must Read
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must ReadGerman rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must Read
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must ReadIra Kristina Lumban Tobing
 
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013JLL France
 
Informe País España (country report spain)
Informe País España (country report spain)Informe País España (country report spain)
Informe País España (country report spain)Ignacio Jimenez
 
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity Measure
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity MeasureStudy of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity Measure
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity MeasureErick Prajogo
 
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)ESADE
 
España revision de la ue
España revision de la ueEspaña revision de la ue
España revision de la ueManfredNolte
 
The economic fiasco of temer government
The economic fiasco of temer governmentThe economic fiasco of temer government
The economic fiasco of temer governmentFernando Alcoforado
 
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)Círculo de Empresarios
 
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosAsí está the economy march 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosCírculo de Empresarios
 
France faces fiscal balancing act
France faces fiscal balancing act France faces fiscal balancing act
France faces fiscal balancing act Markit
 
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo Back
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo BackEuro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo Back
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo BackAmir Khan
 
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010EMEA Economic Insight November 2010
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010Manpower EMEA
 
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...Dr. Ivo Pezzuto
 

What's hot (20)

Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approach
Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approachSpain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approach
Spain’s disappearing economy demands a bold new approach
 
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016 REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016
REPORT - ESADE TARGET 2016
 
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...
Productivity and wages, dynamics in the euro-system and the role of two-tier ...
 
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013
Enthe case-for-spain-ii-arcano-oct-2013
 
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazil
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazilPec 241 threatening the development of brazil
Pec 241 threatening the development of brazil
 
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must Read
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must ReadGerman rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must Read
German rebalancing: Waiting for GODOT? *Another Must Read
 
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013
The Paris office market overview & forecast 2013
 
Economy... at a glance January 2019
Economy... at a glance January 2019 Economy... at a glance January 2019
Economy... at a glance January 2019
 
Informe País España (country report spain)
Informe País España (country report spain)Informe País España (country report spain)
Informe País España (country report spain)
 
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity Measure
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity MeasureStudy of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity Measure
Study of Spain Global Crisis and Austeriity Measure
 
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)
REPORT: Diana ESADE 2014 (eng)
 
Research - debt crisis
Research - debt crisis Research - debt crisis
Research - debt crisis
 
España revision de la ue
España revision de la ueEspaña revision de la ue
España revision de la ue
 
The economic fiasco of temer government
The economic fiasco of temer governmentThe economic fiasco of temer government
The economic fiasco of temer government
 
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)
Así está the economy (may 2015 Círculo de Empresarios)
 
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosAsí está the economy march 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Así está the economy march 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
 
France faces fiscal balancing act
France faces fiscal balancing act France faces fiscal balancing act
France faces fiscal balancing act
 
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo Back
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo BackEuro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo Back
Euro Area & Global Economy - Getting its Mojo Back
 
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010EMEA Economic Insight November 2010
EMEA Economic Insight November 2010
 
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...
Ivo Pezzuto on the EU integration Process: "More Catalonias to Come. Spain a ...
 

Viewers also liked

The perfect Hedger and the Fox
The perfect Hedger and the FoxThe perfect Hedger and the Fox
The perfect Hedger and the FoxAntonie Kotzé
 
Cloud Security 2014 AASNET
Cloud Security 2014 AASNETCloud Security 2014 AASNET
Cloud Security 2014 AASNETFarrukh Shahzad
 
WordCamp Tokyo2012 Session
WordCamp Tokyo2012 SessionWordCamp Tokyo2012 Session
WordCamp Tokyo2012 Sessionregret raym
 
Polymer入門
Polymer入門 Polymer入門
Polymer入門 Y OCHI
 
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DM
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DMEnhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DM
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DMPlus Technologies
 
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012giorgiocorradi
 
Farsi in quattro n 15 marzo 2012
Farsi in quattro n 15   marzo 2012Farsi in quattro n 15   marzo 2012
Farsi in quattro n 15 marzo 2012giorgiocorradi
 
Css拡張言語のコトハジメ
Css拡張言語のコトハジメCss拡張言語のコトハジメ
Css拡張言語のコトハジメregret raym
 
Available Output Management Support in Germany
Available Output Management Support in GermanyAvailable Output Management Support in Germany
Available Output Management Support in GermanyPlus Technologies
 
Dollars and sense part, pitfalls and purpose of finances
Dollars and sense  part, pitfalls and purpose of financesDollars and sense  part, pitfalls and purpose of finances
Dollars and sense part, pitfalls and purpose of financesRoger Hernandez
 
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!Sandra Braconnot
 
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...innovatiecentra
 
Web制作のアレコレ
Web制作のアレコレWeb制作のアレコレ
Web制作のアレコレregret raym
 
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracer
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracerPpp raymond vanstraelen bioracer
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracerinnovatiecentra
 

Viewers also liked (20)

The perfect Hedger and the Fox
The perfect Hedger and the FoxThe perfect Hedger and the Fox
The perfect Hedger and the Fox
 
Cloud Security 2014 AASNET
Cloud Security 2014 AASNETCloud Security 2014 AASNET
Cloud Security 2014 AASNET
 
WordCamp Tokyo2012 Session
WordCamp Tokyo2012 SessionWordCamp Tokyo2012 Session
WordCamp Tokyo2012 Session
 
Bản tin Hoa Sen
Bản tin Hoa Sen Bản tin Hoa Sen
Bản tin Hoa Sen
 
Polymer入門
Polymer入門 Polymer入門
Polymer入門
 
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DM
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DMEnhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DM
Enhancing Functionality on Epic OMS: New Features for OM Plus DM
 
Au Psy492 M7 A2 Jones K
Au Psy492 M7 A2 Jones KAu Psy492 M7 A2 Jones K
Au Psy492 M7 A2 Jones K
 
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012
Farsi in Quattro N 16, Aprile 2012
 
Farsi in quattro n 15 marzo 2012
Farsi in quattro n 15   marzo 2012Farsi in quattro n 15   marzo 2012
Farsi in quattro n 15 marzo 2012
 
Css拡張言語のコトハジメ
Css拡張言語のコトハジメCss拡張言語のコトハジメ
Css拡張言語のコトハジメ
 
materi PSSITI
materi PSSITI materi PSSITI
materi PSSITI
 
Why Is Tympanometry Performed?
Why Is Tympanometry Performed?Why Is Tympanometry Performed?
Why Is Tympanometry Performed?
 
Available Output Management Support in Germany
Available Output Management Support in GermanyAvailable Output Management Support in Germany
Available Output Management Support in Germany
 
Dollars and sense part, pitfalls and purpose of finances
Dollars and sense  part, pitfalls and purpose of financesDollars and sense  part, pitfalls and purpose of finances
Dollars and sense part, pitfalls and purpose of finances
 
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!
Toda pessoa é uma flor... só varia o tipo!
 
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...
Innovatiesubsidies voor bedrijven + rol van het innovatiecentrum bij subsidie...
 
Vw revista
Vw revistaVw revista
Vw revista
 
Web制作のアレコレ
Web制作のアレコレWeb制作のアレコレ
Web制作のアレコレ
 
Eyes wide open
Eyes wide openEyes wide open
Eyes wide open
 
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracer
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracerPpp raymond vanstraelen bioracer
Ppp raymond vanstraelen bioracer
 

Similar to "Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain"; Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra, Daniel Sotelsek

Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...Grupo de Economia Política IE-UFRJ
 
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009Eusebi Carles Pastor
 
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londr
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En LondrPresentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londr
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londrricard santamaria
 
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate Market
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate MarketDeloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate Market
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate MarketRoger Blikkberget
 
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015Jaime Cubillo Fleming
 
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for Economic Environment of Business
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for  Economic Environment of Business Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for  Economic Environment of Business
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for Economic Environment of Business Renzil D'cruz
 
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosAsi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosCírculo de Empresarios
 
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018Miguel Sánchez de Pedro
 
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?Amir Khan
 
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda española
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda españolaNuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda española
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda españolaManfredNolte
 
Investment opportunities in new catalan state update
Investment opportunities in new catalan state   updateInvestment opportunities in new catalan state   update
Investment opportunities in new catalan state updateAlbert Macià Vivó
 
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...British Chamber of Commerce in Spain
 
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docx
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docxRunning Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docx
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docxwlynn1
 
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...Círculo de Empresarios
 

Similar to "Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain"; Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra, Daniel Sotelsek (20)

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENTCOMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
 
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
 
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009
Savills - Office Market Report - Barcelona - Spring 2009
 
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londr
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En LondrPresentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londr
Presentacion Del Secretario De Estado En Londr
 
9063081BMAN24091
9063081BMAN240919063081BMAN24091
9063081BMAN24091
 
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate Market
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate MarketDeloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate Market
Deloitte: Spotlight on the Spanish Real Estate Market
 
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015
COFACE Insolvencias en Europa Occidental Septiembre 2015
 
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for Economic Environment of Business
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for  Economic Environment of Business Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for  Economic Environment of Business
Project on Greece Crisis and Impact for Economic Environment of Business
 
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de EmpresariosAsi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Asi está the economy july 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
 
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018
Spain fiscal outlook cayman financialreview-19082018
 
J.P. Morgan - "Spain is back"
J.P. Morgan - "Spain is back"J.P. Morgan - "Spain is back"
J.P. Morgan - "Spain is back"
 
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?
Germany - Towards a New Growth Model?
 
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda española
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda españolaNuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda española
Nuevo rating (BBB-) de la deuda española
 
dcp171776_420406
dcp171776_420406dcp171776_420406
dcp171776_420406
 
Investment opportunities in new catalan state update
Investment opportunities in new catalan state   updateInvestment opportunities in new catalan state   update
Investment opportunities in new catalan state update
 
Euro area contries
Euro area contriesEuro area contries
Euro area contries
 
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...
Executive summary. Barometer on climate and outlook for British investment in...
 
Spain economic recovery
Spain economic recoverySpain economic recovery
Spain economic recovery
 
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docx
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docxRunning Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docx
Running Head GLOBAL ECONOMICS1GLOBAL ECONOMICS 7.docx
 
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...
2016 General State Budget: possible but we need more reforms to strengthen gr...
 

More from Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)

Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...
Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...
Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambientalEconomía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambientalInvestigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad AmbientalEconomía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad AmbientalInvestigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH)
 

More from Investigador Principal (IELAT_UAH) (20)

Presentation cepal 2018
Presentation cepal 2018Presentation cepal 2018
Presentation cepal 2018
 
Conferencia Universidad de Anahuac 2020
Conferencia Universidad de Anahuac 2020Conferencia Universidad de Anahuac 2020
Conferencia Universidad de Anahuac 2020
 
A. infraestructura y medio ambiente
A. infraestructura y medio ambienteA. infraestructura y medio ambiente
A. infraestructura y medio ambiente
 
Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...
Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...
Economía Social: Nuevos desafíos en economía colaborativa y reglas de juego d...
 
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...
Desarrollo del Mercado de Valores y Crecimiento Económico: ¿Existe una Relaci...
 
Reflexiones en torno al Microcrédito y las Microfinanzas
Reflexiones en torno al Microcrédito y las MicrofinanzasReflexiones en torno al Microcrédito y las Microfinanzas
Reflexiones en torno al Microcrédito y las Microfinanzas
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambientalEconomía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 10 | Subdesarrollo y degradación ambiental
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 9 | Empresa y Medio Ambiente
Economía Ambiental | Tema 9 | Empresa y Medio AmbienteEconomía Ambiental | Tema 9 | Empresa y Medio Ambiente
Economía Ambiental | Tema 9 | Empresa y Medio Ambiente
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 7 | Política Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 7 | Política AmbientalEconomía Ambiental | Tema 7 | Política Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 7 | Política Ambiental
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad AmbientalEconomía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad Ambiental
Economía Ambiental | Tema 6 | Indicadores Ambientales. Contabilidad Ambiental
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Segunda Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Aná...
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 5 | (Primera Parte) Evaluación de Proyectos: El Des...
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 4 | Valoración Monetaria
Economía Ambiental | Tema 4 | Valoración Monetaria Economía Ambiental | Tema 4 | Valoración Monetaria
Economía Ambiental | Tema 4 | Valoración Monetaria
 
Economía ambiental | Tema 3 | El valor del medio ambiente
Economía ambiental | Tema 3 | El valor del medio ambienteEconomía ambiental | Tema 3 | El valor del medio ambiente
Economía ambiental | Tema 3 | El valor del medio ambiente
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...
Economía Ambiental | Tema 2 | El Problema Ambiental desde un punto de vista e...
 
Economía Ambiental | Tema 1 | 2014-15
Economía Ambiental | Tema 1 | 2014-15Economía Ambiental | Tema 1 | 2014-15
Economía Ambiental | Tema 1 | 2014-15
 
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...
Value chain and technical efficiency: an empirical analysis in the Eastern Eu...
 
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...
Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence Fr...
 
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...
The Effect of Poverty, Gender Exclusion, and Child Labor on Out-of-School Rat...
 
De la burbuja inmobiliaria a la burbuja fiscal
De la burbuja inmobiliaria a la burbuja fiscalDe la burbuja inmobiliaria a la burbuja fiscal
De la burbuja inmobiliaria a la burbuja fiscal
 

Recently uploaded

Financial analysis on Risk and Return.ppt
Financial analysis on Risk and Return.pptFinancial analysis on Risk and Return.ppt
Financial analysis on Risk and Return.ppttadegebreyesus
 
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.ppt
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.pptAnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.ppt
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.pptPriyankaSharma89719
 
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptx
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptxIntroduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptx
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptxDrRkurinjiMalarkurin
 
Gender and caste discrimination in india
Gender and caste discrimination in indiaGender and caste discrimination in india
Gender and caste discrimination in indiavandanasingh01072003
 
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书rnrncn29
 
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024Money Forward
 
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdf
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdfThe top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdf
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdfJhon Thompson
 
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...Amil baba
 
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...Amil baba
 
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...Amil baba
 
Hello this ppt is about seminar final project
Hello this ppt is about seminar final projectHello this ppt is about seminar final project
Hello this ppt is about seminar final projectninnasirsi
 
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptx
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptxFinancial Preparation for Millennia.pptx
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptxsimon978302
 
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdf
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdfKempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdf
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdfHenry Tapper
 
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consulting
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride ConsultingGlobal Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consulting
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consultingswastiknandyofficial
 
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdfglobusfinanza
 
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...Amil baba
 
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...beulahfernandes8
 
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024prajwalgopocket
 
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...Amil baba
 
Liquidity Decisions in Financial management
Liquidity Decisions in Financial managementLiquidity Decisions in Financial management
Liquidity Decisions in Financial managementshrutisingh143670
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Financial analysis on Risk and Return.ppt
Financial analysis on Risk and Return.pptFinancial analysis on Risk and Return.ppt
Financial analysis on Risk and Return.ppt
 
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.ppt
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.pptAnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.ppt
AnyConv.com__FSS Advance Retail & Distribution - 15.06.17.ppt
 
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptx
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptxIntroduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptx
Introduction to Health Economics Dr. R. Kurinji Malar.pptx
 
Gender and caste discrimination in india
Gender and caste discrimination in indiaGender and caste discrimination in india
Gender and caste discrimination in india
 
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书
『澳洲文凭』买科廷大学毕业证书成绩单办理澳洲Curtin文凭学位证书
 
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024
Money Forward Integrated Report “Forward Map” 2024
 
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdf
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdfThe top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdf
The top 4 AI cryptocurrencies to know in 2024 .pdf
 
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...
Uae-NO1 Rohani Amil In Islamabad Amil Baba in Rawalpindi Kala Jadu Amil In Ra...
 
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...
Uae-NO1 Pakistani Amil Baba Real Amil baba In Pakistan Najoomi Baba in Pakist...
 
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...
NO1 Certified Black Magic Specialist Expert In Bahawalpur, Sargodha, Sialkot,...
 
Hello this ppt is about seminar final project
Hello this ppt is about seminar final projectHello this ppt is about seminar final project
Hello this ppt is about seminar final project
 
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptx
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptxFinancial Preparation for Millennia.pptx
Financial Preparation for Millennia.pptx
 
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdf
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdfKempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdf
Kempen ' UK DB Endgame Paper Apr 24 final3.pdf
 
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consulting
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride ConsultingGlobal Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consulting
Global Economic Outlook, 2024 - Scholaride Consulting
 
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf
10 QuickBooks Tips 2024 - Globus Finanza.pdf
 
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
Uae-NO1 Black Magic Specialist In Lahore Black magic In Pakistan Kala Ilam Ex...
 
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...
Unveiling Poonawalla Fincorp’s Phenomenal Performance Under Abhay Bhutada’s L...
 
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024
What is sip and What are its Benefits in 2024
 
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...
NO1 Certified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale bab...
 
Liquidity Decisions in Financial management
Liquidity Decisions in Financial managementLiquidity Decisions in Financial management
Liquidity Decisions in Financial management
 

"Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain"; Guido Zack, Pilar Poncela, Eva Senra, Daniel Sotelsek

  • 1. Some New Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain GUIDO ZACK* Alcalá University PILAR POnCELA** Universidad Autónoma de Madrid EvA SEnRA Alcalá University DAnIEL SOTELSEK*** Alcalá University Received: April, 2014 Accepted: July, 2014 Summary The recession that started in 2008 caused a sharp deterioration of the budget balance of Spain. This de- cline was not fully anticipated by the structural budget balance due to some methodology limitations. In this article, we calculate an alternative structural balance for Spain in the years prior to the subprime crisis that includes residential investment as an explanatory variable. This estimate shows that by 2004 the Spanish fiscal situation was not as strong as presumed. This fragility was hidden by the extraordi- nary revenue from the real estate bubble and the construction boom. Keywords: Crisis, structural budget balance, real estate bubble, construction boom, Spain. JEL Classification: C20, E32, E63, H62. 1. Introduction Until 2006 Spain seemed to have one of the most countercyclical fiscal policies in Eu- rope. In fact, the observed budget balance (OBB) improved from a deficit of 6.5% of GDP in 1995 to a surplus of 2% in 2006. nevertheless, the crisis revealed the fragility of this improve- ment, since between 2007 and 2009 the OBB fell by 13 percentage points (p.p.) of GDP. * Guido Zack acknowledges the support of the Institute of Latin American Studies (IELAT), Alcalá Universtity. ** Pilar Poncela acknowledges financial support from the Spanish government, Ministerio de Economía y Compet- itividad, contract grant ECO2012–32854. *** Daniel Sotelsek acknowledges the support of SIPA-ILAS (Columbia University), during his 2013–2014 visit- ing scholar. Hacienda Pública Española / Review of Public Economics, 210-(3/2014): 11-31 © 2014, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales DOI: 10.7866/HPE-RPE.14.3.1
  • 2. This strong fall is also shown in the structural budget balance (SBB), however neither the consolidation until 2006 nor the deterioration between 2007 and 2009 can be explained only by discretionary measures. Situations like that not only happened in Spain, but they have been occurring in several countries (Larch and Turrini, 2009). Thus, since 2000 there are several proposals to improve the SBB. The main objective of this paper is to adapt some of these proposals to the Spanish case in the years prior to the subprime crisis. In particular, the fiscal impact of the real estate bub- ble and the boom in the construction industry are incorporated, showing that the SBB is not capable to identify completely the cycle effect on the budget balance. The improvement of the SBB methodology is essential in Spain, given that its new budgetary stability law is based on this indicator. The article is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the evolution of the Spanish budget within the European context, identifying a particularly volatile observed and struc- tural budget balanced trend. This would have been a reflection of the volatile evolution of residential investment. The SBB was not able to identify the transitory component of the rev- enue and expenditure. Consequently, in the third section, several improvements of the SBB traditional methodology proposed by the literature are reviewed. The fourth section adapts some of these improvements to the particular case of Spain and shows the results obtained. Finally, conclusions and policy recommendations are presented in section 5. 2. Descriptive analysis of the case of Spain within the European context 2.1. Evolution of public accounts During the 90s, the budgetary policy in Eurozone countries was dominated by compli- ance with the Stability and Growth Pact, which established limits on both government deficit and public debt (3% and 60% of GDP, respectively). In this context, Spain seemed to pio- neer a counter-cyclical policy. As shown in figure 1, the country progressed from a chroni- cally high fiscal deficit in the first half of the 90s to a moderate deficit by the end of the decade, and finally achieved a surplus of 2% of GDP in the years leading up to the reces- sion. nevertheless, Spanish apparent solvency disappeared with the subprime crisis. Al- though the recession punished the budgets of all European countries, Spain was particularly affected. Indeed, between 2007 and 2009 the balance fell from a surplus of 1.9% of GDP to a deficit of 11.1%, a decline of 13 p.p. in just two years, when the European Union average (15 countries) fell only by 6 p.p. Spanish fiscal decline was the result of the evolution of both expenditure and revenue. The weight of expenditure in the GDP increased by 7 p.p. due to the combined effect of dis- cretionary policies aimed at maintaining aggregate demand and automatic stabilisers in the form of unemployment benefits. Revenue, meanwhile, fell by 6 p.p. of GDP, from slightly more than 41% in 2007 to less than 35% in 2009, the lowest of all Eurozone countries. As 12 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
  • 3. 13Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain Figure 1. Observed and structural budget balance (as a % of GDP and potential GDP) Source: European Commission. shown figure 2, the main reason for this was the loss of revenue from corporate tax (2.4 p.p.), added value tax (2.3 p.p.), personal income tax (0.9 p.p.) and capital transfer tax and stamp duty (0.9 p.p.). The evolution of Spanish SBB in these years did not differ substantially from the OBB. Indeed, from the mid-90s the SBB also showed a process of fiscal consolidation, reaching a surplus of 1% of potential GDP in 2006 1. When the subprime crisis hit the market, the SBB returned to negative figures, with a deficit of 8.6% of potential GDP in 2009 (figure 1). This shortfall in the Spanish SBB was not seen in other European countries. Thus, it is essential to ascertain what was different in Spain, moreover considering that its new budg- etary stability law included in the Spanish Constitution is based on this indicator 2. The an- swer can be found in the collapse of residential investment, since most revenues were direct- ly and indirectly linked to the construction industry, while this sector was mainly responsible for the loss of employment and, therefore, the increase in related expenditure (REAF, 2007).
  • 4. 2.2. Evolution of residential investment In the years leading up to the 2007 crisis, housing prices rose sharply across most Euro- pean countries, particularly in the UK and Spain, where they increased threefold, and to a lesser extent in other countries such as France, Italy and Portugal (figure 3). Although price variations in Spain were among the greatest, this would not seem enough to explain the no- table difference in public accounts. The greatest difference is found in the number of units built: while the GDP share of res- idential investment remained either steady or even declined in most EU countries, in Spain it rose sharply until 2006 (figure 4). This is because the increase in housing prices, instead of discouraging buyers fearful of a reversal of the trend, had the opposite effect based on the belief that prices would continue to raise, a clear indication of the creation of a bubble 3 (Gar- cía Montalvo, 2003). 14 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Figure 2. Spanish government revenue and expenditure (as a % of GDP) Source: Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations.
  • 5. Accordingly, residential investment in Spain grew at an average rate of 8% per year in real terms over the 1998-2007 period, twice the rate of the economy as a whole and accounting for one fifth of the rise in GDP. Thus, by 2006 it accounted for 12.5% of nominal GDP in Spain, when historically it had stood between 5% and 8%. In the labour market, the construction sector accounted for 13.5% of all jobs in Spain, and nearly a quarter of the growth in employment over the same period. When the bubble burst, residential investment shrank to 4.4% of nominal GDP in 2013, while the con- struction sector was directly responsible for the loss of 60% of the jobs between 2007 and 2011. To sum up, the evolution of the construction sector and the housing market, not only in terms of prices but also in the number of units built, could be responsible for the volatility of Spanish public accounts. 15Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain Figure 3. Housing prices in Europe (1996=100) Source: European Central Bank.
  • 6. 3. SBB traditional methodology limitations The SBB is estimated by the European Commission (EC) and the International Mone- tary Fund (IMF). Both organisations base their calculation on the cyclical position of the economy, i.e., the output gap (OG), and on the relationship between the cycle and the differ- ent balance components (revenue and expenditure) 4. The cycle is linked to the budget through the elasticities between the main revenue items (direct taxation of individuals and companies, indirect taxes and social security contributions) and the OG, while in terms of expenditure, only unemployment expenditures are considered cyclical. Then, the structural components are calculated by multiplying the observed revenue or expenditure net of one- off and temporary measures (Mourre et al., 2013) by the OG to the corresponding elasticity power. In the case of expenditure, the IMF approach differs from the EC in that instead of basing their calculations on the OG and the elasticity, they use a simple proportional rule be- tween observed unemployment expenditures, the rate of unemployment and the non-Accel- erating Wage Rate of Unemployment (nAWRU). Finally, the structural revenue and expen- 16 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Figure 4. Residential investment in Europe (as a % of GDP, 2005 prices) Source: European Commission.
  • 7. diture are subtracted and the result is divided by the potential GDP (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999). The objective of estimating the SBB is twofold: first, to assess the cyclical behaviour of discretionary fiscal policies; and second, to attempt to measure the sustainability of such policies by showing whether a fiscal balance is the result of the cyclical components of rev- enue and expenditure, or whether it is based on a more stable trend (Blanchard, 1990). nev- ertheless, in several cases, this indicator failed to explain both, the cyclicality and the sus- tainability of fiscal policy. The reasons that led to these problems are the following. First of all, SBB real-time estimation could be biased not because an error in its method- ology, but because a bias in the OG real-time estimation. Kempkes (2012) shows that the OG real-time estimation is biased. This bias points towards a more negative OG between 0.5% and 0.6% of potential output. Thus, if a fiscal rule is based on this indicator, the real-time admissible deficit will exceed the final value by about 0.5 percentage points per year 5. Assuming an unbiased OG, SBB could still be biased because of the decoupling between the tax base and GDP (Kremer et al., 2006; European Commission, 2013, Part III). This can be partially corrected by taking into account the effects of the composition of demand through more disaggregated indicators than the OG, such as the tax bases (European Com- mission, 2007, Part II). But, each tax has sometimes several bases and it is not always pos- sible to consider all of them. Thus, it is desirable to take into consideration at least the most important ones and the assets that can be affected by a bubble. If not, a significant bias in elasticity estimations could be generated 6. In fact, de Castro et al. (2008) show that output elasticities of revenues and expenditures are not constant across the cycle, but rather pro-cyclical. This could cause the cyclical pat- tern in the revenues windfalls and shortfalls (Morris et al., 2009). That is why, in times of economic growth, part of the cyclical revenue is usually considered structural (Girouard and Price, 2004; Joumard and André, 2008). Therefore, based on real time data, fiscal policies seem to be counter-cyclical, while after-the-event input suggests pro-cyclicality (Cimadomo, 2008; Golinelli and Momigliano, 2007; Forni and Momigliano, 2004). Taking into account the SBB limitations to measure the fiscal policy cyclicality, the Eu- ropean Commission (2013, part III) has developed a new indicator to measure the discre- tionary fiscal effort (DFE). It consists of a narrative (bottom-up) approach on the revenue side and a traditional (top-down) approach on the expenditure side. A comparison of both in- dicators shows that, during booms, DFE indicates a more pro-cyclical policy than real time estimation of SBB, in line with the evidence presented in the previous paragraph. However, the DFE does not aim at measuring the sustainability of the fiscal policy. To do so, and taking into account the SBB limitations reviewed in this section, the impact of bubbles and booms in the cyclical components needs to be considered. In fact, de Castro et al. (2008) and Morris et al. (2009) recognize that the housing boom could be responsible for 17Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
  • 8. the notable revenues windfalls presented in Spain between 1999 and 2007. So, this paper main objective is to include the real estate asset in the Spanish SBB estimation during the years prior to the subprime crisis at the aim of improving the fiscal policy sustainability measure. 4. Estimated structural budget balance for Spain 4.1. Methodology First of all, tax collection must be disaggregated into revenue categories. As we are deal- ing specifically with Spain, we can achieve a more accurate disaggregation instead of rely- ing on the EC general categories. Revenue is therefore disaggregated into: social security contributions (SSC), personal income tax (PIT), corporate tax (CT), property tax (PT; in- cludes inheritance and gift tax and the discontinued wealth tax), value added tax (vAT), cap- ital transfer tax and stamp duty (CTT-SD) and regional governments revenue (RG) 7. Tax base proxies are used instead of the OG as explanatory variables. Thus composition effects are considered. The tax base proxies used for each revenue item are as follows: for the SSC, the average wage (W), the number of people employed (EM), and unemployment benefits (UB); for PIT, the gross disposable household income (GDHI) and the average tax rate (RatePIT); for CT, the gross disposable corporate income (GDCI) and the average tax rate (RateCT) 8; for vAT, private consumption (PRC). Finally, for the PT, the CTT-SD and the RG the residential investment (RI) is the only explanatory variable. RI is also included in all the equations as an additional tax base because it takes into accounts not only prices, but also quantities. Therefore, it can be considered as a proxy of economy-wide effects, since the number of units built may affect employment in the construction sector, wage increases and consumption rises, among others. Annual data from 1986 to 2010 are used and the sources can be found at the annex A. Following Girouard and Price (2004), Kremer et al. (2006), Morris and Schuknecht (2007), and Price and Dang (2011), an error correction model was estimated for each tax rev- enue category to capture both, short- and long-term relationships. Accordingly, we have es- timated a long-term equation (1) linking the levels of the variables (in logarithms) for each revenue category. Equation (2) shows the short-term dynamics between the revenue varia- tion rate, due to long-term deviations from equilibrium, the variation rate of the respective tax base proxies and (nominal) residential investment. (1) (2) ln ln ln, , , ,T B RIi t i i j j N i j t i tlt lt i lt = + + + = ∑α β γ 1 εεi t, ∆ = + ∆ + ∆ = ∑ln ln ln, , , ,T B Ri t i i j j N i j t ist st i st α β γ 1 II et i i t i t+ +−δ ε , ,1 18 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
  • 9. where Ti is the observed revenue of the “i” revenue category; Bi,j is the “j” tax base proxy of the “i” revenue category; Rl is the nominal residential investment; bi,j is the elasticity 9 of “i” revenue to the “j” tax base; gi is the elasticity of the “i” revenue items to nominal residential investment; subscripts “lt” and “st” stand for the long-term and short-term equations respec- tively; di is the error correction factor; ∆ is the first difference operator; and ln is the natural logarithm. Once the coefficients have been obtained, the equation yields the structural value of each revenue item based on the long-term values of the tax bases and residential investment prox- ies. In the former case, following Kremer et al. (2006), tax bases proxies were smoothed using a Hodrick – Prescott filter (λ=30) 10. In the latter case, the long-term value is taken to be a fixed percentage of nominal GDP. various scenarios are developed based on the evo- lution over time in Spain, ranging from 5% to 8% 11. Therefore, the structural value of each revenue item is obtained from the following equation, adapted from the EC and IMF methodology based on the OG (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999): (3) where the superscript “*” indicates structural value. Adding up all structural revenue and tax revenue not included in the quantitative calcu- lation (basically excise tax, foreign trade and gambling tax, that represent less than 10% of total revenue and are taken to be unrelated to the evolution of the construction industry), we obtain the total structural revenue. (4) where the superscript “*” indicates structural value; T is the total revenue; Ti is the revenue stemming from residential investment; and NIT are the revenue items not related to residen- tial investment. According to the EC and IMF approaches, the only cyclical item of expenditure is un- employment benefits (Girouard and André, 2005; Hagemann, 1999). The nAWRU, estimat- ed by the EC, is used as the structural unemployed rate. However, the methodology of this indicator (Mc Morrow and Roeger, 2000) affirms that it cannot be considered structural, since it estimates the unemployment rate that stabilises the inflation rate, while the long-term rate should stabilise both inflation and unemployment. Consequently our methodology does not use the annual nAWRU value, but rather its 20-year moving average 12. This increases the unemployment expenditure that is considered cyclical because it allows a greater differ- ence between the long-term and observed unemployment rate. For the sake of simplicity, we have followed the IMF method of calculating cyclical expenditure, i.e., a proportional rule considering the monetary value of unemployment benefits, divided by the unemployment rate and multiplied by the nAWRU moving average. T T B B RI RI i i i j i jj Ni i jlt * , * , *, =          = ∏ 1 β    γilt T T NITi * * = +∑ 19Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
  • 10. (5) where the superscript “*” indicates the structural value; E is the total public expenditure; Ec is the cyclical public expenditure; Eu is the unemployment expenditure; and UR is the unem- ployment rate. Finally, SBB is obtained by subtracting revenue from structural expenditures. SBB* = T* – E* (6) 4.4. Results First of all, we perform Dickey-Fuller (1981) unit roots tests to identify the order of in- tegration of all variables. As shown in table B.1 in the annex B, we did not reject the unit root hypothesis for the levels of the variables (in logarithms) in any case. Table 1 shows short- and long-term coefficients obtained from the error correction model estimated on each tax revenue using as covariates their tax base and nominal residen- tial investment proxies, together with the error correction term. The annex B shows evidence that confirms the suitability of the models used. Specifically, table B.2 shows the statistics of the unit root test on the residuals of the long-term equations and MacKinnon’s (1991) crit- ical values. It can be seen that, with the exception of the RG variable, the unit root null hy- potheses is rejected for the residuals of all long-term equations (1), and as such they can be considered stationary. In the case of RG, we concluded that there is no cointegration rela- tionship between this variable and residential investment. Table B.3 shows the autocorrela- tion value of the first two lags of the residuals from the long-term equations (1) and the error correction models (2). The Ljung-Box (1978) statistic shows that the residuals in all short- term equations are white noise, which confirms the suitability of the models. The residuals of the long-term equations or cointegration relationships can be considered white noise for all variables, except for IS. In this case, the efficiency of the cointegration vector estimation can be improved using Stock and Watson’s (1993) dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS) technique, that shows very similar results 13. Going back to table 1, it can be seen that residential investment turned out to be a very significant variable to explain the evolution of all the revenue items considered, and that the coefficients signs are as expected. Likewise, the remaining variables are also significant, and their signs as expected too 14. Error correction terms, which show the percentage of devia- tion corrected for each period, are significant, being in all cases between 39% and 87%, ex- cept for SSC, which seems to over-correct the deviation by 9%. It can also be seen that there are no RG values in either the long-term equation or the error correction term. This is because, as discussed previously, the residuals from its long- E E E E E E E E E UR UR E Ec u u u u u * * * ( )= − = − − = − −       = − 1−−       UR UR * 20 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
  • 11. term equation were not stationary. Therefore, in this case, we supposed that there is no coin- tegration relationship between variables, meaning that the coefficient used to estimate structural revenue is taken from the short-term equation in which no error correction was included. Table 1 TAX REVENUE ELASTICITIES Error RI W EM UB GDHI RatePIT GDCI RateCT PRC C correction R2 term Short-term SSC 0.15** 0.82*** 0.59** 0.07** 0 –1.09*** 0,90 –0,06 –0,1 –0,22 –0,03 –0,01 –0,26 PIT 0.20*** 0.43*** 0.18*** 0.03*** –0.69*** 0,98 –0,03 –0,14 –0,01 –0,01 –0,2 CT 0.39*** 0.42** 0.33*** 0 –0.39** 0,92 –0,08 –0,12 –0,03 –0,01 –0,15 PT 0.99*** 0 –0.87*** 0,58 –0,25 –0,04 –0,21 vAT 0.73*** 1.58*** –0.11*** –0.89*** 0,99 –0,13 –0,45 –0,02 –0,16 CTT–SD 1.39*** 0 –0.82*** 0,66 –0,19 –0,03 –0,21 RG 0.29*** 0.06*** – 0,47 –0,06 –0,02 – Long–term SSC 0.13*** 0.87*** 0.61*** 0.08*** 0,16 0,99 –0,04 –0,04 –0,16 –0,02 –0,85 PIT 0.14*** 0.90*** 0.14*** –3.62*** 0,99 –0,02 –0,04 –0,01 –0,32 CT 0.28** 0.65*** 0.38*** –1,30 0,98 –0,12 –0,15 –0,05 –1,00 PT 0.85*** –0,38 0,93 –0,05 –0,86 vAT 0.46*** 0.33*** 0,00 0,99 –0,04 –0,04 –3,95 CTT–SD 1.05*** –2.98*** 0,97 –0,04 –0,65 note: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. Figures 5 and 6 show the evolution of total revenue and unemployment expenditure, re- spectively, both in terms of observed and structural values. In the case of revenue, different long-term residential investment scenarios are presented. It can be seen that up to 2002 the observed revenue did not differ significantly from the structural revenue as expected. How- ever, from 2002 to 2008 the observed revenue exceeded all long-term residential investment scenarios, peaking in 2007 with a difference of 3.3% of GDP compared with the average sce- nario (6.5%). Since 2009, after the bubble burst, the observed value has returned to the struc- tural one. 21Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
  • 12. Regarding unemployment expenditures, the observed and the traditional structural ones are very close to each other, given the small difference between the unemployment rate and the nAWRU. On the contrary, our structural estimation presents lower values until 1998 and higher values from that year on. The highest difference in comparison with the observed value is 1.1% of GDP in 2006 and 2007. Since 2009, our estimation is lower again, given that it does not take into account completely the extremely high unemployment rate of these years and due to the reduction in the unitary benefits. Finally, figure 7 shows the OBB, the SBB estimated by the EC and IMF, our own esti- mate of the SBB for the average scenario (where the nominal GDP share of residential in- vestment is 6.5%) and other estimates from earlier papers (Price and Dang, 2011; Morris and Schuknetch, 2007). First, it can be seen that all the SBB are relatively similar until 1998. From this year onwards, our own estimate starts to show a downward trend that dips more sharply after 2001, while the remaining estimations maintain their upward trend for several more years. 22 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Figure 5. Observed and structural revenue (as a % of GDP and potential GDP) Source: Own estimations and Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations.
  • 13. With regard to the SBB estimated by the EC and IMF, it is interesting to note how sim- ilar they are to the OBB, particularly in the case of EC estimates. IMF estimates differ to a certain extent due to subsequent corrections, but the unrevised estimates are very similar to those of the EC and the OBB. As discussed above, it is obvious that these indicators need to be adjusted, since the advantage of a long-term indicator lies in its capacity to differ from observed data in order to present an overview of the economy that is unaffected by circum- stantial factors. This is the aim of the articles written by Price and Dang (2011) and Morris and Schuknetch (2007). To achieve this, both incorporated the price of financial and property as- sets in their balance estimates. As indicated above, the methodology used is similar to that used in this article. Total revenue is divided in different categories, for each category an error correction model is developed that includes the tax base of the different taxes and the asset price as explanatory variables. Price and Dang (2011) obtain the structural value of the fore- going prices in two ways: one based on fundamentals, and the other by means of a Hodrick 23Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain Figure 6. Observed and structural unemployment expenditure (as a % of GDP and potential GDP) Source: Own estimations, Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations and European Commission.
  • 14. and Prescott filter. Morris and Schuknetch (2007) only use the filter. Despite these changes, it is interesting to note that their structural estimates do not differ to any great extent; at least they are not capable of identifying fiscal difficulties in advance of observed balances. The main advantage of the approach suggested here, therefore, is that it shows that long- term public accounts had started to deteriorate in 1999, with a 3% potential GDP deficit by 2002, and below 4% from 2004 onwards. This would have identified Spanish potential fis- cal troubles several years in advance, and measures could have been taken to correct them in real time. The estimation is improved because the general methodology for all countries is adapted to a particular case. The main feature of Spain over the period studied, as dis- cussed above, is that the real estate bubble was accompanied by a construction boom, which means that the process not only affected prices but also the number of units built, a factor that was not taken into consideration in earlier papers. In other words, instead of discourag- ing buyers, the rise in housing prices had the opposite effect due to the belief that the upward trend would continue. This is why it was decided to include nominal residential investment in our SBB calculation in order to capture the effect of both the prices and units built. 24 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Figure 7. Observed and structural budget balance (as a % of GDP and potential GDP, respectively) Source: Own estimations, Spanish Ministry of the Finance and Public Administrations, EC, IMF and referred papers.
  • 15. As a robustness check, we have estimated our model with data up to 2004 and 2007. We obtain similar results and none of our conclusions are altered 15. The scenario after the crisis may have changed. We were able to estimate a model with data up to 2004 and 2007 because we had enough data. Unfortunately, we only have few observations after the crisis and it is not possible to estimate a model with these few data. But, in any case, the current SBB esti- mation is not the final word on the future outlook for public finances in Spain. In fact, the lower growth rates that are foreseen for Spain in the next years should be taken into account in future research. 5. Conclusions This article attempts to make a contribution to understand the extremely deterioration in the Spanish budget balance. This situation could not be anticipated by the SBB estimated by the EC and the IMF, given that they showed a structural surplus until 2007. Based on these figures, the Spanish authorities took a series of decisions to fight against the recession of 2008 on the assumption that public accounts were structurally sound and had a large enough buffer to allow counter-cyclical policies to be implemented. However, it later became evi- dent that the buffer was nowhere near as robust as expected, forcing them to withdraw tax incentives before the private sector was ready to spearhead the aggregate demand. Such situations might arise due to the failure to include the effect of bubbles in SBB cal- culations. nevertheless, estimates carried out by other authors who did include such vari- ables in their calculations were not capable of improved significantly Spanish SBB either, at least not enough to identify the deterioration of the fiscal situation in time. The main reason for this is that the studies were carried out for a group of countries or a particular region, and as such the particular characteristics of each country are not factored in. In this regard, Spain was in a unique situation because the real estate bubble affected not only prices but also the number of units built, which means that including property prices as the sole explanatory variable of tax revenue was not enough. In this article we have used nominal residential investment as a way of including the number of units built too. It is in- teresting to note that this type of investment has, historically, represented around 6.5% of nominal GDP, but it reached 12.5% in the years leading up to the crisis. The results obtained confirm how important residential investment was in Spanish tax revenue, at least, until the bubble burst. Indeed, it can be seen that including this variable in the equation, and assuming different scenarios concerning its long-term share in GDP, re- veals that Spanish SBB started to show a strong deficit as far back as 2004. Taken this data into consideration, different fiscal policy decisions would probably have been taken not only from 2008 onwards, since the start of the crisis, but also in preceding years. To conclude, it is essential to include bubbles and booms in SBB estimates. This is es- pecially important in Spain, given that its fiscal rule is based on this indicator. 25Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
  • 16. 26 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Annex A Serie Source Observed budget balance Total revenues Social security contributions Total expenditures Unemployment benefits Gross domestic product Gross disposable corporate income Gross disposable household income Private consumption Employment Unemployment Wages Personal income tax Corporate tax Inheritance and gift tax Wealth tax value added tax Capital transfer tax Stamp duty Real Property Tax Motor vehicle Tax Urban Land value Increase Tax Tax on Economic Activities Tax on Building, Installations and other Work Local rates Structural budget balance Potential GDP Structural revenues Structural expenditures nAWRU Residential investment Housing prices Average personal income tax rate Average corporate tax rate Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas de España http://www.sepg.pap.minhap.gob.es/sitios/sepg/es-ES/Presu- puestos/Documentacion/paginas/bdmacro.aspx Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas de España http://www.minhap.gob.es/es-ES/Estadistica%20e%20Infor- mes/Impuestos/Paginas/Impuestos.aspx Ministerio de Hacienda y Administraciones Públicas de España http://serviciosweb.meh.es/apps/EntidadesLocales/ European Commission http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/Se- lectSerie.cfm International Monetary Fund http://www.imf.org/external/ns/cs.aspx?id=28 European Commission http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/Se- lectSerie.cfm European Commission http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/s earch_database European Central Bank http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/browse.do?node=2120781 OECD http://stats.oecd.org/
  • 17. 27Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain AnnexB TableB.1 UNITROOTTESTS(Dickey-Fullercriticalvalues,1981) LevelsFirstDifferencesSeconddifferences Variable Nointercept,Withintercept,Withintercept,Nointercept,Withintercept,Nointercept, notrendnotrendandtrendnotrendnotrendnotrend “t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value“t”statisticP-value Socialsecuritycontributions0,2770,757–0,7770,807–2,5250,314–1,1570,218–1,8260,359–4,6650,000 Personalincometax3,7771,0002,1441,000–0,9670,9250,5130,817–4,2660,003–– Corporatetax–0,3180,560–1,3990,566–1,7320,697–3,5340,001–2,0340,271–– Propertytax–0,2400,589–1,4840,524–2,8840,185–4,6110,000–4,5700,002–– valueaddedtax0,9580,905–1,0110,732–2,8500,197–4,0010,000–4,0080,007–– Capitaltransfertaxand stampduty–0,8680,329–1,8810,335–0,7340,956–2,6240,011–3,1880,035–– Regionalgovernmentrevenue3,9401,0003,6221,0001,3661,000–0,6840,408–2,0410,268–5,2650,000 Residentialinvestment3,3400,9991,9421,000–0,5740,971–1,3450,160–4,2650,003–– Wage1,1650,932–1,0450,718–3,2090,114–0,7010,401–3,4930,018–– Employed1,5800,968–1,3800,574–2,8690,190–1,7940,070–2,7210,087–– Unemploymentbenefits3,1200,9992,0781,0000,7550,999–2,4700,016–2,7980,074–– Consumption2,7070,9972,0581,000–2,0310,555–1,4190,141–3,2460,030–– Householdincome21,1201,0006,4911,0002,6591,000–0,9220,306–1,0520,713–5,9630,000 Corporateincome3,3390,9990,6270,987–2,0000,566–2,1640,032–3,9220,008–– PITrate0,5340,824–1,6940,421–2,1580,489–6,2630,000–6,0740,000–– CTrate–0,4220,520–1,7720,385–2,7600,225–4,0050,000–3,9030,007––
  • 18. 28 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK Table B.2 UNIT ROOT TESTS OF THE RESIDUALS OF LONG-TERM EQUATIONS (MacKinnon critical values, 1991) “t” statistic Critical values a = 0,05 a = 0,1 Social security contributions –4,759 –4,998 –4,567 Personal income tax –4,980 –4,564 –4,152 Corporate tax –4,562 –4,564 –4,152 Property tax –4,218 –3,591 –3,218 value added tax –5,357 –4,098 –3,706 Capital transfer tax and stamp duty –3,363 –3,591 –3,218 Regional government revenue –1,920 –3,591 –3,218 Table B.3 AUTOCORRELATIONS OF THE FIRST TWO LAGS AND p-values ASSOCIATED TO THE LJUNG-BOX STATISTICS (1978) FOR THE RESIDUAL OF THE LONG- AND SHORT- TERM EQUATIONS Equation Lags Long term Short term Auto P-value Auto P-value correlations correlations Social security contributions 1 –0,021 0,913 –0,042 0,827 2 –0,062 0,939 –0,082 0,887 Personal income tax 1 –0,036 0,847 0,223 0,245 2 –0,007 0,981 0,087 0,457 Corporate tax 1 0,401 0,040 –0,022 0,911 2 –0,228 0,060 –0,147 0,747 Property tax 1 0,126 0,504 –0,029 0,879 2 0,266 0,284 0,245 0,422 value added tax 1 0,070 0,709 0,107 0,577 2 –0,231 0,426 –0,076 0,788 Capital transfer tax and stamp duty 1 0,355 0,060 0,073 0,704 2 –0,142 0,126 –0,282 0,301 Regional government revenue 1 – – 0,137 0,476 2 – – –0,095 0,682 Notes 1. Alternative SBB estimations, which are analyzed afterwards (Price and Dang, 2011; Morris and Schuknetch, 2007), also showed a surplus in the years prior to the crisis (see figure 7). 2. For an analysis of the changes introduced, the rationale and shortcomings of the new budgetary stability law see Hernández de Cos and Pérez (2013).
  • 19. 3. According to Stiglitz (1990) a bubble exists when the price of an asset grows only because investors believe it will continue to increase in the future, although fundamental factors do not justify this belief. 4. While the OG is an essential driver of the SBB, its estimation remains outside the scope of this paper. For the OG estimation, see Denis et al. (2006) and D’Auria et al. (2010). 5. This real-time bias in the admissible deficit would be added to another bias identified by de Castro et al. (2013), related to political issues such as unfavorable economic conditions or elections. 6. For example, if a financial or real estate bubble raises the price of assets, it would affect certain tax bases, but not the OG, affecting the elasticities (Joumard and André, 2008). 7. This category is the sum of Real Property Tax (Impuesto sobre bienes inmuebles, or “IBI”), Motor vehicle Tax (Impuesto sobre vehículos tracción mecánica, or “IvTM”), Urban Land value Increase Tax (Impuesto sobre incremento valor terrenos naturaleza urbana, or “IIvTnU”), Tax on Economic Activities (Impuesto sobre actividades económicas, or “IAE”), Tax on Building, Installations and other Work (Impuesto sobre con- strucciones, instalaciones y obras, or “ICIO”), and local rates. 8. RatePIT and RateCT are calculated by the OECD as the ratio between the personal income tax and the corpo- rate tax revenues, respectably, and the GDP. Therefore, these are not statutory rates. 9. Equations (1) and (2) should take on board legislation changes in order for β and γ to be interpreted as proper tax elasticities in the sense in which the literature uses them. As we focus on the fit of the equations, we use these coefficients as proxies of the real elasticities. 10. The choice of the value of the parameter is discussed in Bouthevillain et al. (2001). 11. In the pre-bubble two decades (between 1980 and 2000), residential investment had never been less than 5% or more than 8% of GDP. 12. Results are not significantly modified when different moving averages are used. 13. Results are available upon request. 14. We attempted to include lagged variables in short-term equations, but none were significant. This was expect- ed since annual data are used. Thus, only contemporary dynamics are shown. 15. We thank both anonymous referees for suggesting this robustness check. References Blanchard, O. J. (1990), “Suggestions for a new set of fiscal indicators”, OECD Department of Eco- nomics and Statistics Working Papers, 79. Bouthevillain, C.; Cour-Thimann, P.; van den Dool, G.; Hernández de Cos, P.; Langenus, G.; Mohr, M.; Momigliano, S. and Tujula, M. (2001), “Cyclically adjusted budget balances: an alternative ap- proach”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 77. Cimadomo, J. (2008), “Fiscal policy in real time”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 919. D’Auria, F.; Denis, C.; Havik, K.; Mc Morrow, K.; Planas, C.; Raciborski, R.; Röger, W. and Rossi, A. (2010), “The production function methodology for calculating potential growth rates and output gaps”, European Commission Economic Papers, 420. de Castro Fernández, F.; Estrada García, A.; Hernández de Cos, P. and Martí Esteve, F. (2008), “Una aproximación al componente transitorio del saldo público en España”, Boletín Económico del Banco de España, 6: 71-81. 29Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain
  • 20. de Castro, F.; Pérez, J. and Rodríguez-vives, M. (2013), “Fiscal Data Revisions in Europe”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45 (6): 1187-1209. Denis, C.; Grenouilleau, D.; Mc Morrow, K. and Röger, W. (2006), “Calculating potential growth rates and output gaps – A revised production function approach”, European Commission Economic Pa- pers, 247. Dickey, D. A. and Fuller, W. A. (1981), “Likehood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root”, Econometrica, 49 (4): 1057-1072. European Commission (2007), “Public finances in EMU 2007”, European Economy, 3. European Commission (2013), “Report on Public finances in EMU 2013”, European Economy, 4. Forni, L. and Momigliano, S. (2004), “Cyclical sensitivity of fiscal policies based on real-time data”, MPRA Paper, 4315. García Montalvo, J. (2003), “La vivienda en España: desgravaciones, burbujas y otras historias”, Fun- dación de las Cajas de Ahorro (FUNCAS), Perspectivas del Sistema Financiero, 78. Girouard, n. and André, C. (2005), “Measuring Cyclically-adjusted Budget Balances for OECD Coun- tries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 434. Girouard, n. and Price, R. (2004), “Asset Price Cycles, ´One-Off´ Factors and Structural Budget Bal- ances”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 391. Golinelli, R. and Momigliano, S. (2007), “The Cyclical Response of Fiscal Policies in the Euro Area - Why Do Results of Empirical Research Differ so Strongly?”, Banca d`Italia Working Papers, 654. Hagemann, R. (1999), “The Structural Budget Balance. The IMF´s Methodology”, IMF Working Paper, 95. Hernández de Cos, P. and Pérez, J. (2013), “The new budgetary stability law”, Bank of Spain Econom- ic bulletin, April: 13-25. Joumard, I. and André, C. (2008), “Revenue Buoyancy and its Fiscal Policy Implications”, OECD Eco- nomics Department Working Papers, 598. Kempkes, G. (2012), “Cyclical adjustment in fiscal rules: some evidence on real-time bias for EU-15 countries”, Discussion Paper Deutsche Bundesbank, 15. Kremer, J.; Rodrigues Braz, C.; Brosens, T.; Langenus, G.; Momigliano, S. and Spolander, M. (2006), “A Disaggregated Framework for the Analysis of Structural Developments in Public Finances”, Eu- ropean Central Bank Working Paper Series, 579. Larch, M. and Turrini, A. (2009), “The cyclically-adjusted budget balance in EU fiscal policy making: A love at first sight turned into a mature relationship”, European Commission Economic Papers, 374. Ljung, G. M. and Box, G. E. P. (1978), “On a Measure of a Lack of Fit in Time Series Models”, Bio- metrika, 65(2): 297-303. MacKinnon, J. G. (1991), “Critical values for Cointegration Tests”, in R. F. Engel and C. W. I. Granger (eds.), Long Run Economic Relationship, Oxford University Press, 267-76. Mc Morrow, K. and Roeger, W. (2000), “Time –varying nairu / nawru Estimates for the EU’s Mem- ber States”, Economic and Financial Affairs (ECFIN) of the European Commission, 145. 30 GUIDO ZACK, PILAR POnCELA, EvA SEnRA y DAnIEL SOTELSEK
  • 21. Morris, R. and Schuknecht, L. (2007), “Structural balances and revenue windfalls. The role of asset prices revisited”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 737. Morris, R.; Rodrigues Braz, C.; de Castro, F.; Jonk, S.; Kremer, J.; Linehan, S.; Marino, M.; Schalck, C. and Tkacevs, O (2009), “Explaining government revenue windfalls and shortfalls: an analysis for selected EU countries”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 1114. Mourre, G.; Isbasoiu, G.; Paternoster, D. and Salto, M. (2013), “The cyclically-adjusted budget bal- ance used in the EU fiscal framework: an update”, European Economy Economic Papers, 478. Price, R. and Dang, T. (2011), “Adjusting fiscal balances for asset prices cycles”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper, 868. REAF (Registro de Economistas Asesores Fiscales) (2007), “Costes asociados a la adquisición, uso y alquiler de viviendas”. http://www.unionprofesional.com/index.php/unionprofesional/sala_prensa/noti- cias_colegiales/economia_sociedad/costes_fiscales_asociados_a_la_adquisicion_uso_y_alquiler_de_vi viendas_segun_un_estudio_del_reaf Stiglitz, J. (1990), “Symposium on Bubbles”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2): 13-18. Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (1993), “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating vectors in Higher Order Integrated Systems”, Econometrica, 61(4): 783-820. Resumen La recesión iniciada en 2008 generó un fuerte deterioro del resultado fiscal de España. Este deterioro no fue completamente anticipado por el resultado fiscal estructural debido a ciertas limitaciones meto- dológicas. En este artículo se calcula un resultado estructural alternativo para España durante los años previos a la crisis subprime, que incluye la inversión en vivienda como variable explicativa. Esta esti- mación muestra que desde 2004 la situación fiscal española no era tan sólida como se creía y que la fragilidad estuvo oculta gracias a los recursos extraordinarios resultantes de la burbuja inmobiliaria y del boom en la construcción. Palabras clave: crisis, resultado fiscal estructural, burbuja inmobiliaria, boom de la construcción, Es- paña. Clasificación JEL: C20, E32, E63, H62. 31Some new Results on the Estimation of Structural Budget Balance for Spain