SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 28
Download to read offline
STATE OF THE FINANCIAL SERVICES INDUSTRY | 2011




       The Financial Crisis of 2015
       An Avoidable History
John Banks was woken by his phone at 3am on Sunday, April 26, 2015.
John worked for Garland Brothers, a formerly British bank that had
relocated its headquarters to Singapore in late 2011 as a result of what
Garland’s CEO had described as “irreconcilable differences” between
the bank and the UK regulators. The last three years had been the
most exciting of John’s life. Having led the bank’s aggressive expansion
into emerging markets wholesale activities, he had recently been
promoted to its executive committee.

John picked up the phone. It was the bank’s legal counsel, Peter
Thompson, calling. He had dramatic news. Garland Brothers, one of
the world’s oldest banks, would declare bankruptcy tomorrow. As he
lay there in his spacious air-conditioned bedroom, unable to return to
sleep, John tried to reconstruct the events of the last four years.

Planting the seeds of failure
At the beginning of 2011, the global economy was showing signs of
finding a “new normal”. With the exception of a few smaller troubled
economies, the world had returned to positive growth, and Western
stock markets had returned to their levels prior to the Lehman
crisis. Banks had started lending to each other again, becoming
gradually less reliant on central bank funding. Insurers had rebuilt
their capital positions back to pre-crisis levels. Ireland had joined
Greece in the list of peripheral Euro countries requiring a bailout, but
there was a general sense that the broader contagion problems had
been contained.

New bank (Basel III) and insurance (Solvency II, in Europe) regulatory
regimes had been introduced and were designed to avoid a repeat of
the sub-prime crisis. Banks were phasing in the new tougher controls
around capital, liquidity and leverage, albeit over a relatively relaxed
timeframe. The Basel Committee’s impact study had estimated that
the largest banks needed to raise a total of €577 BN to meet the new
standards, and several banks came to market in 2011 with multi-
billion Euro rights issues.

Beneath this relatively calm surface, however, trouble was brewing.
Stakeholders in financial services firms wanted lower risk, but
shareholders were still demanding high returns. Executives felt their
institutions were holding more capital than they needed, and they
were struggling to find investment opportunities that satisfied their
shareholders’ return requirements. Despite attempts by central banks
to inject liquidity into the system, loan growth in Western economies
had ground to a halt as consumers continued to deleverage and
companies remained reluctant to invest, uncertain of the future
interest rate, tax and regulatory environment.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                              1
The ability of banks to generate fee income by re-packaging credit
books had been eliminated by punitive new securitization rules. New
consumer protection laws prevented the sale of complex derivatives to
many customers. Proprietary trading by banks had been outlawed in
many jurisdictions.

The talented and ambitious employees of Western banks found
themselves under-utilized in an industry that was starting to resemble
a utility. They needed to find new outlets for their creativity and drive.

Disappearing into the shadows
Talent began shifting into the shadow banking sector. During the
low interest rate environment of 2011, investors were desperate
for alternative investments with additional yield. Assets under
management in the shadow banking sector grew rapidly during 2011.
Asset managers were promising “inflation busting” returns but many
of the strategies were based on the short-term growth prospects of the
hottest markets and often employed leverage to maximize gains.

New types of specialist loan funds disintermediated the highly
regulated banking sector by matching borrowers and investors directly.
These funds tapped into the long-term liquidity pools of pension
funds and insurance companies. Their pitch books described such
investors as “advantaged holders of illiquid credit”. Lacking their own
distribution channels, these funds relied on outsourced origination,
either through banks or networks of “hungry” agents. Credit discipline
was poor. Even at this early stage, the pattern was familiar, but
regulators did not intervene. Because the asset flows were global
and did not have banks at their center, no single regulatory body
felt responsible.

Go East (or South) young man!
Other restless Western banks and bankers moved, not into the
shadows, but into the heat of emerging markets. In contrast to the
anti-banking sentiment growing in the West, many emerging markets
jurisdictions were still viewed as “banker friendly”. At the same time,
growth opportunities in emerging markets had already encouraged
some banks to base their growth strategies on these markets. In early
2011, several small international banks closed down their Western
wholesale subsidiaries and re-located them to Singapore or Hong
Kong. Garland Brothers was the first British bank to make the move,
giving up its UK base when it decided to relocate its headquarters to
Singapore in late 2011.




2                                              Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Western banks tackled the emerging markets in different ways. Those
that had already established deposit and customer bases in emerging
markets continued to grow organically, employing a well-tested
and consistent set of risk standards across markets regardless of
regulatory inconsistencies. Other Western players, such as Garland
Brothers, that were struggling to find an edge, employed unorthodox
techniques to build a presence in the faster growing markets. Some
began to build large wholesale divisions in Asia and set up complex
legal entity structures to take advantage of inconsistencies across
regulatory regimes.

Sales of complex derivatives were once again producing a large
proportion of many banks’ income. Lacking an emerging markets
deposit franchise, many of these Western banks started to fund their
emerging markets lending activities via the wholesale markets or
by tapping domestic funding sources in the West. Problems in the
Eurozone meant that many European banks were paying 200-300bps
above LIBOR for funding back home, and there were few opportunities
in Europe to lend out such funds profitably. European banks found
that lending to emerging markets banks and governments was one
of the few ways of generating a positive margin over their rising cost
of funds. This was part of a general trend among Western banks of
moving down the credit spectrum to pick up yield.

Bubble creation
Based on favorable demographic trends and continued liberalization,
the growth story for emerging markets was accepted by almost
everyone. However, much of the economic activity in these markets
was buoyed by cheap money being pumped into the system by Western
central banks. Commodities prices had acted as a sponge to soak
up the excess global money supply, and commodities-rich emerging
economies such as Brazil and Russia were the main beneficiaries.

High commodities prices created strong incentives for these emerging
economies to launch expensive development projects to dig more
commodities out of the ground, creating a massive oversupply of
commodities relative to the demand coming from the real economy. In
the same way that over-valued property prices in the US had allowed
people to go on debt-fueled spending sprees, the governments of
commodities-rich economies started spending beyond their means.
They fell into the familiar trap of borrowing from foreign investors to
finance huge development projects justified by unrealistic valuations.
Western banks built up large and concentrated loan exposures in
these new and exciting growth markets.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                         3
The banking M&A market was turned on its head. Banks pursuing
high growth strategies, particularly those focussed on lending to the
booming commodities-rich economies, started to attract high market
valuations and shareholder praise. In the second half of 2012 some of
these banks made successful bids for some of the leading European
players that had been cut down to a digestible size by the new anti-
“too big to fail” regulations. The market was, once again, rewarding the
riskiest strategies. Stakeholders and commentators began pressing
risk-averse banks to mimic their bolder rivals.

The narrative driving the global commodities bubble assumed a
continuation of the increasing demand from China, which had become
the largest commodities importer in the world. Any rumors of a
slowing Chinese economy sent tremors through global markets. Much
now depended on continued demand growth in China and continued
appreciation of commodities prices.

The bubble bursts
Western central banks pumping cheap money into the financial
system was seen by many as having the dual purposes of kick-starting
Western economies and pressing China to appreciate its currency.
Strict capital controls initially enabled the Chinese authorities to resist
pressure on their currency. Yet the dramatic rises in commodities prices
resulting from loose Western monetary policies eventually caused
rampant inflation in China. China was forced to raise interest rates and
appreciate its currency to bring inflation under control. The Western
central banks had been granted their wish of an appreciating Chinese
currency but with the unwanted side effect of a slowing Chinese
economy and the reduction in global demand that came with it.

Once the Chinese economy began to slow, investors quickly realized
that the demand for commodities was unsustainable. Combined
with the massive oversupply that had built up during the boom, this
led to a collapse of commodities prices. Having borrowed to finance
expensive development projects, the commodities-rich countries in
Latin America and Africa and some of the world’s leading mining
companies were suddenly the focus of a new debt crisis. In the same
way that the sub-prime crisis led to a plethora of half-completed
real estate development projects in the US, Ireland and Spain,
the commodities crisis of 2013 left many expensive commodity
exploration projects unfinished.




4                                               Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Western banks and insurers did not escape the consequences of the
commodities crisis. Some, such as the Spanish banks, had built up
direct exposure by financing Latin American development projects.
Others, such as US insurers, had amassed indirect exposures through
investments in infrastructure funds and bank debt. Inflation pressure
in the US and UK during the commodities boom had forced the Bank
of England and Fed to push through a series of interest rate hikes that
forced many Western debtors that had been holding on since the sub-
prime crisis, to finally to default on their debts. With growth in both
developed and emerging markets suppressed, the world once again
fell into recession.

Judgement day for sovereigns
The final phase of the crisis saw the US, UK and European debt
mountains emerge as the ultimate source of global systemic risk.
Long-term sovereign yields had been gradually rising during the
last few years, but analysts had assumed that this was because of
increasing inflationary expectations. With the advent of the new
commodities lending crisis, rising sovereign yields were suddenly
being attributed to the deteriorating solvency of the sovereigns. Their
high debts, combined with increasing refinancing costs, made it
apparent that the debt burden of many developed world sovereigns
was unserviceable. It was judgement day for sovereigns.

Those sovereigns that were highly indebted and needed to roll over
large amounts of short-term debt were forced to either restructure
their debts or accept bailout money from other healthier sovereigns.
This period, which spanned 2013 to 2015, was the single biggest
rebalancing of economic and political power since World War II.

The final irony in the tale was that the large sovereign exposures that
the banking system had built up as a result of the new liquidity buffer
requirements left the banking system, once again, sitting on the edge
of the abyss.

Our unemployed protagonist
As John ran through these facts it became clear to him that not enough
had been learned from the sub-prime crisis. Bankers had gone chasing
the next rainbow only to find another pot of toxic waste rather than
a pot of gold. The new wave of regulations had proved ineffective
at stopping another bubble from forming. John was struggling to
understand what he should have done differently. Heads would
certainly roll. But who was really to blame this time around?




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                             5
1.	 The	purpose	and	structure	of	
this	report

The sub-prime crisis of 2007 will not be the last financial sector crisis.
Even during the relative calm of the last 25 years, we witnessed the
property crises of the early 90s, the Asia currency crisis, the LTCM/
Russia crisis and a number of other smaller emerging markets-led
financial crises. We are due another crisis soon.

Financial services executives and regulators have worked hard to
design a safer and more stable financial system, but we will not know
whether they have succeeded until it is tested by the next crisis. The
first aim of our 2015 crisis scenario is to stress test the design of the
new financial system, to consider how well it would stand up to this
type of adverse scenario.

The broader aim of the report is to encourage readers to think about
the future financial system using several scenarios rather than basing
decisions on a single predicted course of events. Shell Oil, guided by
Arie de Geus1, was a pioneer in using scenario planning in the 1980s.
De Geus claimed that the main purpose of using scenarios was to
“think the unthinkable” and claimed that scenarios were “vastly
superior in dealing with the future than predictions”. Strategists who
focus on a single path of future events, he claimed, tend to filter out
news that does not fit their view of the world. Companies with a single
strategy or plan are “virtually blind” to new information.

Our scenario is not a prediction. Our aim in describing it is to show
that current efforts underway to create a better system should not
be taken as an assurance that the system is now safe from future
crises. Other plausible scenarios may show the same thing, though
potentially with different strategic implications. We encourage you to
use several such adverse scenarios in your planning, tailoring them to
the risks facing your institution.

The rest of this report is structured as follows. Section 2 presents
supporting evidence for our scenario, showing that it is not as unlikely
as we might hope. Then, in Section 3, we review some of the measures
regulators and financial institutions are taking to limit the probability
and severity of future crises and, based on lessons from our 2015
crisis scenario, we make some suggestions about what they could
do differently.


1   See The Living Company by Arie de Geus, Harvard Business Press, 1997




6                                                            Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
2.	 How	plausible	is	our	2015	
crisis	scenario?

In our scenario, the crisis has three principal drivers: the resurgence
of shadow banking, the formation of emerging market asset bubbles
and sovereign debt restructurings in developed markets. Below, we
consider the likelihood of these three events.



2.1.	 The	resurgence	of	shadow	banking

Definition of shadow banking
By “shadow banking” we refer to credit intermediation, maturity
transformation and liquidity transformation that takes place outside
of the deposit-taking institutions that have access to central bank
liquidity and whose depositors receive government guarantees
(or deposit insurance). Money market mutual funds, structured
investment vehicles, credit hedge funds, asset-backed commercial
paper conduits and securities lenders are all, therefore, parts of the
shadow banking system, though not the whole of it.

Since the 1980s, shadow banking has grown even more rapidly than
the official banking sector (see Exhibit 1). This growth has been caused
in part by the real economic advantages of some shadow banking
activities in matching the needs of investors and borrowers through
product innovation. However, it has also been driven by “regulatory
arbitrage”: that is, by the desire to hide leverage outside of the official
banking sector, especially to avoid regulatory capital requirements. As
can be seen in Exhibit 1, the liabilities of the shadow banking sector
dropped rapidly during the recent crisis, showing that the official
banking system was by comparison a safe place to keep your money.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                             7
Exhibit 1: Shadow Bank Liabilities vs. Traditional Bank Liabilities (US$ TN)
20

18

16

14

12

10

 8

 6

 4

 2

 0
     1945   1950   1955   1960   1965   1970   1975   1980   1985   1990    1995   2000   2005   2010

                                  Shadow Banking        Traditional Liabilities

Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States as of 2010:Q1 (FRB) and FRBNY



The connections between shadow banking and the
official banking sector
When these off-balance sheet activities ran into trouble during the
recent crisis, many banks were forced to bring the troubled assets back
onto their balance sheets, in some cases to protect their reputations in
the bond markets.

In theory, the shadow banking system did not enjoy the same implicit
support that is offered by governments to the banking system
which is the main reason it has escaped the same level of regulatory
scrutiny. However, given its scale and its connections with the official
banking sector, governments could not allow many parts of the
shadow banking sector to fail during the crisis. The AIG bailout and
government support for money market funds that had promised never
to “break the buck” are cases in point.

Regulatory response
The response from policy makers has been to increase the strictness
of regulation for shadow banking. For example, the European Union
recently approved a new Directive on Alternative Fund Managers
which introduces official capital and reporting requirements.

These regulations may constrain risk-taking at alternative fund
managers, and other regulations may similarly constrain other
known types of shadow banks. But shadow banking is a remarkably
dynamic and opaque industry, and we are skeptical about the ability
of regulators to control the quantity of risk it takes on. In a game of
cat and mouse between regulators and shadow bankers, the mice will



8                                                                Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
win. There are far more mice; they are typically better informed and
better motivated than the cats; and the extraordinary complexity of
modern financial products and the global scope of the industry give
the mice a nearly limitless supply of nooks and crannies to hide in.

Squeezing the balloon
The regulatory trend of coming down hard on the banks will increase
the amount of risk in the shadow banking sector. The fundamental
macro imbalances2 that are driving up levels of risk in the financial
system will not be addressed by any of the new regulations. The
only question is where these risks will go. Squeezing them out of the
more transparent and manageable banking system could prove to be
a mistake.

Exhibit 2: The regulatory squeeze on banking




                          Regulation


                                                                   Shadow
  Macro                     Banking                                banking
imbalances




Given the tendency of financial institutions to manage their risks
by partially placing them in the shadow banking sector, there is also
a strong possibility that the interconnectedness between the two
systems will increase as the new rules create even greater incentives
for regulatory arbitrage. Short of any reduction in the actual risks,
and contrary to the instincts of vote-seeking politicians, the best
way to avoid another bubble may be to loosen the regulatory vice on
the banks.




2   For example, the trade imbalances between the US and China have actually grown during
    the crisis rather than having been diffused




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                                               9
2.2.	 Emerging	markets	asset	bubbles

In a study of emerging markets crises for the IMF in 19993, Graciela
Kaminski observed that such crises tended to be “preceded by an
explosion of international lending to emerging markets at very
low real interest rates” and that the crises later erupted “as the
industrialized countries engaged in extremely tight monetary
policies”. In other words, emerging markets’ asset bubbles, and their
bursting, are to a great extent effects of Western monetary policy. She
then notes that the sudden “switch to contractionary monetary policy
provoked a sharp rise in real interest rates, profound recessions in
industrial countries, and plummeting commodity prices.”

Our scenario builds on these historical observations and has a
commodity price bubble at its center. The fallout from such an emerging
markets crisis could be even more severe than in previous crises, with
the biggest losers coming from the developed world. Western monetary
policy is looser than ever, so the bubble could be unprecedented in size.
And the high levels of indebtedness in developed economies means
that they are in no position to absorb a rapid monetary tightening
without experiencing a massive rise in insolvencies, including perhaps
the insolvency of several developed world sovereigns.

Below we outline in more detail the two phases of our scenario.
Phase 1 describes the “bubble formation” while Phase 2 describes the
“bursting of the bubble”.

Exhibit 3: Phase 1 – Bubble formation
Phase 1: Bubble formation
    Emerging markets – commodities exporters                        China – world’s largest commodities importer
    (LatAm, Africa, Australia)                                          “Commodities narrative”
      Storage of                                                                          Strong
        excess                                           Real           Real world
                                                                                          Chinese
     commodities                                       demand          commodities
                                                                                         economic
        supply                                                           demand
                                                         CNY                              growth

                                                      Speculative
                                                                                                        Undervalued
     Commodities                                       demand         Commodities         Chinese
                       Business case   Commodities                                                        Chinese
     development                                         CNY            investors/       inflation
                                          price                                                           currency
       projects                                                        speculators       concerns
                                         bubble                                                             CNY


         US$ Cheap debt financing          US$ Speculative demand                                      Currency peg


       Western
        banks




       Loose                           Commodities                                                         Weak
                          Inflation
      monetary                           investors/                                                     US currency
                          concerns
       policy                           speculators                                                         US$

    Western world (US, UK, Eurozone) – loose monetary policy




3     Currency and Banking Crises: The Early Warnings of Distress, Graciela Kaminsky, IMF Institute, 1999




10                                                                            Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
During phase 1 we distinguish between two sources of demand
affecting commodities prices: demand for use in the production of other
goods (“real” demand) and demand for the purpose of price speculation
(“speculative” demand). There are three major groups of players in our
scenario. Firstly, there are economies, such as Latin America, Africa,
Russia, Canada and Australia, which are the largest commodities
producers. Secondly, there is China, which is now the world’s largest
commodity importer. Thirdly, there are the developed world economies,
such as the US, which are pumping liquidity into the financial system
through their loose monetary policies.

As with any bubble, our scenario contains a compelling narrative that
allows investors to convince themselves that “this time is different”.
In this case it is a story of strong economic growth coming from China
creating a sustainable increase in demand for commodities.

However, it is already apparent that increasing commodities prices are
also creating inflationary pressure in China, which is exacerbated by
China holding its currency artificially low by effectively pegging it to the
US dollar. This makes commodities look like an attractive hedge against
inflation for Chinese investors. The loose monetary policy in developed
markets is similarly making commodities look attractive for Western
investors. This “commodities rush” is demonstrated in the right-hand
chart below, which shows the asset allocations of European and Asian
investors. A recent investor survey by Barclays also found that 76% of
investors predicted an even bigger inflow into commodities in 2011.

Exhibit 4: The Commodities Rush
CRX index vs. S&P 500 (Market value of                                         European and Asian mutual fund
equity of commodity-related companies)                                         investments in commodities

Index: 2005-05-31 = 100                                                            €MM

450                                                                            40,000
                                                                        CRX
400                                                                            35,000

350
                                                                               30,000
300
                                                                               25,000
250
                                                                               20,000
200
                                                                               15,000
150
                                                                 S&P 500       10,000
100

 50                                                                             5,000

  0                                                                                0
                                                                                        2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 20101
  2000
         2001
                2002
                       2003
                              2004
                                     2005
                                            2006
                                                   2007
                                                          2008
                                                                 2009
                                                                        2010




1. Based on Q3 data
Source: Bloomberg, FERI, Oliver Wyman analysis




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                                                                        11
Based on the currently inflated commodity prices, commodity
producers in countries such as Brazil and Russia have clear business
cases for investing in projects to dig more commodities out of the
ground. As competition to launch such projects increases, the costs
of completing them also starts to rise, with the owners of mining
equipment and laborers capitalizing on the increased demand by
charging higher rates. Because a portion of the demand for the
projects is not coming from the real economy, an excess supply of
mining capacity and commodities will be created.

As with previous asset bubbles, we expect much of the debt financing
for these projects to come from banks. And much of this bank
financing is likely to be supplied by Western banks that are eager
to preserve their diminishing return-on-equity and need to find
lending opportunities that are sufficiently lucrative to cover their own
increasing cost of funds. The balance sheets of life insurers will play
a supporting role here, as insurers look for long-term investments
that can match their liabilities and seek to earn additional
illiquidity premia.

Exhibit 5: Phase 2 – Bubble bursts: commodities price crash
Phase 2: Bubble bursts – commodities price crash
 Emerging markets – commodities exporters                                   China – major commodities importer
                                                                              Commodities narrative ends
       Massive
     oversupply of                                                               Fall in            Slowing            Currency
     commodities                                                              commodities          economic           allowed to
                                                                                demand              growth            appreciate


                              Broken        Commodities
  Commodities
                           business case       price                          Commodities          Tightened
  development                                                                                                          Spiraling
                                               crash            CNY             investors/         monetary
    projects                                                                                                           inflation
                                                                Rush           speculators           policy
     halted
                                                                for exits

         US$ Debt crisis                       US$ Rush for exits


                                           Commodities
       Western
                                             investors/
        banks
                                            speculators

                                                                                             As a result of Phase 1
      Tightened
                                             Inflation                                                                Commodities
      monetary
                                             pressure                                                                    price
        policy
                                                                                                                        bubble

 Western world – tightened monetary policy



Whatever bursts the bubble, it will involve investors coming to doubt
that the real demand for commodities is sustainable. For example,
further trouble in the Eurozone or political instability in the Middle
East or Asia could lead to concerns about global growth prospects
and burst the bubble. In our scenario, we have made the “prick” a
tightening of monetary policy in China in response to inflationary
pressure caused by China’s hot economy and rising commodities
prices. Once China’s currency appreciates and its economy slows, it
will become clear that the commodities narrative is over optimistic.




12                                                                                    Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
At the first sign of trouble, the speculative investors will head for
the exits, causing commodities prices to crash. Many development
projects will be abandoned before completion. The parallels with the
recent real estate development crisis are clear. Developed markets’
banks that lent to the developers will suffer large losses. The ensuing
pressures on emerging market debt will also be felt by insurers that
operate in these countries and invest a large proportion of their assets
in local sovereign debt.

How big could the losses be?
Recent disclosures from mining companies and economies that
export commodities suggest that several hundred billion dollars will
be invested in commodities exploration projects in the coming years.
Losses from a commodities debt crisis could therefore be on a similar
scale to the $400 BN of direct losses that stemmed from the sub-prime
crisis. However, the IMF now estimates that the combined direct and
indirect losses stemming from the sub-prime crisis are more like
$4 TN (a factor of 10 larger). Should we expect a similar multiplier
effect in a commodities crisis?

There are reasons to think so. Commodities prices are correlated with
the broader economic growth of economies that are big commodities
producers. The chart below demonstrates this for Latin America:

Exhibit 6: Correlation between commodities prices and Latin American GDP
Year-on-year growth

40%



30%



20%



10%



 0%



-10%



-20%
       1990   1992    1994    1996    1998    2000    2002     2004   2006   2008   2010

                             Commodities prices      Latin American GDP

Source: IMF commodities price and GDP data; Oliver Wyman analysis




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                                        13
It is likely then that the prices of other assets classes in these
economies, such as real estate, will rise and fall with commodities
prices. We should expect significant additional losses for those who
own these other asset classes, and for their financiers.



2.3.	 Sovereign	debt	crisis

The next part of our scenario brings the 2015 crisis home to the
Western sovereigns. A commodities crash driven by a bank-led
financing boom would cause more problems for Western banks and,
as with any price crash, create deflationary pressure. A return to
worldwide recession would be a strong possibility.

Do Western sovereigns have the debt servicing capacity to absorb
another recession? In our scenario, they do not and the next step is
the debt restructuring of some of the world’s leading sovereigns. Is
there any historical precedence for such a dramatic sovereign default
scenario? Alas, the answer is “yes”. The chart below is based on data
compiled by the economic historians Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth
Rogoff. It shows that while sovereign defaults in recent history have
been contained to a few small countries, the longer term history of
sovereign defaults is very different.

Exhibit 7: Historical sovereign default/restructuring events
As percentage of
world income

45
                                                  Share of countries in default
40
                                                                                         Which
35                                                                                       Scenario?

30                                                                                       Power
                            Defaults increased                                           re-balancing
25                             dramatically                                              scenario
                           during the previous
                          re-balancing of power
20

15                                                                                       Post-war
                                                                                         average
10                                                                                       Average of
                                                                                         last 20 years
 5
                                                                                         Recent
                                                                                         history
 0
 1800
 1807
 1814
 1821
 1828
 1835
 1842
 1849
 1856
 1863
 1870
 1877
 1884
 1891
 1898
 1905
 1912
 1919
 1926
 1933
 1940
 1947
 1954
 1961
 1968
 1975
 1982
 1989
 1996
 2003




                                                                                       2010-2015

Source: Reinhart, Carmen M and Rogoff, Kenneth S; This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial
Folly. ©2009 Princeton university Press. Reprinted by permission of Princeton university;
Oliver Wyman analysis




14                                                               Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Based on our analysis of this data, we think it makes sense to consider
four scenarios for how sovereign risk might evolve during the period of
our story (2011-15):

 Scenario severity                            Example scenario1
 (sovereigns in default or restructuring as
 a percentage of world GDP)
 Benign case                                  Default events limited to very minor economies such
 Recent history continues                     as Iceland

 1-2%
 Base case                                    Defaults limited to smaller Eurozone economies (e.g.
 Average from last 20 years                   Ireland, Greece and Portugal) and the occasional
                                              emerging market sovereign
 3-4%
 Bad case                                     Some of the bigger names in the Eurozone caught
 Return to post-war average                   in the contagion. China’s slowing economy causes
                                              instability and sovereign problems in the Asia
 8-10%                                        Pacific region
 Worst case                                   Doubts about the ability of the world’s most indebted
 Global power re-balancing                    economies (US, UK, Japan and Eurozone) to service
                                              their debt causes a global sovereign debt crisis
 20% +

1. The countries named in our examples are intended merely to give examples of the types of
countries that might get caught if default rates rise to the levels specified in our four scenarios.
In reality, if default rates rise to, say, 10%, the exact list of countries that would make up that
10% is difficult to predict; the reader should not attach too much weight to the names used in
our example.



Benign case
Over the last decade, sovereign default and restructurings have been
restricted to a few small countries, such as Iceland. Our most benign
scenario is therefore to assume that future default and restructuring
events continue to be limited to the smallest players on the
global scene.

Base case
Our base case assumes that sovereign default rates revert to the average
default rate observed over the last 20 years. The peripheral nations of
the Eurozone would be candidates for inclusion in this scenario, and
external shocks such as our commodities crisis could see some of the
larger emerging economies such as Brazil and Russia involved in the
problems. If the external shock comes from something other than
commodities then the countries involved could be very different.

Bad case
A worse scenario would see default rates rise up to their post-war
average. Under this scenario we might see problems in the Eurozone
spread to some of the bigger countries, such as Spain. The network
of exposures that exist between the Eurozone banks and sovereigns
could see some of the other larger Eurozone countries dragged down
and survival of the Euro currency in its current form brought into
question. Alternative scenarios of this magnitude might see a slowing


Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                                                        15
Chinese economy or rising food prices lead to political instability
which could destabilize the Asia Pacific region. There are many other
political hotspots, including problems in the Middle East or the Korean
peninsula, which could be the driver of future sovereign problems as
either civil unrest or war takes hold.

Worst case
Our worst-case scenario assumes that default rates move back up to
their historical peak based on the 200 years of data in the Reinhart
& Rogoff chart. This would represent the culmination of trends that
amount to a complete global rebalancing of economic power: most
likely from the US and European economies to the emerging markets.
From this perspective, the sub-prime crisis was merely the start of a
period of economic instability engendered by this realignment.

One way of interpreting the historical data in the chart is that the
transfer of power from the British Empire to the United States in the
first half of the 20th century caused a period of global instability that
ultimately led to the default of some of the world’s largest economies.
Only when the US emerged as the dominant economic and military
power at the end of WWII did the world enter a new period of
economic stability. In 1940 the British pound still accounted for two-
thirds of foreign currency reserves but by 1945 the US dollar had
become the global reserve currency.

We attach only a small probability to this severe version of a global
rebalancing scenario given that many of the historical defaults in
the early 20th century example were caused by massive wartime
spending combined with the destruction of a large proportion of the
world’s economic production capabilities. In addition, there is no clear
alternative to the US dollar as a reserve currency now that the Euro
has lost its luster (and it feels a little early, in our view, to be talking
about a Renminbi reserve currency).

Optimists might argue that the G20 will avoid the chaos in our more
adverse scenarios by resolving the global economic imbalances
through negotiation and careful management of the process. However,
the recent history of Greece and Ireland has shown that a nation
needs to be on its knees before it is willing to make these types
of concessions.




16                                               Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
3.	 What	financial	institutions	and	
regulators	might	learn	from	our	
pessimistic	scenario

The purpose of considering pessimistic scenarios, such as ours, is not
simply to depress readers. Our scenario is designed to “stress” the
new financial and regulatory system and uncover the weaknesses
that remain. In this section, based on these findings, we suggest
some possible changes in course for regulators and for those running
financial institutions.



3.1.	 Ideas	for	regulators

Prepare	for	crises

Our scenario should remind regulators that they cannot succeed in
creating a risk-free financial system and that future crises will occur.
William Shakespeare noted that there is a “tide in the affairs of men”
and we believe that any attempt to eliminate this natural tide is
neither achievable nor desirable. Regulators should encourage banks
and insurers to put as much effort into preparing for adverse events as
into modeling their probability. Many efforts have been focused on the
areas of contingency planning and resolution regimes but much more
can be done.


Do	not	force	risk	out	of	sight

Removing risk from the regulated banking sector sometimes merely
shifts it into the shadow banking sector, where it is harder for
supervisors to monitor and contain (see section 2.1 above). A financial
system in which more risk stays in the traditional or regulated sector
may be safer altogether. Regulators should avoid squeezing too hard,
especially given that a shadow banking crisis will almost certainly
precipitate failures in the regulated sector.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                         17
Focus	on	scenario	analysis	and	stress	testing

Many of the most successful initiatives that regulators have launched
recently have incorporated the use of stress testing and scenario
analysis to help financial institutions understand how much capital
                                                4
they need to guard against future crisis events . These approaches
are a useful complement to the internal models that currently lie
at the heart of financial regulation. We recommend that regulators
take these exercises further and make them a regular part of the
supervisory process.

In addition to requiring banks and insurers to run stress tests,
regulators should run scenarios to stress test their entire financial
system. As much as policymakers might reassure the public that it
will never happen, we would hope that behind closed doors European
regulators have, for example, assessed what might happen to their
financial system in the event of a break-up of the Eurozone. Like
financial institutions, regulators should have clear contingency plans
for dealing with such scenarios.


Follow	the	money

Another lesson from our scenario is that a financial crisis tends to be
preceded by a period of excessive profit generation. When trying to
identify risks, regulators should ask which businesses and investment
strategies are currently contributing most to the earnings growth of
financial institutions. There were notable examples from the previous
crisis where off-balance sheet SIV vehicles were at times generating
much of the profits of some large international banks.

Although we do not recommend regulators trying to micro-manage
financial institutions’ business decisions, one suggestion is that any
lines of business that are generating “super profits” should receive
additional attention from regulators. It may turn out that the next
generation of super-profitable businesses have manageable risks, but
we would not bet on it.




4    The Fed, CEBS and the UK FSA have all implemented successful bank stress testing
     exercises during the last few years and, in all three cases, the results of the exercises helped
     to identify vulnerable areas in the system and led to additional capital raising efforts by
     the banks




18                                                               Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Remove	subsidies

The scale of the damage caused by the recent crisis created an
understandable backlash against financial services and even raised
questions about the merits of free markets. We believe that financial
institutions should continue to play a key role in ensuring the efficient
allocation of capital and that the global economy will continue to
benefit from the free flow of trade and capital.

The most common source of “market failure” is governmental distortion
of prices, usually by way of taxes or subsidies. In the financial markets,
the most obvious such distortion arises from the implicit government
support for bank creditors. This effectively subsidizes bank risk-taking
by reducing the risk premia on banks’ debt funding. Requiring banks to
hold more and higher quality capital should help to counteract the risk
subsidy, and “living wills” and other measures aimed at imposing losses
on debt holders may help to eliminate the subsidy.

However, regulators should also address the other sources of price
distortion in markets that financial institutions operate in. These can
cover very diverse areas of public policy ranging from tax incentives
to housing policy to the existence of government-backed lending
institutions. A broader definition of price distortion might also include
the effects of quantitative easing and the expansion of central bank repo
facilities. As our scenario reminds us, such price distortions can cause
bubbles to form and changes in them can be a source of future risk.

We recommend that financial regulators work to understand how
market distortions might be perverting incentives and behavior in
their financial markets and to work with other policy makers to
eliminate them or, at least, to mitigate their impact.



3.2.	 Ideas	for	Financial	institutions

Let	your	risk	capabilities	shape	your	strategy

It is often said that a financial institution’s risk capabilities should
be better used to support business activities. We would go a step
further. Risk management is (or, at least, should be) what financial
institutions do well. Your risk capabilities should not merely support
your business activities but should drive your business strategy. If you
are trying to decide which markets to operate in, the first question
you should ask is whether you have the right risk management



Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                           19
capabilities to understand and manage the risks they present. The
same thinking can be extended to other functional capabilities, such
as your infrastructure and systems. Are you using these capabilities to
support, align or drive your business strategy? Our scenario highlights
the dangers of entering new markets where you lack the capabilities
required to back up your strategy.


Plan	with	scenarios
While working for Shell in the 1980s, Arie de Geus was a pioneer
in scenario-based planning. His approach built on the company’s
engineering heritage. Any engineer who builds a new bridge will
“stress” its design. Can the bridge withstand unusually heavy traffic?
Can it withstand heavy lateral wind? What happens if we try twisting
the bridge? Similarly, Shell began analyzing its business plans under
various possible external conditions.

Most financial institutions have something they would describe as a
“scenario-based planning” process, but it is a million miles away from
what Arie de Geus had in mind. They typically begin with a base case
forecast from which they then construct some alternative scenarios.
However, the thought put into the scenarios often amounts to little
more than “let’s move revenues and costs up and down by 20% and
see what happens”. Shell’s approach was, and still is, to invest a great
deal of effort into the articulation of alternative scenarios and then to
force senior managers to engage in a thorough discussion and analysis
of the scenarios as they apply to each business line. An illustration of
how this might work for a financial institution is shown below.

Exhibit 8: Scenario-based planning framework
                                      4 Iteration

1 Business plans
                                      2 Micro view – P&L by business under each scenario
    Current P&L and B/S by                                                       Historial scenarios                     Hypothetical scenarios
     business (2010)                                        Base      Equity     Asian     LTCM/     Sub-prime Commodities Eurozone CCP     Interest
                                      Business              Case      crash 87   crisis 97 Russia 98 crisis 08 crisis      crisis   blow up rate hike
    Growth plans by                  Retail                 100          80          60       90         -500        70       -300    70      130
     business (2011 to 2013)          Middle Market             50        20        20           50      -200       40        -230       40         40
                                      Specialized lending       30       -50      -150       -500       -1,500    -900        -450       20         40
    Starting capital and
                                      Capital Markets           60      -200       -80       -420        -400     -300       -1,600    -600        -150
     RWA position for entire          Insurance                 40        10        30       -120          20      -50        -350       -30       -200
     group (year-end 2010)            TOTAL                     280     -140       120       -900       -2,580   -1,120      -2,930    -500        -140




                    Macro view – commodities crisis

                    GDP              –                      +
                    Interest rates   –                      +                                3 Risk appetite constraints
                    Commodities      –                      +                                    Regulatory constraints
                    Equity           –                      +                                    Minimum capital ratios
                    Property         –                      +                                    Target credit rating
                                                                                                 Ability to pay dividend
                    Etc.                       Base




20                                                                                               Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Our commodities crisis scenario might be one of many adverse
scenarios to consider in such a framework. Another might be a
“CCP blow up” now that vast volumes of derivatives exposures
will be concentrated within these centrally cleared counterparties.
Some companies also include unusually benign scenarios to ensure
they all understand the full spectrum of opportunities during
planning discussions.

A more substantive scenario planning process would include
the following:

1. Each business unit submits its business plans and
   growth ambitions

2. These plans are stressed using the various scenarios (note: it
   is vital that the risk factor shocks used in the scenarios are
   set independently of the business, incorporating the views of
   risk management)

3. A number of criteria are checked to see whether the scenario
   combined with the business plans breaches the bank’s risk
   appetite statement

4. If the risk appetite is breached then the businesses must iterate
   their plans until the plans are consistent with the company’s risk
   appetite statement

Only a handful of financial institutions have anything close to these
scenario capabilities, either in terms of generating scenarios or using
them for planning. The true test of the integration of scenario analysis
into the planning process is the extent to which businesses modify
their growth plans as a result of the scenario outputs.

The example above focuses on the quantitative aspects of scenario
analysis but de Geus’ framework also encouraged senior management
to engage in a qualitative discussion of each scenario. A budgeting
process generally leads to a “consensus view” of the world where
individual opinions are lost. Scenario-based discussions allow people
to explore and develop individual opinions and to drill down into
areas of the business that might otherwise remain hidden.

Such an approach would elevate the status of risk managers that have
the ability to think laterally rather than the previous tendency to value
most highly those with the greatest quant skills. The narrower a risk
manager’s focus, the more likely they are to get sidelined and miss out
on the important discussions that shape the future of the company.
Any process that creates a closer working relationship between risk
managers and business people would be, in our view, a good thing.



Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                           21
Diversify	in	a	new	way
The textbook concept of diversification usually involves spreading
your bets across multiple assets, asset classes or markets. One of the
lessons from our crisis scenario is that, in a globally connected world,
the risks in different geographical markets may actually be highly
correlated. The sub-prime crisis, in particular, showed that credit
assets across the entire globe can simultaneously drop in value.

An alternative way for financial institutions to create diversification
is to find revenue sources that are either insensitive to the economic
cycle or are driven by sources of risk other than credit. These could
include investing in less cyclical businesses, such as payment systems
or for insurers, underwriting-driven products. Other ideas might
include developing retirement solutions for our aging populations
which would contain a new set of risks that are uncorrelated to credit
and equity risks. Given the low expected loan growth in developed
markets, such diversification may be necessary not only to avoid
future downside but to grow at all.


Lead	rather	than	follow
Our scenario includes two phases of herd behavior. The first involves
investors trying to squeeze into an already overcrowded market;
the second occurs when the same investors simultaneously rush
for the exits. It is the actions taken during this first phase that will
determine exposure to a crisis. Options during the second phase are
severely limited.

In the build up to the sub-prime crisis bank balance sheets became
more and more homogenous with all banks basically betting on
the same set of risks. Most banks jumped on the structured credit
bandwagon in one form or another, regardless of whether they had
any expertise or other advantage to bring to this market. Insurers
followed the banking “herd’, taking an investment grade credit rating
as an article of faith and building up large positions in “high quality”
structured credit for relatively small improvements in yield. We
are now seeing a similar type of herd behavior as banks rush into
emerging markets.

The alternative to herd behavior is leadership. By this we mean
leading your own organization down a path that is right for it based
on its ability to manage certain types of risks. This is easier said than
done. Once the herd starts running towards the new Promised Land,
only the strongest leaders can stand firm against criticism that they
are falling behind the pack.


22                                              Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Follow	the	money

As we highlight in the regulatory section above, bubbles are highly
correlated with super profits. Focusing additional board and executive
attention on extraordinary growth areas will help to prevent the
situation we experienced in the last crises where many in senior roles
did not fully understand the risks that accompanied the extraordinary
sources of profits at the time.


Be	patient

While our scenario paints a picture of doom and gloom, we should
remember that two of the greatest banking dynasties in history,
Rothschild and JP Morgan, emerged from the crises of 1815 and 1907
respectively. A conservative strategy that allows you to operate as a
safe haven in a storm can guarantee your future and provide many
opportunities to take actions from a position of strength.

It is also interesting to compare the timing of RBS’s acquisition of ABN
Amro to Barclays’ takeover of Lehman Brothers. No level of operational
or management savvy can fix the problem of having overpaid for an
asset. But the rewards can be great for those who pounce when the
time is right which often means waiting for a bubble to burst. Such
opportunities are, however, reserved for those that have resisted the
temptation to take too much risk during the boom period.


Accept	that	the	world	has	changed

All stakeholders in financial institutions must understand that their
world has changed. The last couple of decades of constantly falling
interest rates is over; customer demographics are shifting; regulations
are tightening. Trying to replay the successful strategies of the past
25 years will not work.

Highlighting the difficulty of accepting this change, many bank
executives have stated that their number one priority is “RoE
preservation” in the face of these new challenges. However, they need
to understand that with higher capital requirements, the returns
of the past are unsustainable. It is vital that bank shareholders
also understand this if we are to avoid the irresponsible risk taking
that might otherwise result. More dialogue is required between
shareholders and executives to agree realistic targets for the next
five years.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman                                           23
Conclusion

The financial crisis of 2008 shook politicians, bankers, regulators,
commentators and ordinary citizens out of the complacency created
by the 25 year “great moderation”. Yet, for all the rhetoric around a
new financial order, and all the improvements made, many of the
old risks remain. The basic regulatory framework – of bank debtor
guarantees and regulatory bank capital and liquidity minima (that is,
of risk subsidies and compensatory risk taxes) – has been maintained
with tweaked parameters. And, within this system, bank shareholders,
bondholders and executives still have incentives that might herd them
towards excessive risk taking. The crisis scenario described at the
beginning of this report can be seen as a continuation, after a breathing
space provided by taxpayer-funded bailouts, of the 2008 crisis.

Of course, events will not unfold precisely as described in our scenario.
But the observable fragilities in the global economy suggest that it
would take little to create a renewed crisis. Our purpose is not to
promote defeatism, but a sense of urgency. As argued above, regulators
should put less effort into holding the lid down on banks and more
into addressing the financial market distortions that fuel the pressure
under the lid. And bankers should use scenario analysis to take an
honest look at the risks to which their strategies expose them and
their institutions’ ability to manage them.

We called our story an “avoidable history”. Unfortunately, future crises
are not avoidable, but being a victim of the next one is.




24                                             Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
Oliver Wyman is an international management consulting firm that combines deep industry knowledge
with specialized expertise in strategy, operations, risk management, organizational transformation, and
leadership development.




Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman. All rights reserved. This report may not be reproduced or redistributed, in whole or in part, without the written
permission of Oliver Wyman and Oliver Wyman accepts no liability whatsoever for the actions of third parties in this respect.
The information and opinions in this report were prepared by Oliver Wyman.
This report is not a substitute for tailored professional advice on how a specific financial institution should execute its strategy. This report is not investment
advice and should not be relied on for such advice or as a substitute for consultation with professional accountants, tax, legal or financial advisers.
Oliver Wyman has made every effort to use reliable, up-to-date and comprehensive information and analysis, but all information is provided without
warranty of any kind, express or implied. Oliver Wyman disclaims any responsibility to update the information or conclusions in this report. Oliver Wyman
accepts no liability for any loss arising from any action taken or refrained from as a result of information contained in this report or any reports or sources
of information referred to herein, or for any consequential, special or similar damages even if advised of the possibility of such damages.
This report may not be sold without the written consent of Oliver Wyman.
For more information please contact the marketing department by email at info-FS@oliverwyman.com or by
phone at one of the following locations:

North America                       EMEA                                Asia Pacific
+1 212 541 8100                     +44 20 7333 8333                    +65 6510 9700

More Related Content

What's hot

Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013Fasanara Capital ltd
 
European banking presentation 20.04.2012
European banking presentation 20.04.2012European banking presentation 20.04.2012
European banking presentation 20.04.2012429287
 
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challenges
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challengesBanking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challenges
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challengesKarl Meekings
 
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets Luis Taveras EMBA, MS
 
20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff finalBruegel
 
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"Oliver Grave
 
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners 2011 outlook primer- final
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners   2011 outlook primer- finalMichael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners   2011 outlook primer- final
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners 2011 outlook primer- finalMichael Durante
 
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...SYRTO Project
 
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012Fasanara Capital ltd
 
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016Tyler Stuart
 
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...Alexander Decker
 
FMA of NH: Safeguarding Cash
FMA of NH: Safeguarding CashFMA of NH: Safeguarding Cash
FMA of NH: Safeguarding Cashtravismd
 
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel Race
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel RaceMichael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel Race
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel RaceMichael Durante
 
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 FinalMT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 FinalJim Welsh
 

What's hot (16)

Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook | May 3rd 2013
 
European banking presentation 20.04.2012
European banking presentation 20.04.2012European banking presentation 20.04.2012
European banking presentation 20.04.2012
 
mc project
mc projectmc project
mc project
 
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challenges
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challengesBanking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challenges
Banking-in-emerging-markets-seizing-opportunities-overcoming-challenges
 
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets
Corporate leverage in Emerging Markets
 
Mang of fin ins.
Mang of fin ins.Mang of fin ins.
Mang of fin ins.
 
20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final20130905 sapirwolff final
20130905 sapirwolff final
 
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"
Deloitte Report "Global Powers of Retail 2014"
 
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners 2011 outlook primer- final
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners   2011 outlook primer- finalMichael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners   2011 outlook primer- final
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners 2011 outlook primer- final
 
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...
The microstructure of the european sovereign bond market. Loriana Pellizzon. ...
 
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012
Fasanara Capital | Investment Outlook May 2012
 
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016
SJP Special Investment Bulletin Feb 2016
 
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...
Stock market performance of some selected nigerian commercial banks amidst ec...
 
FMA of NH: Safeguarding Cash
FMA of NH: Safeguarding CashFMA of NH: Safeguarding Cash
FMA of NH: Safeguarding Cash
 
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel Race
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel RaceMichael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel Race
Michael Durante Western Reserve Blackwall Partners Camel Race
 
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 FinalMT-Fundamental Recap  2007-2009 Final
MT-Fundamental Recap 2007-2009 Final
 

Viewers also liked

SOS presentation 19.11.2011
SOS presentation 19.11.2011SOS presentation 19.11.2011
SOS presentation 19.11.2011bsandeep75
 
Attijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieAttijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieOldman9 Old
 
Attijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieAttijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieOldman9 Old
 
Attijari Tunisie
Attijari TunisieAttijari Tunisie
Attijari TunisieOldman9 Old
 
Rachat septembre 10
Rachat septembre 10Rachat septembre 10
Rachat septembre 10Oldman9 Old
 
Resume mensuel 20111130
Resume mensuel 20111130Resume mensuel 20111130
Resume mensuel 20111130Oldman9 Old
 
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012www.bourse-maroc.org
 
Certification cartier
Certification cartierCertification cartier
Certification cartierOldman9 Old
 
Trimestriel boursier cdmc t1 2011 -
Trimestriel  boursier cdmc   t1  2011 -Trimestriel  boursier cdmc   t1  2011 -
Trimestriel boursier cdmc t1 2011 -Oldman9 Old
 
South African Scholarly Publishing Landscape
South African Scholarly Publishing LandscapeSouth African Scholarly Publishing Landscape
South African Scholarly Publishing LandscapeIna Smith
 
Mo xprof warning_fr
Mo xprof warning_frMo xprof warning_fr
Mo xprof warning_frOldman9 Old
 
African countries
African countriesAfrican countries
African countriesOldman9 Old
 
Hype vs. Reality: The AI Explainer
Hype vs. Reality: The AI ExplainerHype vs. Reality: The AI Explainer
Hype vs. Reality: The AI ExplainerLuminary Labs
 

Viewers also liked (19)

Tax
TaxTax
Tax
 
Health Booklet
Health BookletHealth Booklet
Health Booklet
 
SOS presentation 19.11.2011
SOS presentation 19.11.2011SOS presentation 19.11.2011
SOS presentation 19.11.2011
 
Attijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieAttijari tunisie
Attijari tunisie
 
Attijari tunisie
Attijari tunisieAttijari tunisie
Attijari tunisie
 
Attijari Tunisie
Attijari TunisieAttijari Tunisie
Attijari Tunisie
 
Holcim octobre
Holcim octobreHolcim octobre
Holcim octobre
 
Physio
PhysioPhysio
Physio
 
Rachat septembre 10
Rachat septembre 10Rachat septembre 10
Rachat septembre 10
 
Resume mensuel 20111130
Resume mensuel 20111130Resume mensuel 20111130
Resume mensuel 20111130
 
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012
M2M Résultats annuels consolides 2012
 
Col 2010 arb
Col 2010  arbCol 2010  arb
Col 2010 arb
 
Certification cartier
Certification cartierCertification cartier
Certification cartier
 
Trimestriel boursier cdmc t1 2011 -
Trimestriel  boursier cdmc   t1  2011 -Trimestriel  boursier cdmc   t1  2011 -
Trimestriel boursier cdmc t1 2011 -
 
South African Scholarly Publishing Landscape
South African Scholarly Publishing LandscapeSouth African Scholarly Publishing Landscape
South African Scholarly Publishing Landscape
 
Mo xprof warning_fr
Mo xprof warning_frMo xprof warning_fr
Mo xprof warning_fr
 
African countries
African countriesAfrican countries
African countries
 
Weekly
WeeklyWeekly
Weekly
 
Hype vs. Reality: The AI Explainer
Hype vs. Reality: The AI ExplainerHype vs. Reality: The AI Explainer
Hype vs. Reality: The AI Explainer
 

Similar to Crise

Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?
Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?
Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?Brien Desilets
 
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...Fernando Alcoforado
 
American crises in 2007 hard copy
American crises in 2007 hard copyAmerican crises in 2007 hard copy
American crises in 2007 hard copyDharmik
 
Explaining the Financial Crisis
Explaining the Financial CrisisExplaining the Financial Crisis
Explaining the Financial CrisisSal DB
 
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docx
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docxEndogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docx
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docxbudabrooks46239
 
Risk confronting the international banking systems
Risk confronting the  international banking systemsRisk confronting the  international banking systems
Risk confronting the international banking systemsDr.Teitey Emmanuel Ph.D
 
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore Global Financial Crisis and Singapore
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore Vikas Sharma
 
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banks
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banksPerspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banks
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banksInfosys Finacle
 
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...Kaan Sapanatan, CFA, CAIA
 
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16Robert Rosenberg
 
Recent development
Recent developmentRecent development
Recent developmentnileshsen
 
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008Viết Nội Dung
 
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private Equity
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private EquityEY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private Equity
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private EquityThorsten Lederer 托尔斯滕
 
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequencesWorld crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequencesFernando Alcoforado
 
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-success
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-successEY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-success
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-successKarl Meekings
 
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa 98 127
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa  98 1279.amalendu bhunia's rjfa  98 127
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa 98 127Alexander Decker
 

Similar to Crise (20)

Us crisis 2008
Us crisis 2008Us crisis 2008
Us crisis 2008
 
Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?
Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?
Will the US Rebound Cause Another Emerging Markets Crisis?
 
Ashar crisis
Ashar crisisAshar crisis
Ashar crisis
 
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...
Reflections on the global crisis of 2008 and its possible economic, social an...
 
American crises in 2007 hard copy
American crises in 2007 hard copyAmerican crises in 2007 hard copy
American crises in 2007 hard copy
 
Explaining the Financial Crisis
Explaining the Financial CrisisExplaining the Financial Crisis
Explaining the Financial Crisis
 
Inside job
Inside jobInside job
Inside job
 
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docx
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docxEndogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docx
Endogenous Developments in the financial sector that led to th.docx
 
Risk confronting the international banking systems
Risk confronting the  international banking systemsRisk confronting the  international banking systems
Risk confronting the international banking systems
 
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore Global Financial Crisis and Singapore
Global Financial Crisis and Singapore
 
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banks
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banksPerspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banks
Perspective: The rise and rise of emerging market banks
 
Ahmad crisis
Ahmad crisisAhmad crisis
Ahmad crisis
 
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...
Are Collateralized Loan Obligations the ticking time bomb that could trigger ...
 
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16
JRC 2016 Conference Newsletter 5-19-16
 
Recent development
Recent developmentRecent development
Recent development
 
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008
Thiet ke Bao cao thuong nien - Vietcapital 2008
 
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private Equity
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private EquityEY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private Equity
EY Global Market Outlook 2016 - Trends in Real Estate Private Equity
 
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequencesWorld crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
World crisis of 2008 and its economic, social and geopolitical consequences
 
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-success
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-successEY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-success
EY-Banking-in-emerging-markets-Investing-for-success
 
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa 98 127
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa  98 1279.amalendu bhunia's rjfa  98 127
9.amalendu bhunia's rjfa 98 127
 

More from Oldman9 Old

Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1Oldman9 Old
 
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119Oldman9 Old
 
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-fr
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-frMaroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-fr
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-frOldman9 Old
 
Diac salaf 20121008
Diac salaf 20121008Diac salaf 20121008
Diac salaf 20121008Oldman9 Old
 
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917Oldman9 Old
 
Rankings 2012 13
Rankings 2012 13Rankings 2012 13
Rankings 2012 13Oldman9 Old
 
Note d'orientation
Note d'orientationNote d'orientation
Note d'orientationOldman9 Old
 
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0Oldman9 Old
 
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1Oldman9 Old
 
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011Oldman9 Old
 
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-Oldman9 Old
 
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-Oldman9 Old
 
Secteur minier cdmc
Secteur minier cdmcSecteur minier cdmc
Secteur minier cdmcOldman9 Old
 
Ventillation des transactions
Ventillation des transactionsVentillation des transactions
Ventillation des transactionsOldman9 Old
 
Loi de protection des consommateurs
Loi de protection des consommateursLoi de protection des consommateurs
Loi de protection des consommateursOldman9 Old
 

More from Oldman9 Old (20)

Bmce
BmceBmce
Bmce
 
Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research portfolio strategy annuel 2012.pdf.v1
 
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119
Cp em ennakl_automobiles_20121119
 
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-fr
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-frMaroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-fr
Maroc telecom cp-resultats-9m-2012-fr
 
Diac salaf 20121008
Diac salaf 20121008Diac salaf 20121008
Diac salaf 20121008
 
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917
Cp cdvm diac_salaf_20120917
 
Sni
SniSni
Sni
 
Rankings 2012 13
Rankings 2012 13Rankings 2012 13
Rankings 2012 13
 
Note d'orientation
Note d'orientationNote d'orientation
Note d'orientation
 
Atw res 1_s_fr
Atw res 1_s_frAtw res 1_s_fr
Atw res 1_s_fr
 
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0
Cp mediaco post_ago_rapport_cac_0
 
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1
Bmce capital research flash holcim.pdf.v1
 
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011
Profil des investisseurs_t4_2011
 
Iam res 11va_fr
Iam res 11va_frIam res 11va_fr
Iam res 11va_fr
 
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
 
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-Stroc industrie  résultats provisoires 2011-
Stroc industrie résultats provisoires 2011-
 
Secteur minier cdmc
Secteur minier cdmcSecteur minier cdmc
Secteur minier cdmc
 
Iam
IamIam
Iam
 
Ventillation des transactions
Ventillation des transactionsVentillation des transactions
Ventillation des transactions
 
Loi de protection des consommateurs
Loi de protection des consommateursLoi de protection des consommateurs
Loi de protection des consommateurs
 

Crise

  • 1. STATE OF THE FINANCIAL SERVICES INDUSTRY | 2011 The Financial Crisis of 2015 An Avoidable History
  • 2.
  • 3. John Banks was woken by his phone at 3am on Sunday, April 26, 2015. John worked for Garland Brothers, a formerly British bank that had relocated its headquarters to Singapore in late 2011 as a result of what Garland’s CEO had described as “irreconcilable differences” between the bank and the UK regulators. The last three years had been the most exciting of John’s life. Having led the bank’s aggressive expansion into emerging markets wholesale activities, he had recently been promoted to its executive committee. John picked up the phone. It was the bank’s legal counsel, Peter Thompson, calling. He had dramatic news. Garland Brothers, one of the world’s oldest banks, would declare bankruptcy tomorrow. As he lay there in his spacious air-conditioned bedroom, unable to return to sleep, John tried to reconstruct the events of the last four years. Planting the seeds of failure At the beginning of 2011, the global economy was showing signs of finding a “new normal”. With the exception of a few smaller troubled economies, the world had returned to positive growth, and Western stock markets had returned to their levels prior to the Lehman crisis. Banks had started lending to each other again, becoming gradually less reliant on central bank funding. Insurers had rebuilt their capital positions back to pre-crisis levels. Ireland had joined Greece in the list of peripheral Euro countries requiring a bailout, but there was a general sense that the broader contagion problems had been contained. New bank (Basel III) and insurance (Solvency II, in Europe) regulatory regimes had been introduced and were designed to avoid a repeat of the sub-prime crisis. Banks were phasing in the new tougher controls around capital, liquidity and leverage, albeit over a relatively relaxed timeframe. The Basel Committee’s impact study had estimated that the largest banks needed to raise a total of €577 BN to meet the new standards, and several banks came to market in 2011 with multi- billion Euro rights issues. Beneath this relatively calm surface, however, trouble was brewing. Stakeholders in financial services firms wanted lower risk, but shareholders were still demanding high returns. Executives felt their institutions were holding more capital than they needed, and they were struggling to find investment opportunities that satisfied their shareholders’ return requirements. Despite attempts by central banks to inject liquidity into the system, loan growth in Western economies had ground to a halt as consumers continued to deleverage and companies remained reluctant to invest, uncertain of the future interest rate, tax and regulatory environment. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 1
  • 4. The ability of banks to generate fee income by re-packaging credit books had been eliminated by punitive new securitization rules. New consumer protection laws prevented the sale of complex derivatives to many customers. Proprietary trading by banks had been outlawed in many jurisdictions. The talented and ambitious employees of Western banks found themselves under-utilized in an industry that was starting to resemble a utility. They needed to find new outlets for their creativity and drive. Disappearing into the shadows Talent began shifting into the shadow banking sector. During the low interest rate environment of 2011, investors were desperate for alternative investments with additional yield. Assets under management in the shadow banking sector grew rapidly during 2011. Asset managers were promising “inflation busting” returns but many of the strategies were based on the short-term growth prospects of the hottest markets and often employed leverage to maximize gains. New types of specialist loan funds disintermediated the highly regulated banking sector by matching borrowers and investors directly. These funds tapped into the long-term liquidity pools of pension funds and insurance companies. Their pitch books described such investors as “advantaged holders of illiquid credit”. Lacking their own distribution channels, these funds relied on outsourced origination, either through banks or networks of “hungry” agents. Credit discipline was poor. Even at this early stage, the pattern was familiar, but regulators did not intervene. Because the asset flows were global and did not have banks at their center, no single regulatory body felt responsible. Go East (or South) young man! Other restless Western banks and bankers moved, not into the shadows, but into the heat of emerging markets. In contrast to the anti-banking sentiment growing in the West, many emerging markets jurisdictions were still viewed as “banker friendly”. At the same time, growth opportunities in emerging markets had already encouraged some banks to base their growth strategies on these markets. In early 2011, several small international banks closed down their Western wholesale subsidiaries and re-located them to Singapore or Hong Kong. Garland Brothers was the first British bank to make the move, giving up its UK base when it decided to relocate its headquarters to Singapore in late 2011. 2 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 5. Western banks tackled the emerging markets in different ways. Those that had already established deposit and customer bases in emerging markets continued to grow organically, employing a well-tested and consistent set of risk standards across markets regardless of regulatory inconsistencies. Other Western players, such as Garland Brothers, that were struggling to find an edge, employed unorthodox techniques to build a presence in the faster growing markets. Some began to build large wholesale divisions in Asia and set up complex legal entity structures to take advantage of inconsistencies across regulatory regimes. Sales of complex derivatives were once again producing a large proportion of many banks’ income. Lacking an emerging markets deposit franchise, many of these Western banks started to fund their emerging markets lending activities via the wholesale markets or by tapping domestic funding sources in the West. Problems in the Eurozone meant that many European banks were paying 200-300bps above LIBOR for funding back home, and there were few opportunities in Europe to lend out such funds profitably. European banks found that lending to emerging markets banks and governments was one of the few ways of generating a positive margin over their rising cost of funds. This was part of a general trend among Western banks of moving down the credit spectrum to pick up yield. Bubble creation Based on favorable demographic trends and continued liberalization, the growth story for emerging markets was accepted by almost everyone. However, much of the economic activity in these markets was buoyed by cheap money being pumped into the system by Western central banks. Commodities prices had acted as a sponge to soak up the excess global money supply, and commodities-rich emerging economies such as Brazil and Russia were the main beneficiaries. High commodities prices created strong incentives for these emerging economies to launch expensive development projects to dig more commodities out of the ground, creating a massive oversupply of commodities relative to the demand coming from the real economy. In the same way that over-valued property prices in the US had allowed people to go on debt-fueled spending sprees, the governments of commodities-rich economies started spending beyond their means. They fell into the familiar trap of borrowing from foreign investors to finance huge development projects justified by unrealistic valuations. Western banks built up large and concentrated loan exposures in these new and exciting growth markets. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 3
  • 6. The banking M&A market was turned on its head. Banks pursuing high growth strategies, particularly those focussed on lending to the booming commodities-rich economies, started to attract high market valuations and shareholder praise. In the second half of 2012 some of these banks made successful bids for some of the leading European players that had been cut down to a digestible size by the new anti- “too big to fail” regulations. The market was, once again, rewarding the riskiest strategies. Stakeholders and commentators began pressing risk-averse banks to mimic their bolder rivals. The narrative driving the global commodities bubble assumed a continuation of the increasing demand from China, which had become the largest commodities importer in the world. Any rumors of a slowing Chinese economy sent tremors through global markets. Much now depended on continued demand growth in China and continued appreciation of commodities prices. The bubble bursts Western central banks pumping cheap money into the financial system was seen by many as having the dual purposes of kick-starting Western economies and pressing China to appreciate its currency. Strict capital controls initially enabled the Chinese authorities to resist pressure on their currency. Yet the dramatic rises in commodities prices resulting from loose Western monetary policies eventually caused rampant inflation in China. China was forced to raise interest rates and appreciate its currency to bring inflation under control. The Western central banks had been granted their wish of an appreciating Chinese currency but with the unwanted side effect of a slowing Chinese economy and the reduction in global demand that came with it. Once the Chinese economy began to slow, investors quickly realized that the demand for commodities was unsustainable. Combined with the massive oversupply that had built up during the boom, this led to a collapse of commodities prices. Having borrowed to finance expensive development projects, the commodities-rich countries in Latin America and Africa and some of the world’s leading mining companies were suddenly the focus of a new debt crisis. In the same way that the sub-prime crisis led to a plethora of half-completed real estate development projects in the US, Ireland and Spain, the commodities crisis of 2013 left many expensive commodity exploration projects unfinished. 4 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 7. Western banks and insurers did not escape the consequences of the commodities crisis. Some, such as the Spanish banks, had built up direct exposure by financing Latin American development projects. Others, such as US insurers, had amassed indirect exposures through investments in infrastructure funds and bank debt. Inflation pressure in the US and UK during the commodities boom had forced the Bank of England and Fed to push through a series of interest rate hikes that forced many Western debtors that had been holding on since the sub- prime crisis, to finally to default on their debts. With growth in both developed and emerging markets suppressed, the world once again fell into recession. Judgement day for sovereigns The final phase of the crisis saw the US, UK and European debt mountains emerge as the ultimate source of global systemic risk. Long-term sovereign yields had been gradually rising during the last few years, but analysts had assumed that this was because of increasing inflationary expectations. With the advent of the new commodities lending crisis, rising sovereign yields were suddenly being attributed to the deteriorating solvency of the sovereigns. Their high debts, combined with increasing refinancing costs, made it apparent that the debt burden of many developed world sovereigns was unserviceable. It was judgement day for sovereigns. Those sovereigns that were highly indebted and needed to roll over large amounts of short-term debt were forced to either restructure their debts or accept bailout money from other healthier sovereigns. This period, which spanned 2013 to 2015, was the single biggest rebalancing of economic and political power since World War II. The final irony in the tale was that the large sovereign exposures that the banking system had built up as a result of the new liquidity buffer requirements left the banking system, once again, sitting on the edge of the abyss. Our unemployed protagonist As John ran through these facts it became clear to him that not enough had been learned from the sub-prime crisis. Bankers had gone chasing the next rainbow only to find another pot of toxic waste rather than a pot of gold. The new wave of regulations had proved ineffective at stopping another bubble from forming. John was struggling to understand what he should have done differently. Heads would certainly roll. But who was really to blame this time around? Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 5
  • 8. 1. The purpose and structure of this report The sub-prime crisis of 2007 will not be the last financial sector crisis. Even during the relative calm of the last 25 years, we witnessed the property crises of the early 90s, the Asia currency crisis, the LTCM/ Russia crisis and a number of other smaller emerging markets-led financial crises. We are due another crisis soon. Financial services executives and regulators have worked hard to design a safer and more stable financial system, but we will not know whether they have succeeded until it is tested by the next crisis. The first aim of our 2015 crisis scenario is to stress test the design of the new financial system, to consider how well it would stand up to this type of adverse scenario. The broader aim of the report is to encourage readers to think about the future financial system using several scenarios rather than basing decisions on a single predicted course of events. Shell Oil, guided by Arie de Geus1, was a pioneer in using scenario planning in the 1980s. De Geus claimed that the main purpose of using scenarios was to “think the unthinkable” and claimed that scenarios were “vastly superior in dealing with the future than predictions”. Strategists who focus on a single path of future events, he claimed, tend to filter out news that does not fit their view of the world. Companies with a single strategy or plan are “virtually blind” to new information. Our scenario is not a prediction. Our aim in describing it is to show that current efforts underway to create a better system should not be taken as an assurance that the system is now safe from future crises. Other plausible scenarios may show the same thing, though potentially with different strategic implications. We encourage you to use several such adverse scenarios in your planning, tailoring them to the risks facing your institution. The rest of this report is structured as follows. Section 2 presents supporting evidence for our scenario, showing that it is not as unlikely as we might hope. Then, in Section 3, we review some of the measures regulators and financial institutions are taking to limit the probability and severity of future crises and, based on lessons from our 2015 crisis scenario, we make some suggestions about what they could do differently. 1 See The Living Company by Arie de Geus, Harvard Business Press, 1997 6 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 9. 2. How plausible is our 2015 crisis scenario? In our scenario, the crisis has three principal drivers: the resurgence of shadow banking, the formation of emerging market asset bubbles and sovereign debt restructurings in developed markets. Below, we consider the likelihood of these three events. 2.1. The resurgence of shadow banking Definition of shadow banking By “shadow banking” we refer to credit intermediation, maturity transformation and liquidity transformation that takes place outside of the deposit-taking institutions that have access to central bank liquidity and whose depositors receive government guarantees (or deposit insurance). Money market mutual funds, structured investment vehicles, credit hedge funds, asset-backed commercial paper conduits and securities lenders are all, therefore, parts of the shadow banking system, though not the whole of it. Since the 1980s, shadow banking has grown even more rapidly than the official banking sector (see Exhibit 1). This growth has been caused in part by the real economic advantages of some shadow banking activities in matching the needs of investors and borrowers through product innovation. However, it has also been driven by “regulatory arbitrage”: that is, by the desire to hide leverage outside of the official banking sector, especially to avoid regulatory capital requirements. As can be seen in Exhibit 1, the liabilities of the shadow banking sector dropped rapidly during the recent crisis, showing that the official banking system was by comparison a safe place to keep your money. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 7
  • 10. Exhibit 1: Shadow Bank Liabilities vs. Traditional Bank Liabilities (US$ TN) 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Shadow Banking Traditional Liabilities Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States as of 2010:Q1 (FRB) and FRBNY The connections between shadow banking and the official banking sector When these off-balance sheet activities ran into trouble during the recent crisis, many banks were forced to bring the troubled assets back onto their balance sheets, in some cases to protect their reputations in the bond markets. In theory, the shadow banking system did not enjoy the same implicit support that is offered by governments to the banking system which is the main reason it has escaped the same level of regulatory scrutiny. However, given its scale and its connections with the official banking sector, governments could not allow many parts of the shadow banking sector to fail during the crisis. The AIG bailout and government support for money market funds that had promised never to “break the buck” are cases in point. Regulatory response The response from policy makers has been to increase the strictness of regulation for shadow banking. For example, the European Union recently approved a new Directive on Alternative Fund Managers which introduces official capital and reporting requirements. These regulations may constrain risk-taking at alternative fund managers, and other regulations may similarly constrain other known types of shadow banks. But shadow banking is a remarkably dynamic and opaque industry, and we are skeptical about the ability of regulators to control the quantity of risk it takes on. In a game of cat and mouse between regulators and shadow bankers, the mice will 8 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 11. win. There are far more mice; they are typically better informed and better motivated than the cats; and the extraordinary complexity of modern financial products and the global scope of the industry give the mice a nearly limitless supply of nooks and crannies to hide in. Squeezing the balloon The regulatory trend of coming down hard on the banks will increase the amount of risk in the shadow banking sector. The fundamental macro imbalances2 that are driving up levels of risk in the financial system will not be addressed by any of the new regulations. The only question is where these risks will go. Squeezing them out of the more transparent and manageable banking system could prove to be a mistake. Exhibit 2: The regulatory squeeze on banking Regulation Shadow Macro Banking banking imbalances Given the tendency of financial institutions to manage their risks by partially placing them in the shadow banking sector, there is also a strong possibility that the interconnectedness between the two systems will increase as the new rules create even greater incentives for regulatory arbitrage. Short of any reduction in the actual risks, and contrary to the instincts of vote-seeking politicians, the best way to avoid another bubble may be to loosen the regulatory vice on the banks. 2 For example, the trade imbalances between the US and China have actually grown during the crisis rather than having been diffused Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 9
  • 12. 2.2. Emerging markets asset bubbles In a study of emerging markets crises for the IMF in 19993, Graciela Kaminski observed that such crises tended to be “preceded by an explosion of international lending to emerging markets at very low real interest rates” and that the crises later erupted “as the industrialized countries engaged in extremely tight monetary policies”. In other words, emerging markets’ asset bubbles, and their bursting, are to a great extent effects of Western monetary policy. She then notes that the sudden “switch to contractionary monetary policy provoked a sharp rise in real interest rates, profound recessions in industrial countries, and plummeting commodity prices.” Our scenario builds on these historical observations and has a commodity price bubble at its center. The fallout from such an emerging markets crisis could be even more severe than in previous crises, with the biggest losers coming from the developed world. Western monetary policy is looser than ever, so the bubble could be unprecedented in size. And the high levels of indebtedness in developed economies means that they are in no position to absorb a rapid monetary tightening without experiencing a massive rise in insolvencies, including perhaps the insolvency of several developed world sovereigns. Below we outline in more detail the two phases of our scenario. Phase 1 describes the “bubble formation” while Phase 2 describes the “bursting of the bubble”. Exhibit 3: Phase 1 – Bubble formation Phase 1: Bubble formation Emerging markets – commodities exporters China – world’s largest commodities importer (LatAm, Africa, Australia) “Commodities narrative” Storage of Strong excess Real Real world Chinese commodities demand commodities economic supply demand CNY growth Speculative Undervalued Commodities demand Commodities Chinese Business case Commodities Chinese development CNY investors/ inflation price currency projects speculators concerns bubble CNY US$ Cheap debt financing US$ Speculative demand Currency peg Western banks Loose Commodities Weak Inflation monetary investors/ US currency concerns policy speculators US$ Western world (US, UK, Eurozone) – loose monetary policy 3 Currency and Banking Crises: The Early Warnings of Distress, Graciela Kaminsky, IMF Institute, 1999 10 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 13. During phase 1 we distinguish between two sources of demand affecting commodities prices: demand for use in the production of other goods (“real” demand) and demand for the purpose of price speculation (“speculative” demand). There are three major groups of players in our scenario. Firstly, there are economies, such as Latin America, Africa, Russia, Canada and Australia, which are the largest commodities producers. Secondly, there is China, which is now the world’s largest commodity importer. Thirdly, there are the developed world economies, such as the US, which are pumping liquidity into the financial system through their loose monetary policies. As with any bubble, our scenario contains a compelling narrative that allows investors to convince themselves that “this time is different”. In this case it is a story of strong economic growth coming from China creating a sustainable increase in demand for commodities. However, it is already apparent that increasing commodities prices are also creating inflationary pressure in China, which is exacerbated by China holding its currency artificially low by effectively pegging it to the US dollar. This makes commodities look like an attractive hedge against inflation for Chinese investors. The loose monetary policy in developed markets is similarly making commodities look attractive for Western investors. This “commodities rush” is demonstrated in the right-hand chart below, which shows the asset allocations of European and Asian investors. A recent investor survey by Barclays also found that 76% of investors predicted an even bigger inflow into commodities in 2011. Exhibit 4: The Commodities Rush CRX index vs. S&P 500 (Market value of European and Asian mutual fund equity of commodity-related companies) investments in commodities Index: 2005-05-31 = 100 €MM 450 40,000 CRX 400 35,000 350 30,000 300 25,000 250 20,000 200 15,000 150 S&P 500 10,000 100 50 5,000 0 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 20101 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 1. Based on Q3 data Source: Bloomberg, FERI, Oliver Wyman analysis Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 11
  • 14. Based on the currently inflated commodity prices, commodity producers in countries such as Brazil and Russia have clear business cases for investing in projects to dig more commodities out of the ground. As competition to launch such projects increases, the costs of completing them also starts to rise, with the owners of mining equipment and laborers capitalizing on the increased demand by charging higher rates. Because a portion of the demand for the projects is not coming from the real economy, an excess supply of mining capacity and commodities will be created. As with previous asset bubbles, we expect much of the debt financing for these projects to come from banks. And much of this bank financing is likely to be supplied by Western banks that are eager to preserve their diminishing return-on-equity and need to find lending opportunities that are sufficiently lucrative to cover their own increasing cost of funds. The balance sheets of life insurers will play a supporting role here, as insurers look for long-term investments that can match their liabilities and seek to earn additional illiquidity premia. Exhibit 5: Phase 2 – Bubble bursts: commodities price crash Phase 2: Bubble bursts – commodities price crash Emerging markets – commodities exporters China – major commodities importer Commodities narrative ends Massive oversupply of Fall in Slowing Currency commodities commodities economic allowed to demand growth appreciate Broken Commodities Commodities business case price Commodities Tightened development Spiraling crash CNY investors/ monetary projects inflation Rush speculators policy halted for exits US$ Debt crisis US$ Rush for exits Commodities Western investors/ banks speculators As a result of Phase 1 Tightened Inflation Commodities monetary pressure price policy bubble Western world – tightened monetary policy Whatever bursts the bubble, it will involve investors coming to doubt that the real demand for commodities is sustainable. For example, further trouble in the Eurozone or political instability in the Middle East or Asia could lead to concerns about global growth prospects and burst the bubble. In our scenario, we have made the “prick” a tightening of monetary policy in China in response to inflationary pressure caused by China’s hot economy and rising commodities prices. Once China’s currency appreciates and its economy slows, it will become clear that the commodities narrative is over optimistic. 12 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 15. At the first sign of trouble, the speculative investors will head for the exits, causing commodities prices to crash. Many development projects will be abandoned before completion. The parallels with the recent real estate development crisis are clear. Developed markets’ banks that lent to the developers will suffer large losses. The ensuing pressures on emerging market debt will also be felt by insurers that operate in these countries and invest a large proportion of their assets in local sovereign debt. How big could the losses be? Recent disclosures from mining companies and economies that export commodities suggest that several hundred billion dollars will be invested in commodities exploration projects in the coming years. Losses from a commodities debt crisis could therefore be on a similar scale to the $400 BN of direct losses that stemmed from the sub-prime crisis. However, the IMF now estimates that the combined direct and indirect losses stemming from the sub-prime crisis are more like $4 TN (a factor of 10 larger). Should we expect a similar multiplier effect in a commodities crisis? There are reasons to think so. Commodities prices are correlated with the broader economic growth of economies that are big commodities producers. The chart below demonstrates this for Latin America: Exhibit 6: Correlation between commodities prices and Latin American GDP Year-on-year growth 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% -10% -20% 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Commodities prices Latin American GDP Source: IMF commodities price and GDP data; Oliver Wyman analysis Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 13
  • 16. It is likely then that the prices of other assets classes in these economies, such as real estate, will rise and fall with commodities prices. We should expect significant additional losses for those who own these other asset classes, and for their financiers. 2.3. Sovereign debt crisis The next part of our scenario brings the 2015 crisis home to the Western sovereigns. A commodities crash driven by a bank-led financing boom would cause more problems for Western banks and, as with any price crash, create deflationary pressure. A return to worldwide recession would be a strong possibility. Do Western sovereigns have the debt servicing capacity to absorb another recession? In our scenario, they do not and the next step is the debt restructuring of some of the world’s leading sovereigns. Is there any historical precedence for such a dramatic sovereign default scenario? Alas, the answer is “yes”. The chart below is based on data compiled by the economic historians Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff. It shows that while sovereign defaults in recent history have been contained to a few small countries, the longer term history of sovereign defaults is very different. Exhibit 7: Historical sovereign default/restructuring events As percentage of world income 45 Share of countries in default 40 Which 35 Scenario? 30 Power Defaults increased re-balancing 25 dramatically scenario during the previous re-balancing of power 20 15 Post-war average 10 Average of last 20 years 5 Recent history 0 1800 1807 1814 1821 1828 1835 1842 1849 1856 1863 1870 1877 1884 1891 1898 1905 1912 1919 1926 1933 1940 1947 1954 1961 1968 1975 1982 1989 1996 2003 2010-2015 Source: Reinhart, Carmen M and Rogoff, Kenneth S; This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. ©2009 Princeton university Press. Reprinted by permission of Princeton university; Oliver Wyman analysis 14 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 17. Based on our analysis of this data, we think it makes sense to consider four scenarios for how sovereign risk might evolve during the period of our story (2011-15): Scenario severity Example scenario1 (sovereigns in default or restructuring as a percentage of world GDP) Benign case Default events limited to very minor economies such Recent history continues as Iceland 1-2% Base case Defaults limited to smaller Eurozone economies (e.g. Average from last 20 years Ireland, Greece and Portugal) and the occasional emerging market sovereign 3-4% Bad case Some of the bigger names in the Eurozone caught Return to post-war average in the contagion. China’s slowing economy causes instability and sovereign problems in the Asia 8-10% Pacific region Worst case Doubts about the ability of the world’s most indebted Global power re-balancing economies (US, UK, Japan and Eurozone) to service their debt causes a global sovereign debt crisis 20% + 1. The countries named in our examples are intended merely to give examples of the types of countries that might get caught if default rates rise to the levels specified in our four scenarios. In reality, if default rates rise to, say, 10%, the exact list of countries that would make up that 10% is difficult to predict; the reader should not attach too much weight to the names used in our example. Benign case Over the last decade, sovereign default and restructurings have been restricted to a few small countries, such as Iceland. Our most benign scenario is therefore to assume that future default and restructuring events continue to be limited to the smallest players on the global scene. Base case Our base case assumes that sovereign default rates revert to the average default rate observed over the last 20 years. The peripheral nations of the Eurozone would be candidates for inclusion in this scenario, and external shocks such as our commodities crisis could see some of the larger emerging economies such as Brazil and Russia involved in the problems. If the external shock comes from something other than commodities then the countries involved could be very different. Bad case A worse scenario would see default rates rise up to their post-war average. Under this scenario we might see problems in the Eurozone spread to some of the bigger countries, such as Spain. The network of exposures that exist between the Eurozone banks and sovereigns could see some of the other larger Eurozone countries dragged down and survival of the Euro currency in its current form brought into question. Alternative scenarios of this magnitude might see a slowing Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 15
  • 18. Chinese economy or rising food prices lead to political instability which could destabilize the Asia Pacific region. There are many other political hotspots, including problems in the Middle East or the Korean peninsula, which could be the driver of future sovereign problems as either civil unrest or war takes hold. Worst case Our worst-case scenario assumes that default rates move back up to their historical peak based on the 200 years of data in the Reinhart & Rogoff chart. This would represent the culmination of trends that amount to a complete global rebalancing of economic power: most likely from the US and European economies to the emerging markets. From this perspective, the sub-prime crisis was merely the start of a period of economic instability engendered by this realignment. One way of interpreting the historical data in the chart is that the transfer of power from the British Empire to the United States in the first half of the 20th century caused a period of global instability that ultimately led to the default of some of the world’s largest economies. Only when the US emerged as the dominant economic and military power at the end of WWII did the world enter a new period of economic stability. In 1940 the British pound still accounted for two- thirds of foreign currency reserves but by 1945 the US dollar had become the global reserve currency. We attach only a small probability to this severe version of a global rebalancing scenario given that many of the historical defaults in the early 20th century example were caused by massive wartime spending combined with the destruction of a large proportion of the world’s economic production capabilities. In addition, there is no clear alternative to the US dollar as a reserve currency now that the Euro has lost its luster (and it feels a little early, in our view, to be talking about a Renminbi reserve currency). Optimists might argue that the G20 will avoid the chaos in our more adverse scenarios by resolving the global economic imbalances through negotiation and careful management of the process. However, the recent history of Greece and Ireland has shown that a nation needs to be on its knees before it is willing to make these types of concessions. 16 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 19. 3. What financial institutions and regulators might learn from our pessimistic scenario The purpose of considering pessimistic scenarios, such as ours, is not simply to depress readers. Our scenario is designed to “stress” the new financial and regulatory system and uncover the weaknesses that remain. In this section, based on these findings, we suggest some possible changes in course for regulators and for those running financial institutions. 3.1. Ideas for regulators Prepare for crises Our scenario should remind regulators that they cannot succeed in creating a risk-free financial system and that future crises will occur. William Shakespeare noted that there is a “tide in the affairs of men” and we believe that any attempt to eliminate this natural tide is neither achievable nor desirable. Regulators should encourage banks and insurers to put as much effort into preparing for adverse events as into modeling their probability. Many efforts have been focused on the areas of contingency planning and resolution regimes but much more can be done. Do not force risk out of sight Removing risk from the regulated banking sector sometimes merely shifts it into the shadow banking sector, where it is harder for supervisors to monitor and contain (see section 2.1 above). A financial system in which more risk stays in the traditional or regulated sector may be safer altogether. Regulators should avoid squeezing too hard, especially given that a shadow banking crisis will almost certainly precipitate failures in the regulated sector. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 17
  • 20. Focus on scenario analysis and stress testing Many of the most successful initiatives that regulators have launched recently have incorporated the use of stress testing and scenario analysis to help financial institutions understand how much capital 4 they need to guard against future crisis events . These approaches are a useful complement to the internal models that currently lie at the heart of financial regulation. We recommend that regulators take these exercises further and make them a regular part of the supervisory process. In addition to requiring banks and insurers to run stress tests, regulators should run scenarios to stress test their entire financial system. As much as policymakers might reassure the public that it will never happen, we would hope that behind closed doors European regulators have, for example, assessed what might happen to their financial system in the event of a break-up of the Eurozone. Like financial institutions, regulators should have clear contingency plans for dealing with such scenarios. Follow the money Another lesson from our scenario is that a financial crisis tends to be preceded by a period of excessive profit generation. When trying to identify risks, regulators should ask which businesses and investment strategies are currently contributing most to the earnings growth of financial institutions. There were notable examples from the previous crisis where off-balance sheet SIV vehicles were at times generating much of the profits of some large international banks. Although we do not recommend regulators trying to micro-manage financial institutions’ business decisions, one suggestion is that any lines of business that are generating “super profits” should receive additional attention from regulators. It may turn out that the next generation of super-profitable businesses have manageable risks, but we would not bet on it. 4 The Fed, CEBS and the UK FSA have all implemented successful bank stress testing exercises during the last few years and, in all three cases, the results of the exercises helped to identify vulnerable areas in the system and led to additional capital raising efforts by the banks 18 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 21. Remove subsidies The scale of the damage caused by the recent crisis created an understandable backlash against financial services and even raised questions about the merits of free markets. We believe that financial institutions should continue to play a key role in ensuring the efficient allocation of capital and that the global economy will continue to benefit from the free flow of trade and capital. The most common source of “market failure” is governmental distortion of prices, usually by way of taxes or subsidies. In the financial markets, the most obvious such distortion arises from the implicit government support for bank creditors. This effectively subsidizes bank risk-taking by reducing the risk premia on banks’ debt funding. Requiring banks to hold more and higher quality capital should help to counteract the risk subsidy, and “living wills” and other measures aimed at imposing losses on debt holders may help to eliminate the subsidy. However, regulators should also address the other sources of price distortion in markets that financial institutions operate in. These can cover very diverse areas of public policy ranging from tax incentives to housing policy to the existence of government-backed lending institutions. A broader definition of price distortion might also include the effects of quantitative easing and the expansion of central bank repo facilities. As our scenario reminds us, such price distortions can cause bubbles to form and changes in them can be a source of future risk. We recommend that financial regulators work to understand how market distortions might be perverting incentives and behavior in their financial markets and to work with other policy makers to eliminate them or, at least, to mitigate their impact. 3.2. Ideas for Financial institutions Let your risk capabilities shape your strategy It is often said that a financial institution’s risk capabilities should be better used to support business activities. We would go a step further. Risk management is (or, at least, should be) what financial institutions do well. Your risk capabilities should not merely support your business activities but should drive your business strategy. If you are trying to decide which markets to operate in, the first question you should ask is whether you have the right risk management Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 19
  • 22. capabilities to understand and manage the risks they present. The same thinking can be extended to other functional capabilities, such as your infrastructure and systems. Are you using these capabilities to support, align or drive your business strategy? Our scenario highlights the dangers of entering new markets where you lack the capabilities required to back up your strategy. Plan with scenarios While working for Shell in the 1980s, Arie de Geus was a pioneer in scenario-based planning. His approach built on the company’s engineering heritage. Any engineer who builds a new bridge will “stress” its design. Can the bridge withstand unusually heavy traffic? Can it withstand heavy lateral wind? What happens if we try twisting the bridge? Similarly, Shell began analyzing its business plans under various possible external conditions. Most financial institutions have something they would describe as a “scenario-based planning” process, but it is a million miles away from what Arie de Geus had in mind. They typically begin with a base case forecast from which they then construct some alternative scenarios. However, the thought put into the scenarios often amounts to little more than “let’s move revenues and costs up and down by 20% and see what happens”. Shell’s approach was, and still is, to invest a great deal of effort into the articulation of alternative scenarios and then to force senior managers to engage in a thorough discussion and analysis of the scenarios as they apply to each business line. An illustration of how this might work for a financial institution is shown below. Exhibit 8: Scenario-based planning framework 4 Iteration 1 Business plans 2 Micro view – P&L by business under each scenario  Current P&L and B/S by Historial scenarios Hypothetical scenarios business (2010) Base Equity Asian LTCM/ Sub-prime Commodities Eurozone CCP Interest Business Case crash 87 crisis 97 Russia 98 crisis 08 crisis crisis blow up rate hike  Growth plans by Retail 100 80 60 90 -500 70 -300 70 130 business (2011 to 2013) Middle Market 50 20 20 50 -200 40 -230 40 40 Specialized lending 30 -50 -150 -500 -1,500 -900 -450 20 40  Starting capital and Capital Markets 60 -200 -80 -420 -400 -300 -1,600 -600 -150 RWA position for entire Insurance 40 10 30 -120 20 -50 -350 -30 -200 group (year-end 2010) TOTAL 280 -140 120 -900 -2,580 -1,120 -2,930 -500 -140 Macro view – commodities crisis GDP – + Interest rates – + 3 Risk appetite constraints Commodities – +  Regulatory constraints Equity – +  Minimum capital ratios Property – +  Target credit rating  Ability to pay dividend Etc. Base 20 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 23. Our commodities crisis scenario might be one of many adverse scenarios to consider in such a framework. Another might be a “CCP blow up” now that vast volumes of derivatives exposures will be concentrated within these centrally cleared counterparties. Some companies also include unusually benign scenarios to ensure they all understand the full spectrum of opportunities during planning discussions. A more substantive scenario planning process would include the following: 1. Each business unit submits its business plans and growth ambitions 2. These plans are stressed using the various scenarios (note: it is vital that the risk factor shocks used in the scenarios are set independently of the business, incorporating the views of risk management) 3. A number of criteria are checked to see whether the scenario combined with the business plans breaches the bank’s risk appetite statement 4. If the risk appetite is breached then the businesses must iterate their plans until the plans are consistent with the company’s risk appetite statement Only a handful of financial institutions have anything close to these scenario capabilities, either in terms of generating scenarios or using them for planning. The true test of the integration of scenario analysis into the planning process is the extent to which businesses modify their growth plans as a result of the scenario outputs. The example above focuses on the quantitative aspects of scenario analysis but de Geus’ framework also encouraged senior management to engage in a qualitative discussion of each scenario. A budgeting process generally leads to a “consensus view” of the world where individual opinions are lost. Scenario-based discussions allow people to explore and develop individual opinions and to drill down into areas of the business that might otherwise remain hidden. Such an approach would elevate the status of risk managers that have the ability to think laterally rather than the previous tendency to value most highly those with the greatest quant skills. The narrower a risk manager’s focus, the more likely they are to get sidelined and miss out on the important discussions that shape the future of the company. Any process that creates a closer working relationship between risk managers and business people would be, in our view, a good thing. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 21
  • 24. Diversify in a new way The textbook concept of diversification usually involves spreading your bets across multiple assets, asset classes or markets. One of the lessons from our crisis scenario is that, in a globally connected world, the risks in different geographical markets may actually be highly correlated. The sub-prime crisis, in particular, showed that credit assets across the entire globe can simultaneously drop in value. An alternative way for financial institutions to create diversification is to find revenue sources that are either insensitive to the economic cycle or are driven by sources of risk other than credit. These could include investing in less cyclical businesses, such as payment systems or for insurers, underwriting-driven products. Other ideas might include developing retirement solutions for our aging populations which would contain a new set of risks that are uncorrelated to credit and equity risks. Given the low expected loan growth in developed markets, such diversification may be necessary not only to avoid future downside but to grow at all. Lead rather than follow Our scenario includes two phases of herd behavior. The first involves investors trying to squeeze into an already overcrowded market; the second occurs when the same investors simultaneously rush for the exits. It is the actions taken during this first phase that will determine exposure to a crisis. Options during the second phase are severely limited. In the build up to the sub-prime crisis bank balance sheets became more and more homogenous with all banks basically betting on the same set of risks. Most banks jumped on the structured credit bandwagon in one form or another, regardless of whether they had any expertise or other advantage to bring to this market. Insurers followed the banking “herd’, taking an investment grade credit rating as an article of faith and building up large positions in “high quality” structured credit for relatively small improvements in yield. We are now seeing a similar type of herd behavior as banks rush into emerging markets. The alternative to herd behavior is leadership. By this we mean leading your own organization down a path that is right for it based on its ability to manage certain types of risks. This is easier said than done. Once the herd starts running towards the new Promised Land, only the strongest leaders can stand firm against criticism that they are falling behind the pack. 22 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 25. Follow the money As we highlight in the regulatory section above, bubbles are highly correlated with super profits. Focusing additional board and executive attention on extraordinary growth areas will help to prevent the situation we experienced in the last crises where many in senior roles did not fully understand the risks that accompanied the extraordinary sources of profits at the time. Be patient While our scenario paints a picture of doom and gloom, we should remember that two of the greatest banking dynasties in history, Rothschild and JP Morgan, emerged from the crises of 1815 and 1907 respectively. A conservative strategy that allows you to operate as a safe haven in a storm can guarantee your future and provide many opportunities to take actions from a position of strength. It is also interesting to compare the timing of RBS’s acquisition of ABN Amro to Barclays’ takeover of Lehman Brothers. No level of operational or management savvy can fix the problem of having overpaid for an asset. But the rewards can be great for those who pounce when the time is right which often means waiting for a bubble to burst. Such opportunities are, however, reserved for those that have resisted the temptation to take too much risk during the boom period. Accept that the world has changed All stakeholders in financial institutions must understand that their world has changed. The last couple of decades of constantly falling interest rates is over; customer demographics are shifting; regulations are tightening. Trying to replay the successful strategies of the past 25 years will not work. Highlighting the difficulty of accepting this change, many bank executives have stated that their number one priority is “RoE preservation” in the face of these new challenges. However, they need to understand that with higher capital requirements, the returns of the past are unsustainable. It is vital that bank shareholders also understand this if we are to avoid the irresponsible risk taking that might otherwise result. More dialogue is required between shareholders and executives to agree realistic targets for the next five years. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman 23
  • 26. Conclusion The financial crisis of 2008 shook politicians, bankers, regulators, commentators and ordinary citizens out of the complacency created by the 25 year “great moderation”. Yet, for all the rhetoric around a new financial order, and all the improvements made, many of the old risks remain. The basic regulatory framework – of bank debtor guarantees and regulatory bank capital and liquidity minima (that is, of risk subsidies and compensatory risk taxes) – has been maintained with tweaked parameters. And, within this system, bank shareholders, bondholders and executives still have incentives that might herd them towards excessive risk taking. The crisis scenario described at the beginning of this report can be seen as a continuation, after a breathing space provided by taxpayer-funded bailouts, of the 2008 crisis. Of course, events will not unfold precisely as described in our scenario. But the observable fragilities in the global economy suggest that it would take little to create a renewed crisis. Our purpose is not to promote defeatism, but a sense of urgency. As argued above, regulators should put less effort into holding the lid down on banks and more into addressing the financial market distortions that fuel the pressure under the lid. And bankers should use scenario analysis to take an honest look at the risks to which their strategies expose them and their institutions’ ability to manage them. We called our story an “avoidable history”. Unfortunately, future crises are not avoidable, but being a victim of the next one is. 24 Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman
  • 27. Oliver Wyman is an international management consulting firm that combines deep industry knowledge with specialized expertise in strategy, operations, risk management, organizational transformation, and leadership development. Copyright © 2011 Oliver Wyman. All rights reserved. This report may not be reproduced or redistributed, in whole or in part, without the written permission of Oliver Wyman and Oliver Wyman accepts no liability whatsoever for the actions of third parties in this respect. The information and opinions in this report were prepared by Oliver Wyman. This report is not a substitute for tailored professional advice on how a specific financial institution should execute its strategy. This report is not investment advice and should not be relied on for such advice or as a substitute for consultation with professional accountants, tax, legal or financial advisers. Oliver Wyman has made every effort to use reliable, up-to-date and comprehensive information and analysis, but all information is provided without warranty of any kind, express or implied. Oliver Wyman disclaims any responsibility to update the information or conclusions in this report. Oliver Wyman accepts no liability for any loss arising from any action taken or refrained from as a result of information contained in this report or any reports or sources of information referred to herein, or for any consequential, special or similar damages even if advised of the possibility of such damages. This report may not be sold without the written consent of Oliver Wyman.
  • 28. For more information please contact the marketing department by email at info-FS@oliverwyman.com or by phone at one of the following locations: North America EMEA Asia Pacific +1 212 541 8100 +44 20 7333 8333 +65 6510 9700