Uploaded on

 

More in: Technology , Education
  • Full Name Full Name Comment goes here.
    Are you sure you want to
    Your message goes here
    Be the first to comment
    Be the first to like this
No Downloads

Views

Total Views
890
On Slideshare
0
From Embeds
0
Number of Embeds
1

Actions

Shares
Downloads
7
Comments
0
Likes
0

Embeds 0

No embeds

Report content

Flagged as inappropriate Flag as inappropriate
Flag as inappropriate

Select your reason for flagging this presentation as inappropriate.

Cancel
    No notes for slide

Transcript

  • 1. ECON 377/477
  • 2. Topic 1.2
    Production functions
  • 3. Outline
    Introduction
    Properties
    Quantities of interest
    An example
    Short-run production functions
    Transformation functions
    3
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 4. Introduction
    Consider a firm that uses amounts of N inputs to produce a single output
    The technological possibilities of such a firm can be summarised using the production function:
    q = f(x)
    where q is output and x = (x1, x2, …, xN)׳ is an Nx1 vector of inputs
    We assume these inputs are under the control of the decision maker
    4
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 5. Properties
    Non-negativity: the value of f(x) is a finite, non-negative, real number
    Weak essentiality: the production of positive output is impossible without the use of at least one input
    Non-decreasing in x (monotonicity): additional units of an input will not decrease output , i.e. if x0≥ x1, then f(x0)≥ f(x1)
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
    5
  • 6. Properties
    Concave in x: Any linear combination of the vectors x0 and x1 will produce an output that is no less than the same linear combination of f(x0) and f(x1)
    Formally, f(θx0) + (1 – θ)x1 ≥ θ f(x0) + (1 – θ)f(x1)
    If the production function is continuously differentiable, concavity implies that all marginal products (MPs) are non-increasing (the law of diminishing marginal productivity)
    6
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 7. Properties
    The diagram on the next slide depicts a production function defined over a single input, x
    The values of q are all non-negative and finite real numbers for the values of x represented on the horizontal axis (non-negativity)
    The function passes through the origin (weak essentiality)
    The MP of x is positive at all points between the origin and point G (monotonicity) but monotonicity is violated on the curved segment GR
    7
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 8. q
    MP at G = 0
    G
    E
    AP at E is the slope of the ray through the origin and E
    R
    q = f(x)
    Point of optimal scale
    D
    x
    0
    Concavity violated
    Feasible region
    Monotonicity violated
  • 9. Properties
    As we move along the production function from the origin to point D, MPx increases
    Thus, the concavity property is violated at these points
    But concavity is satisfied at all points on the curve segment DR
    9
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 10. Properties
    Extending the graphical analysis to the multiple-input case is difficult
    In such cases it is common practice to plot the relationship between two of the variables while holding all others fixed
    We now consider a two-input production function and plot the relationship between the inputs x1 and x2 while holding output fixed at the values q0
    10
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 11. Properties
    We also plot the relationship between the two inputs when output is fixed at the values q1 and q2, where q2 > q1 > q0 (output isoquants), shown in the diagram on the next slide
    If properties are satisfied, these isoquants are non-intersecting functions that are convex to the origin, as depicted
    The slope of the isoquant is the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) that measures the rate at which x1 must be substituted for x2 in order to keep output at its fixed level
    11
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 12. x2
    F
    F(x1,x2) = q2
    MRTS at F = slope of the isoquant at F
    F(x1,x2) = q1
    F(x1,x2) = q0
    x1
    0
    12
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 13. Properties
    An alternative representation of a two-input production function is provided in the diagram on the next slide
    The lowest of the four functions plots the relationship between q and x1:
    The value of x2 is held fixed
    The other functions plot the relationship between q and x1 when x2 is fixed at different values
    13
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 14. q
    0
    x1
    14
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 15. Quantities of interest
    If the production function is twice-continuously differentiable we can use calculus to define a number of economic quantities of interest
    For example, two quantities we have already encountered are the MP and the MRTS
    Related concepts that do not depend on units of measurement are the output elasticity and the direct elasticity of substitution, which is usually denoted as σin the two-input case
    15
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 16. Quantities of interest
    In the next slide, an infinitesimal movement from one side of point A to the other results in an infinitesimal change in the input ratio but an infinitely large change in the MRTS, implying that σ = 0
    Thus, in the case of a right-angled isoquant, an efficient firm must use its inputs in fixed proportions
    That is, no input substitution is possible
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
    16
  • 17. x2
    σ = 0
    A
    x1
    0
    17
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 18. Quantities of interest
    In the next slide, a movement from D to E results in a large percentage change in the input ratio but leaves the MRTS unchanged
    This result implies that the isoquant is a straight line and inputs are perfect substitutes
    18
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 19. x2
    D
    σ = infinity
    E
    x1
    0
    19
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 20. Quantities of interest
    In the next slide, an intermediate (and more common) case is depicted where σ lies somewhere between zero and infinity
    20
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 21. x2
    σ lies between zero and infinity
    x1
    0
    21
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 22. Quantities of interest
    In the multiple-input case it is possible to define at least two other elasticities of substitution: the Allen partial elasticity of substitution (AES) and the Morishima elasticity of substitution (MES)
    The DES is sometimes regarded as a short-run elasticity because it measures substitutability between xn and xm while holding all other inputs fixed
    22
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 23. Quantities of interest
    Economists use the term, short-run, to refer to time horizons so short that at least one input is fixed
    The AES and MES are long-run elasticities because they allow all inputs to vary
    When there are only two inputs, DES = AES
    23
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 24. Quantities of interest
    The MP measures the output response when one input is varied and all other inputs are held fixed
    But we are often interested in measuring output response when all inputs are varied simultaneously
    If a proportionate increase in all inputs results in a less than proportionate increase in output, then we say the production function exhibits decreasing returns to scale (DRS)
    24
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 25. Quantities of interest
    If a proportionate increase in inputs results in the same proportionate increase in output, the production function is said to exhibit constant returns to scale (CRS)
    If a proportionate increase inputs leads to a more than proportionate increase in output the production function exhibits increasing returns to scale (IRS)
    There are many reasons why firms may experience different returns to scale
    25
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 26. Quantities of interest
    A widely used measure of returns to scale is the elasticity of scale or total elasticity of production
    The production function exhibits locally DRS, CRS or IRS as the elasticity of scale is less than, equal to or greater than 1
    For the Cobb-Douglas production function defined over N inputs:
    q = ax1β1x2β2 … xNβN
    The output elasticities are En = Σβnfor n = 1, …, N
    26
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 27. An example
    Refer to pages 18-19 for an example illustrating the computation of MPs and elasticities in a two-input Cobb-Douglas production function
    27
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 28. Short-run production functions
    Short-run production functions are obtained by holding one or more inputs fixed
    Consider equation (2.10) on page 18 of CROB:
    q = 2x10.5x20.4
    If x2 were fixed at 100 in the short run, the short-run production function would be:
    q = 2x10.51000.4, = 12.619x10.5
    This function is depicted in the diagram on the next slide, along with another function based on the assumption that x2 is fixed at 150, when:
    q = 14.841x10.5
    28
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 29. Short-run production functions
    q = 2x10.51500.4, = 14.841x10.5
    q = 2x10.51000.4, = 12.619x10.5
    29
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 30. Short-run production functions
    A family of short-run production functions could be constructed in this way, each of which satisfies the four properties outlined above
    As a group, this family could be viewed as a long-run production function because it depicts the production possibilities of the firm when both inputs vary
    30
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2
  • 31. Transformation functions
    The production function concept can be generalised to more than one output
    The technological possibilities of a firm that uses N inputs to produce M outputs can be summarised by the transformation function:
    T(x,q) = 0
    where q = (q1, q2, …, qM)׳ is an Mx1 vector of outputs
    Transformation functions are special cases of distance functions, which are discussed in detail later
    31
    ECON377/477 Topic 1.2