SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 40
Download to read offline
The Success
of Small
Countries
July 2014
Research InstituteThought leadership from Credit Suisse Research
and the world’s foremost experts
Contents
03	Introduction
04	 The debate
06	Success:
Size, age, trade and heterogeneity
12	 Intangible infrastructure
19	 Efficiencies or inefficiencies of scale?
26	 The break-up of Czechoslovakia
28	 German re-unification
30	 Cities and corporations
36	References
39	 Imprint / Disclaimer
COVERPHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/OTMARW,PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/ALIJA
For more information, please contact:
Richard Kersley, Head of Global Securities
Products and Themes, Credit Suisse
Investment Banking,
richard.kersley@credit-suisse.com
Michael O’Sullivan, Chief Investment
Officer, UK & EEMEA, Credit Suisse
Private Banking & Wealth Management,
michael.o’sullivan@credit-suisse.com
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 2
Introduction
Since 1945, the number of UN country members has
risen from nearly 50 to 193, a nearly four-fold rise in the
number of countries in the world, two-thirds of which
could be classified as ‘small’. Note that 77% of all of the
small states in the world have been formed in the past
70 years. Many of these have been born out of transi-
tions to democracy. In a recent Credit Suisse Research
Institute report (From Spring to Revival) we noted 87
transitions to democracy since 1952, 46% of which
involved small countries such as Georgia, Latvia, the
Czech Republic and Slovakia.
There is clearly an important underlying trend at work
here, the rise of small states. Does size matter to the
economic success of a state? Are smaller states at a dis-
advantage versus larger ones in an increasingly competi-
tive world? Can breakups lead to better
economic outcomes?
Not only is the number of small countries growing, but
the global political economy has changed in a way that
both enables and challenges small countries. For exam-
ple, globalization (as measured by global trade as a % of
GDP) and the rise in the number of states have grown in
tandem. Globalization has driven the growth of small
states and separate customs territories (WTO definition)
such as Dubai, Hong Kong SAR, Singapore and Ireland.
One innovation in this study is our construction of the CS
Country Strength index, that helps to identify those small
countries that are best placed to weather the pressures
placed upon them by globalization.
Recent financial crises have also shone the spotlight
on small countries. They were the prominent financial
and economic losers in the aftermath of the global finan-
cial crisis and the onset of the Eurozone crisis. Peak to
trough falls in GDP from 2008 to 2014 have been most
dramatic for the Baltic States, Iceland, Ireland, and Por-
tugal. On the other hand, it is worth mentioning that
older small countries such as Switzerland and Sweden
fared much better.
We fully recognize that economic considerations are
just one dimension of many when issues of statehood
are at stake. Yet, there is no doubt the Eurozone crisis
has brought to the fore the issues of the economic inde-
pendence, political power and institutional quality of
Europe’s small states. As small states have been
amongst the economic success stories of the past 20
years, we think it is worth exploring this trend in depth.
Stefano Natella, Head of Global Equity Research,
Investment Banking
Giles Keating, Head of Research and Deputy Global
CIO, Private Banking and Wealth Management
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 3
We do not seek to add to these arguments but we would like
to add another, important dimension to the debate. That is, can
small, independent states be successful on their own? The issue
is a complex one.
We need to define size and we need to agree on how to measure
success (GDP growth, GDP per capita, etc).1
But other factors might
influence the relationship between size and success. Consider trade
openness, homogeneity and age for instance. The more open a coun-
try is to trade the more the whole world becomes the relevant market
for that country. So in a world of free trade, political borders are eco-
nomically irrelevant and small countries can be as successful as some
of the larger ones, that can benefit from a large domestic market.
Homogeneity or heterogeneity is another important issue. As we
will see, heterogeneity provides a ceiling to a potential size of
a country.
For instance, age or “vintage” has multiple influences: the
stability of institutions or infrastructure depends on the country’s
age. Older, small countries, notably those in the Alpine and Nor-
dic regions tend to be pinpointed as the ‘model’ for other small
nations to follow though many of the factors that have contrib-
uted to the success of the Alpine or Nordic countries are
not transferrable.
Finally, we consider the lessons and economies of the ami-
cable divorces of the Czech Republic and Slovakia, and the
fusion of West and East Germany – clearly recognizing that
these are all unique cases with their specific characteristics.
What is new or unexpected?
•• The rise of new small states in the context of globalization
has been one of the key geo-economic megatrends of the
past 30 years. We found a negative correlation between
size and GDP per capita. This is particularly true for high
income countries.
1	 We adopt two relatively simple definitions of state size. 1. Population:
Large: Population > 25 million, Medium: 10 million < Population < 25 million,
Small: Population < 10 million. By this classification, we have 100 small, 34
medium and 47 large countries. 2. We have also overlaid territory size to
population as another measure following the work of Alouini & Hubert. For the
sake of comparison we have included the likes of Hong Kong, which is a Special
Administrative Region of the People’s Republic of China. By this classification
(PAC index), we have 109 small, 46 medium and 39 large countries.
The debate
The debate on what would happen if Scotland or Catalonia became independent
opens up some very interesting arguments. On one side we have politicians and
corporations advocating the “united we stand, divided we fail” view. Their main
argument is that a break-up would create a lot of uncertainty on the legal,
monetary and fiscal fronts. On the other side, those in favor of independence
argue that Scotland and Catalonia are culturally, politically and economically
distinct from the “Union”.
•• If we add education, healthcare or intangible infrastructure
as measures of success, we find that small countries do
proportionately very well. For example, with respect to UN’s
Human Development Index (which combines GNI per cap-
ita, education and health metrics), small countries make up
over half of the world’s top 30 countries. Scotland and
Catalonia show higher HDI scores than the U.K. and
Spain, respectively.
•• Our Country Strength indicator (which includes other fac-
tors such as HDI, Credit Suisse Intangible Infrastructure
Index, Credit Suisse Globalization index, etc.) has six small
countries in the top 10. In addition, wealth inequality is less
pronounced for small than large countries.
•• Small countries are more homogeneous and homogeneity
plays an important role in determining the success of a
country. Cultural, ethnic, religious and linguistic diversity
creates a ceiling to the potential size of a country. Homoge-
neous countries tend to have higher HDI scores.
•• We also found that small countries are more open to inter-
national trade or have embraced globalization to a higher
extent than larger countries. Trade openness is another fac-
tor that is statistically relevant in determining the success of
a country. Increased specialization helps small countries be
more successful in an increasingly competitive environ-
ment. However, we also found that small countries tend to
experience higher volatility in economic growth.
•• In theory, large countries should benefit from economies of
scale. We found that there is a weak correlation between
government spending as a percentage of GDP and size.
The only area where large countries appear to benefit from
economies of scale is in public sector salaries, which are
probably a good proxy for the relative size of the govern-
ment. Smaller countries spend more on education and
healthcare as a percentage of GDP (where scale should not
be a factor), key factors for the long-term success of
a country.
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/CLAUDIODIVIZIA
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 4
•• Contrary to expectations, large countries’ economies of
scale do not accrue to the population. Our research shows
that large countries tend to have higher tax rates for indi-
viduals (by 5%). So the cost of funding public services for
the individual is higher in larger countries than in small
countries. This is true in theory also for corporate rates,
which are higher in larger countries. But the ability of cor-
porations and multinationals to minimize their global tax bill
is evident when measuring corporate tax collections as a
percentage of GDP: it is significantly smaller for
larger countries.
•• We found a significant difference in economic, social and
institutional performance between ‘old’ small countries and
‘new’ small countries. In other words, for some new coun-
tries where the institutional and legal framework is not yet
developed, it might take time to achieve the benefits we
uncovered for smaller countries. Institutional quality, rule of
law, investment in technology and education are key drivers
of the ‘path’ toward higher output levels.
•• As expected, urbanization is a major driver of economic
growth. Hong Kong SAR and Singapore show among the
world’s highest GDP per capita and five city-states are
among the top 30 in the HDI metrics. Cities also benefit
from significant economies of scale, a higher proportion of
services in the economy relative to manufacturing and agri-
culture, and are completely open to trade.
•• Companies are also an important engine for growth. Of the
top 500 companies by market capitalization, 86% are
based in large countries. However, the contribution of large
companies to economic growth accrues to a whole set of
countries, not just to the home country. One third of U.S.
multinationals’ workforce for example is based abroad. In
sectors like manufacturing or retail, production often tends
to be based in countries different from the “home” country.
So, small countries do not need to attempt to attract large
corporations to grow at a faster rate, but they need to spe-
cialize in areas that provide large corporations with a com-
petitive edge.
Figure 1
Evolution of countries
Source: UN, Credit Suisse
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Global trade as a % of global GDP 55
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
180
200 Number of UN members
1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005
Number of UN members Global trade as a % of global GDP (rhs)
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 5
Success:
Size, age, trade and
heterogeneity
Intangible infrastructure – education, governance, the rule of law – the ability to
manage globalization and macro volatility, human development factors drive the
success of small countries. Corporate tax receipts, size, democracy and
intellectual property are much less important factors.
In order to measure the influence of size on suc-
cess, we took a sample of 58 countries for which we
analyzed data over a 33-year period (1980-2012) and
ran a balanced panel regression. We used GDP per
capita as a measure of success and the PCA index as
a measure of size. We found a strong negative rela-
tionship between size and GDP per capita (see
Table 1). In a recent paper, Alouini and Hubert use
GDP growth as a measure of success. They con-
cluded that in general there is no clear relationship
between size and GDP growth; but for high income
countries the relationship is negative and this is par-
ticularly true for the Eurozone countries. This is
extremely relevant as the Eurozone countries tend to
represent quite a homogeneous sample.
In the sample we used above, given the long time
frame, small old countries dominate the small country
sample. Is age important? Age or perhaps ‘vintage’
appears to have some influence. There is a four-fold dif-
ference in GDP per capita between ‘old’ small states
(those in existence before 1945) and ‘new’ small coun-
tries. This is understandable given that many new small
states have come into existence in the emerging world. It
also helps to put in perspective the fascination that many
economists have with the steady performance of the
Alpine economies (Switzerland and the Nordic countries).
Further, as Figure 2 shows, new and old small coun-
tries together tend to have a higher per capita GDP than
medium sized countries, though they fare less well than
the median level for large countries. These aggregated
figures disguise the contribution that largely ‘old’ small
countries make to the world’s economic elite. They
make up 90%, 63% and 66% of the world’s Top 10,
30 and 50 countries by GDP per capita, respectively.
This at least underlines the importance of small coun-
tries as economic dynamos and policy models.
Table 1
Regression size vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Variable Coefficient Standard
Error
t-Statistic Prob.
C 5.26 0.11 47.39 0.00
PCA Index -0.52 0.04 -12.32 0.00
Trade openness 0.15 0.02 9.33 0.00
Inflation 0.00 0.00 0.15 0.88
Real Interest Rate -0.00 0.00 -1.22 0.22
Regression results
R-squared 0.98
Adjusted R-squared 0.98
S.E. of regression 0.07
Sum squared resid 9.37
Log likelihood 2374.74
F-statistic 1202.08
Prob(F-statistic) 0
Figure 2
Wealth held by top 10% of the population
Source: Credit Suisse
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 6
Figure 3
Nominal GDP per capita small (median)
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0
1,000
2,000
3,000
4,000
5,000
6,000
7,000
8,000
Small Medium Large
Wealth offers another way of assessing prosperity.
Here we draw upon the data available in the Credit
Suisse Global Wealth Report that measures the wealth
of the 4.6 billion adults in the world (wealth is mea-
sured as financial plus non-financial wealth (i.e. prop-
erty less debt). Wealth tends to have a high correlation
with GDP but in itself can also reveal how small states
manage their prosperity, particularly in the context of
the current debate on wealth inequality.
In terms of wealth per adult, small countries are just
ahead of large countries on average. When we
sharpen the analysis, we find that wealth concentration
as highlighted by the proportion of total wealth held by
the top 10%, large countries (62%) appear to be
more unequal than small ones (54%), Figure 2. What
is also interesting is that while there is a gulf in
difference between old small countries and new small
countries in average wealth per adult (USD 140,000
vs. USD 25,000) there is not such a large difference
between them in terms of concentration of wealth in
the top 10%. We note that of the top 10 countries in
the world by wealth per adult, 6 of them are small
countries led by Switzerland and followed by Norway.
To further extend the analysis beyond GDP or wealth-
based measures, we measure other variables of political
economic and social attainment. On the basis of the
UN’s Human Development Index 2
,‘old’ small countries
make up 11 of the world’s top 20 countries (Figure 4).
If we break the data down further, we find that
smaller countries in general tend to have higher human
development scores (HDI) though the reverse is not
true, as a significant share of large countries in our
sample also score high on HDI (Figure 5). Interest-
ingly, low and medium level HDI scores are dominant
in medium-sized countries. In general, we can say that
older, established small countries lead the rankings of
global human development score.
A positive trend is that new countries have in gen-
eral seen an improvement in their human development
rankings. As Figure 6 shows, smaller states like Croa-
tia, Slovenia and the Baltics in particular have seen
their HDI scores improve consistently.
In several regions of the world, independence
movements exist or have existed (e.g. Quebec).
Purely for the sake of comparison we have included
them in the human development score table on page
8. Given the prevailing interest, we calculate the HDI
scores for Catalonia, Flanders, Wallonia, Quebec and
Scotland. Quebec would rank the highest among
these regions/countries and 13th globally, compared
to 11th for Canada. However, based on our
2	http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/hdi
The Human Development Index (HDI) is a composite measure of
health, education and income that was introduced in the first Human
Development Report in 1990 as an alternative to purely economic
assessments of national progress, such as GDP growth. It soon
became the most widely accepted and cited measure of its kind, and
has been adapted for national use by many countries. HDI values and
rankings in the global Human Development Report are calculated
using the latest internationally comparable data from mandated inter-
national data providers. Previous HDI values and rankings are retro-
actively recalculated using the same updated data sets and current
methodologies.
Figure 4
Top 20 based on HDI
Source: UNDP
Old small 45%
New small 10%
Medium 15%
Large 30%
Figure 5
Human Development Index vs. country size
Source: UNDP, Credit Suisse
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70% of total
Large countries Medium sized countries Small countries
High HDI
Scores>0.75
Medium HDI
Scores between 0.45-0.75
Low HDI
Scores<0.45
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 7
calculations, both Catalonia and Scotland will rank
higher than Spain and the UK, respectively. Catalonia
would rank 20th globally, while Spain ranks currently
23rd and would slip to 26th ex-Catalonia. Scotland
would rank 23rd if we include a geographical alloca-
tion to Scotland’s GNI related to the North Sea oil out-
put, versus the current 27th place for the UK and the
hypothetical 30th for the UK ex-Scotland. Note that
even excluding any allocation of oil output, Scotland
would still rank ahead of the UK, but just so.
We mentioned before that trade and heterogeneity
influence the potential size of a country and its suc-
cess. Let us focus on heterogeneity first.
Small countries can differ from large ones in terms
of their cultural diversity, the larger the country the
more diverse its population is likely to be. Following the
approach established in Alesina & Spolaore (2004),
we have developed a fractionalization index that aims
to gauge the degree of ethnic, religious and linguistic
diversity between small and larger countries. We sim-
ply equally weight the fractionalization scores across
the three variables – language, ethnicity and religion.
As the source data is old (2001) there will have been
Country HDI Score HDI Rank
Norway O.955 1
Australia 0.938 2
United States 0.937 3
Netherlands 0.921 4
Germany 0.92 5
New Zealand 0.919 6
Ireland 0.916 7
Sweden 0.916 7
Switzerland 0.913 9
Japan 0.912 10
Canada 0.911 11
South Korea 0.909 12
Quebec 0.906 13
Hong Kong SAR 0.906 13
Iceland 0.906 13
Denmark 0.901 16
Israel 0.900 17
Belgium 0.897 18
Flanders 0.895 19
Austria 0.895 19
Singapore 0.895 19
Catalonia 0.894 22
France 0.893 23
Finland 0.892 24
Slovenia 0.892 24
Scotland* 0.887 26
Spain 0.885 27
Liechtenstein 0.883 28
Italy 0.881 29
Spain (Ex-Catalonia) 0.880 30
Luxembourg 0.875 31
United Kingdom 0.875 32
Czech Republic 0.873 33
United Kingdom (ex-Scotland) 0.871 34
Wallonia 0.869 35
Greece 0.86 36
Brunei Darussalam 0.855 37
Cyprus 0.848 38
Malta 0.847 39
Andorra 0.846 40
Estonia 0.846 41
Slovakia 0.84 42
*	 Accounting for a geographical share of North Sea oil production.
Table 2
HDI league tables
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 8
PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/PERESANZ
Figure 6
Average change in HDI percentile rank since independence
Source: UNDP, Credit Suisse
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4 change in HDI percentile rank
Croatia
Lithuania
Latvia
Estonia
Slovenia
Palau
Slovakia
CzechRepublic
Kazakhstan
Georgia
Ukraine
GroupAverage
Montenegro
Belarus
BosniaandHerzegovina
Macedonia
Germany
Moldova
Azerbaijan
Turkmenistan
Eritrea
Uzbekistan
Tajikistan
Armenia
Timor-Leste
Kyrgyzstan
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 9
some changes to the figures, notably in ethnicity.
The overall picture shows that small countries are
amongst the least ‘fractionalized’ or rather more
homogenous. We also note that the ‘old small’ coun-
tries have the lowest median fractionalization score
(Figure 7). There can be several explanations for this,
and we will discuss this later on when we focus on
the efficiencies or inefficiencies of scale.
Trade or globalization off the world economy is
another important variable in determining the suc-
cess of a country, particularly small countries. What
is globalization? In general, it is not difficult to distil a
couple of core characteristics from the many defini-
tions that are offered of globalization. One is that glo-
balization involves the increasing integration of mar-
kets, economies and societies, as borders become
less relevant. The other is that integration brings
increased interdependence between nations.
Taking the Foreign Policy/AT Kearney methodol-
ogy as a basis, we construct a globalization index
based around economic, social and technological
factors3
. As Table 3 highlights, small countries tend
to dominate the globalization rankings, led by Luxem-
bourg, Singapore, Switzerland and Ireland. In fact of
the top 20 countries as ranked by our methodology,
85% are small.
3	 Economic globalization: Trade openness (% of GDP), FDI
(% of GDP), FPI (% of GDP)
Social globalization: Cellphone subscription (per 100 people),
Telecom lines (per 100 people), Remittances (inward + outward) (%
of GDP). There is a partial overlap with Intangible Infrastructure
Index’s Technological Infrastructure dimension here
Corporate openness: Ease of doing business rank (by World
Bank), import delays (in days), mean tariff rates (in %), Taxes on
trade (% of government revenue). Once again, first three indicators
are common to II’s business services dimension
Technological globalization: Internet users (per 100 people),
secure servers (per million people). Overlap with II Index’s
technology dimension
	 Luxembourg leads the index because it has the highest proportion of
foreign investment flows (direct and portfolio) to its GDP among
all countries
Figure 8
Expectedly, smaller countries tend to be more globalized
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Figure 9
Trade openness
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100% of total
Low score Medium score High score
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80 Trade openness (% of GDP)
Large Medium Small
Figure 7
Fractionalization vs. HDI
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
0.45
0.50 Median fractionalization
High HDI Medium HDI Low HDI
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 10
PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/PERCDS
European countries dominate the top while
African nations tend to be the least globalized.
Table 3
Globalization index
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Country Size Globalization
Index score
Luxembourg S 0.93
Singapore S 0.93
Hong Kong SAR S 0.88
Switzerland S 0.85
Ireland S 0.83
Belgium M 0.82
Iceland S 0.81
Netherlands M 0.81
Estonia S 0.81
Hungary S 0.79
Norway S 0.79
Montenegro S 0.78
Denmark S 0.78
Malta S 0.78
Bahrain S 0.77
Austria S 0.77
United Kingdom L 0.77
Sweden S 0.75
Finland S 0.75
Cyprus S 0.75
Malaysia L 0.74
Panama S 0.74
Portugal M 0.73
Bulgaria S 0.73
Mauritius S 0.72
There are some data issues here that we should
flag. Small countries that act as trade or financial
entrepots (i.e. Luxembourg) have very heavy finance
and trade flows relative to their GDP size and as such
appear intensely ‘globalized’ in an economic sense.
Monaco ranked high, though its excellent performance
was almost entirely driven by an unusual number of
secure internet servers and internet users per capita.
The rank for St. Kitts and Nevis has also been boosted
by extremely low trade tariff rates and very high density
of technological infrastructure. Leaving these “excep-
tions” aside, Table 3 shows a very clear picture.4
Using the same data mentioned above (58 coun-
tries and 33 years), we found that trade openness
and GDP per capita are strongly correlated. As
expected, openness to trade allows for success and
small countries tend to be more open. So, it is easy
to conclude that the globalization of the world econ-
omy has been a major factor in the success of
smaller economies. The other side of the coin though
is that small countries are more susceptible to show
higher volatility in economic growth.
However, Alouini and Hubert show that there is no
correlation between trade openness and economic
volatility. Their hypothesis is that in a more globalized
economy, small countries have tended to specialize in
certain areas (Singapore in IT services for financial
companies, for example) and that has made them
more exposed to the volatility of that particular sector.
Later on, we will focus on what determines the ability
of countries to withstand economic shocks.
4	 https://www.credit-suisse.com/ch/en/news-and-expertise/
research/credit-suisse-research-institute/publications.html
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 11
Figure 10
Intangible infrastructure (II) Index vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Intangible infrastructure
Our focus on human development indicators helps to open up the debate on
the factors that drive the success of smaller economies and societies. We
developed the notion of ‘intangible infrastructure’ (II)4
which we had defined
as “the set of factors that develop human capability and permit the easy and
efficient growth of business activity”.
These factors can be essentially political, legal
or socio-economic in nature. Examples of political
factors include the degree of political stability or the
strength of the institutional framework. Legal fac-
tors include the rule of law, tax policies and intel-
lectual and physical property rights protection.
Examples of socio-economic factors include
research and development capabilities, business
processes or employee training and education.
We consider five specific components of intan-
gible infrastructure – education, healthcare,
finance, business services and technology5
. Our
sense is that while developing countries can
achieve a record of high growth through physical
investment (i.e. physical infrastructure), they need
to cultivate intangible infrastructure in order to
achieve a high and sustained level of growth and
human development. In our analysis, we update our
intangible infrastructure rankings that score coun-
tries from 0 to 1, with increasing values indicating
increasing strength of infrastructure.
The link between the level of GDP a country
enjoys and the quality of its intangible infrastructure
is evident in Figure 10, where levels of intangible
infrastructure appear to be linked to GDP per cap-
ita. We repeat this graphic for the small country
universe only, and the relation holds, in just as
strong a form (Figure 11).
Education is a key determinant of human capa-
bility. The value of education is intrinsic in almost all
levels of economic output. As we illustrate in Figure
12, and discuss in more detail later, the correlation
between high school educational attainment and
GDP per capita is particularly strong . We can also
track the historical precedents of economies, such
as the early “Asian tigers” whose emphasis on
investing in education paved the way for their suc-
cess. Government commitment to education can
be shown to have a significant impact on the nature
of growth that economies then display, as much as
the GDP level itself.
5	 The sub-components of the intangible infrastructure index are as fol-
lows: Education: Secondary and Tertiary enrolment ratio. Healthcare:
Infant mortality, Life expectancy and health spending per capita.
Technology: Cellphone users (per 100), telephone lines (per 100),
secure servers (per million), Internet users (per 100), R&D expendi-
ture (% of GDP). Financial services: Credit Information score, legal
rights score, lending risk premium, Equity market capitalization (% of
GDP). Business services: Ease of doing business rank, Import
delays, mean tariff rates, procedures needed to register a business
Figure 11
II Index vs. GDP per capita (small country version)
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Figure 12
High school education vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
R² = 0.71
0
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
Intangible Infra. score
Qatar
Norway
Denmark
Seychelles
Suriname
R² = 0.6844
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140
Gross secondary school enrolment ratio
Norway
USA Ireland
Switzerland
Iceland
JapanItaly
China
Poland
South Africa
Angola
0
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
R² = 0.7623
0
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00
Intangible Infra. score
USA
Germany Australia
Norway
Finland
Italy
Switzerland
China
India
KoreaMalaysia
Vietnam
PolandTurkey
CzechMexico
Colombia
Bahrain
Oman
Saudi Arabia
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 12
With considerations such as life expectancy (Fig-
ure 13) and related demographic trends, healthcare
is another key factor in determining the average
individual’s output. Through time and across bor-
ders, there are very few exceptions to the rule that
better healthcare fosters an environment of higher
economic activity as well as human development.
Despite this fact, it has not been a priority in many
of the markets that we currently view as high growth
markets such as China. This looks set to change.
While we have sought to categorize the nature of
intangible infrastructure in these five categories, in
reality, it is far more complicated than that. It is of
course heavily inter-related and interdependent. It is
not impossible, but it is highly unlikely that any
country with a high degree of technology penetra-
tion would not also have a fairly comprehensive edu-
cation system. In the same way, financial systems
would struggle in the absence of a legal framework
and advances in technology might falter without
property rights to support the R&D.
Adding support to the case for “intangible infra-
structure” are the broad trends in demographics,
economics, society and geopolitics that point toward
the rising importance of intangible factors, as well
as the significant body of academic literature on
economics and development. Nobel prize-winning
work by Robert Solow has helped to structure ideas
on the role that technology and human capital play
in generating economic growth.
In turn, this has paved the way for theories that
map out the means by which developing countries
could “catch up” to wealthier ones. Acemoglu and
Robinson6
are amongst the leading academic con-
tributors on this topic, stressing the strong link
between the economic development of states and
their institutional strength.
Stability rather than democracy
We note that the notion of a “fair society” is not
necessarily a prerequisite for intangible infrastruc-
ture to function. In the political-economic field, a
good deal of the academic literature that links
income and economic growth to “intangibles” has
focused on democracy. At a broad level, the rela-
tionship between democracy and development is a
close one, though the causality of this relationship is
increasingly being questioned. Instead, the emerg-
ing consensus is that institutions and intangible fac-
tors like the rule of law matter more for economic
development than democracy itself.
6	 ‘D. Acemoglu & J. Robinson ‘Why Nations Fail?’
(Deckle Edge, 2012)’
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/DBVIRAGO
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 13
Figure 13
Life expectancy vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Our own findings suggest that institutions, or at
least the quality of institutions, drive the distribution
of resources in an economy and the way incentives
and contracts are set up. Decent institutions
encourage trust, investment in human capital and
help to lower the frictions of doing business. A
simple illustration is to compare the fit of GDP per
capita with (a) World Bank data that scores the
Rule of Law in each country and (b) with Political
Freedom scores, again from the World Bank. The
data clearly shows that the rule of law (R2
of 0.5
with GDP) seems to be a far more important deter-
minant of economic success than political freedom
(R2
of 0.15 with GDP, and 0.11 for small countries
only). See Figures 14, 15 and 16.
Equally, if we examine state fragility7
index
developed by Systemic Peace as a variable, there
is a marked difference between small and medium
countries, with small countries in general having
much lower fragility scores. Medium sized states,
mostly in Western Asia and Africa, tend to be more
fragile than the rest.
Small countries and intangible infrastructure
To get into the detail of our intangible infrastruc-
ture index, Table 3 highlights the top 25 countries
in terms of our intangible infrastructure rankings,
with small countries such as Finland and Denmark,
as well as bigger states Australia and the UK to the
fore. Many of the countries that do well here are
‘usual suspects’ from the Nordic region, though
New Zealand in particular scores well. Singapore,
Ireland and Israel follow on.
It seems that excellence in intangible infrastruc-
ture is a small country speciality. Small countries
make up 7 of the top 10 countries by intangible
infrastructure and 60% of the top 30. From Figure
17, we see that medium sized countries fare less
well here. The results are interesting because they
suggest that small countries deploy their resources
well and get a positive return on their investment.
In addition, we note that when we compare the
changes in the II ranking from 2011 to 2013, small
countries tend to be prominent in terms of having
the best improvements in intangible infrastructure
(Czech Republic, Iceland, Qatar, Bulgaria
and Cyprus).
When we break down the overall intangible
infrastructure index into its five component parts,
small (mostly old) countries score best on four of
five criteria (Figure 18). The exception is financial
services, where large cities (London, Frankfurt and
New York) in large countries have historically had
an advantage in terms of the scale and depth of
their financial markets and also where in the recent
past the record of small countries as financial pow-
erhouses has been a checkered one. Another
interesting break out is to examine patents, which
in larger countries have tended to mark economic
7	www.systemicpeace.org
Figure 14
Rule of law vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Figure 15
Political freedom vs. GDP per capita
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Figure 16
Political freedom vs. GDP per capita (small country version)
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
R² = 0.5264
-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5
Rule of law score
Qatar
Singapore
Sweden
USA
China
Switzerland
Russia
India
Ireland
Bahrain
Malaysia
Brazil
Japan
UK
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0
R² = 0.5967
40.00 45.00 50.00 55.00 60.00 65.00 70.00 75.00 80.00 85.00
Life expectancy (years, 2012)
Japan
USA
Germany
France
Spain
Norway
ChinaIndia
Brazil
Russia20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0
R² = 0.1563
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Political freedom score
Luxembourg
Qatar
USA
China India
Switzerland
Sweden
Singapore
Kuwait
Japan UK
Brazil
Russia20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0
R² = 0.116
Political freedom score
Norway
Austria
Israel
Bulgaria
Qatar
BosniaLaos
Singapore
Kuwait
Brunei
Oman
Bahrain
UAE
Eq. Guinea
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012)
0
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 14
success (Figures 19 and 20), though for some of
the smaller countries that top the II league tables,
patent applications appear to be low, with Israel an
exception here.
When we compare ‘old’ small countries to ‘new’
small countries, the older ones like Switzerland or
Sweden have a clear and understandable advan-
tage. What is interesting however is to compare
new small countries to large and medium ones, and
here new small states are clearly in the ascendancy.
Our sense is that intangible infrastructure forms
the backbone of a country, a key conduit for eco-
nomic growth, and it is a crucial determinant in a
state’s ability to withstand and engage with global-
ization. For instance a country is more likely to
engage in international trade if the rule of law holds
and if its financial institutions are well developed.
A Country Strength Index
So far, we have examined some of the individual
factors that are believed to influence the success of
countries. Bringing this together we develop the
CS Country Strength Index. The aim is to rank
countries on the basis of the quality of their institu-
tions and intangible infrastructure, their aptness to
thrive in a globalized world, their ability to grow con-
sistently with low volatility and lower volatility mac-
roeconomic output and their level of human devel-
opment. These many angles are closely related and
in most cases the causality between them is hard
to unravel. Our sense is that by looking at social
and institutional aspects of states as well as eco-
nomic ones, we achieve as rounded as possible a
view on a state and in particular of its ability to be
successful on a consistent basis.
In detail the factors we consider are as follows:
•• The UN Human Development Indicator,
•• The Credit Suisse Intangible Infrastructure
index globalization index
•• Macroeconomic volatility8
•• Governance9
In general the ‘Strength’ strikes a chord with
both the analysis we have carried out on the sub-
components of the Strength index and with the
broad literature on political economic development.
Small countries tend to do well in terms of ‘strength’
but the results are biased in favor of ‘old’ small
countries. Thirteen of the top twenty countries are
small states, led by Switzerland, followed by Singa-
pore and Hong Kong SAR, Denmark, Ireland and
8	 Here we have taken two variables- Standard Deviation of GDP
growth rates and inflation, taken from World Bank database,
from 1960 onward. The average of these two standard devia-
tions is then taken and then we assign them percentile rank
such that lower volatility is given a higher rank. There is no clear
relationship between age and macro volatility. Economic volatil-
ity is high in old Eastern European and Latin American countries
(Uruguay, Bulgaria and Albania for example) whereas it is still
small in closed island economies (Cape Verde, Pacific Islands).
Surprisingly, macro volatility is not very high even for new oil-
rich states in Asia.
9	 The average of Transparency International’s Corruption Percep-
tions Index Center for Systemic Peace’s State Fragility Index.
Table 4
Top 25 countries by intangible infrastructure (II)
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Country Size II Index score
United Kingdom L 0.89
Finland S 0.89
Australia M 0.89
Singapore S 0.88
Hong Kong SAR S 0.88
Sweden S 0.87
Denmark S 0.87
Switzerland S 0.87
Netherlands M 0.86
Iceland S 0.86
Norway S 0.86
New Zealand S 0.86
Ireland S 0.85
Israel S 0.84
United States L 0.83
Korea, Rep. L 0.83
Japan L 0.83
Austria S 0.82
France L 0.81
Canada L 0.81
Estonia S 0.80
Spain L 0.80
Belgium M 0.80
Germany L 0.78
Luxembourg S 0.78
Figure 17
Smaller countries have significantly better levels of
intangible infrastructure
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100% of total
Low score
Large countries Medium sized countries Small countries
Medium score High score
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 15
Norway. A cluster of larger countries is led by Aus-
tralia, the Netherlands and the UK. Other ‘resilient’
small countries are Finland, Austria, Sweden and
New Zealand.
We should highlight that there are some factors
our model does not capture – the favorable effect
of geography (proximity to China) on Singapore and
Hong Kong SAR, the role of oil for Norway and
transfer from the EU to smaller European states’.
These have certainly helped small states, but we
would argue that long-term success depends on
the ability of policy makers to manage the bonuses
as well as the risks posed to small states. What is
perhaps more interesting are the countries that do
not make the top echelons. Hungary, Cyprus, Por-
tugal (classified as medium sized) and Estonia are
grouped together below the top table and in the
middle of the table, the UAE and some of the
Caribbean states are grouped together – their
scores are lower than the top group owing to lower
readings for globalization, macro volatility and
intangible infrastructure.
Generally, speaking, the weaker nations in terms
of our ‘Strength’ index tend to be African, both
large and small states, States that have medium
level ’Strength’ cores and that we think have the
potential to move higher given HDI and macro vola-
tility improvements might be Costa Rica, Serbia,
Kuwait and Latvia.
Figure 18
Small countries perform the best on most II metrics
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0.00
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60 Average scores
Overall Index Education Healthcare Technology Financial
services
Business
services
Small Medium Large
1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012
USA China Japan USSR/Russia
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700 No. of patents (in '000)
Figure 19
Patent filings in large countries
Source: Credit Suisse
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20 No. of patents (in '000)
1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012
Switzerland Sweden Ireland Israel
Figure 20
Patent filings in small countries
Source: Credit Suisse
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 16
A small country model?
There is a considerable amount of analysis by
international institutions such as the OECD and
IMF, as well as think tanks (Bruegel is notable here
with Andre Sapir’s analysis of socio-economic
models) and academics on the notion that some
countries are ‘models’ for others to follow. We are
somewhat sceptical here in that the designation of
a particular country as a model for others to follow
invariably marks the peak in that country’s (hubris-
tic) growth. Ireland and Turkey are two good
recent examples.
For the sake of argument and comparison, if we
were to compare some of the economic, social and
policy indicators for Scotland we find that it has
some similarities to neighboring countries like Nor-
way in terms of size, education, healthcare indica-
tors and oil production (22% of GDP for Norway,
12% for Scotland assuming production is allocated
on the basis of the median line principle).
The recurring dilemma is that many of the ingre-
dients that have contributed to one country’s suc-
cess are very difficult to ‘cut and paste’ on to other
nations. However, based on the broad literature on
this subject and the findings that come through
from the data, we would flag the following as being
part of the ‘secret sauce’ of developing a small
country: sense of strategic planning and an aware-
ness of the impact that outside forces (markets,
trade, immigration) can have on a small state as
well as the institutional ability to implement policy in
these fields.
PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/STOCKCAM
Table 5
Country strength index
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
Country Size Country strength index
Switzerland S 0.87
Hong Kong SAR S 0.85
Singapore S 0.85
Denmark S 0.84
Netherlands M 0.83
Australia M 0.83
United Kingdom L 0.83
Belgium M 0.82
Ireland S 0.82
Norway S 0.82
Bottom 10
Afghanistan L 0.18
Myanmar L 0.18
Guinea-Bissau S 0.18
Niger M 0.18
Burundi S 0.17
Central African Rep. S 0.14
Congo, Dem. Rep. L 0.13
Chad M 0.11
Eritrea S 0.10
South Sudan S 0.08
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 17
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/SHIYALI
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 18
Efficiencies or
inefficiencies
of scale?
In an ideal world, larger countries should
benefit from economies of scale in several
areas related to public spending. The cost
of nonrival public goods such as military
spending, tangible infrastructure (roads,
bridges, airports, etc), government or
collecting taxes should be lower, on a per
head basis, the larger the
country’s population.
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 19
On the other hand, public services such as educa-
tion or healthcare are driven by the number of stu-
dents or patients; so the size of a country in terms of
population should not have much influence on the per
capita costs of these public services. However, if the
definition of size includes or focuses on the geo-
graphical size of the country, some of these costs
would vary according to the population’s density.
In general, most academic research supports the
view above, that the public sector expenditures on a per
capita basis is larger for smaller countries; larger coun-
tries have in principle the ability to spread their cost over
a larger pool of taxpayers. Our findings show a different
story. Let us start with the big picture by first focusing
on public spending and then how it is financed.
Alesina and Spolaore in their 2003 book “The size
of Nations” show that expenditures as a percentage
of GDP are negatively correlated to size. They focus
on a large sample of countries over 1986 to 1990. In
our analysis, we find a very weak correlation between
government spending and size (R2
=0.03). The
results do not change much using either one year
(2012), three years (2010-12) or five years (2008-
10). Note that we define size as a combination of
population and physical size of the country. We get
similar results when we look at the correlation of gov-
ernment spending per capita with size.
Figure 21
Government spending
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
R² = 0.0274
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40 Gov’t spending as % of GDP
4 5 6 7 8 9 10
PCA index value (country size)
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/FINTASTIQUE
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 20
Figure 22
Spending on military as % of GDP
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
What is definitely more interesting is to look at the
components of government spending. For example,
spending on defense tends to be uncorrelated to size
and spending on education as a percentage of GDP
tends to be smaller for larger countries. As education
gives a country a long-term growth advantage and
there are some scale benefits (e.g., text books shared
by a larger number of students), this is quite surprising.
Public spending on healthcare shows again that
small countries invest more in healthcare compared
to large countries, but not a lot more. Finally, we ana-
lyzed the data related to all salaries paid by the gov-
ernment. This is the only result consistent with the
theory of the economies of scale: it shows that larger
countries tend to spend less relative to GDP on sala-
ries (5% of GDP for large countries versus almost
8% for small countries). Salaries here are a good
proxy for the direct cost of “governing” a country.
However, the most surprising finding is on the fund-
ing side of government expenditures. The core postulate
of the economies of scale for public services, military
capabilities, etc. is that the cost of these “services” on a
per head basis should be lower for larger countries. Not
really. Tax rates for individuals tend to be higher in larger
countries, by a hefty 5 percentage points! We need to
add indirect taxes to this analysis, but it is quite a compli-
cated exercise. A qualitative analysis of a few countries
suggests that the results above would not change.
Figure 23
Spending on education as % of GDP
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0.0
1.0
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0 Spending on Education as % of GDP
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
Figure 24
Spending on healthcare as % of GDP
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
7.5
8.0 Healthcare expenditure as a % of GDP
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5 Military spending as % of GDP
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
Figure 25
Compensation of public sector employees as % of GDP
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
0%
1%
2%
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
8% Compensation of Employees (% of GDP)
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 21
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/DOUGALL_PHOTOGRAPHY
Figure 26
Tax rate for individuals
Source: KPMG, Credit Suisse
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32 Average of highest marginal tax rate (individual)
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
Corporate taxes also look higher in large countries
versus small countries by a full 7 percentage points.
But is that really the case? Only in theory. If we look at
corporate taxes as a percentage of GDP we will find
that the opposite is true: 3.2% for small countries and
2.6% for big countries. The issue, we think, is corpo-
rate tax management by large companies in large
countries. Large corporations have subsidiaries abroad
that allow them to minimize the tax burden at the home
country level. So, in reality, in large countries few large
corporations pay the marginal corporate rate.
Another interesting area on the funding front is
leverage. As we would expect small countries show
less leverage and smaller fiscal deficits. Part of this is
the “age” effect: small younger countries have lesser
need to mortgage the future of the country as they
have less “historical” welfare burden, as the accumula-
tion time has been shorter. We could read this on the
basis that less leverage carries less risk; but this might
also reflect that smaller countries are more vulnerable
as they have less access to the global capital markets
and therefore they need to be more conservative.
This was brought to light during the European crisis
where the institutional framework of a larger ”commu-
nity” allowed larger countries in the EU to contribute to
the rescue of several smaller countries. At crisis time,
the size effect (US or EU) is a clear positive as larger
resources and funds can be pulled and channeled
across to help smaller countries, states, or cities.
Another way to explore the relative efficiency of
countries is to measure the level of output or GDP rela-
tive to the level of input. Milner and Weyman-Jones
have written several papers10
on the topic, focusing on
developing countries. Intuitively again, we would expect
that larger countries should have a “production” scale
advantage. Yet, the authors concluded that there is no
simple correlation between a country’s size and its rela-
tive efficiency rating, and that actually larger countries
are more inefficient than smaller ones, albeit with a
small statistical significance. The key factors for suc-
cess based on their analysis is not size but education,
healthcare and technology (i.e., the intangible infra-
structure). This is confirmed by our own analysis which
shows that smaller countries tend to have on average
better intangible infrastructure than the larger ones.
So there are some inefficiencies of scale, maybe
more so than the much touted efficiencies of scale.
Why? This might be explained in part by a natural
trend of larger countries towards the decentralization
of power. The larger the country, the more the need
for local and regional governments to manage some of
the key social services like education or police services.
Decentralization also gives rise to transfers from the
central government to the poorer regions or states to
allow for a more balanced growth and relative wealth
across the country. Transfers—a political tool to keep a
country together— add complexity and may lead to dis-
tortions and inefficiencies if not allocated properly (the
10	 e.g. Milner, C., and T. Weyman-Jones (2003): “Relative
National Efficiency and Country Size: Evidence for Developing
Countries,” Review of Development Economics, 7(1), 1–14.
Figure 28
Corporate tax revenue
Source: OECD 2012, Credit Suisse
Figure 27
Corporate taxes
Source: KPMG, Credit Suisse
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28 Average of highest marginal tax rate (corporate)
Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries
0.00
0.50
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
3.00
3.50 Corporate tax revenue (% GDP)
Small Large
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 22
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 23
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 24
Table 6
Heterogeneity scorecard
Source: Alesina database, Credit Suisse
Country Size Fractionalization
index
Kenya L 0.83
Cameroon M 0.82
Uganda L 0.82
South Africa L 0.82
Central African Republic S 0.81
Congo, Dem. Rep. (Zaire) L 0.81
Nigeria L 0.81
Zambia S 0.79
Chad S 0.78
Cote d'Ivoire M 0.78
Bottom 10
Iceland S 0.12
Bangladesh L 0.11
Greece S 0.11
Poland L 0.11
Norway S 0.11
Ireland S 0.10
Malta S 0.08
Portugal S 0.07
Tunisia S 0.02
Comoros S 0.01
perfect government has not yet been invented). This is
further accentuated by the effects of heterogeneity.
The more heterogeneous the population is or the
more heterogeneous are the preferences of the pop-
ulation, the higher is the cost of some services: edu-
cation spending for example has to take into account
the diversity of cultures and languages that exist in
one country. Table 6 shows the top 10 countries
under this metric (5 out of 10 are large ones) and the
bottom 10 (8 out of 10 are small ones). Not surpris-
ingly, the median fractionalization index of low HDI
countries is 22% higher than that of high HDI coun-
tries. In other words, the more homogeneous a coun-
try is, the higher the HDI score is likely to be.
The USA and the European Union provide a
valuable illustration of this dynamic. In the USA,
Federalism has added costs as each state has its
own government infrastructure and ability to issue
legislation. The result of this “government” structure
is often overspending and higher deficits at the
regional or local level.
The same could be said about the European Union
and the component states; 40% of the legislative acts
of the EU concern agricultural policies, while agricul-
ture represents less than 5% of European GDP.
On the other hand, Switzerland provides an
excellent example of very successful federalism—
arguably a highly efficient form of decentralization.
Switzerland had to be set up as a decentralized,
federal state because of its linguistic and cultural as
well as religious heterogeneity and the resulting fis-
cal federalism is certainly one of the defining fea-
tures of Switzerland’s political system and widely
cited as one of the institutional reasons for the
country’s economic success. So, we should not
underestimate the power of a larger pool of coun-
tries, states or regions or a larger country. The
European Union has been able to “rescue” one of
its member countries by “emergency” loans and the
US Federal government rescued the auto industry
(Detroit and surroundings) not Michigan State. So,
size has some advantages.
This is an important point as government size and
economic growth tend to be negatively correlated.
Several studies point to this link, which is particularly
strong for richer countries. This effect is visible even
when discounting the natural effect of increases in
government spending during recessions. In other
words, the size of a government beyond a certain
level, creates inefficiencies in resource allocation and
is not conducive to higher growth.
Alouini and Hubert make a valid point on why we
observe these inefficiencies of scale. It could be that
the costs associated with large size countries—trans-
portation, transactions and heterogeneity – or con-
versely the benefits of smaller sized countries —
homogeneity, density, higher efficiency and
flexibility—helps explain why smaller countries tend to
exhibit higher GDP growth or a higher HDI.
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/LINGBEEK
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 25
SPECIAL FEATURE
The break-up of
CzechoslovakiaGergely Hudecz
Following the collapse of communism, Czecho-
slovakia undertook reforms to introduce a mar-
ket-based system, but the transition was more
costly for Slovakia than for the Czech Republic.
Between 1990-92 the Czech Republic’s real
GDP declined by around 15%, while Slovakia’s
by about 22%. Unemployment was 2.6% in the
Czech Republic but reached 10.4% in Slovakia in
December 1992. There were no legal restrictions
on migration, but labor mobility did not mitigate
the adverse effects of the shock.1
The asymmetric shock led to the break-up of
Czechoslovakia in 1993. Following the elections
in 1992, centre-right parties in the Czech Repub-
lic and a nationalist party in Slovakia were unable
to agree about the redistribution of power
between the federation and its constituent states,
and decided to create two independent countries
on 1 January 1993. The two sides agreed to
divide immovable assets and territorial debt
according to location, and other assets and fed-
1	 Source: Fidrmuc et al. Stability of Monetary Unions: Lessons
from the Break-up of Czechoslovakia, Transition Economics
Series No. 10, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna
eral debt proportional to their population (around
2:1 in favor of the Czech Republic). In the mean-
time, fiscal transfers from the Czech Republic to
Slovakia stopped (which may have reached as
much as 8% of Slovakia’s GDP in 1992).
The two newly independent states planned to
maintain the common currency at least for the
first half of 1993, but the lack of political commit-
ment undermined the monetary union’s credibility.
Capital transfers by Slovak residents to Czech
commercial banks surged, presumably anticipat-
ing a devaluation in Slovakia after the split. The
Czech central bank initially attempted to balance
the capital flow from Slovakia by credits to Slovak
banks, but these became increasingly difficult to
sustain and eventually the Czech government
decided to separate the two currencies. The sep-
aration was implemented on 8 February 1993,
and the Slovak central bank decided to devalue
its currency by 10% in July 1993.
The break-up was more costly for Slovakia in
the short run. In 1993, real GDP declined by 1% in
the Czech Republic, while it fell by 4% in Slovakia,
and by 1995 GDP per capita in Slovakia was only
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 26
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12 Year-on-year, %
1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013
Germany Czech Republic Slovak Republic
60%
70%
80%
90%
100% GDP per capita in Slovakia compared to Czech Republic, PPP, %
1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013
Figure 29
Real GDP growth
Source: Eurostat, Fidrmuc et al, International Monetary Fund, Credit Suisse
Figure 30
Re-converging
Source: International Monetary Fund, Credit Suisse
around 68% of the Czech level, on purchasing-
power-parity. Bilateral trade also declined signifi-
cantly over the longer run: In 1991, around 50% of
Slovakia’s foreign trade was with the Czech Repub-
lic, but this dropped to about 25% by 1997. Czech
trade with Slovakia declined from around 30% in
1991 to about 10% in 1997. However, such a
sharp fall in bilateral trade suggests that the previ-
ous interdependence was artificial, and the large
public sectors were not developed according to
comparative advantages.
Integration with the EU mitigated the impact of
the break-up to some extent, as much of the
decline in Czech-Slovak trade reflected the
growth in trade with other countries, in particular
with the EU. Although the Czech Republic was
the front-runner for EU integration initially, Slova-
kia’s real GDP growth also rebounded sharply
and the government change in 1998 opened the
way for further reforms. Consequently, real GDP
growth in Slovakia outpaced growth in the Czech
Republic between 2001 and 2008, and the two
countries joined the EU at the same time in 2004.
Furthermore, Slovakia introduced the euro in
2009, and its GDP per capita almost reached the
Czech level by 2014, on purchasing-power-parity.
PHOTO: SHUTTERSTOCK.COM/BREZINA
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 27
SPECIAL FEATURE
German re-unificationChristel Aranda Hassel
On the night of 9 November 1989, the wall
dividing Berlin was breached starting negotiations
that would culminate in a re-unified Germany. The
monetary, economic and social union happened on
1 July 1990 followed by the political union on 3
October. For the first time in history, a capitalist and
a socialist economy became one. To start with, all
western institutions were transplanted to a large
degree: justice, industrial relations, banking, edu-
cation and social welfare.
On the economic front, the West German gov-
ernment decided to privatize the East German
economy. This was carried out by the eastern Treu-
handanstalt (THA, Trust Agency, commonly known
as Treuhand). The agency became a politically
independent body in charge of privatizing 8,500
previously state-owned enterprises containing
44,000 plants and accounting for nearly half of the
eastern workforce. The THA closed unviable firms
and plants, reduced employment at the viable plans
and sought buyers for the remaining core busi-
nesses which to a large extent became subsidiaries
of western companies since two-thirds were sold to
West German firms or families. At the end of 1994,
the THA finished its privatization brief with net
losses of nearly 11% of 1994 GDP.
Other key economic decisions included convert-
ing the exchange rate at 1:1 and a high wage strat-
egy in the east dictated by strong labor unions.
Generous financial transfers to the east saw east-
ern GDP per capita and compensation rise sharply
to start with.
In the early years of re-unification the economic
outcome of these decisions was a collapse in east-
ern real GDP. It fell by nearly 16% and 23% in
1990 and 1991, respectively, resulting in the
unemployment rate peaking above 20% in the sec-
ond half of the 1990s. For the west and on the
back of the positive aggregate demand shock, the
early years of re-unification were boom years with
GDP growth rates of more than 5%.
A series of studies have looked into the causes
of the sharp decline in eastern GDP and employ-
ment. Often mentioned are the disruption of east-
ern supply chains and the substitution to western
goods resulting in a sudden fall in demand for east-
ern goods and therefore output. The sharp reduc-
tion in labor supply was also a factor. In 1989-92,
employment in the east declined by more than 3 m
people. Early retirement on western pension bene-
fits was offered to more than 1 m and more than 1
m emigrated to the west. The rapid wage conver-
gence with the west not mirrored by productivity did
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 28
Figure 31
Remaining on convergence path
Source:	 Bundesministerium des Innern: “Jahresbericht der Bundesregierung zum Stand der
	 Deutschen Einheit 2013”,Credit Suisse
40
45
50
55
60
65
GDP per capita in east Germany compared to west Germany in %. West Germany = 100
70
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
Phase 1: Rapid
convergence
Phase 2: Structural
adjustment
Phase 3: Slow, continuous convergence
not help either. It led to the whole of Germany see-
ing double-digit wage growth in the early 1990s.
Union power was only severely weakened
after 1993.
From 1990 to date, the net cost of re-unification
has been estimated at around EUR 2 tn equivalent
to two-thirds of Germany’s entire 2013 GDP. Pay-
ments into the social security system account for
60-65% of that cost. The east, including Berlin,
accounts for 20% of the German population but
only for 15% of German GDP. Eastern GDP per
capita, at just over 70% of the average western
level, continues to converge slowly but the modest
upward trend suggests that it will take many years
to close the gap. Thanks to social transfers, the
difference between eastern and western dispos-
able income is less marked, with the east standing
at over 80% of the average western level. It helps
that the eastern labor market has improved. While
the eastern unemployment rate was more than 10
pp higher than that of the west for many years, at
4 pp the current gap is the most narrow since Ger-
many re-united.
The political decision to integrate the east with
the west as fast as possible was costly not only for
Germany but the cost of adjustment spread also to
the rest of Europe. High German wage growth trig-
gered high interest rates in order to contain inflation
but this led to the crisis of the Exchange Rate
Mechanism (ERM), the forerunner of the Economic
and Monetary Union (EMU). For Germany, it meant
that in addition to the re-unification shock to inter-
est rates it entered the monetary union with an
overvalued exchange rate.
PHOTO: SHUTTERSTOCK.COM/LINERPICS
Re-unification was costly and remains costly.
German households and companies continue to
pay a solidarity surcharge tax introduced in 1991
even if nowadays more than half of east Germans
and more than four-fifths in the west believe it
should be removed. The good news, however, is
that eastern Germany remains on the path of con-
vergence. The German parliament in its most
recent annual review on the stand of German re-
unification talks about an ‘impressive’ re-industrial-
isation of the east.
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 29
PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/SFSK
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 30
Cities and corporations
“Globalization is the ongoing process of greater interdependence among
countries and their citizens, and is complex and multifaceted.”
Stanley Fischer – Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve and former managing director of the
International Monetary Fund (IMF)
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 31
Figure 32
Urbanization and prosperity
Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/HOLGS
Cities
With this in mind, it is not surprising to see that
Hong Kong SAR or Singapore is among the coun-
tries/states/regions with the highest GDP/capita or
the highest HDI. We have showed that in a world of
free trade, size does not matter. This applies also to
city-states, with easy access to global markets via
unique deepwater harbors. In addition, cities are the
most efficient form of human settlement. History
shows that the richest countries in the twelfth to
fifteenth century were the city-states of Venice,
Genoa, Amsterdam and Hamburg. Free trade,
larger cities and small governments was a recipe for
raising wealth and growth.
This has been again the case in recent years: city-
states have prospered and cities have become the
most important engines of economic growth, particu-
larly in developing economies. Five city-states are in
the top 30 countries in HDI terms. Jakarta’s econ-
omy is growing at twice the rate of growth of Indone-
sia. Urbanization is a massive driver of growth and of
wealth, as we have recently highlighted in the CSRI
Emerging Capital Market Report.11
If we measure prosperity as GDP per capita, we
can see that countries that have a higher proportion
of the population in urban areas tend to show higher
GDP per capita numbers. Using the HDI metric and
dividing countries in four groups—from very high
human development to low human development—
we find that countries in the top group have a rate
of urbanization of 81%, countries in the bottom
group 34%. Not surprisingly, Tokyo’s GDP is more
than three times that of Switzerland, New York
City’s is more than twice that of Sweden and Mex-
ico City’s is twice that of Finland.
11	 https://www.credit-suisse.com/ch/en/news-and-expertise/
research/credit-suisse-research-institute/publications.html
Burundi
BelgiumBahrain
Brazil
China
GermanySpain
Equatorial Guinea
India
Ireland
Jordan
Kuwait
St. Lucia
Russia
Singapore
Sweden
Trinidad and
Tobago
United States
Venezuela
R² = 0.5391
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100 % of urban population
0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000
GDP per capita in USD (PPP)
Figure 33
Cities within small countries
Source: Brookings Institute, Credit Suisse
40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Buenos Aires (Argentina)
Santiago (Chile)
Budapest (Hungary)
Seoul-Incheon (South Korea)
Tel Aviv (Israel)
Vienna (Austria)
Lima (Peru)
Copenhagen (Denmark)
Brussels (Belgium)
Abu Dhabi (UAE)
Singapore
Hong Kong
GDP (city as % of country)
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 32
In this context, large cities can be considered
100% open economies, free to trade with the rest
of the country. In addition, the higher concentration
of the population allows for significant economies of
scale in most public services (transport, healthcare,
etc). Finally, cities thrive on services rather than
manufacturing; services (banking, retail) are in gen-
eral a higher-value-added sector and carry
higher incomes.
But what about heterogeneity? Social studies
show that the diverse interests and demands of het-
erogeneous groups tend to be softened by density
and that the common interest of a well functioning
city brings people closer together. Cities tend to
attract “foreigners” (people from other cities,
regions or countries) and “foreigners” want to inte-
grate; the concept of city becomes the common
denominator and a powerful unifying force. Polls
show that higher density areas in cities are more
open to immigration.
City inhabitants also tend to be more practical
and less ideological. New York City—one of the
country’s Democratic strongholds can easily elect
and live with Republican mayors (Bloomberg,
Giuliani, etc.). Local issues in cities are to a large
extent beyond parties, race or age and the demo-
cratic process is much more direct and allows voters
much more control and influence. Cities are charac-
terized by a pro-business attitude, openness, global
connections, relatively good education and in most
cases a pragmatic and modern governance.
Table 7
Large cities vs. small countries
Source: Brookings Institution 2012, World Bank
City GDP in USD
bn (PPP)
Tokyo 1519.4
New York City 1209.6
Los Angeles 786.7
Seoul 773.8
London 731.2
Paris 669.2
Osaka-Kobe 654.8
Chicago 524.6
Moscow 520.1
Shanghai 516.4
Sao Paulo 472.9
Cologne 465.1
Beijing 427.1
Washington 415.2
Mexico City 411.3
Houston 399.7
Dallas 368
Nagoya 366.9
Hong Kong SAR 350.4
Buenos Aires 348.4
Singapore 327.2
Country GDP in USD
bn (PPP)
UAE 534.3
Switzerland 425.3
Sweden 408
Austria 371.9
Norway 331.9
Qatar 282.2
Kuwait 278.4
Israel 247.9
Denmark 239.1
Hungary 224.5
Finland 212.2
Ireland 201.1
Belarus 162.4
Ecuador 156.1
New Zealand 145.9
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 33
Figure 34
Revenue distribution
Source: Thomson Reuters DataStream, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service, Credit Suisse
Corporations
One of the first and more prescient definitions of globalization
came in 1983 in a paper by Theodore Levitt, professor of mar-
keting at Harvard. Levitt wrote that:
The globalization of markets is at hand. With that, the multina-
tional commercial world nears its end, and so does the multi-
national corporation. The multinational and the global corpora-
tion are not the same thing. The multinational corporation
operates in a number of countries, and adjusts its products
and practices in each – at high relative costs. The global cor-
poration operates with resolute constancy – at low relative
cost – as if the entire world were a single entity, it sells the
same things in the same way everywhere12
.
His distinction between multinational and global companies is
crucial to understanding how globalization differs from internation-
alization. A multinational company tends to replicate itself on a
regional or national basis, building planning, marketing, production
and distribution operations in each area. Conversely, a truly global
corporation can locate its production operations in one country,
marketing in another and be headquartered in yet another country.
Companies are an integral part of the framework of a country and
provide a significant engine for economic growth. Among the top
12	 Theodore Levitt, ‘The Globalization of markets’, Harvard Business Review,
May/June 1983, p.2.
500 companies by market capitalization, 86% are based in
large countries, 5% in medium-size countries and 9% in
small countries. Large countries provide a large domestic
market that allows most companies to grow without the need
to embark at the early stages in a foreign expansion.
Should we thus deduce that large countries are the main
beneficiaries of the development of large corporations? Not
necessarily. We divided the top 100 companies by market
capitalization (we worked on smaller sample, just to illus-
trate the point) into multinationals (more than 50% of rev-
enue generated by foreign subsidiaries), locals (less than
10% of revenues from foreign subsidiaries) and mixed
(between 10-50% of revenues generated by foreign sub-
sidiaries). Almost 50% of our sample is made of companies
where foreign subsidiaries account for over half of revenues
and only 22 of the 100 companies we considered could be
considered tied just to the home country.
But even local companies source goods (manufactur-
ing) and services (call centers) from abroad. So in a world
of free trade, large local companies do not impact just the
home country. This is even more evident for 50% of our
sample, multinationals. Data from the U.S. Commerce
Department show that, at the end of 2009, U.S. multina-
tionals employed 21 million people at home (20% of the
total workforce) and 10 million people abroad. According
to a 2010 Business Impact Report, 20 Dutch multination-
als have a positive direct impact outside Holland on 4.2
Figure 35
Most companies located in large countries
Source: Thomson Reuters DataStream, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service, Credit Suisse
Small 9%
Medium 5%
Large 86%
Local 22%
Multinationals 43%
Combination 35%
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/ONFILM
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 34
million people (commercial activities) and indirectly benefited
another 4 million through philanthropic programs.
Not all is good news, though. From 2000 to 2009, U.S. mul-
tinationals reduced jobs at home by 2.9 million, but created 2.4
million jobs abroad. In 2009, undoubtedly a very tough year for
the global economy, these same multinationals cut 5% of their
U.S. based workforce (1.2 million people), but only 1% of their
workforce abroad (100,000 people).
The impact of globalization on the host countries has been at
the center of considerable debate. We reviewed several papers
and articles and came to a few basic conclusions in the context
of our analysis of large versus small countries.
•• First, we did not find that multinationals or large corpora-
tions tend to invest significantly more in large host countries
than in small ones. It varies a lot from sector to sector.
Several small countries tend to have a highly educated and
specialized work force that is extremely attractive to compa-
nies in sectors such as tech, for example. Other countries
provide large pools of labor at very competitive rates. In
addition, several host countries provide very attractive tax
rebates and the ability to minimize the overall tax burden—
corporate taxes paid as a percentage of GDP are larger for
small countries than for larger ones.
•• Second, it is difficult to generalize the impact of large corpora-
tion or multinationals on host countries. In some cases, the
effect has been incredibly positive: job creation, overall wage
increases across the whole country’s workforce, higher educa-
tion, and better living standards. In other cases, the out-
come has been quite negative, as the safety standards
of some corporations abroad did not match their
home standards.
•• Third, in a world of free trade of goods and people,
companies have evolved to consider the whole world
not only as a market for their products and services,
but also as a source of talented or attractively priced
labor (we hate the word cheap) to foster growth and
profitability. The overall effect has been higher pro-
ductivity and higher global growth, with clear benefits
for all those who participated either in the home or in
the host countries.13
In conclusion, while it is true that large corporations are
more likely to develop initially in large countries, they are
also likely to expand quickly beyond the home boundaries,
benefiting the rest of the world. A successful small country
can benefit from this global trend by investing in education
and specializing to provide services that might be signifi-
cantly more expensive or not available at all in larger host
countries. Singapore, Iceland and Switzerland are great
examples of success stories in the growing trend
towards specialization.
13	 On the potential implications for publicly traded companies of a “yes”
choice in the 18 of September vote in Scotland, we suggest reading an
excellent paper by Paul Marsh and Scott Evans “The Scotsie 100: Sixty
Years of Scottish Stocks.”
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 35
PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/LAGUI
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 36
References
Aghion, P., and A. Banerjee (eds.) (2005): Volatility and Growth, Clarendon Lectures in Economics.
Oxford University Press, USA.
Alcalá, F., Ciccone, A. (2004). “Trade and productivity”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (2), 613–646.
Alesina, A., Baqir, R., Hoxby, C. (2004). “Political jurisdictions in heterogeneous communities”. Journal of Political
Economy 112 (2), 348–396.
Alesina, A., Spolaore, E. (2003). The Size of Nations. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Alesina, A., E. Spolaore, and R. Wacziarg (2005): “Trade, Growth and the Size of Countries,” in Handbook of
Economic Growth, ed. by P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf, vol. 1 of Handbook of Economic Growth, chap. 23, pp.
1499–1542. Elsevier.
Alouini O. and P. Hubert (2014): “Country Size, Economic Performance and Volatility”. Working Paper,
http://hubertpaul.free.fr/
Baldwin, R. E. (2003): “Openness and Growth: What’s the Empirical Relationship?,” NBER Working Papers
9578, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Frankel, J.A., Romer, D. (1999). “Does trade cause growth?”. American Economic Review 89 (3), 379–399.
Furceri, D., and G. Karras (2007): “Country size and business cycle volatility: Scale really matters,” Journal of the
Japanese and International Economies, 21(4), 424–434.
Grossman, G., Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Lloyd, P. J., and R. M. Sundrum (1982): “Characteristics of Small Economies,” in Problems and Policies in Small
Economies, ed. by B. Jalan, pp. 17–38. Commonwealth Secretariat and Croom Helm, London.
Marsh, Paul and Evans, Scott (2014) “The Scotsie 100: Sixty Years of Scottish Stocks.”
Milner, C., and T. Weyman-Jones (2003): “Relative National Efficiency and Country Size: Evidence for Developing
Countries,” Review of Development Economics, 7(1), 1–14.
Rose, A. K. (2006): “Size really doesn’t matter: In search of a national scale
effect,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 20(4), 482–507.
Salvatore, D. (2001): “Defining country size,” in Small countries in a global economy: new challenges and
opportunities, ed. by D. Salvatore, M. Svetlicic, and J. P. Damijan, pp. xii, 305 p. :. Palgrave, Basingstoke.
Spolaore, E. (2002). “Conflict, trade and the size of countries”. Working Paper. Brown University.
Spolaore, E. (2005). “The political economy of national borders”. In: Weingast, B.R., Wittman, D. (Eds.),
The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, in preparation.
Spolaore, E., Wacziarg, R. (2005). “Borders and growth”. Journal of Economic Growth 10 (4), in press.
Wacziarg, R. (2001). “Measuring the dynamic gains from trade”.World Bank Economic Review 15 (3), 393–429.
Wacziarg, R., Welch, K.H. (2003). “Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence”. NBER Working Paper
10152, December.
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 37
Also published by the Research Institute
Global Investment
Returns Yearbook 2014
February 2014
Latin America:
The long road
February 2014
Emerging Consumer
Survey 2014
February 2014
Emerging
capital markets:
The road to 2030
July 2014
Family businesses:
Sustaining
performance
September 2012
Opportunities in an
urbanizing world
April 2012
Gender diversity
and corporate
performance
August 2012
Global Wealth
Report 2012
October 2012
Credit Suisse Global
Investment Returns
Yearbook 2012
January 2012
The shale revolution
December 2012
Emerging Consumer
Survey 2013
January 2013
Credit Suisse Global
Investment Returns
Yearbook 2013
February 2013
Sugar
Consumption at
a crossroads
September 2013
Global Wealth
Report 2013
October 2013
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 38
SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 39
General disclaimer / Important information
This document was produced by and the opinions expressed are those of Credit Suisse as of the date of writing and are subject to change. It has been prepared
solely for information purposes and for the use of the recipient. It does not constitute an offer or an invitation by or on behalf of Credit Suisse to any person to
buy or sell any security. Nothing in this material constitutes investment, legal, accounting or tax advice, or a representation that any investment or strategy is
suitable or appropriate to your individual circumstances, or otherwise constitutes a personal recommendation to you. The price and value of investments mentioned
and any income that might accrue may fluctuate and may fall or rise. Any reference to past performance is not a guide to the future.
The information and analysis contained in this publication have been compiled or arrived at from sources believed to be reliable but Credit Suisse does not make
any representation as to their accuracy or completeness and does not accept liability for any loss arising from the use hereof. A Credit Suisse Group company
may have acted upon the information and analysis contained in this publication before being made available to clients of Credit Suisse. Investments in emerging
markets are speculative and considerably more volatile than investments in established markets. Some of the main risks are political risks, economic risks, credit
risks, currency risks and market risks. Investments in foreign currencies are subject to exchange rate fluctuations. Before entering into any transaction, you should
consider the suitability of the transaction to your particular circumstances and independently review (with your professional advisers as necessary) the specific
financial risks as well as legal, regulatory, credit, tax and accounting consequences. This document is issued and distributed in the United States by Credit Suisse
Securities (USA) LLC, a U.S. registered broker-dealer; in Canada by Credit Suisse Securities (Canada), Inc.; and in Brazil by Banco de Investimentos Credit
Suisse (Brasil) S.A.
This document is distributed in Switzerland by Credit Suisse AG, a Swiss bank. Credit Suisse is authorized and regulated by the Swiss Financial Market
Supervisory Authority (FINMA). This document is issued and distributed in Europe (except Switzerland) by Credit Suisse (UK) Limited and Credit Suisse Securities
(Europe) Limited. Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited and Credit Suisse (UK) Limited, both authorized by the Prudential Regulation Authority and regulated
by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority, are associated but independent legal entities within Credit Suisse. The protections
made available by the Financial Conduct Authority and/or the Prudential Regulation Authority for retail clients do not apply to investments or services provided
by a person outside the UK, nor will the Financial Services Compensation Scheme be available if the issuer of the investment fails to meet its obligations. This
document is distributed in Guernsey by Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, an independent legal entity registered in Guernsey under 15197, with its
registered address at Helvetia Court, Les Echelons, South Esplanade, St Peter Port, Guernsey. Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited is wholly owned by Credit
Suisse AG and is regulated by the Guernsey Financial Services Commission. Copies of the latest audited accounts are available on request. This document is
distributed in Jersey by Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, Jersey Branch, which is regulated by the Jersey Financial Services Commission. The business
address of Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, Jersey Branch, in Jersey is: TradeWind House, 22 Esplanade, St Helier, Jersey JE2 3QA. This document
has been issued in Asia-Pacific by whichever of the following is the appropriately authorised entity of the relevant jurisdiction: in Hong Kong SAR by Credit Suisse
(Hong Kong) Limited, a corporation licensed with the Hong Kong Securities and Futures Commission or Credit Suisse Hong Kong branch, an Authorized
Institution regulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority and a Registered Institution regulated by the Securities and Futures Ordinance (Chapter 571 of the
Laws of Hong Kong); in Japan by Credit Suisse Securities (Japan) Limited; elsewhere in Asia/Pacific by whichever of the following is the appropriately authorized
entity in the relevant jurisdiction: Credit Suisse Equities (Australia) Limited, Credit Suisse Securities (Thailand) Limited, Credit Suisse Securities (Malaysia) Sdn
Bhd, Credit Suisse AG,  Singapore Branch,  and elsewhere in the world by the relevant authorized affiliate of the above.
This document may not be reproduced either in whole, or in part, without the written permission of the authors and Credit Suisse. © 2014 Credit Suisse Group
AG and/or its affiliates. All rights reserved
PUBLISHER
CREDIT SUISSE AG
Research Institute
Paradeplatz 8
CH-8070 Zurich
Switzerland
cs.researchinstitute@credit-suisse.com
PRODUCTION MANAGEMENT
INVESTMENT STRATEGY & RESEARCH
INVESTMENT PUBLISHING
Markus Kleeb (Head)
Ross Hewitt
Katharina Schlatter
AUTHORS
Stefano Natella
Michael O’Sullivan
CONTRIBUTORS
Nilanjan Das
Utkarsh Goklani
Christel Aranda Hassel
Gergely Hudecz
Shailesh Jha
Prateek Nigudkar
Vinit Sinha
EDITORIAL DEADLINE
25 July 2014
ADDITIONAL COPIES
Additional copies of this publication can be
ordered via the Credit Suisse publication shop
www.credit-suisse.com/publications or via your
customer advisor.
Imprint
RCE154590407/2014
CREDIT SUISSE AG
Research Institute
Paradeplatz 8
CH-8070 Zurich
Switzerland
cs.researchinstitute@credit-suisse.com
www.credit-suisse.com/researchinstitute
neutral
Printed Matter
No. 01-14-316782 – www.myclimate.org
© myclimate – The Climate Protection Partnership
PERFORMANCE

More Related Content

What's hot

The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and Development
The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and DevelopmentThe Effects of International Trade on Poverty and Development
The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and DevelopmentHaley Wadel
 
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentation
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentationMeeting 2 team B globalization presentation
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentationgcmnoteborn
 
Lifting the small boats
Lifting the small boatsLifting the small boats
Lifting the small boatsananto widodo
 
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?Edward Hugh
 
DS Keynote Menu 2017
DS Keynote Menu 2017DS Keynote Menu 2017
DS Keynote Menu 2017Daniel Silke
 
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd Healthcare consultant
 
February 2010 A Very Dangerous Decade
February 2010   A Very Dangerous DecadeFebruary 2010   A Very Dangerous Decade
February 2010 A Very Dangerous Decadegatelyw396
 
Trade ee background_globalization
Trade ee background_globalizationTrade ee background_globalization
Trade ee background_globalizationBokkul Ful
 
Globalization in HRP
Globalization in HRPGlobalization in HRP
Globalization in HRPGLewis16
 
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisation
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisationPowerpoint presentation of_business_globalisation
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisationshub-singhania
 
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...KhazanahResearchInstitute
 
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...KhazanahResearchInstitute
 
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...KhazanahResearchInstitute
 
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central America
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central AmericaFGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central America
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central AmericaFGV | Fundação Getulio Vargas
 
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practices
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business PracticesGlobalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practices
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practicesjackgowen
 
Uhy international-business-jan-14
Uhy international-business-jan-14Uhy international-business-jan-14
Uhy international-business-jan-14Dawgen Global
 
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman washington...
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman   washington...Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman   washington...
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman washington...JMHolifield
 

What's hot (19)

The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and Development
The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and DevelopmentThe Effects of International Trade on Poverty and Development
The Effects of International Trade on Poverty and Development
 
Common Purpose: Realigning Business, Economies, and Society
Common Purpose: Realigning Business, Economies, and SocietyCommon Purpose: Realigning Business, Economies, and Society
Common Purpose: Realigning Business, Economies, and Society
 
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentation
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentationMeeting 2 team B globalization presentation
Meeting 2 team B globalization presentation
 
Lifting the small boats
Lifting the small boatsLifting the small boats
Lifting the small boats
 
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?
Demographic revolution - A Threat To Our Pensions?
 
DS Keynote Menu 2017
DS Keynote Menu 2017DS Keynote Menu 2017
DS Keynote Menu 2017
 
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd
Unchained globalization by Dr.Mahboob ali khan Phd
 
February 2010 A Very Dangerous Decade
February 2010   A Very Dangerous DecadeFebruary 2010   A Very Dangerous Decade
February 2010 A Very Dangerous Decade
 
Trade ee background_globalization
Trade ee background_globalizationTrade ee background_globalization
Trade ee background_globalization
 
Globalization in HRP
Globalization in HRPGlobalization in HRP
Globalization in HRP
 
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisation
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisationPowerpoint presentation of_business_globalisation
Powerpoint presentation of_business_globalisation
 
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...
Session IV - Cross-National Frameworks for the Management of National Inequal...
 
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...
Session I - Framing the Conversation on Inequality and Development Choices by...
 
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...
Session IV - Policy Considerations in Addressing Malaysian Economic Inequalit...
 
The Artisan Fall 2013
The Artisan Fall 2013The Artisan Fall 2013
The Artisan Fall 2013
 
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central America
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central AmericaFGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central America
FGV / IBRE - América Latina | A look at Central America
 
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practices
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business PracticesGlobalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practices
Globalization And Its Affect Upon Domestic Business Practices
 
Uhy international-business-jan-14
Uhy international-business-jan-14Uhy international-business-jan-14
Uhy international-business-jan-14
 
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman washington...
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman   washington...Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman   washington...
Black america needs angels to create entrepreneurs, not superman washington...
 

Viewers also liked

Catalunya Lliure de Peatges
Catalunya Lliure de PeatgesCatalunya Lliure de Peatges
Catalunya Lliure de PeatgesMiqui Mel
 
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)Miqui Mel
 
Cost of Signing of Neymar Jr
Cost of Signing of Neymar JrCost of Signing of Neymar Jr
Cost of Signing of Neymar JrMiqui Mel
 
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your Business
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your BusinessHow to Create a Social Content Strategy for your Business
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your BusinessMiqui Mel
 
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal Miqui Mel
 
Rough Sleeping Statistics England
Rough Sleeping Statistics EnglandRough Sleeping Statistics England
Rough Sleeping Statistics EnglandMiqui Mel
 
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14Miqui Mel
 
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...Miqui Mel
 
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of Catalonia
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of CataloniaLegal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of Catalonia
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of CataloniaMiqui Mel
 
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17)
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17) The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17)
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17) Miqui Mel
 
1714 (IT In Transit #19)
1714 (IT In Transit #19)1714 (IT In Transit #19)
1714 (IT In Transit #19)Miqui Mel
 
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANC
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANCDeclaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANC
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANCMiqui Mel
 
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013Miqui Mel
 
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El Món
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El MónThe Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El Món
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El MónMiqui Mel
 
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)Miqui Mel
 
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)Miqui Mel
 
Les Inversions de la UE a Catalunya
Les Inversions de la UE a CatalunyaLes Inversions de la UE a Catalunya
Les Inversions de la UE a CatalunyaMiqui Mel
 
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014Corruption Perceptions Index 2014
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014Miqui Mel
 

Viewers also liked (18)

Catalunya Lliure de Peatges
Catalunya Lliure de PeatgesCatalunya Lliure de Peatges
Catalunya Lliure de Peatges
 
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)
Discovering (Catalan) America (IT In Transit #14)
 
Cost of Signing of Neymar Jr
Cost of Signing of Neymar JrCost of Signing of Neymar Jr
Cost of Signing of Neymar Jr
 
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your Business
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your BusinessHow to Create a Social Content Strategy for your Business
How to Create a Social Content Strategy for your Business
 
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal
El Que Cal Saber Sobre el Dèficit Fiscal
 
Rough Sleeping Statistics England
Rough Sleeping Statistics EnglandRough Sleeping Statistics England
Rough Sleeping Statistics England
 
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14
F.C.Barcelona - Balanç Area Social 2013-14
 
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...
El Sector Empresarial a Catalunya i Espanya Impacte Econòmic de diferents esc...
 
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of Catalonia
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of CataloniaLegal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of Catalonia
Legal Basis for a Referendum on the Political Future of Catalonia
 
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17)
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17) The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17)
The Catalan Welfare State (IT In Transit #17)
 
1714 (IT In Transit #19)
1714 (IT In Transit #19)1714 (IT In Transit #19)
1714 (IT In Transit #19)
 
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANC
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANCDeclaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANC
Declaració de Cornellà - Full de Ruta de l'ANC
 
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013
Barcelona-Catalonia - The Mediterranean Innovation Hub 2013
 
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El Món
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El MónThe Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El Món
The Catalan Way - Com Ens Veu El Món
 
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)
Looking to the Future (In Transit #30)
 
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)
Catalan Language in Education (In Transit #27)
 
Les Inversions de la UE a Catalunya
Les Inversions de la UE a CatalunyaLes Inversions de la UE a Catalunya
Les Inversions de la UE a Catalunya
 
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014Corruption Perceptions Index 2014
Corruption Perceptions Index 2014
 

Similar to The Success of Small Countries

Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic Inequality
Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic InequalityWorking For the Few - Political Capture and Economic Inequality
Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic InequalityMiqui Mel
 
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptx
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptxChapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptx
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptxumalHarun
 
GVCs a new development strategy for chile
GVCs   a new development strategy for chileGVCs   a new development strategy for chile
GVCs a new development strategy for chileAlfredo Barriga
 
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment Ii
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment IiPreparing For The 21st Century Installment Ii
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment IiAnthony Vincent
 
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency Peg
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency PegExporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency Peg
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency PegEdward Hugh
 
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...Trevor Hopper
 
What is DE- Globalization & its examples
What is DE- Globalization & its examplesWhat is DE- Globalization & its examples
What is DE- Globalization & its examplesDEEPAK KUMAR
 
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The Next
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The NextSaying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The Next
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The NextEdward Hugh
 
The drivers of income inequality
The drivers of income inequalityThe drivers of income inequality
The drivers of income inequalitystephenboydstuc
 
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's Economy
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's EconomyReport on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's Economy
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's EconomyThe New York Fed
 
Kyklos London Brochure
Kyklos London BrochureKyklos London Brochure
Kyklos London BrochureKyklosLondon
 
Globalization (the glory of the world)
Globalization (the glory of the world)Globalization (the glory of the world)
Globalization (the glory of the world)Morgan Stanley
 
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docx
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docxFINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docx
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docxericn8
 
Chapter 2 market globalism
Chapter 2 market globalismChapter 2 market globalism
Chapter 2 market globalismoryzasativa0720
 
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-en
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-enBp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-en
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-enSalisu Borodo
 
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdfamericandigitalshop
 
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012Shahab Khan
 

Similar to The Success of Small Countries (20)

Working for the Few
Working for the FewWorking for the Few
Working for the Few
 
Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic Inequality
Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic InequalityWorking For the Few - Political Capture and Economic Inequality
Working For the Few - Political Capture and Economic Inequality
 
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptx
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptxChapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptx
Chapter-2 Characterstics of UDs.pptx
 
GVCs a new development strategy for chile
GVCs   a new development strategy for chileGVCs   a new development strategy for chile
GVCs a new development strategy for chile
 
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment Ii
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment IiPreparing For The 21st Century Installment Ii
Preparing For The 21st Century Installment Ii
 
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency Peg
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency PegExporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency Peg
Exporting Your Way Out Of Trouble Under A Currency Peg
 
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...
Final globalisation accounting and developing countries cpa submission march ...
 
What is DE- Globalization & its examples
What is DE- Globalization & its examplesWhat is DE- Globalization & its examples
What is DE- Globalization & its examples
 
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The Next
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The NextSaying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The Next
Saying Goodbye To One Crisis and Hello To The Next
 
The drivers of income inequality
The drivers of income inequalityThe drivers of income inequality
The drivers of income inequality
 
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's Economy
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's EconomyReport on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's Economy
Report on the Competitiveness of Puerto Rico's Economy
 
Kyklos London Brochure
Kyklos London BrochureKyklos London Brochure
Kyklos London Brochure
 
Globalization (the glory of the world)
Globalization (the glory of the world)Globalization (the glory of the world)
Globalization (the glory of the world)
 
2013 Depth Index of Globalization
2013 Depth Index of Globalization2013 Depth Index of Globalization
2013 Depth Index of Globalization
 
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docx
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docxFINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docx
FINANCE AND LABOR PERSPECTIVES ONRISK, INEQUALITY, AND DEMO.docx
 
Chapter 2 market globalism
Chapter 2 market globalismChapter 2 market globalism
Chapter 2 market globalism
 
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-en
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-enBp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-en
Bp working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-en
 
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf
1. What exactly is globalization2. What has been the impact of th.pdf
 
ebbf25 key drivers towards human prosperity by Augusto Lopez-Claros
ebbf25 key drivers towards human prosperity by Augusto Lopez-Clarosebbf25 key drivers towards human prosperity by Augusto Lopez-Claros
ebbf25 key drivers towards human prosperity by Augusto Lopez-Claros
 
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012
Kevin Lynch on Innovation at IPAC Annual Conference August 20 2012
 

More from Miqui Mel

TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - Fallo
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - FalloTC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - Fallo
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - FalloMiqui Mel
 
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCatTC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCatMiqui Mel
 
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a Espanya
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a EspanyaCom Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a Espanya
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a EspanyaMiqui Mel
 
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CC
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CCAcord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CC
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CCMiqui Mel
 
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...Miqui Mel
 
Fem la República, Declaració de Vilanova
Fem la República, Declaració de VilanovaFem la República, Declaració de Vilanova
Fem la República, Declaració de VilanovaMiqui Mel
 
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de Futur
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de FuturFil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de Futur
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de FuturMiqui Mel
 
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015Miqui Mel
 
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015Miqui Mel
 
El Govern en Funcions
El Govern en FuncionsEl Govern en Funcions
El Govern en FuncionsMiqui Mel
 
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´Independència
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´IndependènciaEl Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´Independència
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´IndependènciaMiqui Mel
 
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015Miqui Mel
 
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna Miqui Mel
 
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...Miqui Mel
 
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...Miqui Mel
 
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...Miqui Mel
 
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014Miqui Mel
 
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013Miqui Mel
 
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love Catalonia
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love CataloniaDiari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love Catalonia
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love CataloniaMiqui Mel
 
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)Miqui Mel
 

More from Miqui Mel (20)

TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - Fallo
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - FalloTC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - Fallo
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat - Fallo
 
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCatTC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat
TC vs el Pla Estratègic d'Acció Exterior GenCat
 
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a Espanya
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a EspanyaCom Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a Espanya
Com Es Distribueix la Corrupció Política a Espanya
 
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CC
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CCAcord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CC
Acord Parlamentari Junts Pel Si-CUP-CC
 
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...
Frau i Improvisació en la Despesa - Anàlisi del pressupost de defensa espanyo...
 
Fem la República, Declaració de Vilanova
Fem la República, Declaració de VilanovaFem la República, Declaració de Vilanova
Fem la República, Declaració de Vilanova
 
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de Futur
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de FuturFil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de Futur
Fil a l'Agulla - I Ara Què? Bases per a un Acord Polític de Futur
 
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015
Baròmetre d'Opinió Política Catalunya · 3a Onada 2015
 
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015
Political Opinion Barometer Catalonia - 3rd Wave 2015
 
El Govern en Funcions
El Govern en FuncionsEl Govern en Funcions
El Govern en Funcions
 
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´Independència
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´IndependènciaEl Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´Independència
El Cami d'Escòcia Cap al Referendum d´Independència
 
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015
Reuters Institute Digital News Report 2015
 
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna
La Identitat de Barcelona i dels Barcelonins a l’Època Moderna
 
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...
Junts Pel Sí - Acord per crear un Estat independent i establir un Govern de c...
 
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...
Economic effects of a potential secession of Catalonia from Spain and paths f...
 
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...
Carta adreçada al M. Hble. Sr. Artur Mas, l’Hble. Sr. Oriol Junqueras i el Sr...
 
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2014
 
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013
Anuari Mediacat: Els Silencis Mediatics de 2013
 
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love Catalonia
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love CataloniaDiari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love Catalonia
Diari ANC #03 - I Love Spain, I Love Catalonia
 
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)
Political Opinion Barometer - CEO (July 2015)
 

Recently uploaded

12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdfFIRST INDIA
 
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdfFIRST INDIA
 
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.ppt
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.pptGeostrategic significance of South Asian countries.ppt
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.pptUsmanKaran
 
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdfFIRST INDIA
 
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptx
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptxPolitical-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptx
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptxSasikiranMarri
 
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)Power in International Relations (Pol 5)
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)ssuser583c35
 

Recently uploaded (6)

12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
12042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
 
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
11042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
 
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.ppt
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.pptGeostrategic significance of South Asian countries.ppt
Geostrategic significance of South Asian countries.ppt
 
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
13042024_First India Newspaper Jaipur.pdf
 
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptx
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptxPolitical-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptx
Political-Ideologies-and-The-Movements.pptx
 
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)Power in International Relations (Pol 5)
Power in International Relations (Pol 5)
 

The Success of Small Countries

  • 1. The Success of Small Countries July 2014 Research InstituteThought leadership from Credit Suisse Research and the world’s foremost experts
  • 2. Contents 03 Introduction 04 The debate 06 Success: Size, age, trade and heterogeneity 12 Intangible infrastructure 19 Efficiencies or inefficiencies of scale? 26 The break-up of Czechoslovakia 28 German re-unification 30 Cities and corporations 36 References 39 Imprint / Disclaimer COVERPHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/OTMARW,PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/ALIJA For more information, please contact: Richard Kersley, Head of Global Securities Products and Themes, Credit Suisse Investment Banking, richard.kersley@credit-suisse.com Michael O’Sullivan, Chief Investment Officer, UK & EEMEA, Credit Suisse Private Banking & Wealth Management, michael.o’sullivan@credit-suisse.com SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 2
  • 3. Introduction Since 1945, the number of UN country members has risen from nearly 50 to 193, a nearly four-fold rise in the number of countries in the world, two-thirds of which could be classified as ‘small’. Note that 77% of all of the small states in the world have been formed in the past 70 years. Many of these have been born out of transi- tions to democracy. In a recent Credit Suisse Research Institute report (From Spring to Revival) we noted 87 transitions to democracy since 1952, 46% of which involved small countries such as Georgia, Latvia, the Czech Republic and Slovakia. There is clearly an important underlying trend at work here, the rise of small states. Does size matter to the economic success of a state? Are smaller states at a dis- advantage versus larger ones in an increasingly competi- tive world? Can breakups lead to better economic outcomes? Not only is the number of small countries growing, but the global political economy has changed in a way that both enables and challenges small countries. For exam- ple, globalization (as measured by global trade as a % of GDP) and the rise in the number of states have grown in tandem. Globalization has driven the growth of small states and separate customs territories (WTO definition) such as Dubai, Hong Kong SAR, Singapore and Ireland. One innovation in this study is our construction of the CS Country Strength index, that helps to identify those small countries that are best placed to weather the pressures placed upon them by globalization. Recent financial crises have also shone the spotlight on small countries. They were the prominent financial and economic losers in the aftermath of the global finan- cial crisis and the onset of the Eurozone crisis. Peak to trough falls in GDP from 2008 to 2014 have been most dramatic for the Baltic States, Iceland, Ireland, and Por- tugal. On the other hand, it is worth mentioning that older small countries such as Switzerland and Sweden fared much better. We fully recognize that economic considerations are just one dimension of many when issues of statehood are at stake. Yet, there is no doubt the Eurozone crisis has brought to the fore the issues of the economic inde- pendence, political power and institutional quality of Europe’s small states. As small states have been amongst the economic success stories of the past 20 years, we think it is worth exploring this trend in depth. Stefano Natella, Head of Global Equity Research, Investment Banking Giles Keating, Head of Research and Deputy Global CIO, Private Banking and Wealth Management SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 3
  • 4. We do not seek to add to these arguments but we would like to add another, important dimension to the debate. That is, can small, independent states be successful on their own? The issue is a complex one. We need to define size and we need to agree on how to measure success (GDP growth, GDP per capita, etc).1 But other factors might influence the relationship between size and success. Consider trade openness, homogeneity and age for instance. The more open a coun- try is to trade the more the whole world becomes the relevant market for that country. So in a world of free trade, political borders are eco- nomically irrelevant and small countries can be as successful as some of the larger ones, that can benefit from a large domestic market. Homogeneity or heterogeneity is another important issue. As we will see, heterogeneity provides a ceiling to a potential size of a country. For instance, age or “vintage” has multiple influences: the stability of institutions or infrastructure depends on the country’s age. Older, small countries, notably those in the Alpine and Nor- dic regions tend to be pinpointed as the ‘model’ for other small nations to follow though many of the factors that have contrib- uted to the success of the Alpine or Nordic countries are not transferrable. Finally, we consider the lessons and economies of the ami- cable divorces of the Czech Republic and Slovakia, and the fusion of West and East Germany – clearly recognizing that these are all unique cases with their specific characteristics. What is new or unexpected? •• The rise of new small states in the context of globalization has been one of the key geo-economic megatrends of the past 30 years. We found a negative correlation between size and GDP per capita. This is particularly true for high income countries. 1 We adopt two relatively simple definitions of state size. 1. Population: Large: Population > 25 million, Medium: 10 million < Population < 25 million, Small: Population < 10 million. By this classification, we have 100 small, 34 medium and 47 large countries. 2. We have also overlaid territory size to population as another measure following the work of Alouini & Hubert. For the sake of comparison we have included the likes of Hong Kong, which is a Special Administrative Region of the People’s Republic of China. By this classification (PAC index), we have 109 small, 46 medium and 39 large countries. The debate The debate on what would happen if Scotland or Catalonia became independent opens up some very interesting arguments. On one side we have politicians and corporations advocating the “united we stand, divided we fail” view. Their main argument is that a break-up would create a lot of uncertainty on the legal, monetary and fiscal fronts. On the other side, those in favor of independence argue that Scotland and Catalonia are culturally, politically and economically distinct from the “Union”. •• If we add education, healthcare or intangible infrastructure as measures of success, we find that small countries do proportionately very well. For example, with respect to UN’s Human Development Index (which combines GNI per cap- ita, education and health metrics), small countries make up over half of the world’s top 30 countries. Scotland and Catalonia show higher HDI scores than the U.K. and Spain, respectively. •• Our Country Strength indicator (which includes other fac- tors such as HDI, Credit Suisse Intangible Infrastructure Index, Credit Suisse Globalization index, etc.) has six small countries in the top 10. In addition, wealth inequality is less pronounced for small than large countries. •• Small countries are more homogeneous and homogeneity plays an important role in determining the success of a country. Cultural, ethnic, religious and linguistic diversity creates a ceiling to the potential size of a country. Homoge- neous countries tend to have higher HDI scores. •• We also found that small countries are more open to inter- national trade or have embraced globalization to a higher extent than larger countries. Trade openness is another fac- tor that is statistically relevant in determining the success of a country. Increased specialization helps small countries be more successful in an increasingly competitive environ- ment. However, we also found that small countries tend to experience higher volatility in economic growth. •• In theory, large countries should benefit from economies of scale. We found that there is a weak correlation between government spending as a percentage of GDP and size. The only area where large countries appear to benefit from economies of scale is in public sector salaries, which are probably a good proxy for the relative size of the govern- ment. Smaller countries spend more on education and healthcare as a percentage of GDP (where scale should not be a factor), key factors for the long-term success of a country. PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/CLAUDIODIVIZIA SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 4
  • 5. •• Contrary to expectations, large countries’ economies of scale do not accrue to the population. Our research shows that large countries tend to have higher tax rates for indi- viduals (by 5%). So the cost of funding public services for the individual is higher in larger countries than in small countries. This is true in theory also for corporate rates, which are higher in larger countries. But the ability of cor- porations and multinationals to minimize their global tax bill is evident when measuring corporate tax collections as a percentage of GDP: it is significantly smaller for larger countries. •• We found a significant difference in economic, social and institutional performance between ‘old’ small countries and ‘new’ small countries. In other words, for some new coun- tries where the institutional and legal framework is not yet developed, it might take time to achieve the benefits we uncovered for smaller countries. Institutional quality, rule of law, investment in technology and education are key drivers of the ‘path’ toward higher output levels. •• As expected, urbanization is a major driver of economic growth. Hong Kong SAR and Singapore show among the world’s highest GDP per capita and five city-states are among the top 30 in the HDI metrics. Cities also benefit from significant economies of scale, a higher proportion of services in the economy relative to manufacturing and agri- culture, and are completely open to trade. •• Companies are also an important engine for growth. Of the top 500 companies by market capitalization, 86% are based in large countries. However, the contribution of large companies to economic growth accrues to a whole set of countries, not just to the home country. One third of U.S. multinationals’ workforce for example is based abroad. In sectors like manufacturing or retail, production often tends to be based in countries different from the “home” country. So, small countries do not need to attempt to attract large corporations to grow at a faster rate, but they need to spe- cialize in areas that provide large corporations with a com- petitive edge. Figure 1 Evolution of countries Source: UN, Credit Suisse 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Global trade as a % of global GDP 55 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Number of UN members 1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 Number of UN members Global trade as a % of global GDP (rhs) SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 5
  • 6. Success: Size, age, trade and heterogeneity Intangible infrastructure – education, governance, the rule of law – the ability to manage globalization and macro volatility, human development factors drive the success of small countries. Corporate tax receipts, size, democracy and intellectual property are much less important factors. In order to measure the influence of size on suc- cess, we took a sample of 58 countries for which we analyzed data over a 33-year period (1980-2012) and ran a balanced panel regression. We used GDP per capita as a measure of success and the PCA index as a measure of size. We found a strong negative rela- tionship between size and GDP per capita (see Table 1). In a recent paper, Alouini and Hubert use GDP growth as a measure of success. They con- cluded that in general there is no clear relationship between size and GDP growth; but for high income countries the relationship is negative and this is par- ticularly true for the Eurozone countries. This is extremely relevant as the Eurozone countries tend to represent quite a homogeneous sample. In the sample we used above, given the long time frame, small old countries dominate the small country sample. Is age important? Age or perhaps ‘vintage’ appears to have some influence. There is a four-fold dif- ference in GDP per capita between ‘old’ small states (those in existence before 1945) and ‘new’ small coun- tries. This is understandable given that many new small states have come into existence in the emerging world. It also helps to put in perspective the fascination that many economists have with the steady performance of the Alpine economies (Switzerland and the Nordic countries). Further, as Figure 2 shows, new and old small coun- tries together tend to have a higher per capita GDP than medium sized countries, though they fare less well than the median level for large countries. These aggregated figures disguise the contribution that largely ‘old’ small countries make to the world’s economic elite. They make up 90%, 63% and 66% of the world’s Top 10, 30 and 50 countries by GDP per capita, respectively. This at least underlines the importance of small coun- tries as economic dynamos and policy models. Table 1 Regression size vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Variable Coefficient Standard Error t-Statistic Prob. C 5.26 0.11 47.39 0.00 PCA Index -0.52 0.04 -12.32 0.00 Trade openness 0.15 0.02 9.33 0.00 Inflation 0.00 0.00 0.15 0.88 Real Interest Rate -0.00 0.00 -1.22 0.22 Regression results R-squared 0.98 Adjusted R-squared 0.98 S.E. of regression 0.07 Sum squared resid 9.37 Log likelihood 2374.74 F-statistic 1202.08 Prob(F-statistic) 0 Figure 2 Wealth held by top 10% of the population Source: Credit Suisse 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 6
  • 7. Figure 3 Nominal GDP per capita small (median) Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 6,000 7,000 8,000 Small Medium Large Wealth offers another way of assessing prosperity. Here we draw upon the data available in the Credit Suisse Global Wealth Report that measures the wealth of the 4.6 billion adults in the world (wealth is mea- sured as financial plus non-financial wealth (i.e. prop- erty less debt). Wealth tends to have a high correlation with GDP but in itself can also reveal how small states manage their prosperity, particularly in the context of the current debate on wealth inequality. In terms of wealth per adult, small countries are just ahead of large countries on average. When we sharpen the analysis, we find that wealth concentration as highlighted by the proportion of total wealth held by the top 10%, large countries (62%) appear to be more unequal than small ones (54%), Figure 2. What is also interesting is that while there is a gulf in difference between old small countries and new small countries in average wealth per adult (USD 140,000 vs. USD 25,000) there is not such a large difference between them in terms of concentration of wealth in the top 10%. We note that of the top 10 countries in the world by wealth per adult, 6 of them are small countries led by Switzerland and followed by Norway. To further extend the analysis beyond GDP or wealth- based measures, we measure other variables of political economic and social attainment. On the basis of the UN’s Human Development Index 2 ,‘old’ small countries make up 11 of the world’s top 20 countries (Figure 4). If we break the data down further, we find that smaller countries in general tend to have higher human development scores (HDI) though the reverse is not true, as a significant share of large countries in our sample also score high on HDI (Figure 5). Interest- ingly, low and medium level HDI scores are dominant in medium-sized countries. In general, we can say that older, established small countries lead the rankings of global human development score. A positive trend is that new countries have in gen- eral seen an improvement in their human development rankings. As Figure 6 shows, smaller states like Croa- tia, Slovenia and the Baltics in particular have seen their HDI scores improve consistently. In several regions of the world, independence movements exist or have existed (e.g. Quebec). Purely for the sake of comparison we have included them in the human development score table on page 8. Given the prevailing interest, we calculate the HDI scores for Catalonia, Flanders, Wallonia, Quebec and Scotland. Quebec would rank the highest among these regions/countries and 13th globally, compared to 11th for Canada. However, based on our 2 http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/hdi The Human Development Index (HDI) is a composite measure of health, education and income that was introduced in the first Human Development Report in 1990 as an alternative to purely economic assessments of national progress, such as GDP growth. It soon became the most widely accepted and cited measure of its kind, and has been adapted for national use by many countries. HDI values and rankings in the global Human Development Report are calculated using the latest internationally comparable data from mandated inter- national data providers. Previous HDI values and rankings are retro- actively recalculated using the same updated data sets and current methodologies. Figure 4 Top 20 based on HDI Source: UNDP Old small 45% New small 10% Medium 15% Large 30% Figure 5 Human Development Index vs. country size Source: UNDP, Credit Suisse 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70% of total Large countries Medium sized countries Small countries High HDI Scores>0.75 Medium HDI Scores between 0.45-0.75 Low HDI Scores<0.45 SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 7
  • 8. calculations, both Catalonia and Scotland will rank higher than Spain and the UK, respectively. Catalonia would rank 20th globally, while Spain ranks currently 23rd and would slip to 26th ex-Catalonia. Scotland would rank 23rd if we include a geographical alloca- tion to Scotland’s GNI related to the North Sea oil out- put, versus the current 27th place for the UK and the hypothetical 30th for the UK ex-Scotland. Note that even excluding any allocation of oil output, Scotland would still rank ahead of the UK, but just so. We mentioned before that trade and heterogeneity influence the potential size of a country and its suc- cess. Let us focus on heterogeneity first. Small countries can differ from large ones in terms of their cultural diversity, the larger the country the more diverse its population is likely to be. Following the approach established in Alesina & Spolaore (2004), we have developed a fractionalization index that aims to gauge the degree of ethnic, religious and linguistic diversity between small and larger countries. We sim- ply equally weight the fractionalization scores across the three variables – language, ethnicity and religion. As the source data is old (2001) there will have been Country HDI Score HDI Rank Norway O.955 1 Australia 0.938 2 United States 0.937 3 Netherlands 0.921 4 Germany 0.92 5 New Zealand 0.919 6 Ireland 0.916 7 Sweden 0.916 7 Switzerland 0.913 9 Japan 0.912 10 Canada 0.911 11 South Korea 0.909 12 Quebec 0.906 13 Hong Kong SAR 0.906 13 Iceland 0.906 13 Denmark 0.901 16 Israel 0.900 17 Belgium 0.897 18 Flanders 0.895 19 Austria 0.895 19 Singapore 0.895 19 Catalonia 0.894 22 France 0.893 23 Finland 0.892 24 Slovenia 0.892 24 Scotland* 0.887 26 Spain 0.885 27 Liechtenstein 0.883 28 Italy 0.881 29 Spain (Ex-Catalonia) 0.880 30 Luxembourg 0.875 31 United Kingdom 0.875 32 Czech Republic 0.873 33 United Kingdom (ex-Scotland) 0.871 34 Wallonia 0.869 35 Greece 0.86 36 Brunei Darussalam 0.855 37 Cyprus 0.848 38 Malta 0.847 39 Andorra 0.846 40 Estonia 0.846 41 Slovakia 0.84 42 * Accounting for a geographical share of North Sea oil production. Table 2 HDI league tables Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 8
  • 9. PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/PERESANZ Figure 6 Average change in HDI percentile rank since independence Source: UNDP, Credit Suisse -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 change in HDI percentile rank Croatia Lithuania Latvia Estonia Slovenia Palau Slovakia CzechRepublic Kazakhstan Georgia Ukraine GroupAverage Montenegro Belarus BosniaandHerzegovina Macedonia Germany Moldova Azerbaijan Turkmenistan Eritrea Uzbekistan Tajikistan Armenia Timor-Leste Kyrgyzstan SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 9
  • 10. some changes to the figures, notably in ethnicity. The overall picture shows that small countries are amongst the least ‘fractionalized’ or rather more homogenous. We also note that the ‘old small’ coun- tries have the lowest median fractionalization score (Figure 7). There can be several explanations for this, and we will discuss this later on when we focus on the efficiencies or inefficiencies of scale. Trade or globalization off the world economy is another important variable in determining the suc- cess of a country, particularly small countries. What is globalization? In general, it is not difficult to distil a couple of core characteristics from the many defini- tions that are offered of globalization. One is that glo- balization involves the increasing integration of mar- kets, economies and societies, as borders become less relevant. The other is that integration brings increased interdependence between nations. Taking the Foreign Policy/AT Kearney methodol- ogy as a basis, we construct a globalization index based around economic, social and technological factors3 . As Table 3 highlights, small countries tend to dominate the globalization rankings, led by Luxem- bourg, Singapore, Switzerland and Ireland. In fact of the top 20 countries as ranked by our methodology, 85% are small. 3 Economic globalization: Trade openness (% of GDP), FDI (% of GDP), FPI (% of GDP) Social globalization: Cellphone subscription (per 100 people), Telecom lines (per 100 people), Remittances (inward + outward) (% of GDP). There is a partial overlap with Intangible Infrastructure Index’s Technological Infrastructure dimension here Corporate openness: Ease of doing business rank (by World Bank), import delays (in days), mean tariff rates (in %), Taxes on trade (% of government revenue). Once again, first three indicators are common to II’s business services dimension Technological globalization: Internet users (per 100 people), secure servers (per million people). Overlap with II Index’s technology dimension Luxembourg leads the index because it has the highest proportion of foreign investment flows (direct and portfolio) to its GDP among all countries Figure 8 Expectedly, smaller countries tend to be more globalized Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Figure 9 Trade openness Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100% of total Low score Medium score High score Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Trade openness (% of GDP) Large Medium Small Figure 7 Fractionalization vs. HDI Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40 0.45 0.50 Median fractionalization High HDI Medium HDI Low HDI SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 10
  • 11. PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/PERCDS European countries dominate the top while African nations tend to be the least globalized. Table 3 Globalization index Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Country Size Globalization Index score Luxembourg S 0.93 Singapore S 0.93 Hong Kong SAR S 0.88 Switzerland S 0.85 Ireland S 0.83 Belgium M 0.82 Iceland S 0.81 Netherlands M 0.81 Estonia S 0.81 Hungary S 0.79 Norway S 0.79 Montenegro S 0.78 Denmark S 0.78 Malta S 0.78 Bahrain S 0.77 Austria S 0.77 United Kingdom L 0.77 Sweden S 0.75 Finland S 0.75 Cyprus S 0.75 Malaysia L 0.74 Panama S 0.74 Portugal M 0.73 Bulgaria S 0.73 Mauritius S 0.72 There are some data issues here that we should flag. Small countries that act as trade or financial entrepots (i.e. Luxembourg) have very heavy finance and trade flows relative to their GDP size and as such appear intensely ‘globalized’ in an economic sense. Monaco ranked high, though its excellent performance was almost entirely driven by an unusual number of secure internet servers and internet users per capita. The rank for St. Kitts and Nevis has also been boosted by extremely low trade tariff rates and very high density of technological infrastructure. Leaving these “excep- tions” aside, Table 3 shows a very clear picture.4 Using the same data mentioned above (58 coun- tries and 33 years), we found that trade openness and GDP per capita are strongly correlated. As expected, openness to trade allows for success and small countries tend to be more open. So, it is easy to conclude that the globalization of the world econ- omy has been a major factor in the success of smaller economies. The other side of the coin though is that small countries are more susceptible to show higher volatility in economic growth. However, Alouini and Hubert show that there is no correlation between trade openness and economic volatility. Their hypothesis is that in a more globalized economy, small countries have tended to specialize in certain areas (Singapore in IT services for financial companies, for example) and that has made them more exposed to the volatility of that particular sector. Later on, we will focus on what determines the ability of countries to withstand economic shocks. 4 https://www.credit-suisse.com/ch/en/news-and-expertise/ research/credit-suisse-research-institute/publications.html SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 11
  • 12. Figure 10 Intangible infrastructure (II) Index vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Intangible infrastructure Our focus on human development indicators helps to open up the debate on the factors that drive the success of smaller economies and societies. We developed the notion of ‘intangible infrastructure’ (II)4 which we had defined as “the set of factors that develop human capability and permit the easy and efficient growth of business activity”. These factors can be essentially political, legal or socio-economic in nature. Examples of political factors include the degree of political stability or the strength of the institutional framework. Legal fac- tors include the rule of law, tax policies and intel- lectual and physical property rights protection. Examples of socio-economic factors include research and development capabilities, business processes or employee training and education. We consider five specific components of intan- gible infrastructure – education, healthcare, finance, business services and technology5 . Our sense is that while developing countries can achieve a record of high growth through physical investment (i.e. physical infrastructure), they need to cultivate intangible infrastructure in order to achieve a high and sustained level of growth and human development. In our analysis, we update our intangible infrastructure rankings that score coun- tries from 0 to 1, with increasing values indicating increasing strength of infrastructure. The link between the level of GDP a country enjoys and the quality of its intangible infrastructure is evident in Figure 10, where levels of intangible infrastructure appear to be linked to GDP per cap- ita. We repeat this graphic for the small country universe only, and the relation holds, in just as strong a form (Figure 11). Education is a key determinant of human capa- bility. The value of education is intrinsic in almost all levels of economic output. As we illustrate in Figure 12, and discuss in more detail later, the correlation between high school educational attainment and GDP per capita is particularly strong . We can also track the historical precedents of economies, such as the early “Asian tigers” whose emphasis on investing in education paved the way for their suc- cess. Government commitment to education can be shown to have a significant impact on the nature of growth that economies then display, as much as the GDP level itself. 5 The sub-components of the intangible infrastructure index are as fol- lows: Education: Secondary and Tertiary enrolment ratio. Healthcare: Infant mortality, Life expectancy and health spending per capita. Technology: Cellphone users (per 100), telephone lines (per 100), secure servers (per million), Internet users (per 100), R&D expendi- ture (% of GDP). Financial services: Credit Information score, legal rights score, lending risk premium, Equity market capitalization (% of GDP). Business services: Ease of doing business rank, Import delays, mean tariff rates, procedures needed to register a business Figure 11 II Index vs. GDP per capita (small country version) Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Figure 12 High school education vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse R² = 0.71 0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Intangible Infra. score Qatar Norway Denmark Seychelles Suriname R² = 0.6844 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 Gross secondary school enrolment ratio Norway USA Ireland Switzerland Iceland JapanItaly China Poland South Africa Angola 0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) R² = 0.7623 0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 Intangible Infra. score USA Germany Australia Norway Finland Italy Switzerland China India KoreaMalaysia Vietnam PolandTurkey CzechMexico Colombia Bahrain Oman Saudi Arabia SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 12
  • 13. With considerations such as life expectancy (Fig- ure 13) and related demographic trends, healthcare is another key factor in determining the average individual’s output. Through time and across bor- ders, there are very few exceptions to the rule that better healthcare fosters an environment of higher economic activity as well as human development. Despite this fact, it has not been a priority in many of the markets that we currently view as high growth markets such as China. This looks set to change. While we have sought to categorize the nature of intangible infrastructure in these five categories, in reality, it is far more complicated than that. It is of course heavily inter-related and interdependent. It is not impossible, but it is highly unlikely that any country with a high degree of technology penetra- tion would not also have a fairly comprehensive edu- cation system. In the same way, financial systems would struggle in the absence of a legal framework and advances in technology might falter without property rights to support the R&D. Adding support to the case for “intangible infra- structure” are the broad trends in demographics, economics, society and geopolitics that point toward the rising importance of intangible factors, as well as the significant body of academic literature on economics and development. Nobel prize-winning work by Robert Solow has helped to structure ideas on the role that technology and human capital play in generating economic growth. In turn, this has paved the way for theories that map out the means by which developing countries could “catch up” to wealthier ones. Acemoglu and Robinson6 are amongst the leading academic con- tributors on this topic, stressing the strong link between the economic development of states and their institutional strength. Stability rather than democracy We note that the notion of a “fair society” is not necessarily a prerequisite for intangible infrastruc- ture to function. In the political-economic field, a good deal of the academic literature that links income and economic growth to “intangibles” has focused on democracy. At a broad level, the rela- tionship between democracy and development is a close one, though the causality of this relationship is increasingly being questioned. Instead, the emerg- ing consensus is that institutions and intangible fac- tors like the rule of law matter more for economic development than democracy itself. 6 ‘D. Acemoglu & J. Robinson ‘Why Nations Fail?’ (Deckle Edge, 2012)’ PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/DBVIRAGO SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 13
  • 14. Figure 13 Life expectancy vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Our own findings suggest that institutions, or at least the quality of institutions, drive the distribution of resources in an economy and the way incentives and contracts are set up. Decent institutions encourage trust, investment in human capital and help to lower the frictions of doing business. A simple illustration is to compare the fit of GDP per capita with (a) World Bank data that scores the Rule of Law in each country and (b) with Political Freedom scores, again from the World Bank. The data clearly shows that the rule of law (R2 of 0.5 with GDP) seems to be a far more important deter- minant of economic success than political freedom (R2 of 0.15 with GDP, and 0.11 for small countries only). See Figures 14, 15 and 16. Equally, if we examine state fragility7 index developed by Systemic Peace as a variable, there is a marked difference between small and medium countries, with small countries in general having much lower fragility scores. Medium sized states, mostly in Western Asia and Africa, tend to be more fragile than the rest. Small countries and intangible infrastructure To get into the detail of our intangible infrastruc- ture index, Table 3 highlights the top 25 countries in terms of our intangible infrastructure rankings, with small countries such as Finland and Denmark, as well as bigger states Australia and the UK to the fore. Many of the countries that do well here are ‘usual suspects’ from the Nordic region, though New Zealand in particular scores well. Singapore, Ireland and Israel follow on. It seems that excellence in intangible infrastruc- ture is a small country speciality. Small countries make up 7 of the top 10 countries by intangible infrastructure and 60% of the top 30. From Figure 17, we see that medium sized countries fare less well here. The results are interesting because they suggest that small countries deploy their resources well and get a positive return on their investment. In addition, we note that when we compare the changes in the II ranking from 2011 to 2013, small countries tend to be prominent in terms of having the best improvements in intangible infrastructure (Czech Republic, Iceland, Qatar, Bulgaria and Cyprus). When we break down the overall intangible infrastructure index into its five component parts, small (mostly old) countries score best on four of five criteria (Figure 18). The exception is financial services, where large cities (London, Frankfurt and New York) in large countries have historically had an advantage in terms of the scale and depth of their financial markets and also where in the recent past the record of small countries as financial pow- erhouses has been a checkered one. Another interesting break out is to examine patents, which in larger countries have tended to mark economic 7 www.systemicpeace.org Figure 14 Rule of law vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Figure 15 Political freedom vs. GDP per capita Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Figure 16 Political freedom vs. GDP per capita (small country version) Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse R² = 0.5264 -2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 Rule of law score Qatar Singapore Sweden USA China Switzerland Russia India Ireland Bahrain Malaysia Brazil Japan UK 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0 R² = 0.5967 40.00 45.00 50.00 55.00 60.00 65.00 70.00 75.00 80.00 85.00 Life expectancy (years, 2012) Japan USA Germany France Spain Norway ChinaIndia Brazil Russia20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0 R² = 0.1563 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Political freedom score Luxembourg Qatar USA China India Switzerland Sweden Singapore Kuwait Japan UK Brazil Russia20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0 R² = 0.116 Political freedom score Norway Austria Israel Bulgaria Qatar BosniaLaos Singapore Kuwait Brunei Oman Bahrain UAE Eq. Guinea 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 GDP per capita (USD, PPP, 2012) 0 SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 14
  • 15. success (Figures 19 and 20), though for some of the smaller countries that top the II league tables, patent applications appear to be low, with Israel an exception here. When we compare ‘old’ small countries to ‘new’ small countries, the older ones like Switzerland or Sweden have a clear and understandable advan- tage. What is interesting however is to compare new small countries to large and medium ones, and here new small states are clearly in the ascendancy. Our sense is that intangible infrastructure forms the backbone of a country, a key conduit for eco- nomic growth, and it is a crucial determinant in a state’s ability to withstand and engage with global- ization. For instance a country is more likely to engage in international trade if the rule of law holds and if its financial institutions are well developed. A Country Strength Index So far, we have examined some of the individual factors that are believed to influence the success of countries. Bringing this together we develop the CS Country Strength Index. The aim is to rank countries on the basis of the quality of their institu- tions and intangible infrastructure, their aptness to thrive in a globalized world, their ability to grow con- sistently with low volatility and lower volatility mac- roeconomic output and their level of human devel- opment. These many angles are closely related and in most cases the causality between them is hard to unravel. Our sense is that by looking at social and institutional aspects of states as well as eco- nomic ones, we achieve as rounded as possible a view on a state and in particular of its ability to be successful on a consistent basis. In detail the factors we consider are as follows: •• The UN Human Development Indicator, •• The Credit Suisse Intangible Infrastructure index globalization index •• Macroeconomic volatility8 •• Governance9 In general the ‘Strength’ strikes a chord with both the analysis we have carried out on the sub- components of the Strength index and with the broad literature on political economic development. Small countries tend to do well in terms of ‘strength’ but the results are biased in favor of ‘old’ small countries. Thirteen of the top twenty countries are small states, led by Switzerland, followed by Singa- pore and Hong Kong SAR, Denmark, Ireland and 8 Here we have taken two variables- Standard Deviation of GDP growth rates and inflation, taken from World Bank database, from 1960 onward. The average of these two standard devia- tions is then taken and then we assign them percentile rank such that lower volatility is given a higher rank. There is no clear relationship between age and macro volatility. Economic volatil- ity is high in old Eastern European and Latin American countries (Uruguay, Bulgaria and Albania for example) whereas it is still small in closed island economies (Cape Verde, Pacific Islands). Surprisingly, macro volatility is not very high even for new oil- rich states in Asia. 9 The average of Transparency International’s Corruption Percep- tions Index Center for Systemic Peace’s State Fragility Index. Table 4 Top 25 countries by intangible infrastructure (II) Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Country Size II Index score United Kingdom L 0.89 Finland S 0.89 Australia M 0.89 Singapore S 0.88 Hong Kong SAR S 0.88 Sweden S 0.87 Denmark S 0.87 Switzerland S 0.87 Netherlands M 0.86 Iceland S 0.86 Norway S 0.86 New Zealand S 0.86 Ireland S 0.85 Israel S 0.84 United States L 0.83 Korea, Rep. L 0.83 Japan L 0.83 Austria S 0.82 France L 0.81 Canada L 0.81 Estonia S 0.80 Spain L 0.80 Belgium M 0.80 Germany L 0.78 Luxembourg S 0.78 Figure 17 Smaller countries have significantly better levels of intangible infrastructure Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100% of total Low score Large countries Medium sized countries Small countries Medium score High score SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 15
  • 16. Norway. A cluster of larger countries is led by Aus- tralia, the Netherlands and the UK. Other ‘resilient’ small countries are Finland, Austria, Sweden and New Zealand. We should highlight that there are some factors our model does not capture – the favorable effect of geography (proximity to China) on Singapore and Hong Kong SAR, the role of oil for Norway and transfer from the EU to smaller European states’. These have certainly helped small states, but we would argue that long-term success depends on the ability of policy makers to manage the bonuses as well as the risks posed to small states. What is perhaps more interesting are the countries that do not make the top echelons. Hungary, Cyprus, Por- tugal (classified as medium sized) and Estonia are grouped together below the top table and in the middle of the table, the UAE and some of the Caribbean states are grouped together – their scores are lower than the top group owing to lower readings for globalization, macro volatility and intangible infrastructure. Generally, speaking, the weaker nations in terms of our ‘Strength’ index tend to be African, both large and small states, States that have medium level ’Strength’ cores and that we think have the potential to move higher given HDI and macro vola- tility improvements might be Costa Rica, Serbia, Kuwait and Latvia. Figure 18 Small countries perform the best on most II metrics Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 Average scores Overall Index Education Healthcare Technology Financial services Business services Small Medium Large 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 USA China Japan USSR/Russia 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 No. of patents (in '000) Figure 19 Patent filings in large countries Source: Credit Suisse 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 No. of patents (in '000) 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 Switzerland Sweden Ireland Israel Figure 20 Patent filings in small countries Source: Credit Suisse SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 16
  • 17. A small country model? There is a considerable amount of analysis by international institutions such as the OECD and IMF, as well as think tanks (Bruegel is notable here with Andre Sapir’s analysis of socio-economic models) and academics on the notion that some countries are ‘models’ for others to follow. We are somewhat sceptical here in that the designation of a particular country as a model for others to follow invariably marks the peak in that country’s (hubris- tic) growth. Ireland and Turkey are two good recent examples. For the sake of argument and comparison, if we were to compare some of the economic, social and policy indicators for Scotland we find that it has some similarities to neighboring countries like Nor- way in terms of size, education, healthcare indica- tors and oil production (22% of GDP for Norway, 12% for Scotland assuming production is allocated on the basis of the median line principle). The recurring dilemma is that many of the ingre- dients that have contributed to one country’s suc- cess are very difficult to ‘cut and paste’ on to other nations. However, based on the broad literature on this subject and the findings that come through from the data, we would flag the following as being part of the ‘secret sauce’ of developing a small country: sense of strategic planning and an aware- ness of the impact that outside forces (markets, trade, immigration) can have on a small state as well as the institutional ability to implement policy in these fields. PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/STOCKCAM Table 5 Country strength index Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse Country Size Country strength index Switzerland S 0.87 Hong Kong SAR S 0.85 Singapore S 0.85 Denmark S 0.84 Netherlands M 0.83 Australia M 0.83 United Kingdom L 0.83 Belgium M 0.82 Ireland S 0.82 Norway S 0.82 Bottom 10 Afghanistan L 0.18 Myanmar L 0.18 Guinea-Bissau S 0.18 Niger M 0.18 Burundi S 0.17 Central African Rep. S 0.14 Congo, Dem. Rep. L 0.13 Chad M 0.11 Eritrea S 0.10 South Sudan S 0.08 SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 17
  • 19. Efficiencies or inefficiencies of scale? In an ideal world, larger countries should benefit from economies of scale in several areas related to public spending. The cost of nonrival public goods such as military spending, tangible infrastructure (roads, bridges, airports, etc), government or collecting taxes should be lower, on a per head basis, the larger the country’s population. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 19
  • 20. On the other hand, public services such as educa- tion or healthcare are driven by the number of stu- dents or patients; so the size of a country in terms of population should not have much influence on the per capita costs of these public services. However, if the definition of size includes or focuses on the geo- graphical size of the country, some of these costs would vary according to the population’s density. In general, most academic research supports the view above, that the public sector expenditures on a per capita basis is larger for smaller countries; larger coun- tries have in principle the ability to spread their cost over a larger pool of taxpayers. Our findings show a different story. Let us start with the big picture by first focusing on public spending and then how it is financed. Alesina and Spolaore in their 2003 book “The size of Nations” show that expenditures as a percentage of GDP are negatively correlated to size. They focus on a large sample of countries over 1986 to 1990. In our analysis, we find a very weak correlation between government spending and size (R2 =0.03). The results do not change much using either one year (2012), three years (2010-12) or five years (2008- 10). Note that we define size as a combination of population and physical size of the country. We get similar results when we look at the correlation of gov- ernment spending per capita with size. Figure 21 Government spending Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse R² = 0.0274 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Gov’t spending as % of GDP 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 PCA index value (country size) PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/FINTASTIQUE SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 20
  • 21. Figure 22 Spending on military as % of GDP Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse What is definitely more interesting is to look at the components of government spending. For example, spending on defense tends to be uncorrelated to size and spending on education as a percentage of GDP tends to be smaller for larger countries. As education gives a country a long-term growth advantage and there are some scale benefits (e.g., text books shared by a larger number of students), this is quite surprising. Public spending on healthcare shows again that small countries invest more in healthcare compared to large countries, but not a lot more. Finally, we ana- lyzed the data related to all salaries paid by the gov- ernment. This is the only result consistent with the theory of the economies of scale: it shows that larger countries tend to spend less relative to GDP on sala- ries (5% of GDP for large countries versus almost 8% for small countries). Salaries here are a good proxy for the direct cost of “governing” a country. However, the most surprising finding is on the fund- ing side of government expenditures. The core postulate of the economies of scale for public services, military capabilities, etc. is that the cost of these “services” on a per head basis should be lower for larger countries. Not really. Tax rates for individuals tend to be higher in larger countries, by a hefty 5 percentage points! We need to add indirect taxes to this analysis, but it is quite a compli- cated exercise. A qualitative analysis of a few countries suggests that the results above would not change. Figure 23 Spending on education as % of GDP Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 Spending on Education as % of GDP Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries Figure 24 Spending on healthcare as % of GDP Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 5.0 5.5 6.0 6.5 7.0 7.5 8.0 Healthcare expenditure as a % of GDP Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 Military spending as % of GDP Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries Figure 25 Compensation of public sector employees as % of GDP Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% Compensation of Employees (% of GDP) Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 21
  • 22. PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/DOUGALL_PHOTOGRAPHY Figure 26 Tax rate for individuals Source: KPMG, Credit Suisse 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 Average of highest marginal tax rate (individual) Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries Corporate taxes also look higher in large countries versus small countries by a full 7 percentage points. But is that really the case? Only in theory. If we look at corporate taxes as a percentage of GDP we will find that the opposite is true: 3.2% for small countries and 2.6% for big countries. The issue, we think, is corpo- rate tax management by large companies in large countries. Large corporations have subsidiaries abroad that allow them to minimize the tax burden at the home country level. So, in reality, in large countries few large corporations pay the marginal corporate rate. Another interesting area on the funding front is leverage. As we would expect small countries show less leverage and smaller fiscal deficits. Part of this is the “age” effect: small younger countries have lesser need to mortgage the future of the country as they have less “historical” welfare burden, as the accumula- tion time has been shorter. We could read this on the basis that less leverage carries less risk; but this might also reflect that smaller countries are more vulnerable as they have less access to the global capital markets and therefore they need to be more conservative. This was brought to light during the European crisis where the institutional framework of a larger ”commu- nity” allowed larger countries in the EU to contribute to the rescue of several smaller countries. At crisis time, the size effect (US or EU) is a clear positive as larger resources and funds can be pulled and channeled across to help smaller countries, states, or cities. Another way to explore the relative efficiency of countries is to measure the level of output or GDP rela- tive to the level of input. Milner and Weyman-Jones have written several papers10 on the topic, focusing on developing countries. Intuitively again, we would expect that larger countries should have a “production” scale advantage. Yet, the authors concluded that there is no simple correlation between a country’s size and its rela- tive efficiency rating, and that actually larger countries are more inefficient than smaller ones, albeit with a small statistical significance. The key factors for suc- cess based on their analysis is not size but education, healthcare and technology (i.e., the intangible infra- structure). This is confirmed by our own analysis which shows that smaller countries tend to have on average better intangible infrastructure than the larger ones. So there are some inefficiencies of scale, maybe more so than the much touted efficiencies of scale. Why? This might be explained in part by a natural trend of larger countries towards the decentralization of power. The larger the country, the more the need for local and regional governments to manage some of the key social services like education or police services. Decentralization also gives rise to transfers from the central government to the poorer regions or states to allow for a more balanced growth and relative wealth across the country. Transfers—a political tool to keep a country together— add complexity and may lead to dis- tortions and inefficiencies if not allocated properly (the 10 e.g. Milner, C., and T. Weyman-Jones (2003): “Relative National Efficiency and Country Size: Evidence for Developing Countries,” Review of Development Economics, 7(1), 1–14. Figure 28 Corporate tax revenue Source: OECD 2012, Credit Suisse Figure 27 Corporate taxes Source: KPMG, Credit Suisse 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Average of highest marginal tax rate (corporate) Small countries Medium sized countries Large countries 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 Corporate tax revenue (% GDP) Small Large SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 22
  • 23. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 23
  • 24. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 24
  • 25. Table 6 Heterogeneity scorecard Source: Alesina database, Credit Suisse Country Size Fractionalization index Kenya L 0.83 Cameroon M 0.82 Uganda L 0.82 South Africa L 0.82 Central African Republic S 0.81 Congo, Dem. Rep. (Zaire) L 0.81 Nigeria L 0.81 Zambia S 0.79 Chad S 0.78 Cote d'Ivoire M 0.78 Bottom 10 Iceland S 0.12 Bangladesh L 0.11 Greece S 0.11 Poland L 0.11 Norway S 0.11 Ireland S 0.10 Malta S 0.08 Portugal S 0.07 Tunisia S 0.02 Comoros S 0.01 perfect government has not yet been invented). This is further accentuated by the effects of heterogeneity. The more heterogeneous the population is or the more heterogeneous are the preferences of the pop- ulation, the higher is the cost of some services: edu- cation spending for example has to take into account the diversity of cultures and languages that exist in one country. Table 6 shows the top 10 countries under this metric (5 out of 10 are large ones) and the bottom 10 (8 out of 10 are small ones). Not surpris- ingly, the median fractionalization index of low HDI countries is 22% higher than that of high HDI coun- tries. In other words, the more homogeneous a coun- try is, the higher the HDI score is likely to be. The USA and the European Union provide a valuable illustration of this dynamic. In the USA, Federalism has added costs as each state has its own government infrastructure and ability to issue legislation. The result of this “government” structure is often overspending and higher deficits at the regional or local level. The same could be said about the European Union and the component states; 40% of the legislative acts of the EU concern agricultural policies, while agricul- ture represents less than 5% of European GDP. On the other hand, Switzerland provides an excellent example of very successful federalism— arguably a highly efficient form of decentralization. Switzerland had to be set up as a decentralized, federal state because of its linguistic and cultural as well as religious heterogeneity and the resulting fis- cal federalism is certainly one of the defining fea- tures of Switzerland’s political system and widely cited as one of the institutional reasons for the country’s economic success. So, we should not underestimate the power of a larger pool of coun- tries, states or regions or a larger country. The European Union has been able to “rescue” one of its member countries by “emergency” loans and the US Federal government rescued the auto industry (Detroit and surroundings) not Michigan State. So, size has some advantages. This is an important point as government size and economic growth tend to be negatively correlated. Several studies point to this link, which is particularly strong for richer countries. This effect is visible even when discounting the natural effect of increases in government spending during recessions. In other words, the size of a government beyond a certain level, creates inefficiencies in resource allocation and is not conducive to higher growth. Alouini and Hubert make a valid point on why we observe these inefficiencies of scale. It could be that the costs associated with large size countries—trans- portation, transactions and heterogeneity – or con- versely the benefits of smaller sized countries — homogeneity, density, higher efficiency and flexibility—helps explain why smaller countries tend to exhibit higher GDP growth or a higher HDI. PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/LINGBEEK SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 25
  • 26. SPECIAL FEATURE The break-up of CzechoslovakiaGergely Hudecz Following the collapse of communism, Czecho- slovakia undertook reforms to introduce a mar- ket-based system, but the transition was more costly for Slovakia than for the Czech Republic. Between 1990-92 the Czech Republic’s real GDP declined by around 15%, while Slovakia’s by about 22%. Unemployment was 2.6% in the Czech Republic but reached 10.4% in Slovakia in December 1992. There were no legal restrictions on migration, but labor mobility did not mitigate the adverse effects of the shock.1 The asymmetric shock led to the break-up of Czechoslovakia in 1993. Following the elections in 1992, centre-right parties in the Czech Repub- lic and a nationalist party in Slovakia were unable to agree about the redistribution of power between the federation and its constituent states, and decided to create two independent countries on 1 January 1993. The two sides agreed to divide immovable assets and territorial debt according to location, and other assets and fed- 1 Source: Fidrmuc et al. Stability of Monetary Unions: Lessons from the Break-up of Czechoslovakia, Transition Economics Series No. 10, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna eral debt proportional to their population (around 2:1 in favor of the Czech Republic). In the mean- time, fiscal transfers from the Czech Republic to Slovakia stopped (which may have reached as much as 8% of Slovakia’s GDP in 1992). The two newly independent states planned to maintain the common currency at least for the first half of 1993, but the lack of political commit- ment undermined the monetary union’s credibility. Capital transfers by Slovak residents to Czech commercial banks surged, presumably anticipat- ing a devaluation in Slovakia after the split. The Czech central bank initially attempted to balance the capital flow from Slovakia by credits to Slovak banks, but these became increasingly difficult to sustain and eventually the Czech government decided to separate the two currencies. The sep- aration was implemented on 8 February 1993, and the Slovak central bank decided to devalue its currency by 10% in July 1993. The break-up was more costly for Slovakia in the short run. In 1993, real GDP declined by 1% in the Czech Republic, while it fell by 4% in Slovakia, and by 1995 GDP per capita in Slovakia was only SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 26
  • 27. -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Year-on-year, % 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013 Germany Czech Republic Slovak Republic 60% 70% 80% 90% 100% GDP per capita in Slovakia compared to Czech Republic, PPP, % 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 Figure 29 Real GDP growth Source: Eurostat, Fidrmuc et al, International Monetary Fund, Credit Suisse Figure 30 Re-converging Source: International Monetary Fund, Credit Suisse around 68% of the Czech level, on purchasing- power-parity. Bilateral trade also declined signifi- cantly over the longer run: In 1991, around 50% of Slovakia’s foreign trade was with the Czech Repub- lic, but this dropped to about 25% by 1997. Czech trade with Slovakia declined from around 30% in 1991 to about 10% in 1997. However, such a sharp fall in bilateral trade suggests that the previ- ous interdependence was artificial, and the large public sectors were not developed according to comparative advantages. Integration with the EU mitigated the impact of the break-up to some extent, as much of the decline in Czech-Slovak trade reflected the growth in trade with other countries, in particular with the EU. Although the Czech Republic was the front-runner for EU integration initially, Slova- kia’s real GDP growth also rebounded sharply and the government change in 1998 opened the way for further reforms. Consequently, real GDP growth in Slovakia outpaced growth in the Czech Republic between 2001 and 2008, and the two countries joined the EU at the same time in 2004. Furthermore, Slovakia introduced the euro in 2009, and its GDP per capita almost reached the Czech level by 2014, on purchasing-power-parity. PHOTO: SHUTTERSTOCK.COM/BREZINA SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 27
  • 28. SPECIAL FEATURE German re-unificationChristel Aranda Hassel On the night of 9 November 1989, the wall dividing Berlin was breached starting negotiations that would culminate in a re-unified Germany. The monetary, economic and social union happened on 1 July 1990 followed by the political union on 3 October. For the first time in history, a capitalist and a socialist economy became one. To start with, all western institutions were transplanted to a large degree: justice, industrial relations, banking, edu- cation and social welfare. On the economic front, the West German gov- ernment decided to privatize the East German economy. This was carried out by the eastern Treu- handanstalt (THA, Trust Agency, commonly known as Treuhand). The agency became a politically independent body in charge of privatizing 8,500 previously state-owned enterprises containing 44,000 plants and accounting for nearly half of the eastern workforce. The THA closed unviable firms and plants, reduced employment at the viable plans and sought buyers for the remaining core busi- nesses which to a large extent became subsidiaries of western companies since two-thirds were sold to West German firms or families. At the end of 1994, the THA finished its privatization brief with net losses of nearly 11% of 1994 GDP. Other key economic decisions included convert- ing the exchange rate at 1:1 and a high wage strat- egy in the east dictated by strong labor unions. Generous financial transfers to the east saw east- ern GDP per capita and compensation rise sharply to start with. In the early years of re-unification the economic outcome of these decisions was a collapse in east- ern real GDP. It fell by nearly 16% and 23% in 1990 and 1991, respectively, resulting in the unemployment rate peaking above 20% in the sec- ond half of the 1990s. For the west and on the back of the positive aggregate demand shock, the early years of re-unification were boom years with GDP growth rates of more than 5%. A series of studies have looked into the causes of the sharp decline in eastern GDP and employ- ment. Often mentioned are the disruption of east- ern supply chains and the substitution to western goods resulting in a sudden fall in demand for east- ern goods and therefore output. The sharp reduc- tion in labor supply was also a factor. In 1989-92, employment in the east declined by more than 3 m people. Early retirement on western pension bene- fits was offered to more than 1 m and more than 1 m emigrated to the west. The rapid wage conver- gence with the west not mirrored by productivity did SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 28
  • 29. Figure 31 Remaining on convergence path Source: Bundesministerium des Innern: “Jahresbericht der Bundesregierung zum Stand der Deutschen Einheit 2013”,Credit Suisse 40 45 50 55 60 65 GDP per capita in east Germany compared to west Germany in %. West Germany = 100 70 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 Phase 1: Rapid convergence Phase 2: Structural adjustment Phase 3: Slow, continuous convergence not help either. It led to the whole of Germany see- ing double-digit wage growth in the early 1990s. Union power was only severely weakened after 1993. From 1990 to date, the net cost of re-unification has been estimated at around EUR 2 tn equivalent to two-thirds of Germany’s entire 2013 GDP. Pay- ments into the social security system account for 60-65% of that cost. The east, including Berlin, accounts for 20% of the German population but only for 15% of German GDP. Eastern GDP per capita, at just over 70% of the average western level, continues to converge slowly but the modest upward trend suggests that it will take many years to close the gap. Thanks to social transfers, the difference between eastern and western dispos- able income is less marked, with the east standing at over 80% of the average western level. It helps that the eastern labor market has improved. While the eastern unemployment rate was more than 10 pp higher than that of the west for many years, at 4 pp the current gap is the most narrow since Ger- many re-united. The political decision to integrate the east with the west as fast as possible was costly not only for Germany but the cost of adjustment spread also to the rest of Europe. High German wage growth trig- gered high interest rates in order to contain inflation but this led to the crisis of the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM), the forerunner of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). For Germany, it meant that in addition to the re-unification shock to inter- est rates it entered the monetary union with an overvalued exchange rate. PHOTO: SHUTTERSTOCK.COM/LINERPICS Re-unification was costly and remains costly. German households and companies continue to pay a solidarity surcharge tax introduced in 1991 even if nowadays more than half of east Germans and more than four-fifths in the west believe it should be removed. The good news, however, is that eastern Germany remains on the path of con- vergence. The German parliament in its most recent annual review on the stand of German re- unification talks about an ‘impressive’ re-industrial- isation of the east. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 29
  • 31. Cities and corporations “Globalization is the ongoing process of greater interdependence among countries and their citizens, and is complex and multifaceted.” Stanley Fischer – Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve and former managing director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 31
  • 32. Figure 32 Urbanization and prosperity Source: World Bank, Credit Suisse PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/HOLGS Cities With this in mind, it is not surprising to see that Hong Kong SAR or Singapore is among the coun- tries/states/regions with the highest GDP/capita or the highest HDI. We have showed that in a world of free trade, size does not matter. This applies also to city-states, with easy access to global markets via unique deepwater harbors. In addition, cities are the most efficient form of human settlement. History shows that the richest countries in the twelfth to fifteenth century were the city-states of Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam and Hamburg. Free trade, larger cities and small governments was a recipe for raising wealth and growth. This has been again the case in recent years: city- states have prospered and cities have become the most important engines of economic growth, particu- larly in developing economies. Five city-states are in the top 30 countries in HDI terms. Jakarta’s econ- omy is growing at twice the rate of growth of Indone- sia. Urbanization is a massive driver of growth and of wealth, as we have recently highlighted in the CSRI Emerging Capital Market Report.11 If we measure prosperity as GDP per capita, we can see that countries that have a higher proportion of the population in urban areas tend to show higher GDP per capita numbers. Using the HDI metric and dividing countries in four groups—from very high human development to low human development— we find that countries in the top group have a rate of urbanization of 81%, countries in the bottom group 34%. Not surprisingly, Tokyo’s GDP is more than three times that of Switzerland, New York City’s is more than twice that of Sweden and Mex- ico City’s is twice that of Finland. 11 https://www.credit-suisse.com/ch/en/news-and-expertise/ research/credit-suisse-research-institute/publications.html Burundi BelgiumBahrain Brazil China GermanySpain Equatorial Guinea India Ireland Jordan Kuwait St. Lucia Russia Singapore Sweden Trinidad and Tobago United States Venezuela R² = 0.5391 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 % of urban population 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 GDP per capita in USD (PPP) Figure 33 Cities within small countries Source: Brookings Institute, Credit Suisse 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Buenos Aires (Argentina) Santiago (Chile) Budapest (Hungary) Seoul-Incheon (South Korea) Tel Aviv (Israel) Vienna (Austria) Lima (Peru) Copenhagen (Denmark) Brussels (Belgium) Abu Dhabi (UAE) Singapore Hong Kong GDP (city as % of country) SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 32
  • 33. In this context, large cities can be considered 100% open economies, free to trade with the rest of the country. In addition, the higher concentration of the population allows for significant economies of scale in most public services (transport, healthcare, etc). Finally, cities thrive on services rather than manufacturing; services (banking, retail) are in gen- eral a higher-value-added sector and carry higher incomes. But what about heterogeneity? Social studies show that the diverse interests and demands of het- erogeneous groups tend to be softened by density and that the common interest of a well functioning city brings people closer together. Cities tend to attract “foreigners” (people from other cities, regions or countries) and “foreigners” want to inte- grate; the concept of city becomes the common denominator and a powerful unifying force. Polls show that higher density areas in cities are more open to immigration. City inhabitants also tend to be more practical and less ideological. New York City—one of the country’s Democratic strongholds can easily elect and live with Republican mayors (Bloomberg, Giuliani, etc.). Local issues in cities are to a large extent beyond parties, race or age and the demo- cratic process is much more direct and allows voters much more control and influence. Cities are charac- terized by a pro-business attitude, openness, global connections, relatively good education and in most cases a pragmatic and modern governance. Table 7 Large cities vs. small countries Source: Brookings Institution 2012, World Bank City GDP in USD bn (PPP) Tokyo 1519.4 New York City 1209.6 Los Angeles 786.7 Seoul 773.8 London 731.2 Paris 669.2 Osaka-Kobe 654.8 Chicago 524.6 Moscow 520.1 Shanghai 516.4 Sao Paulo 472.9 Cologne 465.1 Beijing 427.1 Washington 415.2 Mexico City 411.3 Houston 399.7 Dallas 368 Nagoya 366.9 Hong Kong SAR 350.4 Buenos Aires 348.4 Singapore 327.2 Country GDP in USD bn (PPP) UAE 534.3 Switzerland 425.3 Sweden 408 Austria 371.9 Norway 331.9 Qatar 282.2 Kuwait 278.4 Israel 247.9 Denmark 239.1 Hungary 224.5 Finland 212.2 Ireland 201.1 Belarus 162.4 Ecuador 156.1 New Zealand 145.9 SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 33
  • 34. Figure 34 Revenue distribution Source: Thomson Reuters DataStream, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service, Credit Suisse Corporations One of the first and more prescient definitions of globalization came in 1983 in a paper by Theodore Levitt, professor of mar- keting at Harvard. Levitt wrote that: The globalization of markets is at hand. With that, the multina- tional commercial world nears its end, and so does the multi- national corporation. The multinational and the global corpora- tion are not the same thing. The multinational corporation operates in a number of countries, and adjusts its products and practices in each – at high relative costs. The global cor- poration operates with resolute constancy – at low relative cost – as if the entire world were a single entity, it sells the same things in the same way everywhere12 . His distinction between multinational and global companies is crucial to understanding how globalization differs from internation- alization. A multinational company tends to replicate itself on a regional or national basis, building planning, marketing, production and distribution operations in each area. Conversely, a truly global corporation can locate its production operations in one country, marketing in another and be headquartered in yet another country. Companies are an integral part of the framework of a country and provide a significant engine for economic growth. Among the top 12 Theodore Levitt, ‘The Globalization of markets’, Harvard Business Review, May/June 1983, p.2. 500 companies by market capitalization, 86% are based in large countries, 5% in medium-size countries and 9% in small countries. Large countries provide a large domestic market that allows most companies to grow without the need to embark at the early stages in a foreign expansion. Should we thus deduce that large countries are the main beneficiaries of the development of large corporations? Not necessarily. We divided the top 100 companies by market capitalization (we worked on smaller sample, just to illus- trate the point) into multinationals (more than 50% of rev- enue generated by foreign subsidiaries), locals (less than 10% of revenues from foreign subsidiaries) and mixed (between 10-50% of revenues generated by foreign sub- sidiaries). Almost 50% of our sample is made of companies where foreign subsidiaries account for over half of revenues and only 22 of the 100 companies we considered could be considered tied just to the home country. But even local companies source goods (manufactur- ing) and services (call centers) from abroad. So in a world of free trade, large local companies do not impact just the home country. This is even more evident for 50% of our sample, multinationals. Data from the U.S. Commerce Department show that, at the end of 2009, U.S. multina- tionals employed 21 million people at home (20% of the total workforce) and 10 million people abroad. According to a 2010 Business Impact Report, 20 Dutch multination- als have a positive direct impact outside Holland on 4.2 Figure 35 Most companies located in large countries Source: Thomson Reuters DataStream, the BLOOMBERG PROFESSIONAL™ service, Credit Suisse Small 9% Medium 5% Large 86% Local 22% Multinationals 43% Combination 35% PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/ONFILM SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 34
  • 35. million people (commercial activities) and indirectly benefited another 4 million through philanthropic programs. Not all is good news, though. From 2000 to 2009, U.S. mul- tinationals reduced jobs at home by 2.9 million, but created 2.4 million jobs abroad. In 2009, undoubtedly a very tough year for the global economy, these same multinationals cut 5% of their U.S. based workforce (1.2 million people), but only 1% of their workforce abroad (100,000 people). The impact of globalization on the host countries has been at the center of considerable debate. We reviewed several papers and articles and came to a few basic conclusions in the context of our analysis of large versus small countries. •• First, we did not find that multinationals or large corpora- tions tend to invest significantly more in large host countries than in small ones. It varies a lot from sector to sector. Several small countries tend to have a highly educated and specialized work force that is extremely attractive to compa- nies in sectors such as tech, for example. Other countries provide large pools of labor at very competitive rates. In addition, several host countries provide very attractive tax rebates and the ability to minimize the overall tax burden— corporate taxes paid as a percentage of GDP are larger for small countries than for larger ones. •• Second, it is difficult to generalize the impact of large corpora- tion or multinationals on host countries. In some cases, the effect has been incredibly positive: job creation, overall wage increases across the whole country’s workforce, higher educa- tion, and better living standards. In other cases, the out- come has been quite negative, as the safety standards of some corporations abroad did not match their home standards. •• Third, in a world of free trade of goods and people, companies have evolved to consider the whole world not only as a market for their products and services, but also as a source of talented or attractively priced labor (we hate the word cheap) to foster growth and profitability. The overall effect has been higher pro- ductivity and higher global growth, with clear benefits for all those who participated either in the home or in the host countries.13 In conclusion, while it is true that large corporations are more likely to develop initially in large countries, they are also likely to expand quickly beyond the home boundaries, benefiting the rest of the world. A successful small country can benefit from this global trend by investing in education and specializing to provide services that might be signifi- cantly more expensive or not available at all in larger host countries. Singapore, Iceland and Switzerland are great examples of success stories in the growing trend towards specialization. 13 On the potential implications for publicly traded companies of a “yes” choice in the 18 of September vote in Scotland, we suggest reading an excellent paper by Paul Marsh and Scott Evans “The Scotsie 100: Sixty Years of Scottish Stocks.” SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 35
  • 36. PHOTO:ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/LAGUI SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 36 References Aghion, P., and A. Banerjee (eds.) (2005): Volatility and Growth, Clarendon Lectures in Economics. Oxford University Press, USA. Alcalá, F., Ciccone, A. (2004). “Trade and productivity”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (2), 613–646. Alesina, A., Baqir, R., Hoxby, C. (2004). “Political jurisdictions in heterogeneous communities”. Journal of Political Economy 112 (2), 348–396. Alesina, A., Spolaore, E. (2003). The Size of Nations. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Alesina, A., E. Spolaore, and R. Wacziarg (2005): “Trade, Growth and the Size of Countries,” in Handbook of Economic Growth, ed. by P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf, vol. 1 of Handbook of Economic Growth, chap. 23, pp. 1499–1542. Elsevier. Alouini O. and P. Hubert (2014): “Country Size, Economic Performance and Volatility”. Working Paper, http://hubertpaul.free.fr/ Baldwin, R. E. (2003): “Openness and Growth: What’s the Empirical Relationship?,” NBER Working Papers 9578, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Frankel, J.A., Romer, D. (1999). “Does trade cause growth?”. American Economic Review 89 (3), 379–399. Furceri, D., and G. Karras (2007): “Country size and business cycle volatility: Scale really matters,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 21(4), 424–434. Grossman, G., Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Lloyd, P. J., and R. M. Sundrum (1982): “Characteristics of Small Economies,” in Problems and Policies in Small Economies, ed. by B. Jalan, pp. 17–38. Commonwealth Secretariat and Croom Helm, London. Marsh, Paul and Evans, Scott (2014) “The Scotsie 100: Sixty Years of Scottish Stocks.” Milner, C., and T. Weyman-Jones (2003): “Relative National Efficiency and Country Size: Evidence for Developing Countries,” Review of Development Economics, 7(1), 1–14. Rose, A. K. (2006): “Size really doesn’t matter: In search of a national scale effect,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 20(4), 482–507. Salvatore, D. (2001): “Defining country size,” in Small countries in a global economy: new challenges and opportunities, ed. by D. Salvatore, M. Svetlicic, and J. P. Damijan, pp. xii, 305 p. :. Palgrave, Basingstoke. Spolaore, E. (2002). “Conflict, trade and the size of countries”. Working Paper. Brown University. Spolaore, E. (2005). “The political economy of national borders”. In: Weingast, B.R., Wittman, D. (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, in preparation. Spolaore, E., Wacziarg, R. (2005). “Borders and growth”. Journal of Economic Growth 10 (4), in press. Wacziarg, R. (2001). “Measuring the dynamic gains from trade”.World Bank Economic Review 15 (3), 393–429. Wacziarg, R., Welch, K.H. (2003). “Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence”. NBER Working Paper 10152, December.
  • 37. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 37
  • 38. Also published by the Research Institute Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2014 February 2014 Latin America: The long road February 2014 Emerging Consumer Survey 2014 February 2014 Emerging capital markets: The road to 2030 July 2014 Family businesses: Sustaining performance September 2012 Opportunities in an urbanizing world April 2012 Gender diversity and corporate performance August 2012 Global Wealth Report 2012 October 2012 Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2012 January 2012 The shale revolution December 2012 Emerging Consumer Survey 2013 January 2013 Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2013 February 2013 Sugar Consumption at a crossroads September 2013 Global Wealth Report 2013 October 2013 SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 38
  • 39. SUCCESS OF SMALL COUNTRIES 39 General disclaimer / Important information This document was produced by and the opinions expressed are those of Credit Suisse as of the date of writing and are subject to change. It has been prepared solely for information purposes and for the use of the recipient. It does not constitute an offer or an invitation by or on behalf of Credit Suisse to any person to buy or sell any security. Nothing in this material constitutes investment, legal, accounting or tax advice, or a representation that any investment or strategy is suitable or appropriate to your individual circumstances, or otherwise constitutes a personal recommendation to you. The price and value of investments mentioned and any income that might accrue may fluctuate and may fall or rise. Any reference to past performance is not a guide to the future. The information and analysis contained in this publication have been compiled or arrived at from sources believed to be reliable but Credit Suisse does not make any representation as to their accuracy or completeness and does not accept liability for any loss arising from the use hereof. A Credit Suisse Group company may have acted upon the information and analysis contained in this publication before being made available to clients of Credit Suisse. Investments in emerging markets are speculative and considerably more volatile than investments in established markets. Some of the main risks are political risks, economic risks, credit risks, currency risks and market risks. Investments in foreign currencies are subject to exchange rate fluctuations. Before entering into any transaction, you should consider the suitability of the transaction to your particular circumstances and independently review (with your professional advisers as necessary) the specific financial risks as well as legal, regulatory, credit, tax and accounting consequences. This document is issued and distributed in the United States by Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC, a U.S. registered broker-dealer; in Canada by Credit Suisse Securities (Canada), Inc.; and in Brazil by Banco de Investimentos Credit Suisse (Brasil) S.A. This document is distributed in Switzerland by Credit Suisse AG, a Swiss bank. Credit Suisse is authorized and regulated by the Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority (FINMA). This document is issued and distributed in Europe (except Switzerland) by Credit Suisse (UK) Limited and Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited. Credit Suisse Securities (Europe) Limited and Credit Suisse (UK) Limited, both authorized by the Prudential Regulation Authority and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority, are associated but independent legal entities within Credit Suisse. The protections made available by the Financial Conduct Authority and/or the Prudential Regulation Authority for retail clients do not apply to investments or services provided by a person outside the UK, nor will the Financial Services Compensation Scheme be available if the issuer of the investment fails to meet its obligations. This document is distributed in Guernsey by Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, an independent legal entity registered in Guernsey under 15197, with its registered address at Helvetia Court, Les Echelons, South Esplanade, St Peter Port, Guernsey. Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited is wholly owned by Credit Suisse AG and is regulated by the Guernsey Financial Services Commission. Copies of the latest audited accounts are available on request. This document is distributed in Jersey by Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, Jersey Branch, which is regulated by the Jersey Financial Services Commission. The business address of Credit Suisse (Channel Islands) Limited, Jersey Branch, in Jersey is: TradeWind House, 22 Esplanade, St Helier, Jersey JE2 3QA. This document has been issued in Asia-Pacific by whichever of the following is the appropriately authorised entity of the relevant jurisdiction: in Hong Kong SAR by Credit Suisse (Hong Kong) Limited, a corporation licensed with the Hong Kong Securities and Futures Commission or Credit Suisse Hong Kong branch, an Authorized Institution regulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority and a Registered Institution regulated by the Securities and Futures Ordinance (Chapter 571 of the Laws of Hong Kong); in Japan by Credit Suisse Securities (Japan) Limited; elsewhere in Asia/Pacific by whichever of the following is the appropriately authorized entity in the relevant jurisdiction: Credit Suisse Equities (Australia) Limited, Credit Suisse Securities (Thailand) Limited, Credit Suisse Securities (Malaysia) Sdn Bhd, Credit Suisse AG,  Singapore Branch,  and elsewhere in the world by the relevant authorized affiliate of the above. This document may not be reproduced either in whole, or in part, without the written permission of the authors and Credit Suisse. © 2014 Credit Suisse Group AG and/or its affiliates. All rights reserved PUBLISHER CREDIT SUISSE AG Research Institute Paradeplatz 8 CH-8070 Zurich Switzerland cs.researchinstitute@credit-suisse.com PRODUCTION MANAGEMENT INVESTMENT STRATEGY & RESEARCH INVESTMENT PUBLISHING Markus Kleeb (Head) Ross Hewitt Katharina Schlatter AUTHORS Stefano Natella Michael O’Sullivan CONTRIBUTORS Nilanjan Das Utkarsh Goklani Christel Aranda Hassel Gergely Hudecz Shailesh Jha Prateek Nigudkar Vinit Sinha EDITORIAL DEADLINE 25 July 2014 ADDITIONAL COPIES Additional copies of this publication can be ordered via the Credit Suisse publication shop www.credit-suisse.com/publications or via your customer advisor. Imprint
  • 40. RCE154590407/2014 CREDIT SUISSE AG Research Institute Paradeplatz 8 CH-8070 Zurich Switzerland cs.researchinstitute@credit-suisse.com www.credit-suisse.com/researchinstitute neutral Printed Matter No. 01-14-316782 – www.myclimate.org © myclimate – The Climate Protection Partnership PERFORMANCE