• Like
Monopoly
Upcoming SlideShare
Loading in...5
×

Monopoly

  • 4,400 views
Uploaded on

Monopoly

Monopoly

  • Full Name Full Name Comment goes here.
    Are you sure you want to
    Your message goes here
    Be the first to comment
    Be the first to like this
No Downloads

Views

Total Views
4,400
On Slideshare
0
From Embeds
0
Number of Embeds
3

Actions

Shares
Downloads
46
Comments
0
Likes
0

Embeds 0

No embeds

Report content

Flagged as inappropriate Flag as inappropriate
Flag as inappropriate

Select your reason for flagging this presentation as inappropriate.

Cancel
    No notes for slide
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • Perfect Competition\n\nIn this video we’re going to talk about Perfect Competition.\n\nFirst we’ll draw and label our price-quantity graph.\n\nThen we’ll draw the demand curve.\n\nRemember that under perfect competition there is one price level for all individual sellers. This means the demand curve is flat. This also means the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. So price and demand and marginal revenue are all on the same line.\n\nSo the first question we want to answer is “At what level should we produce to maximize profits?” We always answer this question with the equation MR=MC.\nSo we need to see a marginal cost curve. This curve is a “U-shape” to indicate that costs typically tend to decline and then increase. \n\nNow that we have a MR and a MC curve we can pin-point the intersection. \n\nThe next step is to draw a vertical line down to the Quantity axis. This line will point to the quantity we should produce to maximize profits. \n\nWe can then calculate Total Revenue. This is P times Q, or this area.\n\nThe next step is to calculate Total Costs. Total Costs are calculated as ATC x Q. We need the ATC curve to do this. Once we know the ATC then we pin-point the intersection of the ATC curve and the vertical line we drew. Then we daw a horizontal line from this point over to the price axis. The area below this line represents our total costs. \n\nNow we can calculate profits. The equation is TR -TC, or another way is (Price-ATC) x Q. \n\nLet’s quickly review. We start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. We then look at the Average Total Cost curve and pinpoint where it crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area below this line is Total Cost and the area above is profit. \n\nLets look at another example.\n\nWe start with a flat demand curve which is also our marginal revenue curve. We then add a marginal cost curve. Using MR=MR we pinpoint the profit maximizing location and draw a line down to quantity. This are is total revenue. In this case the ATC curve is above the price line. If this is the case we will be looking for the location that minimizes losses. We pinpoint where ATC crosses our line and then draw a horizontal line. The area is Total Cost. Since Total Costs are larger than Total Revenue, this area represents our losses. Remember that using MC=MR we can figure out where our losses are minimized. \n\nAlright, now you know how to analyze Perfect Competition. \n\nDon’t forget you can rewind this video to make sure you understand how the graph works.\n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n
  • \n

Transcript

  • 1. Microeconomics Monopoly andAnti-Trust Policy
  • 2. Perfect Monopoly CompetitionNumber of Firms Many OneType of Product Identical Unique Ease of Entry Easy Blocked Demand D = MR D > MR Commodities Utilities Examples Rice Government Apples
  • 3. Perfect Monopoly CompetitionNumber of Firms Many OneType of Product Identical Unique Ease of Entry Easy Blocked Demand D = MR D > MR Commodities Utilities Examples Rice Government Apples
  • 4. Perfect Monopoly CompetitionNumber of Firms Many OneType of Product Identical Unique Ease of Entry Easy Blocked Demand D = MR D > MR Commodities Utilities Examples Rice Government Apples
  • 5. Monopoly
  • 6. Monopoly Only SellerNo Close Substitutes
  • 7. Barriers to Entry
  • 8. Barriers to EntryGovernment Protection Key ResourceNetwork Externalities Economies of Scale
  • 9. PatentsCopyrights
  • 10. Patents 20 Years CopyrightsLifetime plus 70 Years
  • 11. Franchise
  • 12. FranchiseExclusive Legal Provider
  • 13. New Drugs
  • 14. New Drugs 10 Years of Testing before Approval10 Years of Monopoly
  • 15. Network Externalities
  • 16. Network ExternalitiesThe more who use itThe more valuable it becomes
  • 17. Natural Monopoly
  • 18. Natural Monopoly One firm can supplyentire market at a loweraverage cost than two or more firms
  • 19. Natural Monopoly
  • 20. Natural Monopoly The more I makethe lower my costsLarge Fixed Costs
  • 21. Is competition always good?
  • 22. Is competition always good?Sometimes it can lead to higher prices
  • 23. MonopolyOutput and Price
  • 24. Monopoly Output and Price Lower Price: Good: Sell MoreBad: Less Revenue Per Unit
  • 25. Perfect Competition
  • 26. Perfect Competition$ Quantity
  • 27. Perfect Competition$P Demand=MR Quantity
  • 28. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MCP Demand=MR Quantity
  • 29. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MCP Demand=MR Quantity
  • 30. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MCP Demand=MR Quantity Q
  • 31. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MCP Demand=MR Total Revenue Quantity Q
  • 32. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATCP Demand=MR Total Revenue Quantity Q
  • 33. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATCP Demand=MR Total Revenue Quantity Q
  • 34. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATCP Demand=MR Total Cost Quantity Q
  • 35. Perfect Competition$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATCP Demand=MR Profit Total Cost Quantity Q
  • 36. Perfect Competition
  • 37. Perfect Competition Demand
  • 38. Perfect Competition Demand MR
  • 39. Perfect Competition Demand = MR
  • 40. Monopoly Demand MR
  • 41. Monopoly MR Demand
  • 42. Monopoly Demand MR
  • 43. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR12345Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 44. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR12345Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 45. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 46. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 47. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 48. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 49. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 50. Perfect Competition MonopolyQ D TR MR D TR MR1 $3 $3 $3 $5 $5 $52 $3 $6 $3 $4 $8 $33 $3 $9 $3 $3 $9 $14 $3 $12 $3 $2 $8 -$15 $3 $15 $3 $1 $5 -$3Monopoly: To get more Quantity must lower price
  • 51. Perfect Competition Demand
  • 52. Perfect Competition Demand = MR
  • 53. Monopoly Demand MR
  • 54. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain MonopolyPrice $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 55. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 56. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 57. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 58. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 59. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 60. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 61. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 62. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 63. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1Price $5 Lose $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 64. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $5 Lose $4 $3 Gain $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 65. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $5 Lose $4 $3 Gain $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 66. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $5 Lose $4 $3 Gain $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 67. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 68. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 69. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 70. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 71. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $5 $4 Lose $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 72. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $4 Lose $3 $2 Gain Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 73. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 74. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 75. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 76. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 77. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $4 $3 Lose $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 78. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $3 Lose $2 Demand Gain $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 79. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 80. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 81. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 82. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 83. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $3 $2 Lose Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 84. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Lose Demand $1 Gain $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 85. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 86. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 87. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 88. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 89. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty
  • 90. Price Qty TR MR Lose Gain Monopoly $5 1 $5 $5 $4 2 $8 $3 -$1 $4Price $3 3 $9 $1 -$2 $3 $5 $2 4 $8 -$1 -$3 $2 $4 $1 5 $5 -$3 -$4 $1 $3 $2 Demand $1 $0 1 2 3 4 5 Qty Marginal Revenue MR
  • 91. Monopoly$ Q
  • 92. Monopoly$ Demand Q
  • 93. Monopoly$ Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q
  • 94. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q
  • 95. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC 1. MR=MC? Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q
  • 96. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC 1. MR=MC? Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q
  • 97. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC 1. MR=MC? Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 98. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC 1. MR=MC?P Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 99. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 100. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 101. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 102. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 103. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 104. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 105. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 106. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 107. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 108. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P Profit 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 109. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost MC Average Cost ATC 1. MR=MC?P Profit 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 110. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost Consumer MC Average Cost Surplus ATC 1. MR=MC?P Profit 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 111. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost Consumer MC Average Cost Surplus ATC 1. MR=MC?P Profit 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 112. Monopoly$ Marginal Cost Consumer MC Average Cost Surplus ATC Deadweight 1. MR=MC?P Loss Profit 2. TR= P x Q 3. TC=ATC x Q 4. Profit =TR-TC or (P-ATC) x Q Cost Demand Marginal Revenue MR Q Q
  • 113. Antitrust Laws
  • 114. Antitrust LawsCollusion Felony